3.1. CGE Model
This research constructs a CGE model to evaluate the impacts of the CBAM on carbon emission reductions and industrial production in China. The CGE model is a recognized and widely utilized approach for conducting dynamic simulations of the energy-economy system and assessing the effects of policy measures [
22]. For instance, ref. [
23] utilized the CGE model to assess the contributions of BECCS technology and forest carbon sinks to China’s pursuit of carbon neutrality, whereas ref. [
24] leveraged it to analyze the economic consequences of BECCS technology in advancing China’s deep decarbonization efforts. Furthermore, ref. [
25] developed an energy-economy-environment model grounded in the CGE framework to explore the carbon market’s contribution to China’s objective of achieving a carbon peak by 2030. Drawing on previous studies, this paper integrates CBAM policy shocks into a DCGE model to establish a CGE framework that includes CBAM considerations. This enables us to examine the effects of CBAM policy shocks on carbon emissions and industrial production. The CGE model presented in this study encompasses four primary modules: production function, income-expenditure, trade, and energy-environment, as depicted in
Figure 2.
Initially, the production function is characterized through the application of a hierarchical Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) function. Within this framework, the highest-tier CES function encompasses both factor inputs and intermediate inputs. Factor inputs comprise labor, capital, and energy inputs, all of which are also delineated using multi-tiered hierarchical CES functions. The intermediate input employs the Leontief function, which implies a structure with unchanging intermediate input proportions. The income-expenditure module illustrates the circulation of income among the government, businesses, households, and overseas entities. Each participant either spends or earns returns from other participants. In the production process, firms procure labor and capital from the factor market and compensate for these inputs accordingly. Labor compensation is allocated to residents, whereas capital compensation is distributed among residents, businesses, and foreign entities. The government collects value-added tax from the production sector, corporate income tax from domestic businesses, personal income tax from households, and tariffs on imported goods. Concurrently, the government disburses transfer payments to residents and offers export rebates for exported goods.
The commerce module delineates how domestic companies allocate their products across both domestic and international markets, as well as how domestic consumers decide between domestically produced and imported items. The aggregate output from production activities is apportioned to domestic supply and exports through the Constant Elasticity of Transformation (CET) function. Imported and domestic supplies collectively constitute the Armington supply. Based on [
26] theory, products within an identical industry are distinguished by their source. Items originating from the same nation are entirely interchangeable, while those from distinct nations are not.
The energy-ecology module demonstrates the influence of energy inputs on the ecological system. By adopting the methodologies of [
27,
28], energy inputs are classified into non-electrical and electrical energy categories. Non-electrical energy encompasses coal, coal-based products, natural gas, petroleum-based products, and thermal energy. Electrical energy, which includes electricity generation and transmission/distribution, is represented using the Leontief function. Power generation sources are divided into stable (such as coal, gas, hydro, and nuclear power) and unstable types (like wind and solar photovoltaic power, owing to their fluctuating output). The ecological module monitors sulfur dioxide, nitrogen oxides, additional pollutants, and carbon emissions. Excluding intermediate inputs and electricity, which are specified by the Leontief production function, all remaining elements employ a production function with a fixed substitution elasticity, denoted by σ.
The detailed calculation method of the CGE model can be referenced in [
29]. Considering that CBAM mainly exerts its influence through taxation and foreign trade mechanisms, here we introduce the relevant module. The Settings of the elastic parameters therein are shown in
Appendix A.3.
The output of production is divided into two parts. One refers to the supply of domestic goods and the other refers to the export of goods. The substitute relationship can be depicted by Formulas (1)–(3), where
represents the output of sector
,
is the domestic product for domestic supply of sector
,
is the export of sector
.
is the scale factor,
is the share factor,
is a coefficient determined by substitute elasticity.
The export price can be calculated by the foreign price
, the exchange rate
, and the export tax ratio
, which can be explained by Formula (4). When the export tax ratio increases, under the condition of the same foreign prices, the tax-excluded export prices of domestic producers decrease, and exports decline. Meanwhile, the income of the producers has decreased. Through the adjustment of the export tax ratio, the CBAM-induced taxation can be integrated into the CGE model.
The dynamic framework employs a recursive approach to determine the model’s dynamic parameters, computing the sequential parameter values for subsequent stages based on the outcomes from preceding ones. For assessing capital accumulation, this study utilizes the Perpetual Inventory Method (PIM) introduced by [
29]. The capital buildup in the current period is derived from the capital stock of the prior period, investments made in the current period, and the depreciation rate. The PIM formula is presented as follows:
This method is currently the most popular one for measuring capital stock. Among them, represents the depreciation rate, represents the capital depreciation rate, represents the current investment amount, and represents the current price of the investment commodity.
3.2. CBAM Shock Setting
The CBAM encompasses six key sectors: iron and steel, cement, aluminum, fertilizers, electricity generation, hydrogen production, and indirect emissions under certain circumstances. This article sets the impact of CBAM on various industries based on the proportion of EU exports to the corresponding industries in China and the CBAM tax rate. The tax rates of the industries involved in CBAM are shown in
Table 3.
Meanwhile, there was an exemption amount at the beginning of the collection of CBAM, but the free quota gradually decreased. Among them, the free quota factor of the corresponding industry of EU ETS will decrease in proportion as shown in
Table 4. Therefore, in the dynamic model, we increase the export cost year by year according to the ratio of the quota to be taxed.
This paper constructs two scenarios based on whether it is impacted by the CBAM policy: the benchmark scenario that is not impacted by the policy and the scenario that considers the impact of the CBAM policy shock. Based on the differences in tax policies under the two scenarios, the impact of CBAM on China’s carbon emissions and macroeconomy is further analyzed. In the short term, the EU will only impose carbon tariffs on five high energy-consuming industries: electricity, steel, cement, aluminum, and fertilizers. In the long term, while the EU will maintain taxation on the import value of the above five major industries, it will also start to impose tariffs on imported products of other industries.
3.3. Data Source
The foundational data for the model is sourced from the 2017 China Input-Output Table, and the construction of the social accounting matrix follows the approach outlined by [
22]. The 2017 China Input-Output Table encompasses 149 product sectors. To streamline the analysis, this study has consolidated and reclassified these sectors. Specifically, drawing on GTAP input-output data [
30], the power and heat production and supply sectors were subdivided into eight categories: power transmission and distribution, coal-powered generation, gas-powered generation, hydroelectric power, nuclear power, wind power, photovoltaic power, and heating. Additionally, the extraction of oil and natural gas was separated into distinct categories.
In terms of population trends, based on United Nations population projections, the anticipated growth rates of the working-age population for the periods 2020–2025, 2025–2030, 2030–2035, 2035–2040, 2040–2045, and 2045–2050 are −0.54%, −2.00%, −4.38%, −4.77%, −3.04%, and −3.75%, respectively. According to the “2017 Statistical Data Report on the Total Social Financing Scale,” the total social financing scale in 2017 amounted to 174.64 trillion yuan. Based on the input-output table, the depreciation of fixed capital in 2017 was 11.03 trillion yuan, yielding a corresponding depreciation rate of 6.32%.