Next Article in Journal
Nonlinear Moving Boundary Model of Low-Permeability Reservoir
Next Article in Special Issue
Pro-Ecological Energy Attitudes towards Renewable Energy Investments before the Pandemic and European Energy Crisis: A Segmentation-Based Approach
Previous Article in Journal
Environmental and Energetic Valorization of Renewable Resources
Previous Article in Special Issue
Bank as a Stakeholder in the Financing of Renewable Energy Sources. Recommendations and Policy Implications for Poland
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditures in EU Countries

by
Alan Barrell
1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9,
Pawel Dobrzanski
10,11,*,
Sebastian Bobowski
12,
Krzysztof Siuda
11 and
Szymon Chmielowiec
9
1
Cambridge Worldwide Associates, Cambridge CB2 8PW, UK
2
Wivenhoe Park, University of Essex, Colchester CO4 3SQ, UK
3
Centre for Entrepreneurial Learning, Judge Business School, University of Cambridge, Cambridge CB2 1QA, UK
4
Ashcroft Business School, Anglia Ruskin University, Cambridge CB1 1PT, UK
5
Cambridge Rare Diseases Network, Cambridge CB22 5NE, UK
6
Aavagen Oy, 20750 Turku, Finland
7
School of Economics, Liaoning University, Shenyang 110036, China
8
China Future Creative Class (CFCC) Ltd., St. John’s Innovation Centre, Cambridge CB4 0WS, UK
9
The Cambridge Learning Gateway, St. John’s Innovation Centre, Cambridge CB4 0WS, UK
10
Minda de Gunzburg Center for European Studies (CES), Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA
11
Department of Mathematical Economics, Wroclaw University of Economics and Business, 53-345 Wroclaw, Poland
12
Department of International Economic Relations, Wroclaw University of Economics and Business, 53-345 Wroclaw, Poland
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2021, 14(24), 8443; https://doi.org/10.3390/en14248443
Submission received: 9 November 2021 / Revised: 4 December 2021 / Accepted: 7 December 2021 / Published: 14 December 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Investment Analysis of Renewable Energy)

Abstract

:
Environmental protection policy is a widely discussed issue in scientific works. However, special attention should be also paid to the effectiveness of expenditures on environmental protection, and this is the main goal of this paper. The countries of the European Union were selected for this analysis due to the fact that, in recent years, this region has become an informal world leader with respect to the implementation of policy measures in the field of environmental protection. For that reason, the data envelopment analysis methodology was used, which allows the calculation of input-output efficiency for the years 2005–2015. The analysis shows that, among the 30 analyzed countries, the most effective in environmental protection actions is Finland. The hypothesis that higher environmental protection expenditures does not result in better environmental results has been confirmed. Our analysis confirmed the problem of the deteriorating efficiency of environmental expenditures across the selected European Union Member States, caused by increases in spending. This research may contribute to the discussion on environmental protection policy design and its assessment, as well as environmental policy results measurement.

1. Introduction

Climate change and pollution are among the most serious challenges facing the world today. Therefore, in March 2007, the EU Heads of State and Government endorsed the European Commission’s integrated strategy on climate change and energy, which sets out the EU’s proposals for a global and comprehensive agreement to combat climate change after 2012, when the targets under the Kyoto Protocol expire. In Paris in December 2015, 195 countries (practically the whole world) agreed to the first-ever legally binding global deal to tackle climate change. In the EU and around the world, governments, companies and individuals are already working to tackle its causes and adapt to the changes it brings. Environmental protection expenditure are related to preventing, reducing and eliminating pollution and any other degradation of the environment, and in EU-27, they increased from 2006 to 2019 by 34%.
However, environmental protection expenditures used to be neglected as a category of public expenditures in favor of, mainly, education, social security and healthcare. On the other hand, however, environmental protection fits perfectly into the category of public goods due to its shared consumption and gains, as well as its limited spectrum of exceptions, related to, among others, water- or land-based assets [1]. Expenditures on environmental protection address market failures with respect to externalities related to the environment [2], which are considered important determinants of environmental quality [3,4,5,6,7,8]. Depending on the set of pollutants considered and environmental components, i.e., the water, air or land to be impacted, jurisdiction can be either local, regional or global. Considering the fact that public goods are underprovided in a market economy, as classic public finance theory states, the institution of the state is expected to deliver them, even though that can be inefficient when compared to the provision of public goods by private sector. In fact, in the case of environmental protection expenditures, the role of the private sector is more and more substantial, resulting from the characteristics of environmental regulations that set some standards or enhance the self-regulation of the corporate sector. Importantly, there is a trend toward the privatization of utilities such as water and energy, which enhances the recategorization of some public environmental protection expenditures as private [1]. The empirical evidence of the impact of privatization on environmental protection expenditures is at least ambiguous to date. Recent studies by Xing and Tan [9] indicated that, in the case of high marginal environmental damage, the impact of privatization on social welfare results in the environmental policy of public enterprises, as well as environmental tax rates. An increase in environmental protection expenditures and the improvement of the environment due to privatization proved to be more probable if the public corporate sector is less environmentally conscious. Conversely, with a stronger focus on environmental protection within state-owned enterprises, privatization may reduce environmental protection expenditures and, as a consequence, the quality of the environment. Those results, however, are highly diverse, depending on the level of development of the country and the industry/sector of the economy [10,11,12,13,14].
The main goal of the paper is to evaluate if environmental protection expenditures are used efficiently. Our research fills the gap in the empirical literature studied in Section 2, as we address the efficiency of environmental protection expenditures. Literature review, covering numerous scientific papers, indicates that environmental protection policy and expenditures are widely discussed issues, whereas the efficiency of expenditures on environmental protection has been a niche topic so far. The study presented in this article verifies the hypothesis that higher environmental protection expenditures do not result in better environmental results. The EU countries were selected for this analysis due to the fact that, in recent years, this region has become an informal world leader with respect to the implementation of policy measures in the field of environmental protection laws [15], especially after the withdrawal of former US president Trump from the Paris Agreement [16]. Fortunately, newly elected US president Biden announced a return to this pact in 2021. Environmental conservation and pollution prevention across the Member States fit into the EU’s general strategy of green transformation under the European Green Deal, i.e., withdrawal from fossil fuels, which, in turn, translates into a reduction of emissions resulting from fossil fuel combustion and a reduction in dependence on external energy supplies. Energy policy cannot be considered in isolation from the environmental policy of the EU [17]. This complies with Allen et al. [18], who stressed the significant impact of energy policy on environmental protection and expenditures. The environmental policy of the EU, as a sectoral policy that relies on the division of competencies between the EU institutions and member states, has gained a lot of importance in recent years, which has translated into regulatory progress [19] and financial allocations in the field of climate policy, which actually links the environmental and energy policies of the EU. However, the climate and energy policies of the EU have become highly politicized since the global financial crisis 2007–2009 [20]. Among the key legislative initiatives of the EU addressing environmental policy, there were: the Lisbon Strategy (2000), Emission Trading Scheme (2005), Lisbon Treaty (2007), Climate and Energy Package (2009), Europe 2020 Strategy (2010), and European Green Deal (2019). Under the European Green Deal, the EU is expected to achieve carbon neutrality by 2050, which means net-zero greenhouse gases emissions, whereas by 2030 the EU commits itself to reducing those emissions by at least 55%, to increase the shares of renewable energy in gross final energy consumption up to 32% and to increase the ratio of energy efficiency up to 32.5% [17,21,22,23,24,25]. One of the flagship initiatives of the European Green Deal is the New EU Forest Strategy for 2030. Among the key priorities, there is the promotion of sustainable forest bioeconomy, the improvement of the quantity and quality of the EU forests and the re- and afforestation of biodiverse forests. Under this strategy, forests may significantly contribute to the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions by 2030 by 55%—according to estimations, up to 310 million tons of CO2. The protection of existing forest areas and the planting of new ones (the EU pledges to plant 3 billion new trees) may, therefore, support actions against climate change, as well as several important nature-based economic sectors, i.e., agriculture, construction and food and drink. Forest policy is expected to positively impact the seafood and insurance industries, when considering, for instance, the conservation of marine stocks and the protection of coastal wetlands. The EU Member States are either high- or middle-income countries, more or less experienced with respect to reindustrialization and the resulting reorientation toward environmental-friendly industries, technologies and energy resources [2]. Thus, studies on the efficiency of environmental expenditures enable the formulation of recommendations in the name of the rationalization of the EU- and national-level sectoral policies in this field.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a review of the literature regarding environmental protection expenditures studies. Section 3 describes methodology. Section 4 presents the data, results and discussion. Section 5 concludes this research.

