Next Article in Journal
Optimal Sizing of Rooftop PV and Battery Storage for Grid-Connected Houses Considering Flat and Time-of-Use Electricity Rates
Next Article in Special Issue
Railway Vehicle Energy Efficiency as a Key Factor in Creating Sustainable Transportation Systems
Previous Article in Journal
Investigating Carbon Emissions from Electricity Generation and GDP Nexus Using Maximum Entropy Bootstrap: Evidence from Oil-Producing Countries in the Middle East
Previous Article in Special Issue
Employee Behaviors toward Using and Saving Energy at Work. The Impact of Personality Traits
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Investigating the Sustainable Impact of Seaport Infrastructure Provision on Maritime Component of Supply Chain

1
Institute of Transport Management, Faculty of Transport Engineering and Economics, Maritime University of Szczecin, 70-500 Szczecin, Poland
2
Institute of Economics and Finance, Faculty of Economics, Finance and Management, University of Szczecin, 70-453 Szczecin, Poland
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2021, 14(12), 3519; https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123519
Submission received: 15 May 2021 / Revised: 8 June 2021 / Accepted: 11 June 2021 / Published: 13 June 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Energy Consumption Patterns in Sustainable Supply Chains)

Abstract

:
The aim of the research is to identify and quantify the direct economic effects resulting from the improved seaport nautical access and capacity expansion. This case study considers a regional port located in the Baltic sea and relates to port users, i.e., shipping operators and shippers. The effects were identified for maritime transport by comparing transport performance in two scenarios: with-the-investment and without-the-investment. Incremental calculus addresses freights (containers, dry bulk, and cereals) traded to and from the given port, changes in size of vessels, and the shipping route alternatives vis-a-vis adjacent ports in the range. Sustainable impact concerns generalized maritime transport cost, i.e., shipping operating costs and port-to-port transit time, as well as energy consumption and external costs of maritime shipping. To capture effects, daily and unit dry bulk, as well as container shipping cost, values of time, and marginal external costs were revealed in freight sea transport. As investigated, shipping operators and shippers will benefit from the reduction in ships’ operating (including ships’ fuel cost savings) and time cost, while the community will enjoy the reduction in externalities. However, the main economic effect is the reduction in shipping operating cost resulting from the increased vessel size (economies of scale).

1. Introduction

In general, a seaport can be described as a place where two domains—the land traffic and maritime traffic—contact and merge with each other. The key role that the seaport plays is to ensure the continuity between two transport systems that cross two spaces with different characteristics [1], which has operations in a foreland, the port proper, and hinterland, thus constituting a (sub) supply chain that brings goods from/to the seaside and to/from the supplier/customer in the hinterland. The foreland of the triptych is a port zone that is far away from the port and is the source or destination of the flow of goods that are coming to or leaving from the port [2]. In particular, the foreland of a port is to be understood as the land area lying on the seaside of the port, excluding the sea area itself. Sea carriers are the link between the foreland of the port and the port itself [3,4]. Port users are entities that operate in the port as part of the process in cargo transshipment from a given place of cargo shipment to a given destination place. Hence, port users are cargo carriers and shippers that utilize ports for freight transportation [5].
Port nautical accessibility refers to the ability of a port to service large vessels at any time. To adjust to the trade growth and offer economies of scale in a highly competitive market, many shipping companies have purchased larger ships. Such a structural change in size of vessels imposes operational challenges on ports. Crucial port investments are needed to accommodate such vessels and to meet the demand for shorter times of turnaround. Moreover, these ports that do not spend their expenditures for investment accordingly may lose their market shares. Therefore, these new requirements become a sine qua non condition for those ports that are willing to keep the pace of market changes and want to defend their competitiveness [6,7].
Seagoing vessels, in general, incur economies of vessel size at sea. Economies of vessel size at sea arise because ship costs in cargo transporting at sea do not grow proportionally to the increase in ship size. At sea, vessels exhibit economies of ship size, i.e., ship costs per tonne/TEU at sea decrease as ship size increases, e.g., [8,9,10]. Ports that can service larger ships while maintaining quick ship turnaround time (i.e., time differences between ships that are entering and leaving a port) will achieve an increase in the number of calls by larger ships and freight volumes in transshipment.
From a microeconomic point of view, an investment in a port’s fixed assets and facilities normally causes an increase of transshipment for both total and per time unit as well as an improvement in quality of port services [11]. First, port investment causes transport-efficiency gains such as shorter service times and lower costs for port users (freight carriers) and economic benefits for port operators. Expansion of the port’s capacity reduces the costs for the port users, which reduces the total generalized transportation costs. This affects the decision of the route choice by freight carriers in favor of the specific port, assuming that everything else stays unchanged [12].
The scope of port investment has an impact on the economic efficiency, which entails the following: (1) direct effects that are manifested in cost savings for port users and operators; (2) indirect effects that are passed on to other companies through a price mechanism; and (3) external effects that are independent of the price mechanism, e.g., traffic congestion and environmental pollution.
The good part is that port users demand efficient (i.e., cheap and fast) port services. Ocean carriers are one of the most important cargo carriers.
This manuscript investigates the impact of improved port nautical access on shipping operators and shippers. It aims at elaborating the direct effects for shipping operators and shippers resulting from port-improved maritime accessibility and capacity expansion. We quantified effects applying a generalized cost concept in maritime transport with the use of shipping operating costs, time cost, as well as cost economies of ship size.
Some aspects of port infrastructure that impact port users can implicitly be derived from studies concerning port competitiveness and port choice. Based on insights from the scientific literature (see e.g., [6]), the endowment of port infrastructure and nautical accessibility is mentioned among the key drivers of port competitiveness. A port is competitive if it possesses excellent hinterland and maritime access and offers superior connectivity to markets [13]. The problem of maritime accessibility and port competitiveness is further explored in [14,15,16,17].
The shipper chooses the port of destination. In fact, it happens through his (or his agent’s) choice of carrier. Even when the carrier chooses the port, he only has a chance if he is himself chosen first [5,18,19]. The choice of destination port is dependent on the choice of supply chains that is made by shippers, shipper representatives, the shipping line, and others [20]. Travel time is considered by shippers as the most crucial factor of port choice. Consequently, thanks to such choice, shippers can minimize the costs of freight transportation incurred by travel time [18,21]. Shippers choose the port that is closest to the import or export cargo destination to keep their transportation costs low enough.
Malchow and Kanafani [22,23] indicate that a shipper, by choosing a carrier, implicitly chooses a port for a given shipment. They concluded that inland distance and ocean distance were the most crucial factors influencing port choice by carriers. Describing the determinants of maritime carriers’ port choice, one of them is the consignment size, i.e., the amount of cargo to be transported by ships to and from the port. The larger the consignment size, the greater probability that a shipping operator will have its vessels call at a given port [5].
Veldman and Buckman [24] analyzed container port choice for both the continental and the overseas hinterland of West European container hub-ports. Such approach was later expanded to include the improvement of the accessibility of the port of Antwerp by deepening the Scheldt River [25]. Models have been developed for measuring competition between ports, and the most prominent explanatory variables for port choice are inland transport costs, ocean transport costs, port costs, and quality of port services [26].
Zondag [27] built a model of container port competition for Northwest Europe using a generalized cost function. The model allows to calculate port freight flows under different maritime sector scenarios. Such port competition-modelling integrates developments in trade by origin, destination, and cargo type, in ship