2. Literature Review

The hypothesis of environmental Kuznets curve for environmental protection expenditures states that, at early stage, of economic transition, the quality of the environment tend to deteriorate but improves prospectively due to structural transformation and the rising expectations of the society resulting from the increase in income per capita [26]. Lopez et al. [5], next to income level, stressed the role of scale, composition and technique, with special regard to higher labor efficiency and increased human-capital-intensive activities, as determinants of government expenditures’ impact on environmental pollution. Rising public expenditures result in higher redistributive transfers, which translate into increased income equality, then, higher expectations with respect to the quality of the environment [27]. In this regard, government expenditures are necessary to combat inequality if development in itself proves insufficient [28]. On the other hand, market forces do not provide effective solutions to inequality; therefore, there is a need for state activity [29]. This, in turn, translates into policy measures established by the advanced institutions that used to be scarce within the developing world [30,31,32,33]. The demand for environmental quality, when treated as luxury public good, can be satisfied through government expenditures when other public goods are already provided [3,4]. Environmental expenditures are expected to decline as the economy reorients itself to more environmentally friendly industries, technologies and energy resources. This, however, might result in the relocation of dirty industries from higher- to lower-income countries [34], while the accumulation of capital in the former group of countries may serve as a trigger for the development of environmental-friendly technologies. A reduction in government size may deteriorate the prosperity of the country [35,36]. Considering the indirect effect of the reduction of government expenditures on environmental protection through its impact on income, the reduction of the government size in developing countries may result in the deterioration of the quality of the environment [6]. Thus, the reduction of government expenditures in developing countries should be accompanied by the introduction of environmental regulations and standards, including the ratification of international environmental treaties. Contrarily, in the case of higher-income countries, i.e., the selected EU Member States, authors verified empirically that cutting government expenditures resulted in an improvement in both income and environmental quality, especially in the long-run [27].
Importantly, empirical studies on the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis, i.e., [1,16,37,38,39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49,50,51,52,53,54,55,56,57,58,59,60,61,62,63,64,65,66,67,68,69,70,71,72], have delivered at least ambiguous results with respect to the correlation between the level of income per capita and environmental pollution, especially when considering one of the most important greenhouse gases contributing to climate change, i.e., carbon dioxide. This greenhouse gas accounting for more than 75 percent of total emissions resulting from human activities has been adopted as a measure of environmental degradation in the empirical verification of the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis [58,64]. Carbon dioxide emissions were proven to increase due to financial development, as pointed out by, i.e., Pata [66] and Shahbaz et al. [73], as well as industrialization and urbanization processes, as analyzed by, i.e., Liu and Bae [74]. The reduction of carbon dioxide can be achieved through the adoption of fiscal expenditures aimed at the development of a low-carbon economy, improvement in energy efficiency and the optimization of energy structure [5,75,76]. From the global perspective, the impact of economic growth and energy structure, as well as population density, on regional and national carbon dioxide emission was studied by, among others, Hubacek et al. [77] and Chen et al. [78]; and from the national perspective, by Zhang et al. [79] and Chen et al. [78]; and from the micro-perspective by Cole et al. [80] and Xu et al. [81]. Whereas Omri et al. [82] and Wang et al. [83] adopted econometric modelling, Rhee et al. [84] and Cansino et al. [85] used input-output methods, and Nag and Parikh [86] and Tan et al. [87] used a factor decomposition approach.
Analyses dedicated to environmental expenditures in the context of carbon dioxide emissions and GDP were conducted for 19 African countries [54], China and India [62], Croatia [60], Malaysia [88], India [64], Turkey [66], Azerbaijan [89] and Eastern European countries [68]. Empirical studies on developed countries addressed the United States [58], Portugal and Spain [61] and the EU countries [44,47,49,50,52,53,56,70,90,91,92,93]. Several authors, Panayotou [94], Cole and Elliott [95], Dinda [96] and Tsurumi and Managi [97], analyzed the correlation between carbon dioxide emissions and trade liberalization processes in the context of the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis. On the other hand, the empirical verification of the impact of renewable energy sources on ecological footprint, which is considered in our analysis next to carbon dioxide with respect to the efficiency of environmental expenditures, were studied across the EU Member States only by a few authors, i.e., Destek et al. [16], Menegaki and Tsagarakis [98].
Maneejuk et al. [70] has confirmed the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis at the country-level only for 9 of 44 analyzed countries of the EU, OECD and G7 groupings. Interestingly, empirical studies by Pearce and Palmer [1], based on data from 1970s–1990s for OECD countries, pointed at no unambiguous upward trend with respect to the involvement of the private sector in environmental protection expenditures, with highly diversified country-level effects. Whereas several authors, i.e., Freeman [99,100], Hahn [101] and Portney [102], addressed the issue of the relative gains and costs of environmental regulations, there is relatively scarce literature on the budgetary costs of environmental protection in the context of government efficiency.
Ercolano and Romano [2] investigated environmental expenditures across 21 European countries (the selected EU Member States, United Kingdom, Iceland and Norway), using a sigma-convergence approach, followed by principal component and cluster analysis. As indicated by the authors, public environmental protection expenditures, as well as their composition within various initiatives and strategies, differ significantly across the countries. However, not only the level but also the efficiency of environmental expenditures should take into consideration the public spending in this field with environmental outcomes, such as greenhouse gas emissions and renewable energy development [103]. Due to the multidimensional character of public expenditures’ impacts, it is useful to adopt composite indicators, such as the environmental performance index (EPI) for the purposes of policy analysis [104]. The fact is that EPI serves as an aggregate measure of the results of policies aimed at the improvement of environmental quality, built on measurable outcomes such as emissions or deforestation, instead of policy inputs, i.e. public expenditures programs. Ercolano and Romano [2] identified no significant bivariate correlation between EPI, public environmental expenditures in terms of GDP and GDP per capita. Authors denied the hypothesis of the convergence of public environmental expenditures across the European countries, with no important changes in the composition of spending in this field. This complied with results obtained by Apergis et al. [105], according to which there is no convergence across the EU Member States, irrespective of several global- and regional-level directives and strategies dedicated to environmental protection, i.e., Sustainable Development Goals, Paris Agreement, Europe 2020 Strategy and the European Green Deal. In fact, a study by Ercolano and Romano [2] proved to be one of the first empirical contributions to the academic debate on the efficiency of environmental expenditures by verifying a correlation between the size and composition of public environmental expenditures and selected environmental performances and results.
Empirical findings by Apergis et al. [105] proved to be in line with analyses by Ferreiro et al. [106,107], which actually pointed at divergence across the EU Member States with respect to the size and composition of environmental expenditures. In fact, there is no single model of fiscal policy that enables the boosting of economic growth, prosperity and social welfare, including environmental quality that impacts people’s life assessment from country to country.
Halkos and Paizanos [6] investigated the public environmental expenditures of 77 countries in the years 1980–2000 and their direct and indirect impacts on the income level, as well as the impacts of income level on environmental pollution. Methodology was based on econometric modelling with panel analysis. The authors focused on the emissions of carbon dioxide and sulfur dioxide, indicating that, in the case of carbon dioxide, government spending had an insignificant direct impact on emissions per capita but a negative one with respect to indirect effects. The authors concluded that the reduction of government expenditures in higher-income countries increases both income and environmental quality, as already established environmental regulations and standards would diminish returns from further increases in government size. This, in turn, provides some analogy to the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis.
Empirical analysis by Ullah et al. [108] considered the asymmetrical effects of fiscal policy on the quality of the environment across the ten Asian countries responsible for the largest carbon emissions, including China and India, as well as Turkey, Iran and Japan, in the years 1981–2018. The authors, using a non-linear autoregressive distributed lag approach, identified the negative impact of a positive shock in government expenditure on environmental quality in the case of, among others, China, India, Turkey and Thailand, while only in the case of Japan did it prove to be positive. On the other hand, only in the case of Japan did the quality of the environment deteriorate in the studied period, because of the reduction in government expenditures. Moreover, due to an increase in governmental income tax revenues, there was an increase in government expenditures, which, in turn, increased carbon emissions everywhere except for Japan, again. As argued by the authors, short-run asymmetric effects translated into long-run effects across most of the Asian countries.
Recently, several analyses dedicated to the impacts of environmental expenditures and their efficiency focused on China, the largest contributor to global carbon dioxide emissions. After nearly three decades of dynamic economic growth, China faces the challenges of structural adjustments and environmental efficiency [109,110]. Zhou and Zhang [111], using a data envelopment analysis (DEA) method, investigated the efficiency of fiscal policies aimed at environmental pollution control across 30 Chinese provinces in the years 2007–2017. Authors empirically proved an improvement in this field since 2014, with special regard to the eastern regions of the country. Analysis confirmed that the efficiency of fiscal policy in the environmental field was negatively impacted by fiscal expenditure decentralization, while in the case of fiscal revenue decentralization, this effect proved to be non-significant. It was recommended to increase public expenditures for environmental pollution control, as well as for the central transfer payment system for environmental protection.

3. Methods and Data

Data envelopment analysis (DEA), created by Farrell [112] and developed by Charnes et al. [113], is the main methodology used in this article. DEA allows the calculation of the maximum performance value for each decision-making unit (DMU) relative to all DMUs in the study. DEA methodology constructs the efficiency production frontier and distance from the frontier at the nearest point for each DMU [114]. It should be noted that DEA measures relative technical efficiency, and, therefore, efficient DMUs are best-practice frontiers rather than production frontiers [115]. Thus, DEA requires the careful interpretation of results. In DEA, variables that may duplicate information should be removed from the model [116].
DEA methodology can be divided into input- and output-oriented models. An input-oriented model assumes a proportional reduction in input, while outputs remain unchanged. By analogy, an output-oriented model undertakes a proportional increase in outputs, while the proportion of inputs remains unchanged [117]. Another division of the DEA methods is based on constant or variable returns to scale (CRS or VRS).
DEA calculates efficiency as the ratio of the weighted sum of outputs to the weighted sum of inputs [118]. The CRS model maximizes this ratio (see Equations (1)–(3)) [119]:
Max θ 0 = r = 1 s u r   y rk i = 1 m v i x ik ,
subject to:
r = 1 s u r   y rj i = 1 m v i x ij 1 ,
u r   ,   v i 0 ;   r = 1 , , s ;   i = 1 , ,   m ;   j = 1 , , n
where:
  • u r —weight of output
  • v i —weight of input
  • y rj —output
  • x ij —input
While VRS model use supplementary restriction equation [113]:
j = 1 n λ j = 1
where λ is the corresponding solution vector for the optimization, and n is the number of DMUs.
This linear programming problem can be solved according to two different approaches. In the first, weighted sums of outputs are maximized while keeping inputs constant (output-oriented model). In the second, the weighted sums of inputs are minimized while keeping the outputs constant (input-oriented model). The primary equations for each model, known as the multiplier form, are given below [120].
The CRS input-oriented model equation becomes:
Minimize   θ k
Subject to
y rk j = 1 n λ j   y rj   0 ;   r = 1 , , s
θ k x ik j = 1 n λ j   x ij   0 ;   i = 1 , , m  
λ j     0 ; j = 1 , , n  
The VRS input-oriented model equation becomes:
Minimize   θ k
Subject to
y rk j = 1 n λ j   y rj   0 ;   r = 1 , , s
θ k x ik j = 1 n λ j   x ij   0 ;   i = 1 , , m
j = 1 n λ j = 1
λ j     0 ; j = 1 , , n
There are numerous advantages to using DEA methodology. DEA can be used when the relationship between variables does not have a known mathematical function [121]. DEA is a flexible method that can be adapted to the data [122]. Moreover, multiple input and output variables in different units can be analyzed at the same time, without a priori information about the importance of particular variables [123]. Furthermore, the sources of inefficiency for analyzed units can be analyzed [117]. There are also some limitations. DEA does not analyze qualitative variables. The inclusion of a large number of input and output variables would reduce the discriminant power of DEA. Also, DEA is criticized for overestimating efficiency and providing information about dominant DMUs [121]. There is also a noticeable negative correlation between efficiency and the number of DMUs [124].
The presented research has some limitations. Firstly, the selected input and output variables and research periods were limited by the availability of international statistics. There were no available more up-to-date data for environment statistics for all analyzed countries. The available data was mainly until 2017; the latest statistics are missing in generally available databases. Only basic statistics for a selected group of countries is available. Some data, such as water pollution, are incomplete or unavailable for all years and countries, and therefore, they had to be removed from the model. Consequently, the analysis would be more complex if this study analyzed additional indicators, such as the effects of all actions covered by environmental protection expenditures, i.e., the protection of ambient air and climate; wastewater management; waste management; the protection and remediation of soil, groundwater and surface water; noise and vibration abatement; protection of biodiversity and landscapes; protection against radiation; research and development and other environmental protection activities. However, a lack of data in some statistics prevented us from creating a comparable dataset. The possibility of using the model aggregate input variable with specific output variables is one of the main advantages of DEA methodology, which allows us to calculate effectiveness without specifying the mathematical form of the production function. On the other hand, this might be treated as one of the limitations of our study. Introducing to the model all possible combinations of specific inputs and outputs would provide a more general picture of environmental conditions in the analyzed countries; however, simultaneously, it would cause a reduction in the discriminatory power of the DEA. Adding variables to a DEA model will result in higher efficiency scores and an expanded set of efficient DMUs. Therefore, in our analysis, we have followed the principle that the number of variables should be less than one-third of the DMUs. In this research, the DEA assessment was performed for the selected group of 30 countries. Expanding the research objects may cause effective DMUs to become ineffective comparing to the new object group. The analysis of a more extended period could bring more general conclusions and recommendations for environmental policies. An additional challenge is the correctness of the environmental outcomes and the indication of the proper time lag between inputs and outputs. In our study, there were no abrupt changes in spending in the EU countries. If they were increasing, they were increasing proportionally. Thanks to this, we would obtain very similar results if we waited, for example, two or three years for the effects. It is also worth noting that the effects are faster in some countries than in others. Therefore, the authors adopted the principle that they would not use time-lag. Our analysis does not take into account differences in energy demand or the favorability of the conditions and capabilities of countries to invest in renewable energy. On the one hand, northern European countries have better natural conditions for renewable energy production, in particular wind and water power, but on the other hand, due to climate, their demand for energy is higher. Southern European countries have warmer climate, as a consequence, demand less electricity and enjoy better conditions for solar energy production. We need to highlight also that the selected research period includes the subprime crisis, which caused an economic downturn in several EU countries and, consequently, lower funding for environmental protection.
In our research, diagnostic variables were selected based on available data from the Eurostat and World Bank. Input indicators are environmental protection expenditures (as % of GDP), represented by EPE. Expenditure for environmental protection consists of outlays and other transactions related to:
  • inputs for environmental protection activities (energy, raw materials and other intermediate inputs, wages and salaries, taxes linked to production, the consumption of fixed capital);
  • capital formation and the buying of land (investment) for environmental protection activities;
  • users’ outlays for buying environmental protection products;
  • transfers for environmental protection (subsidies, investment grants, international aid, donations, taxes earmarked for environmental protection, etc.).
More than half of the environmental protection expenditure is incurred by corporations, the rest by the general government, non-profit institutions serving households and households. However, it is worth mentioning that corporations and households environmental expenditures are directly and indirectly derived from government-imposed regulations and rules.
The three output indicators chosen for analysis were as follows: (a) forest area, (b) renewable electricity output, (c) CO2 emissions. The below principle was followed with respect to the selection of variables [125].
n 3 ( s + m )
where:
  • s —number of inputs
  • m —number of outputs
  • n —numbers of DMUs
Table 1 presents a set of variables. In the DEA method, a positive relationship between inputs and outputs is assumed. Therefore, as in our case, the non-desirable output of CO2 emissions (destimulant) was transformed into desirable (stimulant) with the following transform:
X ij S = 1 X ij D max i   X ij D

4. Results and Discussion

Calculations for the purposes of the examination of the relationship between environmental protection expenditures and environmental results were performed in DeaFrontier Software. The research covers 30 European countries and the period from 2005 to 2015. Due to the limitation of article length, authors present only the sample data for the input and output indicators for one year, 2015, in Table 2.
An input-oriented model is used in the analysis, as most of the environmental protection strategies focus more on inputs than on outputs. The authors used both CRS and VRS models to avoid overestimation. As pointed out by [128,129], using only the VRS model may ignore subsets of proportional inputs and outputs. Therefore the authors used both the CRS and VRS models and then the average efficiency index. The results are presented in Table 3 and Table 4.
The authors also calculated the efficiency of spending on environmental protection expenditure for an additional ten years (2005–2015). A similar technique was carried out separately for each year. The results of this analysis are presented in Table 5, Table 6 and Table 7 and in Appendix A from Table A1, Table A2, Table A3, Table A4, Table A5, Table A6, Table A7, Table A8, Table A9, Table A10, Table A11, Table A12, Table A13, Table A14, Table A15, Table A16, Table A17, Table A18, Table A19 and Table A20.
Among the analyzed European economies, only Finland was efficient in the CRS model in 2015. Other countries may improve their efficiency by decreasing their environmental protection expenditures. In 2015, the Netherlands achieved the worst results (0.102), and, to become effective, it should receive the same results with inputs that are lower by 88.8% (1–0.102). Moreover, DEA methodology point out benchmarks (BDMUs), whose environmental strategies, policies and best practices may be a good pattern for ineffective DMUs, to improve their efficiency results. Finland is a benchmark for all other countries, which requires a closer look at the strategies and programs of environmental protection applied in that country. DEA, also, allows to recognize character of return to scale. In our case, most of the countries have decreasing returns to scale. Constant—optimal returns-to-scale (RTS) are seen only in Finland. Belgium, the Czech Republic, the Netherlands, Spain and Germany, which all have an increasing RTS.
Six countries are efficient under the VRS model: Austria, Finland, Iceland, Latvia, Norway and Sweden—mainly Nordic countries. Similarly to the CRS model, the Netherlands obtained the worst result (0.143). In general, more economies are efficient under the VRS than the CRS methodology.
The final efficiency index was calculated as the average of the CRS and VRS efficiency based on data from Table 5 and Table 6. The ranking of the most efficient countries is presented in Table 7. According to the presented ranking, Finland is the most efficient country. Finland was an efficient DMU in both the CRS and VRS models for the whole analyzed period. Iceland, Norway, Sweden and Latvia (1.00) are efficiency frontiers in the VRS model. Twelve out of thirty economies gained a score higher than average 0.52 in average innovation efficiency index, while the remaining eighteen economies gained scores lower. The Netherland’s low place in the ranking may be surprising as this country spends on environmental protection a relatively higher percentage of GDP than other countries in the Europe on environmental protection. The hypothesis about the non-proportional relation between higher environmental protection expenditures and environmental outputs has not been confirmed. From the interpretation of the results, it is essential to emphasize that the DEA methodology calculates relative efficiency, in the study group of countries, and investigates the degree to which environmental protection funds have been converted into environmental outputs.
Some spikes in CRS and VRS efficiencies were caused by unforeseen events. In 2013, one of Belgium’s lime plants operated without oxygen and, as a result, in the following year, the efficiency of spending on environmental protection expenditure in Belgium increased from 0.12 to 0.17 (CRS) and from 0.15 to 0.21 (VRS), which was partly due to the elimination of a problem from a previous year, rather than an actual improvement caused by the efficient spending of available funds.
As can be observed in the case of Bulgaria and Romania, two EU Member States since 2007, a sudden increase in funds for environmental purposes may result in their inefficient use. Romania spent the available funds efficiently in the years before its accession to the EU (VRS and CRS equal to 1), only to experience a decline in subsequent years to 0.82 in 2008 and 0.32 in 2009 (Table 5). In the case of VRS, the change is noticeable starting from 2009. In 2013, Croatia joined the European Union, and, in the second year after joining, a significant decrease in CRS (2013—0.58; 2014—0.82; 2015—0.43) and VRS (2013—0.91; 2014—1; 2015—0.6) values was observed.
A comparison of the ranking of countries in Table 7 and data on the absorption of EU funds in 2015 provides interesting insights. The absorption rate of the EU Cohesion Policy Funds (European Regional Development Fund, Cohesion Fund and European Social Fund) show the percentage paid to each Member State compared to the total available budget. Countries that have absorbed less than 90% of the funds available to them are: Ireland (rank 23), Hungary (rank 14), UK (rank 25), Netherlands (rank 30), Bulgaria (rank 20), Slovakia (rank 21), Czech Republic (rank 27), Spain (rank 24), Malta (rank 29) and Italy (rank 19). Two cases in particular are worth mentioning. Romania (place 8) has the second-worst absorption rate in the whole EU (less than 71%; the third-worst belongs to Italy, with almost 79%). Such a high ranking with such a low absorption rate is caused by taking into account data from before Romania’s accession to the EU. At the opposite end of the spectrum is Greece (rank 26), which has the highest absorption rate (over 98%, 3% higher than the second-best country). This may indicate that inefficiency can be caused not only by the low absorption of funds but also by the fact that the rush to absorb funds can lead to the insufficient consideration of value for money, poor quality of governance and the selection of projects for funding.
Further study of the impact of accession on the efficiency of environmental protection expenditure by comparing the values of CRS and VRS one and two years after the accession of 10 new countries in 2004 to the values of these measures in 2015 reveals that:
-
CRS values in 2015 decreased compared to 2005 in 8 of the 10 countries and for VRS in 6 of the 10 countries,
-
CRS values in 2015 decreased compared to 2006 in 9 of 10 countries and for VRS in 7 of 10 countries
The thirteen EU countries that joined the EU in 2004, 2007 and 2013 were ranked below the EU average with respect to GDP per capita. However, environmental protection investment in those countries proved to be less efficient than in the case of higher-income Member States, irrespective of the significance of those expenditures for the improvement of environmental quality, life expectancy and related indicators of socioeconomic development, for instance, in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE). CEE countries are heavily affected by the impacts of climate changes, as well as air and noise pollution, on environmental quality and human health when compared to Western Europe. Countries like Poland and Czech Republic are characterized by a concentration of heavy industries and the coal-based energy sector. Both economic development and enforcement have impeded environmental protection investment in CEE [131]. These observations cause one to wonder whether simply comparing the planned budget with its execution is sufficient to assess the performance of individual countries. Our findings are in line with the environmental Kuznets curve, which suggests that economic development initially leads to deterioration in environmental quality, but, after reaching a certain level of economic growth and development, environmental degradation decreases. As argued by Berg et al. [132], in the case of lower income and developing countries, the so-called marginal efficiency, resulting from an increase in public investment, including environmental protection expenditures, generate relatively smaller output multipliers (lower than 1) due to general capital scarcity and historical inefficiencies. The latter involves, among others, lower institutional capacity, governance quality and infrastructure and supply bottlenecks, as well as corruption [133]. Annual reports published by the European Anti-Fraud Office (OLAF) [134] confirm that the problem of fraud of the EU structural funds is more and more significant, with rising number of investigations conducted every year, mostly addressing CEE countries and Italy. The other problems related to the issue, especially in the CEE region are: the selection of contractors under government procurement, budgetary constraints to satisfy national contribution to the project and a heavy reliance on public funds in environmental spending in general.

5. Conclusions

Our analysis confirmed the problem of the deteriorating efficiency of environmental expenditures across the selected EU Member States, caused by an increase in spending, whereas Halkos and Paizanos [27] suggested that the reduction of environmental expenditures in higher-income countries, such as the countries of the EU, led to an improvement in environmental quality and an increase in income. This, in turn, supports the argument that, after reaching a given level of income and economic development, environmental quality improves due to rising social pressure to boost spending in this field; however, an increase in environmental expenditures doesn’t have to translate into proportional results in terms of their efficiency from country to country, year after year. In other words, continuous increases in government size provide diminishing returns [6]. Therefore, environmental expenditures have to be confronted with environmental outcome to consider efficiency, not only the level of spending on this sectoral policy [103]. The European Green Deal requires dedicated environmental expenditures to achieve the far-reaching goal of carbon neutrality [6,75,76]. The problem of carbon dioxide emissions within the single market of the EU, complies with studies by Panayotou [94], Cole and Elliott [95], Dinda [96] and Tsurumi and Managi [97] with respect to the positive correlation between emissions and the degree of trade liberalization, which, in turn, translates into trade creation and diversion effects. Similar to the case of analysis of the EU countries [16,42,44,46,47,49,50,51,52,56,57,70], the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis can be confirmed at the region-level; however, across the selected Member States, results were diversified. For instance, higher-income EU countries relocated dirty industries to lower-income countries, increasing the income and degree of industrialization without the deterioration of environmental quality, as the aforementioned hypothesis assumed. The diversity of environmental outcomes and the efficiency of expenditures proved to vary among the EU Member States due to the diversified approaches and strategies of environmental protection and pollution reduction, which confirms conclusions by Ercolano and Romano [2], based on studies of selected EU Member States. Our research indicated the lack of convergence of public environmental expenditures across the EU Member States, which complies with results achieved by Ercolano and Romano [2], Apergis et al. [105] and Ferreiro et al. [106,107]. The recognition of the positive impact of an increase of shares of renewables in final energy consumption supports the empirical findings by Destek et al. [16] that environmental degradation requires a reorientation from fossil-fuels-based growth policies across the Member States. Therefore, EU policymakers are expected to introduce legislative measures to enhance the production of renewable energy, while discouraging non-renewable sources, including dedicated subsidization and tax schemes.
The European Union, when assessing environmental protection expenditures, should focus on the merits of such investments, with particular emphasis on the expected environmental effects. This would result in reports comparing the ratio of expected to achieved environmental effects. Such data would provide more valuable information and conclusions than a simple comparison of planned budget with its execution. The distribution of European funds should depend more on the efficiency of use of those funds, as opposed to the current situation. Inefficient countries should not be punished, but the period of time dedicated to the use of funds should be extended and divided into smaller sub-periods, to avoid motivating politicians in these countries to absorb funds quickly (inefficiently) to serve propaganda purposes. The re-examination of environmental expenditures with a goal of potentially finding and eliminating those expenditures whose classification in that group is not justified due to negligible or no impact at all on the quality of the environment in terms of its protection and the protection of human health. The limitation of the funds allocated for environmental protection might enhance competition among ideas for environmental expenditures.
Our research has some limitations, and they were discussed in the Section 3.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.B., P.D., S.B., K.S. and S.C.; methodology, P.D.; formal analysis, A.B., P.D., S.B., K.S. and S.C.; investigation, A.B., P.D., S.B., K.S. and S.C.; data curation, P.D. and K.S.; writing—original draft preparation, A.B., P.D., S.B., K.S. and S.C.; writing—review and editing, P.D. and S.B.; visualization, P.D. and S.B.; supervision, A.B. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The project is financed by the Ministry of Science and Higher Education in Poland under the program “Regional Initiative of Excellence” 2019–2022 project number 015/RID/2018/19 total funding amount 10,721,040 PLN.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

We used publicly available statistical data provided by Eurostat and World Bank in the article.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank to the Warsaw-Beijing Forum for the opportunity to participate in the conference “Between China and Europe—Energy for Future Earth” in April 2021, and the conference participants for useful comments and to the anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions, which contributed to the quality of the paper. We would also like to issue thanks for allowing me to intern as a Visiting Scholar at the Minda de Gunzburg Center for European Studies (CES) at Harvard University.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2014. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A1. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2014. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT1.000001.000Constant1.000AUT
2BEL0.173640.730Increasing0.487CYP0.242SWE
3BGR0.442121.032Decreasing0.742CYP0.290FIN
4CHE0.686491.014Decreasing0.032ISL0.982SWE
5CYP1.000001.000Constant1.000CYP
6CZE0.211370.775Increasing0.407CYP0.368FIN
7DEU0.408790.672Increasing0.234CYP0.437SWE
8DNK0.773160.907Increasing0.119ISL0.787SWE
9ESP0.400580.975Increasing0.295CYP0.680SWE
10EST0.301040.702Increasing0.702FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.334061.072Decreasing0.864CYP0.083FIN0.124SWE
13GBR0.363400.881Increasing0.616CYP0.265SWE
14GRC0.204050.899Increasing0.536CYP0.363SWE
15HRV0.822311.077Decreasing0.313ISL0.763SWE
16HUN0.275951.085Decreasing1.028CYP0.057SWE
17IRL0.468110.807Increasing0.418CYP0.389SWE
18ISL1.000001.000Constant1.000ISL
19ITA0.400450.951Increasing0.200CYP0.751SWE
20LTU0.628641.029Decreasing0.344CYP0.685SWE
21LVA0.602621.086Decreasing0.126CYP0.960SWE
22MLT0.197690.988Increasing0.988CYP
23NLD0.138440.598Increasing0.455CYP0.143SWE
24NOR0.744481.110Decreasing0.704AUT0.406ISL
25POL0.443050.886Increasing0.626CYP0.261FIN
26PRT0.709711.025Decreasing0.080ISL0.945SWE
27ROU0.499651.102Decreasing0.410CYP0.692SWE
28SVK0.404211.022Decreasing0.619CYP0.236FIN0.167SWE
29SVN0.346851.046Decreasing0.241CYP0.474FIN0.331SWE
30SWE1.000001.000Constant1.000SWE
Note: DMU—decisio-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A2. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2014. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A2. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2014. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT1.000001.000AUT
2BEL0.214290.687CYP0.313FIN
3BGR0.443930.691CYP0.201FIN0.108SWE
4CHE0.740660.125HRV0.065LVA0.810SWE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.272730.709CYP0.291FIN
7DEU0.500000.398CYP0.602FIN
8DNK0.785470.165AUT0.238FIN0.597SWE
9ESP0.402950.297CYP0.077FIN0.627SWE
10EST0.428571.000FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.388550.115CYP0.885SWE
13GBR0.376230.623CYP0.367FIN0.010SWE
14GRC0.209840.541CYP0.311FIN0.148SWE
15HRV1.000001.000HRV
16HUN0.406200.291LVA0.709SWE
17IRL0.500000.442CYP0.558FIN
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.405140.203CYP0.151FIN0.646SWE
20LTU0.719380.105LVA0.895SWE
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.200001.000CYP
23NLD0.214290.871CYP0.129FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.500000.779CYP0.221FIN
26PRT0.785360.274HRV0.054LVA0.671SWE
27ROU0.869030.984LVA0.016SWE
28SVK0.405320.583CYP0.174FIN0.243SWE
29SVN0.348680.168CYP0.346FIN0.487SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A3. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2013. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A3. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2013. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT1.000001.000Constant1.000AUT
2BEL0.120630.776Increasing0.072AUT0.589CYP0.115FIN
3BGR0.265651.054Decreasing0.002AUT0.774CYP0.278FIN
4CHE0.616911.133Decreasing0.718AUT0.414CYP
5CYP1.000001.000Constant1.000CYP
6CZE0.189070.759Increasing0.386CYP0.373FIN
7DEU0.352910.776Increasing0.156AUT0.366CYP0.254FIN
8DNK0.611210.981Increasing0.547AUT0.435CYP
9ESP0.344351.098Decreasing0.409AUT0.603CYP0.085FIN
10EST0.301090.703Increasing0.703FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.241341.064Decreasing0.060AUT0.837CYP0.166FIN
13GBR0.248440.876Increasing0.118AUT0.758CYP
14GRC0.146370.981Increasing0.198AUT0.653CYP0.130FIN
15HRV0.578921.213Decreasing0.813AUT0.400CYP
16HUN0.245521.082Decreasing1.035CYP0.047FIN
17IRL0.359750.860Increasing0.219AUT0.640CYP
18ISL1.000001.000Constant1.000ISL
19ITA0.327301.032Decreasing0.441AUT0.591CYP
20LTU0.615951.144Decreasing0.369AUT0.721CYP0.054FIN
21LVA0.565801.286Decreasing0.566AUT0.463CYP0.257FIN
22MLT0.139530.977Increasing0.977CYP
23NLD0.097670.631Increasing0.102AUT0.529CYP
24NOR0.619401.132Decreasing0.704AUT0.428ISL
25POL0.332220.863Increasing0.596CYP0.267FIN
26PRT0.537041.179Decreasing0.701AUT0.478CYP
27ROU0.385971.183Decreasing0.361AUT0.822CYP
28SVK0.282861.034Decreasing0.062AUT0.618CYP0.354FIN
29SVN0.428321.085Decreasing0.042AUT0.299CYP0.744FIN
30SWE0.783901.267Decreasing0.373AUT0.256CYP0.638FIN
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A4. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2013. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A4. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2013. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT1.000001.000AUT
2BEL0.146240.080AUT0.886CYP0.033FIN
3BGR0.303710.686CYP0.104FIN0.210SWE
4CHE0.774370.233CYP0.337ISL0.173LVA0.257SWE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.229020.710CYP0.290FIN
7DEU0.416830.164AUT0.663CYP0.173FIN
8DNK0.617820.545AUT0.455CYP
9ESP0.404960.003AUT0.451CYP0.139ISL0.407SWE
10EST0.371480.400CYP0.600FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.273890.760CYP0.009LVA0.231SWE
13GBR0.276160.105AUT0.895CYP
14GRC0.148300.199AUT0.678CYP0.123FIN
15HRV0.913780.022CYP0.247ISL0.731LVA
16HUN0.527320.451CYP0.549LVA
17IRL0.401430.204AUT0.796CYP
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.349420.254AUT0.534CYP0.077ISL0.135SWE
20LTU0.963590.431CYP0.013ISL0.556LVA
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.142861.000CYP
23NLD0.141580.062AUT0.938CYP
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.370020.780CYP0.220FIN
26PRT0.812160.171CYP0.229ISL0.600LVA
27ROU0.863130.019CYP0.981LVA
28SVK0.298080.015AUT0.585CYP0.273FIN0.127SWE
29SVN0.495930.180CYP0.494FIN0.326SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A5. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2012. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A5. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2012. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMU
1AUT0.734971.837Decreasing1.837FIN
2BEL0.130601.045Decreasing1.045FIN
3BGR0.362061.267Decreasing1.267FIN
4CHE0.488761.466Decreasing1.466FIN
5CYP0.847511.271Decreasing1.271FIN
6CZE0.142840.928Increasing0.928FIN
7DEU0.329520.989Increasing0.989FIN
8DNK0.616441.233Decreasing1.233FIN
9ESP0.262241.311Decreasing1.311FIN
10EST0.160130.721Increasing0.721FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.272991.365Decreasing1.365FIN
13GBR0.289041.156Decreasing1.156FIN
14GRC0.211931.166Decreasing1.166FIN
15HRV0.480881.443Decreasing1.443FIN
16HUN0.403571.412Decreasing1.412FIN
17IRL0.280181.121Decreasing1.121FIN
18ISL0.821652.465Decreasing2.465FIN
19ITA0.280281.261Decreasing1.261FIN
20LTU0.351461.406Decreasing1.406FIN
21LVA0.469331.643Decreasing1.643FIN
22MLT0.177871.245Decreasing1.245FIN
23NLD0.118670.890Increasing0.890FIN
24NOR0.603742.415Decreasing2.415FIN
25POL0.369221.108Decreasing1.108FIN
26PRT0.476361.429Decreasing1.429FIN
27ROU0.364191.457Decreasing1.457FIN
28SVK0.283111.274Decreasing1.274FIN
29SVN0.294021.176Decreasing1.176FIN
30SWE0.582501.456Decreasing1.456FIN
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A6. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2012. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A6. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2012. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT1.000001.000AUT
2BEL0.135310.165CYP0.835FIN
3BGR0.475440.689CYP0.098FIN0.213SWE
4CHE0.879620.014CYP0.153LVA0.833SWE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.153851.000FIN
7DEU0.333331.000FIN
8DNK0.941220.076CYP0.361FIN0.563SWE
9ESP0.384800.542CYP0.023FIN0.435SWE
10EST0.222221.000FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.455650.611CYP0.389LVA
13GBR0.321960.576CYP0.424FIN
14GRC0.237330.611CYP0.389FIN
15HRV0.975480.274CYP0.700LVA0.026SWE
16HUN0.763720.413CYP0.587LVA
17IRL0.305620.445CYP0.555FIN
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.393730.462CYP0.178FIN0.361SWE
20LTU0.654440.441CYP0.559LVA
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.207390.903CYP0.097FIN
23NLD0.133331.000FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.399480.397CYP0.603FIN
26PRT0.936970.345CYP0.655LVA
27ROU0.760210.230CYP0.770LVA
28SVK0.389970.579CYP0.111FIN0.310SWE
29SVN0.399080.180CYP0.483FIN0.338SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A7. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2011. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A7. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2011. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMU
1AUT0.791021.084Decreasing0.637FIN0.447ISL
2BEL0.151861.139Decreasing1.139FIN
3BGR0.389081.362Decreasing1.362FIN
4CHE0.547451.529Decreasing1.472FIN0.057ISL
5CYP0.915141.373Decreasing1.373FIN
6CZE0.157171.022Decreasing1.022FIN
7DEU0.378551.136Decreasing1.136FIN
8DNK0.653181.306Decreasing1.306FIN
9ESP0.290041.450Decreasing1.450FIN
10EST0.720700.721Increasing0.721FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.303561.518Decreasing1.518FIN
13GBR0.295071.328Decreasing1.328FIN
14GRC0.292601.317Decreasing1.317FIN
15HRV0.519431.558Decreasing1.558FIN
16HUN0.439241.537Decreasing1.537FIN
17IRL0.315111.260Decreasing1.260FIN
18ISL1.000001.000Constant1.000ISL
19ITA0.302911.363Decreasing1.363FIN
20LTU0.447931.568Decreasing1.568FIN
21LVA0.475461.664Decreasing1.664FIN
22MLT0.218211.418Decreasing1.418FIN
23NLD0.124880.999Increasing0.999FIN
24NOR0.725271.266Decreasing0.448FIN0.818ISL
25POL0.345201.208Decreasing1.208FIN
26PRT0.449081.572Decreasing1.572FIN
27ROU0.355181.598Decreasing1.598FIN
28SVK0.348091.392Decreasing1.392FIN
29SVN0.324541.298Decreasing1.298FIN
30SWE0.847701.419Decreasing1.281FIN0.138ISL
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A8. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2011. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A8. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2011. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.846690.217FIN0.333ISL0.450SWE
2BEL0.158190.373CYP0.627FIN
3BGR0.446610.689CYP0.092FIN0.218SWE
4CHE0.870650.008ISL0.403LVA0.589SWE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.158310.058CYP0.942FIN
7DEU0.393990.364CYP0.636FIN
8DNK0.797600.156CYP0.327FIN0.517SWE
9ESP0.372210.278CYP0.722SWE
10EST1.000001.000EST
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.461590.205LVA0.795SWE
13GBR0.323010.830CYP0.132FIN0.039SWE
14GRC0.324130.728CYP0.178FIN0.095SWE
15HRV0.879320.425LVA0.575SWE
16HUN0.704930.312LVA0.688SWE
17IRL0.348390.539CYP0.337FIN0.124SWE
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.360720.482CYP0.136FIN0.382SWE
20LTU0.775680.477LVA0.523SWE
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.263490.575CYP0.425SWE
23NLD0.125000.003EST0.997FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.365520.559CYP0.441FIN
26PRT0.785100.499LVA0.501SWE
27ROU0.658650.643LVA0.357SWE
28SVK0.414930.570CYP0.055FIN0.375SWE
29SVN0.394010.163CYP0.342FIN0.494SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A9. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2010. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A9. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2010. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMU
1AUT0.603551.207Decreasing1.207LVA
2BEL0.161870.647Increasing0.647LVA
3BGR0.377600.881Increasing0.881LVA
4CHE0.517121.034Decreasing1.034LVA
5CYP0.826920.827Increasing0.827LVA
6CZE0.187830.626Increasing0.034FIN0.592LVA
7DEU0.347680.695Increasing0.695LVA
8DNK0.564080.752Increasing0.752LVA
9ESP0.242570.889Increasing0.889LVA
10EST0.746460.746Increasing0.649FIN0.097LVA
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.273360.911Increasing0.911LVA
13GBR0.232530.775Increasing0.775LVA
14GRC0.297190.792Increasing0.792LVA
15HRV0.572831.146Decreasing1.146LVA
16HUN0.467030.934Increasing0.934LVA
17IRL0.216760.723Increasing0.723LVA
18ISL0.911451.823Decreasing1.823LVA
19ITA0.311980.832Increasing0.832LVA
20LTU0.224290.972Increasing0.972LVA
21LVA1.000001.000Constant1.000LVA
22MLT0.137250.869Increasing0.869LVA
23NLD0.110480.589Increasing0.589LVA
24NOR0.654491.745Decreasing1.745LVA
25POL0.321010.749Increasing0.749LVA
26PRT0.412600.963Increasing0.963LVA
27ROU0.373470.996Increasing0.996LVA
28SVK0.279500.838Increasing0.838LVA
29SVN0.423900.989Increasing0.447FIN0.542LVA
30SWE0.865841.154Decreasing0.323FIN0.832LVA
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A10. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2010. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A10. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2010. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.693630.247ISL0.333LVA0.419SWE
2BEL0.250000.891CYP0.012FIN0.097LVA
3BGR0.428570.553CYP0.447LVA
4CHE0.520810.042ISL0.958LVA
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.300000.712CYP0.288FIN
7DEU0.500000.662CYP0.110FIN0.228LVA
8DNK0.750000.198CYP0.494FIN0.308LVA
9ESP0.272730.413CYP0.587LVA
10EST1.000000.375CYP0.625FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.300000.513CYP0.487LVA
13GBR0.300000.898CYP0.102LVA
14GRC0.375000.677CYP0.012FIN0.311LVA
15HRV0.588510.177ISL0.823LVA
16HUN0.500001.000LVA
17IRL0.300000.590CYP0.405FIN0.005LVA
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.375000.446CYP0.210FIN0.344LVA
20LTU0.230771.000LVA
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.157890.755CYP0.245LVA
23NLD0.187500.720CYP0.280FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.428570.784CYP0.216FIN
26PRT0.428570.038CYP0.962LVA
27ROU0.375001.000LVA
28SVK0.333330.484CYP0.180FIN0.336LVA
29SVN0.428570.025CYP0.462FIN0.513LVA
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A11. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2009. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A11. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2009. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMU
1AUT0.445641.114Decreasing1.114LVA
2BEL0.133470.667Increasing0.667LVA
3BGR0.157350.865Increasing0.865LVA
4CHE0.294910.885Increasing0.885LVA
5CYP0.513900.771Increasing0.771LVA
6CZE0.182670.639Increasing0.639LVA
7DEU0.230080.690Increasing0.690LVA
8DNK0.366340.733Increasing0.733LVA
9ESP0.152310.838Increasing0.838LVA
10EST0.245490.982Increasing0.982LVA
11FIN0.906061.359Decreasing1.359LVA
12FRA0.176440.882Increasing0.882LVA
13GBR0.152080.760Increasing0.760LVA
14GRC0.159980.720Increasing0.720LVA
15HRV0.260570.912Increasing0.912LVA
16HUN0.305460.916Increasing0.916LVA
17IRL0.124170.683Increasing0.683LVA
18ISL0.521971.566Decreasing1.566LVA
19ITA0.201160.805Increasing0.805LVA
20LTU0.161130.967Increasing0.967LVA
21LVA1.000001.000Constant1.000LVA
22MLT0.113270.850Increasing0.850LVA
23NLD0.069580.591Increasing0.591LVA
24NOR0.378091.512Decreasing1.512LVA
25POL0.213480.747Increasing0.747LVA
26PRT0.300000.900Increasing0.900LVA
27ROU0.321360.964Increasing0.964LVA
28SVK0.184860.832Increasing0.832LVA
29SVN0.255721.151Decreasing1.151LVA
30SWE0.509591.274Decreasing1.274LVA
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A12. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2009. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A12. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2009. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.625280.080ISL0.786LVA0.134NOR
2BEL0.200001.000LVA
3BGR0.181821.000LVA
4CHE0.333331.000LVA
5CYP0.666671.000LVA
6CZE0.285711.000LVA
7DEU0.333331.000LVA
8DNK0.500001.000LVA
9ESP0.181821.000LVA
10EST0.250001.000LVA
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.200001.000LVA
13GBR0.200001.000LVA
14GRC0.222221.000LVA
15HRV0.285711.000LVA
16HUN0.333331.000LVA
17IRL0.181821.000LVA
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.250001.000LVA
20LTU0.166671.000LVA
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.133331.000LVA
23NLD0.117651.000LVA
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.285711.000LVA
26PRT0.333331.000LVA
27ROU0.333331.000LVA
28SVK0.222221.000LVA
29SVN0.268860.420FIN0.580LVA
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A13. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2008. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A13. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2008. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.933361.079Decreasing0.602FIN0.398ISL0.079NOR
2BEL0.270360.901Increasing0.760CYP0.141FIN
3BGR0.482751.126Decreasing0.887CYP0.240FIN
4CHE0.902671.444Decreasing1.384FIN0.060ISL
5CYP1.000001.000Constant1.000CYP
6CZE0.279160.837Increasing0.494CYP0.344FIN
7DEU0.582150.970Increasing0.565CYP0.405FIN
8DNK0.659581.099Decreasing0.334CYP0.766FIN
9ESP0.347841.159Decreasing0.608CYP0.552FIN
10EST0.218920.803Increasing0.106CYP0.697FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.407811.223Decreasing0.869CYP0.355FIN
13GBR0.331320.994Increasing0.843CYP0.151FIN
14GRC0.332440.997Increasing0.749CYP0.249FIN
15HRV0.715851.432Decreasing0.159CYP1.273FIN
16HUN0.600531.201Decreasing1.046CYP0.156FIN
17IRL0.258630.948Increasing0.619CYP0.329FIN
18ISL1.000001.000Constant1.000ISL
19ITA0.420601.122Decreasing0.610CYP0.512FIN
20LTU0.473251.262Decreasing1.065CYP0.197FIN
21LVA0.618231.586Decreasing1.524FIN0.062ISL
22MLT0.223221.116Decreasing1.116CYP
23NLD0.169630.848Increasing0.606CYP0.242FIN
24NOR1.000001.000Constant1.000NOR
25POL0.436011.017Decreasing0.810CYP0.207FIN
26PRT0.581441.357Decreasing0.463CYP0.894FIN
27ROU0.819431.366Decreasing0.632CYP0.734FIN
28SVK0.430461.148Decreasing0.712CYP0.436FIN
29SVN0.412941.101Decreasing0.342CYP0.759FIN
30SWE0.891401.450Decreasing1.414FIN0.036ISL
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A14. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2008. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A14. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2008. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.984560.255FIN0.235ISL0.197NOR0.314SWE
2BEL0.300000.860CYP0.140FIN
3BGR0.546710.587CYP0.129ROU0.284SWE
4CHE1.000001.000CHE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.333330.712CYP0.288FIN
7DEU0.600000.595CYP0.405FIN
8DNK0.682420.206CHE0.348CYP0.446FIN
9ESP0.367320.050CHE0.623CYP0.040FIN0.287SWE
10EST0.272730.371CYP0.629FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.491540.288CYP0.609ROU0.103SWE
13GBR0.333330.849CYP0.151FIN
14GRC0.333330.751CYP0.249FIN
15HRV0.820540.582CHE0.038CYP0.264ROU0.117SWE
16HUN0.754490.237CYP0.763ROU
17IRL0.272730.403CYP0.597FIN
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.438330.202CHE0.626CYP0.121FIN0.052SWE
20LTU0.649740.066LVA0.823ROU0.112SWE
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.269090.482CYP0.518ROU
23NLD0.200001.000FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.443370.782CYP0.166FIN0.052SWE
26PRT0.680580.104CHE0.118CYP0.571ROU0.206SWE
27ROU1.000001.000ROU
28SVK0.473140.571CYP0.036FIN0.393SWE
29SVN0.450500.181CYP0.517FIN0.302SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A15. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2007. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A15. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2007. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.976361.129Decreasing0.631FIN0.483ISL0.015NOR
2BEL0.337460.889Increasing0.754CYP0.104FIN0.032ROU
3BGR0.279851.119Decreasing0.880CYP0.240FIN
4CHE0.825101.118Decreasing0.201FIN0.339ISL0.579ROU
5CYP1.000001.000Constant1.000CYP
6CZE0.246020.820Increasing0.470CYP0.350FIN
7DEU0.594220.907Increasing0.408CYP0.247FIN0.251ROU
8DNK0.651330.773Increasing0.083ISL0.689ROU
9ESP0.337100.968Increasing0.261CYP0.239FIN0.468ROU
10EST0.268850.807Increasing0.108CYP0.699FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.402051.098Decreasing0.665CYP0.107FIN0.325ROU
13GBR0.322910.905Increasing0.714CYP0.191ROU
14GRC0.370070.971Increasing0.722CYP0.202FIN0.047ROU
15HRV0.716891.055Decreasing0.182FIN0.131ISL0.742ROU
16HUN0.583491.107Decreasing0.928CYP0.001FIN0.179ROU
17IRL0.269970.771Increasing0.386CYP0.386ROU
18ISL1.000001.000Constant1.000ISL
19ITA0.468200.954Increasing0.382CYP0.155FIN0.416ROU
20LTU0.417891.254Decreasing1.056CYP0.197FIN
21LVA0.595051.323Decreasing0.552FIN0.307ISL0.464ROU
22MLT0.199871.066Decreasing1.066CYP
23NLD0.167260.744Increasing0.467CYP0.277ROU
24NOR1.000001.000Constant1.000NOR
25POL0.511421.023Decreasing0.819CYP0.204FIN
26PRT0.694371.047Decreasing0.199FIN0.090ISL0.758ROU
27ROU1.000001.000Constant1.000ROU
28SVK0.511391.086Decreasing0.454CYP0.312FIN0.321ROU
29SVN0.445741.181Decreasing0.428CYP0.728FIN0.024ROU
30SWE0.978091.331Decreasing0.817FIN0.192ISL0.322ROU
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A16. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2007. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A16. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2007. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.999160.231FIN0.203ISL0.255NOR0.310SWE
2BEL0.375000.528CYP0.472FIN
3BGR0.296880.253CYP0.184FIN0.563ROU
4CHE0.963300.032ISL0.187LVA0.781SWE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.300000.019CYP0.981FIN
7DEU0.606920.531CYP0.435FIN0.035ROU
8DNK0.669830.078CYP0.573FIN0.349ROU
9ESP0.339300.303CYP0.304FIN0.393ROU
10EST0.333331.000FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.420640.152CYP0.062FIN0.786ROU
13GBR0.333330.790CYP0.210FIN
14GRC0.375000.727CYP0.273FIN
15HRV0.719950.045FIN0.099ISL0.688ROU0.168SWE
16HUN0.626810.239CYP0.761ROU
17IRL0.300000.666CYP0.334FIN
18ISL1,000001.000ISL
19ITA0.472690.443CYP0.248FIN0.309ROU
20LTU0.554020.191LVA0.777ROU0.032SWE
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0,209880.642CYP0.358ROU
23NLD0.200000.761CYP0.239FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.517930.699CYP0.194FIN0.108ROU
26PRT0.696940.084FIN0.062ISL0.713ROU0.141SWE
27ROU1.000001.000ROU
28SVK0.532500.000CYP0.272FIN0.727ROU
29SVN0.492780.422FIN0.213ROU0.365SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A17. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2006. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A17. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2006. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.877721.052Decreasing0.326FIN0.505NOR0.222ROU
2BEL0.327360.868Increasing0.742CYP0.113FIN0.014ROU
3BGR0.286991.110Decreasing0.776CYP0.221FIN0.113ROU
4CHE0.635691.038Decreasing0.008FIN0.305NOR0.726ROU
5CYP1.000001.000Constant1.000CYP
6CZE0.227670.835Increasing0.490CYP0.345FIN
7DEU0.478310.910Increasing0.506CYP0.265FIN0.139ROU
8DNK0.480720.732Increasing0.043CYP0.689ROU
9ESP0.334300.989Increasing0.370CYP0.241FIN0.377ROU
10EST0.347040.925Increasing0.266CYP0.660FIN
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.391991.088Decreasing0.707CYP0.118FIN0.263ROU
13GBR0.313460.888Increasing0.732CYP0.157ROU
14GRC0.381950.928Increasing0.481CYP0.175FIN0.272ROU
15HRV0.753731.073Decreasing0.058FIN0.287NOR0.728ROU
16HUN0.485461.090Decreasing0.947CYP0.013FIN0.129ROU
17IRL0.298550.792Increasing0.481CYP0.311ROU
18ISL0.890681.093Decreasing0.970NOR0.123ROU
19ITA0.464570.945Increasing0.373CYP0.156FIN0.416ROU
20LTU0.468071.248Decreasing1.052CYP0.197FIN
21LVA0.720531.278Decreasing0.357FIN0.289NOR0.632ROU
22MLT0.213291.066Decreasing1.065CYP0.001ROU
23NLD0.166720.741Increasing0.463CYP0.278ROU
24NOR1.000001.000Constant1.000NOR
25POL0.432081.008Decreasing0.800CYP0.208FIN
26PRT0.570721.029Decreasing0.156FIN0.036NOR0.836ROU
27ROU1.000001.000Constant1.000ROU
28SVK0.344961.079Decreasing0.532CYP0.333FIN0.214ROU
29SVN0.453261.152Decreasing0.267CYP0.714FIN0.171ROU
30SWE0.932311.294Decreasing0.703FIN0.187NOR0.404ROU
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A18. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2006. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A18. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2006. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.889790.201FIN0.471NOR0.150ROU0.178SWE
2BEL0.375000.462CYP0.538FIN
3BGR0.308480.139CYP0.159FIN0.702ROU
4CHE0.686010.242ISL0.034LVA0.508ROU0.216SWE
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.272730.112CYP0.888FIN
7DEU0.500000.511CYP0.489FIN
8DNK0.521570.432CYP0.503FIN0.065NOR
9ESP0.335290.421CYP0.243FIN0.017NOR0.320ROU
10EST0.375000.095CYP0.905FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.414920.197CYP0.069FIN0.734ROU
13GBR0.333330.713CYP0.287FIN
14GRC0.389970.691CYP0.249FIN0.060NOR
15HRV0.853560.192ISL0.192LVA0.455ROU0.161SWE
16HUN0.525830.319CYP0.681ROU
17IRL0.333330.666CYP0.334FIN
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.471310.617CYP0.163FIN0.079NOR0.140ROU
20LTU0.662080.432LVA0.568ROU
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.228460.573CYP0.427ROU
23NLD0.200000.702CYP0.298FIN
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.434810.753CYP0.203FIN0.044ROU
26PRT0.575430.088FIN0.018NOR0.797ROU0.097SWE
27ROU1.000001.000ROU
28SVK0.363340.077CYP0.289FIN0.633ROU
29SVN0.500670.392FIN0.210ROU0.398SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A19. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2005. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A19. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2005. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU NoDMU NameCRS EfficiencySlRTSBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.872260.994Increasing0.369FIN0.460NOR0.165ROU
2BEL0.272600.727Increasing0.049FIN0.678ROU
3BGR0.411300.960Increasing0.154FIN0.805ROU
4CHE0.576911.026Decreasing0.013FIN0.320NOR0.692ROU
5CYP0.863230.863Increasing0.863ROU
6CZE0.200070.734Increasing0.309FIN0.425ROU
7DEU0.405900.812Increasing0.225FIN0.587ROU
8DNK0.397720.795Increasing0.000NOR0.795ROU
9ESP0.296170.888Increasing0.221FIN0.667ROU
10EST0.270670.812Increasing0.680FIN0.132ROU
11FIN1.000001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.313580.941Increasing0.063FIN0.878ROU
13GBR0.167220.780Increasing0.780ROU
14GRC0.410630.821Increasing0.140FIN0.681ROU
15HRV0.665751.051Decreasing0.074FIN0.281NOR0.696ROU
16HUN0.469770.940Increasing0.940ROU
17IRL0.236060.708Increasing0.708ROU
18ISL0.875621.075Decreasing0.968NOR0.106ROU
19ITA0.322110.859Increasing0.132FIN0.727ROU
20LTU0.523731.047Decreasing0.105FIN0.942ROU
21LVA0.715941.256Decreasing0.354FIN0.415NOR0.487ROU
22MLT0.191500.894Increasing0.894ROU
23NLD0.134750.674Increasing0.674ROU
24NOR1.000001.000Constant1.000NOR
25POL0.435170.870Increasing0.130FIN0.740ROU
26PRT0.487390.975Increasing0.199FIN0.776ROU
27ROU1.000001.000Constant1.000ROU
28SVK0.259410.951Increasing0.306FIN0.645ROU
29SVN0.391641.044Decreasing0.728FIN0.316ROU
30SWE0.822381.203Decreasing0.767FIN0.167NOR0.269ROU
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table A20. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2005. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table A20. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2005. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameVRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMUλDMUλDMUλDMU
1AUT0.873990.366FIN0.457NOR0.178ROU
2BEL0.375000.927CYP0.068FIN0.005ROU
3BGR0.428570.130FIN0.870ROU
4CHE0.617070.042ISL0.117LVA0.228NOR0.613ROU
5CYP1.000001.000CYP
6CZE0.272730.712CYP0.288FIN
7DEU0.500000.696CYP0.249FIN0.055ROU
8DNK0.500001.000ROU
9ESP0.333330.152FIN0.848ROU
10EST0.333330.363CYP0.637FIN
11FIN1.000001.000FIN
12FRA0.333330.026FIN0.974ROU
13GBR0.214290.872CYP0.128FIN
14GRC0.500000.680CYP0.167FIN0.153ROU
15HRV0.730350.191LVA0.200NOR0.600ROU0.008SWE
16HUN0.500000.442CYP0.558ROU
17IRL0.333330.786CYP0.214ROU
18ISL1.000001.000ISL
19ITA0.375000.044FIN0.956ROU
20LTU0.693640.290LVA0.710ROU
21LVA1.000001.000LVA
22MLT0.214291.000ROU
23NLD0.200000.782CYP0.218ROU
24NOR1.000001.000NOR
25POL0.500000.050FIN0.950ROU
26PRT0.500000.184FIN0.816ROU
27ROU1.000001.000ROU
28SVK0.272730.276FIN0.724ROU
29SVN0.438080.525FIN0.222ROU0.252SWE
30SWE1.000001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.

References

  1. Pearce, D.; Palmer, C. Public and private spending for environmental protection: A cross-country policy analysis. Fisc. Stud. 2001, 22, 403–456. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Ercolano, S.; Romano, O. Spending for the environment: General government expenditure trends in Europe. Soc. Indic. Res. 2018, 138, 1145–1169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bernauer, T.; Koubi, V. States as providers of public goods: How does government size affect environmental quality? SSRN 2006, 14, 1–33. Available online: http://ssrn.com/abstract=900487 (accessed on 12 May 2021). [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Frederik, C.; Lundström, S. Political and Economic Freedom and the Environment: The Case of CO2 Emissions; Working Paper in Economics; University of Gothenburg: Gothenburg, Sweden, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  5. Lopez, R.; Galinato, G.I.; Islam, F. Fiscal spending and the environment: Theory and empirics. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2011, 62, 180–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Halkos, G.E.; Paizanos, E.A. The effect of government expenditure on the environment: An empirical investigation. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 91, 48–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Halkos, G.E.; Paizanos, E.A. The effects of fiscal policy on CO2 emissions: Evidence from the USA. Energy Policy 2016, 88, 317–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Galinato, G.I.; Islam, F. The Challenge of Addressing Consumption Pollutants with Fiscal Policy; Working Paper Series WP 2014-1; Washington State University: Washington, DC, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  9. Xing, M.; Tan, T. Environmental attitudes and impactsof privatization on R&D, environment and welfare in a mixed duopoly. Econ. Res.—Ekon. Istr. 2021, 34, 807–827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Hettige, H.; Huq, M.; Pargal, S.; Wheeler, D. Determinants of pollution abatement in developing countries. World Dev. 1996, 24, 1891–1904. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Ohori, S. Optimal environmental tax and level of privatization in an international duopoly. J. Regul. Econ. 2006, 29, 225–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Pal, R.; Saha, B. Pollution tax, partial privatization and environment. Resour. Energy Econ. 2015, 40, 19–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Chang, L.; Li, W.; Lu, X. Government engagement, environmental policy, and environmental performance: Evidence from the most polluting Chinese listed firms. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2015, 24, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Xing, M.; Tan, T.; Wang, X. Environmental R&D subsidy, spillovers and privatization in a mixed duopoly. Econ. Res.—Ekon. Istr. 2019, 32, 2989–3015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Jordan, A.; Adelle, C. Environmental Policy in the EU: Actors, Institutions and Processes; Routledge: London, UK, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  16. Destek, M.A.; Ulucak, R.; Dogan, E. Analyzing the environmental Kuznets curve for the EU countries: The role of ecological footprint. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. Int. 2018, 25, 29387–29396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  17. Wach, K.; Głodowska, A.; Maciejewski, M.; Sieja, M. Europeanization processes of the EU energy policy in Visegrad countries in the years 2005–2018. Energies 2021, 14, 1802. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Allen, M.L.; Allen, M.M.C.; Cumming, D.; Johan, S. Comparative capitalisms and energy transitions: Renewable energy in the European Union. Br. J. Manag. 2020, 32, 611–629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Agranoff, R.; Ballart, X. The Effects on Domestic Versus Europeanization Influences on Intergovernmental Relations: The Case of Spain; Instituto Universitario Ortega y Gasset: Madrid, Spain, 2009; pp. 1–46. [Google Scholar]
  20. Solorio, I.; Jörgens, H. Contested energy transition? Europeanization and authority turns in EU renewable energy policy. J. Eur. Integr. 2020, 42, 77–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Vasconcelos, J. Towards the internal energy market, how to bridge a regulatory gap and build a regulatory framework. Eur. Rev. Energy Mark. 2005, 1, 81–103. [Google Scholar]
  22. Bouzarovski, S.; Petrova, S.; Sarlamanov, R. Energy poverty policies in the EU: A critical perspective. Energy Policy 2012, 49, 76–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Laing, T.; Sato, M.; Grubb, M.; Comberti, C. Assessing the Effectiveness of the EU Emissions Trading System; Working Paper; Center for Climate Change Economics and Policy: London, UK, 2013; Volume 126, Available online: https://www.lse.ac.uk/granthaminstitute/wpcontent/uploads/2014/02/WP106-effectiveness-eu-emissions-trading-system.pdf (accessed on 21 May 2021).
  24. Van de Graaf, T.; Colgan, J.D. Russian gas games or well-oiled conflict? Energy security and the 2014 Ukraine crisis. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2017, 24, 59–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Pollitt, M.G. The European single market in electricity: An economic assessment. Rev. Ind. Organ. 2019, 55, 63–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Kuznets, S. Economic growth and income inequality. Amer. Econ. Rev. 1955, 45, 1–28. [Google Scholar]
  27. Halkos, G.; Paizanos, E.A. Exploring the Effect of Economic Growth and Government Expenditure on the Environment; MRNA Paper: Munich, Germany, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  28. Rodrik, D. The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence; Harvard University: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  29. Stiglitz, J.E. The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers Our Future; WW Norton & Company: New York, NY, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  30. Busch, P.O.; Jörgens, H. The international sources of policy convergence: Explaining the spread of environmental policy innovations. J. Eur. Pub. Policy 2005, 12, 860–884. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Holzinger, K.; Sommerer, T. Race to the bottom or race to Brussels? Environmental competition in Europe. J. Common Mark. Stud. 2011, 49, 315–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Holzinger, K.; Knill, C.; Sommerer, T. Environmental policy convergence: The impact of international harmonization, transnational communication, and regulatory competition. Int. Organ. 2008, 62, 553–587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Holzinger, K.; Knill, C. The interaction of competition, co-operation and communication: Theoretical analysis of different sources of environmental policy convergence. J. Comp. Policy Anal. Res. Pract. 2008, 10, 403–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Halkos, G. Environmental Kuznets curve for sulfur: Evidence using GMM estimation and random coefficient panel data models. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2003, 8, 581–601. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Folster, S.; Henrekson, M. Growth effects of government expenditure and taxation in rich countries. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2001, 45, 1501–1520. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Bergh, A.; Karlsson, M. Government size and growth: Accounting for economic freedom and globalization. Public Choice 2010, 142, 195–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Grossman, G.; Krueger, A. Economic growth and the environment. Q. J. Econ. 1995, 110, 353–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Harbaugh, W.; Levinson, A.; Wilson, D. Re-examining the empirical evidence for an environmental Kuznets curve. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2002, 84, 541–551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. De Bruyn, S.M. Economic Growth and the Environment: An Empirical Analysis; Kluwer Academic Publishers: MA London, UK, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  40. Acemoglu, D.; Robinson, J.A. The political economy of the Kuznets curve. Rev. Dev. Econ. 2002, 6, 183–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Stern, D.I. The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve. World Dev. 2004, 32, 1419–1439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Markandya, A.; Golub, A.; Galinato, S.P. Empirical analysis of national income and SO2 emissions in selected European countries. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2006, 35, 221–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Vehmas, J.; Luukkanen, J.; Kaivo-Oja, J. Linking analyses and environmental Kuznets curves for aggregated material flows in the EU. J. Clean. Prod. 2007, 15, 1662–1673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Coondoo, D.; Dinda, S. Carbon dioxide emission and income: A temporal analysis of cross-country distributional patterns. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 65, 375–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Akbostancı, E.; Türüt-Asık, S.; Tunç, G.I. The relationship between income and environment in Turkey: Is there an environmental Kuznets curve? Energy Policy 2009, 37, 861–867. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Lee, C.C.; Chiu, Y.-B.; Sun, C.-H. The environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis for water pollution: Do regions matter? Energy Policy 2010, 38, 12–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Donfouet, H.P.P.; Jeanty, P.W.; Malin, E. A Spatial Dynamic Panel Analysis of the Environmental Kuznets Curve in European Countries; Center for Research in Economics and Management (CREM): Rennes, France, 2013; Available online: http://crem.univ-rennes1.fr/wp/2013/201318.pdf (accessed on 12 May 2021).
  48. Kaika, D.; Zervas, E. The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) theory—Part A: Concept, causes and the CO2 emissions case. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 1392–1402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Rafaj, P.; Amann, M.; Siri, J.; Wuester, H. Changes in European greenhouse gas and air pollutant emissions 1960–2010: Decomposition of determining factors. Clim. Chang. 2014, 124, 477–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. López-Menéndez, A.J.; Pérez, R.; Moreno, B. Environmental costs and renewable energy: Re-visiting the Environmental Kuznets Curve. J. Environ. Manag. 2014, 145, 368–373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  51. Arbulú, I.; Lozano, J.; Rey-Maquieira, J. Tourism and solid waste generation in Europe: A panel data assessment of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Waste Manag. 2015, 46, 628–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  52. Kasman, A.; Duman, Y.S. CO2 emissions, economic growth, energy consumption, trade and urbanization in new EU member and candidate countries: A panel data analysis. Econ. Model. 2015, 44, 97–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Al-Mulali, U.; Tang, C.F.; Ozturk, I. Estimating the Environment Kuznets Curve hypothesis: Evidence from Latin America and the Caribbean countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 50, 918–924. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Shahbaz, M.; Solarin, S.A.; Ozturk, I. Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis and the role of globalization in selected African countries. Ecol. Indic. 2016, 67, 623–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  55. Bilgili, F.; Koçak, E.; Bulut, Ü. The dynamic impact of renewable energy consumption on CO2 emissions: A revisited Environmental Kuznets Curve approach. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 54, 838–845. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Dogan, E.; Seker, F. Determinants of CO2 emissions in the European Union: The role of renewable and non-renewable energy. Renew. Energy 2016, 94, 429–439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Pablo-Romero, M.P.; Cruz, L.; Barata, E. Testing the transport energy-environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis in the EU27 countries. Energy Econ. 2017, 62, 257–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Atasoy, B.S. Testing the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis across the U.S.: Evidence from panel mean group estimators. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 77, 731–747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Hanif, I.; Gago-De-Santos, P. The importance of population control and macroeconomic stability to reducing environmental degradation: An empirical test of the environmental Kuznets curve for developing countries. Environ. Dev. 2017, 23, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Ahmad, N.; Du, L.; Lu, J.; Wang, J.; Li, H.-Z.; Hashmi, M.Z. Modelling the CO2 emissions and economic growth in Croatia: Is there any environmental Kuznets curve. Energy 2017, 123, 164–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Moutinho, V.; Varum, C.; Madaleno, M. How economic growth affects emissions? An investigation of the environmental Kuznets curve in Portuguese and Spanish economic activity sectors. Energy Policy 2017, 106, 326–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Pal, D.; Mitra, S.K. The environmental Kuznets curve for carbon dioxide in India and China: Growth and pollution at crossroad. J. Policy Model. 2017, 39, 371–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Özokcu, S.; Özdemir, Ö. Economic growth, energy, and environmental Kuznets curve. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 72, 639–647. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Sinha, A.; Shahbaz, M. Estimation of Environmental Kuznets Curve for CO2 emission: Role of renewable energy generation in India. Renew. Energy 2018, 119, 703–711. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  65. Kiliç, C.; Balan, F. Is there an environmental Kuznets inverted-U shaped curve? Panoeconomicus 2018, 65, 79–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Pata, U.K. Renewable energy consumption, urbanization, financial development, income and CO2 emissions in Turkey: Testing EKC hypothesis with structural breaks. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 187, 770–779. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Aruga, K. Investigating the Energy-Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis for the Asia-Pacific region. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  68. Koilo, V. Evidence of the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Unleashing the opportunity of industry 4.0 in emerging economies. J. Risk Financ. Manag. 2019, 12, 122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  69. Maneejuk, P.; Yamaka, W.; Sriboonchitta, S. Does the Kuznets curve exist in Thailand? A two decades’ perspective (1993–2015). Ann. Oper. Res. 2019, 300, 545–576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Maneejuk, N.; Ratchakom, S.; Maneejuk, P.; Yamaka, W. Does the Environmental Kuznets Curve exist? An international study. Sustainability 2020, 12, 9117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Martínez-Navarro, D.; Amate-Fortes, I.; Guarnido-Rueda, A. Inequality and development: Is the Kuznets curve in effect today? Econ. Politica 2020, 37, 703–735. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Halliru, A.M.; Loganathan, N.; Hassan, A.A.G.; Mardani, A.; Kamyab, H. Re-examining the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis in the Economic Community of West African States: A panel quantile regression approach. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 276, 124247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Shahbaz, M.; Tiwari, K.; Nasir, M. The effects of financial development, economic growth, coal consumption and trade openness on CO2 emissions in South Africa. Energy Policy 2013, 61, 1452–1459. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Liu, X.; Bae, J. Urbanization and industrialization impact of CO2 emissions in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 172, 178–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Halkos, G.E.; Paizanos, E.A. The channels of the effect of government expenditure on the environment: Evidence using dynamic panel data. J. Environ. Plann. Manag. 2017, 60, 135–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Krajewski, P.; Mackiewicz, M. The role of capital and labour in shaping the environmental effects of fiscal stimulus. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 216, 323–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Hubacek, K.; Baiocchi, G.; Feng, K. Poverty eradication in a carbon constrained world. Nat. Commun. 2017, 8, 912. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  78. Chen, J.D.; Fan, W.; Li, D.; Liu, X.; Song, M.L. Driving factors of global carbon footprint pressure: Based on vegetation carbon sequestration. Appl. Energy 2020, 267, 114914. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Zhang, W.W.; Xu, S.C.; Sharp, B. Do CO2 emissions impact energy use? An assessment of China evidence from 1953 to 2017. China Econ. Rev. 2019, 57, 101340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Cole, M.A.; Elliott, R.J.R.; Okubo, T.; Zhou, Y. The carbon dioxide emissions of firms: A spatial analysis. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2012, 65, 290–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  81. Xu, X.K.; Han, L.Y.; Lv, X.F. Household carbon inequality in urban China, its sources and determinants. Ecol. Econ. 2016, 128, 77–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Omri, A.; Nguyen, D.K.; Rault, C. Causal interactions between CO2 emissions, FDI, and economic growth: Evidence from dynamic simultaneous-equation models. Econ. Model. 2014, 42, 382–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  83. Wang, G.F.; Deng, X.Z.; Wang, J.Y.; Zhang, F.; Liang, S.Q. Carbon emission efficiency in China: A spatial panel data analysis. China Econ. Rev. 2019, 56, 101313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Rhee, H.C.; Chung, H.S. Change in CO2 emission and its transmissions between Korea and Japan using international input–output analysis. Ecol. Econ. 2006, 58, 788–800. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Cansino, J.M.; Roman, R.; Rueda-Cantuche, J.M. Will China comply with its 2020 carbon intensity commitment? Environ. Sci. Policy 2015, 47, 108–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Nag, B.; Parikh, J. Indicators of carbon emission intensity from commercial energy use in India. Energy Econ. 2000, 22, 441–461. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Tan, X.J.; Liu, Y.; Cui, J.B.; Su, B. Assessment of carbon leakage by channels: An approach combining CGE model and decomposition analysis. Energy Econ. 2018, 74, 535–545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Bekhet, H.A.; Othman, N.S. The role of renewable energy to validate dynamic interaction between CO2 emissions and GDP toward sustainable development in Malaysia. Energy Econ. 2018, 72, 47–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Mikayilov, J.I.; Galeotti, M.; Hasanov, F.J. The impact of economic growth on CO2 emissions in Azerbaijan. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 197, 1558–1572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Acaravcı, A.; Ozturk, I. On the relationship between energy consumption, CO2 emissions and economic growth in Europe. Energy 2010, 35, 5412–5420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Bölük, G.; Mert, M. Fossil & renewable energy consumption, GHGs (greenhouse gases) and economic growth: Evidence from a panel of EU (European Union) countries. Energy 2014, 74, 439–446. [Google Scholar]
  92. Ahmed, A.; Uddin, G.S.; Sohag, K. Biomass energy, technological progress and the environmental Kuznets curve: Evidence from selected European countries. Biomass-Bioenergy 2016, 90, 202–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Abid, M. Does economic, financial and institutional developments matter for environmental quality? A comparative analysis of EU and MEA countries. J. Environ. Manag. 2017, 188, 183–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  94. Panayotou, T. Economic Growth and the Environment; Center for International Development (CID) at Harvard University: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2000; Volume 56. [Google Scholar]
  95. Cole, M.A.; Elliott, R.J. Determining the trade-environment composition effect: The role of capital, labor and environmental regulations. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2003, 46, 363–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Dinda, S. Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis: A survey. Ecol. Econ. 2004, 49, 431–455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  97. Tsurumi, T.; Managi, S. Decomposition of the environmental Kuznets curve: Scale, technique, and composition effects. Environ. Econ. Policy Stud. 2010, 11, 19–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Menegaki, A.N.; Tsagarakis, K.P. Rich enough to go renewable, but too early to leave fossil energy? Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 41, 1465–1477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. Freeman, A.M. Air and Water Pollution Control: A Benefit-Cost Assessment; Wiley: New York, NY, USA, 1982. [Google Scholar]
  100. Freeman, A.M. Water pollution policy. In Public Policies for Environmental Protection; Portney, P., Ed.; Resources for the Future: Washington, DC, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  101. Hahn, R. (Ed.) Regulatory reform: What the government’s numbers tell us. In Risks, Costs and Lives Saved: Getting Better Results from Regulation; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  102. Portney, P. Air pollution policy. In Public Policies for Environmental Protection; Resources for the Future: Washington, DC, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  103. Mandl, U.; Dierx, A.; Ilzkovitz, F. The Effectiveness and Efficiency of Public Spending; Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission: Luxembourg, 2008; Volume 301. [Google Scholar]
  104. Srebotnjak, T. Encyclopedia of Quantitative Risk Analysis and Assessment; Environmental performance index; John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.: Singapore, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  105. Apergis, N.; Christou, C.; Hassapis, C. Convergence in public expenditures across EU countries: Evidence from club convergence. Econ. Financ. Res. 2013, 1, 45–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  106. Ferreiro, J.; García-del-Valle, M.T.; Gómez, C. Social preferences and fiscal policies: An analysis of the composition of public expenditures in the European Union. J. Post Keynes. Econ. 2010, 32, 347–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Ferreiro, J.; García-del-Valle, M.T.; Gómez, C. An analysis of the convergence of the composition of public expenditures in European Union countries. Am. J. Econ. Soc. 2013, 72, 799–825. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Ullah, S.; Majeed, M.T.; Chishti, M.Z. Examining the asymmetric effects of fiscal policy instruments on environmental quality in Asian economies. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2020, 27, 38287–38299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  109. Chen, A.P.; Groenewold, N. China’s ‘’New Normal’’: Is the growth slowdown demand-or supply-driven? China Econ. Rev. 2019, 58, 101203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  110. Cheong, T.S.; Wu, Y.R. The impacts of structural transformation and industrial upgrading on regional inequality in China. China Econ. Rev. 2014, 31, 339–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Zhou, C.; Zhang, X. Measuring the Efficiency of Fiscal Policies for Environmental Pollution Control and the Spatial Effect of Fiscal Decentralization in China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 8974. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Farrell, M.J. The measurement of productive efficiency. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. A 1957, 120, 253–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Charnes, A.; Cooper, W.W.; Rhodes, E. Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 1979, 2, 429–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Cooper, W.W.; Seiford, L.M.; Tone, K. Data Envelopment Analysis: A Comprehensive Text with Models, Applications, References and DEA-Solver Software; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Boston, MA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  115. Cook, W.D.; Tone, K.; Zhu, J. Data envelopment analysis: Prior to choosing a model. Omega 2014, 44, 1–4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  116. Jenkins, L.; Anderson, M. A multivariate statistical approach to reducing the number of variables in data envelopment analysis. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2003, 147, 51–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  117. Thanassoulis, E. Using data envelopment analysis in practice. In Introduction to the Theory and Application of Data Envelopment Analysis; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Norwell, MA, USA, 2001; pp. 89–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  118. Cooper, J.O.; Heron, T.E.; Heward, W.L. Applied Behavior Analysis, 2nd ed.; Pearson: Upper Saddle River, NJ, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  119. Simar, L.; Wilson, P. Non-parametric tests of returns to scale. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2002, 139, 115–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Huguenin, J. Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA): A Pedagogical Guide for Decision Makers in the Public Sector; Swiss Graduate School of Public Administration: Lausanne, Switzerland, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  121. Alirezaee, M.R.; Howland, M.; van de Panne, C. Sampling size and efficiency bias in data envelopment analysis. J. Appl. Math. Decis. Sci. 1998, 2, 51–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  122. Dobrzanski, P. Spending on innovation as a factor of competitiveness of market economies. In Country Experiences in Economic Development, Management and Entrepreneurship; Bilgin, M., Danis, H., Demir, E., Can, U., Eds.; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2017; Volume 5, pp. 125–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  123. Wober, K.W. Data envelopment analysis. J. Travel Tour. Mark. 2007, 21, 91–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. Zhang, Y.; Bartels, R. The effect of sample size on the mean efficiency in DEA with an application to electricity distribution in Australia, Sweden and New Zealand. J. Prod. Anal. 1998, 9, 187–204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Banker, R.D.; Charnes, A.; Cooper, W.W.; Swarts, J.; Thomas, D. An Introduction to Data Envelopment Analysis with Some of Its Models and Their Uses; Research Government and Nonprofit Accounting; JAI Press: Greenich, CT, USA, 1989; Volume 5, pp. 125–163. [Google Scholar]
  126. Eurostat. National Expenditure on Environmental Protection. Available online: https://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/submitViewTableAction.do (accessed on 11 June 2021).
  127. World Bank, Environment. Available online: https://data.worldbank.org/topic/environment (accessed on 11 June 2021).
  128. Cai, Y. Factors Affecting the Efficiency of the BRICS’ National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Study Based on DEA and Panel Data Analysis; Economics (Open e-Journal), Economics Discussion Papers; Kiel Institute for the World Economy: Kiel, Germany, 2011; Volume 52. [Google Scholar]
  129. Podinovski, V. Production trade-offs and weight restrictions in data envelopment analysis. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2004, 55, 1311–1322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  130. European Commission. SF 2007–2013 Funds Absorption Rate. Available online: https://cohesiondata.ec.europa.eu/2007-2013-Finances/SF-2007-2013-Funds-Absorption-Rate/kk86-ceun/data (accessed on 11 June 2021).
  131. European Environment Agency. The European Environment—State and Outlook 2020. Knowledge for Transition to A Sustainable Europe; Publications Office of the European Union: Luxembourg, 2019.
  132. Berg, A.; Buffie, E.F.; Pattillo, C.; Portillo, R.; Presbitero, A.; Zanna, L.-F. Some Misconceptions about Public Investment Efficiency and Growth; IMF Working Paper 15/272; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  133. Shen, W.; Yang, S.-C.S.; Zanna, L.-F. Government spending effects in low-income countries. J. Dev. Econ. 2018, 133, 201–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  134. European Anti-Fraud Office. The OLAF Report 2020; Publications Office of the European Union: Luxembourg, 2021.
Table 1. Indicators and Sources.
Table 1. Indicators and Sources.
VariableIndicator NameUnitsSource
Input—EPEEnvironmental protection expenditure(% GDP)Eurostat, 2021 [126]
Output 1—FAForest area(% of land area)World Bank, 2021 [127]
Output 2—REORenewable electricity output(% of total electricity output)World Bank, 2021 [127]
Output 3—COECO2 emissions(metric tons per capita)World Bank, 2021 [127]
Table 2. Diagnostic set of input and output data—European countries in 2015. Source: World Bank [127], Eurostat [126].
Table 2. Diagnostic set of input and output data—European countries in 2015. Source: World Bank [127], Eurostat [126].
2015Country/IndicatorsEPEFAREOCOE
1AUT0.4046.8876.490.56
2BEL1.3022.7620.800.46
3BGR0.8035.2217.990.62
4CHE0.6031.7362.200.73
5CYP0.4018.698.780.67
6CZE1.1034.5411.400.42
7DEU0.6032.7329.230.45
8DNK0.4014.5865.510.67
9ESP0.9036.8634.950.67
10EST0.7051.3514.420.23
11FIN0.2073.1144.500.52
12FRA1.0031.0315.860.72
13GBR0.8013.0024.840.62
14GRC1.5031.4528.660.63
15HRV0.7034.3566.830.75
16HUN1.2022.8510.580.72
17IRL0.4010.9527.970.53
18ISL0.600.4999.980.63
19ITA0.9031.6138.680.68
20LTU0.5034.8039.410.72
21LVA0.7053.9750.170.78
22MLT1.901.097.670.78
23NLD1.4011.1612.440.37
24NOR0.9033.1797.710.44
25POL0.6030.8113.800.54
26PRT0.6034.7447.530.71
27ROU1.0029.8239.750.78
28SVK0.9040.3522.680.64
29SVN1.0061.9629.390.63
30SWE0.4068.9263.260.76
Note: AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia. EPE—environmental protection expenditure (% GDP), FA—forest area (% of land area), REO—renewable electricity output (% of total electricity output), COE—CO2 emissions (metric tons per capita).
Table 3. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table 3. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of EPS in 2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameInput-Oriented CRS Efficiency∑λRTSBenchmarksDMU
1AUT0.8591.719Decreasing1.719FIN
2BEL0.1350.878Increasing0.878FIN
3BGR0.2961.182Decreasing1.182FIN
4CHE0.4691.410Decreasing1.410FIN
5CYP0.6471.294Decreasing1.294FIN
6CZE0.1460.800Increasing0.800FIN
7DEU0.2890.867Increasing0.867FIN
8DNK0.7361.472Decreasing1.472FIN
9ESP0.2851.281Decreasing1.281FIN
10EST0.2010.702Increasing0.702FIN
11FIN1.0001.000Constant1.000FIN
12FRA0.2761.378Decreasing1.378FIN
13GBR0.2961.184Decreasing1.184FIN
14GRC0.1611.208Decreasing1.208FIN
15HRV0.4291.502Decreasing1.502FIN
16HUN0.2311.385Decreasing1.385FIN
17IRL0.5081.016Decreasing1.016FIN
18ISL0.7492.247Decreasing2.247FIN
19ITA0.2881.296Decreasing1.296FIN
20LTU0.5541.386Decreasing1.386FIN
21LVA0.4281.500Decreasing1.500FIN
22MLT0.1571.488Decreasing1.488FIN
23NLD0.1020.716Increasing0.716FIN
24NOR0.4882.196Decreasing2.196FIN
25POL0.3431.030Decreasing1.030FIN
26PRT0.4521.357Decreasing1.357FIN
27ROU0.2981.491Decreasing1.491FIN
28SVK0.2751.237Decreasing1.237FIN
29SVN0.2401.201Decreasing1.201FIN
30SWE0.7291.458Decreasing1.458FIN
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, ∑λ—Lambda sum, Unit, RTS—Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table 4. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table 4. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of EPS in 2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU NameInput-Oriented VRS EfficiencyBenchmarksDMULambdaDMULambdaDMU
1AUT1.0001.000AUT
2BEL0.1541.000FIN
3BGR0.3490.602FIN0.398SWE
4CHE0.6400.032AUT0.079FIN0.888SWE
5CYP0.8210.359FIN0.641SWE
6CZE0.1821.000FIN
7DEU0.3331.000FIN
8DNK0.9410.336AUT0.117FIN0.547SWE
9ESP0.3590.386FIN0.614SWE
10EST0.2861.000FIN
11FIN1.0001.000FIN
12FRA0.3650.175FIN0.825SWE
13GBR0.3500.599FIN0.401SWE
14GRC0.1940.545FIN0.455SWE
15HRV0.5980.007AUT0.095ISL0.898SWE
16HUN0.3070.159FIN0.841SWE
17IRL0.5180.964FIN0.036SWE
18ISL1.0001.000ISL
19ITA0.3660.354FIN0.646SWE
20LTU0.7370.157FIN0.843SWE
21LVA1.0001.000LVA
22MLT0.3240.722LVA0.278SWE
23NLD0.1431.000FIN
24NOR1.0001.000-
25POL0.3550.934FIN0.066SWE
26PRT0.5930.222FIN0.778SWE
27ROU0.6360.786LVA0.214SWE
28SVK0.3370.482FIN0.518SWE
29SVN0.2880.561FIN0.439SWE
30SWE1.0001.000SWE
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table 5. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditure in 2005–2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table 5. Input-Oriented CRS Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditure in 2005–2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU Name20152014201320122011201020092008200720062005Avr
1FIN1.001.001.001.001.001.000.911.001.001.001.000.99
2ISL0.751.001.000.821.000.910.521.001.000.890.880.89
3CYP0.651.001.000.850.920.830.511.001.001.000.860.87
4AUT0.861.001.000.730.790.600.450.930.980.880.870.83
5SWE0.731.000.780.580.850.870.510.890.980.930.820.81
6NOR0.490.740.620.600.730.650.381.001.001.001.000.75
7LVA0.430.600.570.470.481.001.000.620.600.720.720.65
8CHE0.470.690.620.490.550.520.290.900.830.640.580.60
9HRV0.430.820.580.480.520.570.260.720.720.750.670.59
10DNK0.740.770.610.620.650.560.370.660.650.480.400.59
11ROU0.300.500.390.360.360.370.320.821.001.001.000.58
12PRT0.450.710.540.480.450.410.300.580.690.570.490.52
13LTU0.550.630.620.350.450.220.160.470.420.470.520.44
14HUN0.230.280.250.400.440.470.310.600.580.490.470.41
15DEU0.290.410.350.330.380.350.230.580.590.480.410.40
16POL0.340.440.330.370.350.320.210.440.510.430.440.38
17SVN0.240.350.430.290.320.420.260.410.450.450.390.37
18ITA0.290.400.330.280.300.310.200.420.470.460.320.34
19EST0.200.300.300.160.720.750.250.220.270.350.270.34
20BGR0.300.440.270.360.390.380.160.480.280.290.410.34
21SVK0.270.400.280.280.350.280.180.430.510.340.260.33
22FRA0.280.330.240.270.300.270.180.410.400.390.310.31
23IRL0.510.470.360.280.320.220.120.260.270.300.240.30
24ESP0.280.400.340.260.290.240.150.350.340.330.300.30
25GBR0.300.360.250.290.300.230.150.330.320.310.170.27
26GRC0.160.200.150.210.290.300.160.330.370.380.410.27
27BEL0.140.170.120.130.150.160.130.270.340.330.270.20
28CZE0.150.210.190.140.160.190.180.280.250.230.200.20
29MLT0.160.200.140.180.220.140.110.220.200.210.190.18
30NLD0.100.140.100.120.120.110.070.170.170.170.130.13
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table 6. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditure in 2005–2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
Table 6. Input-Oriented VRS Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditure in 2005–2015. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier.
DMU No.DMU Name20152014201320122011201020092008200720062005Average
1FIN1.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.00
2ISL1.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.00
3LVA1.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.00
4NOR1.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.00
5SWE1.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.001.00
6CYP0.821.001.001.001.001.000.671.001.001.001.000.95
7AUT1.001.001.001.000.850.690.630.981.000.890.870.90
8ROU0.640.870.860.760.660.380.331.001.001.001.000.77
9HRV0.601.000.910.980.880.590.290.820.720.850.730.76
10CHE0.640.740.770.880.870.520.331.000.960.690.620.73
11DNK0.940.790.620.940.800.750.500.680.670.520.500.70
12PRT0.590.790.810.940.790.430.330.680.700.580.500.65
13LTU0.740.720.960.650.780.230.170.650.550.660.690.62
14HUN0.310.410.530.760.700.500.330.750.630.530.500.54
15DEU0.330.500.420.330.390.500.330.600.610.500.500.46
16EST0.290.430.370.221.001.000.250.270.330.370.330.44
17POL0.360.500.370.400.370.430.290.440.520.430.500.42
18SVN0.290.350.500.400.390.430.270.450.490.500.440.41
19ITA0.370.410.350.390.360.380.250.440.470.470.380.39
20BGR0.350.440.300.480.450.430.180.550.300.310.430.38
21FRA0.370.390.270.460.460.300.200.490.420.410.330.37
22SVK0.340.410.300.390.410.330.220.470.530.360.270.37
23IRL0.520.500.400.310.350.300.180.270.300.330.330.34
24ESP0.360.400.400.380.370.270.180.370.340.340.330.34
25GBR0.350.380.280.320.320.300.200.330.330.330.210.31
26GRC0.190.210.150.240.320.380.220.330.380.390.500.30
27CZE0.180.270.230.150.160.300.290.330.300.270.270.25
28BEL0.150.210.150.140.160.250.200.300.370.370.380.24
29MLT0.320.200.140.210.260.160.130.270.210.230.210.21
30NLD0.140.210.140.130.130.190.120.200.200.200.200.17
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Table 7. Efficiency Ranking for European Countries. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier; European Commission [130].
Table 7. Efficiency Ranking for European Countries. Source: Authors’ calculations in DEAFrontier; European Commission [130].
DMU NameCRSVRSCRSVRSAVG EffectivenessRankEU Funds
AverageAverageRankRankIndexAbsorption (%)
FIN0.9911.000111.00194.98
ISL0.8881.000210.942-
CYP0.8740.953360.91391.93
SWE0.8131.000510.91494.71
NOR0.7471.000610.875-
AUT0.8270.901470.86689.08
LVA0.6541.000710.83795.00
ROU0.5830.7721180.68870.87
HRV0.5920.761990.68958.57
CHE0.5970.7308100.6610-
DNK0.5920.70110110.651195.00
PRT0.5160.64812120.581294.98
LTU0.4420.61913130.531394.93
HUN0.4100.54114140.481488.37
DEU0.4000.45615150.431591.80
POL0.3800.41816170.401694.86
EST0.3440.44319160.391795.00
SVN0.3650.41017180.391895.00
ITA0.3440.38718190.371978.97
BGR0.3410.38320200.362085.24
SVK0.3280.36821220.352184.36
FRA0.3080.37322210.342292.12
IRL0.3030.34523230.322389.96
ESP0.2990.34124240.322484.07
GBR0.2740.30625250.292588.01
GRC0.2700.30126260.292698.09
CZE0.1970.25128270.222784.13
BEL0.2010.24427280.222893.06
MLT0.1790.21429290.202981.61
NLD0.1270.16930300.153086.54
Note: DMU—decision-making unit, VRS—Variable Returns to Scale, CRS—Constant Returns to Scale, AVG—Average, AUT—Austria, BEL—Belgium, BGR—Bulgaria, CHE—Switzerland, CYP—Cyprus, CZE—The Czech Republic, DEU—Germany, DNK—Denmark, ESP—Spain, EST—Estonia, FIN—Finland, FRA—ZZZ, GBR—United Kingdom, BEL—Belgium, GRC—Greece, HRV—Croatia, HUN—Hungary, IRL—Ireland, ISL—Iceland, ITA—Italy, LTU—Lithuania, LVA—Latvia, MLT—Malta, NLD—Netherlands, NOR—Norway, POL—Poland, PRT—Portugal, ROU—Romania, SVK—Slovak Republic, SVN—Slovenia.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Barrell, A.; Dobrzanski, P.; Bobowski, S.; Siuda, K.; Chmielowiec, S. Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditures in EU Countries. Energies 2021, 14, 8443. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14248443

AMA Style

Barrell A, Dobrzanski P, Bobowski S, Siuda K, Chmielowiec S. Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditures in EU Countries. Energies. 2021; 14(24):8443. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14248443

Chicago/Turabian Style

Barrell, Alan, Pawel Dobrzanski, Sebastian Bobowski, Krzysztof Siuda, and Szymon Chmielowiec. 2021. "Efficiency of Environmental Protection Expenditures in EU Countries" Energies 14, no. 24: 8443. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14248443

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop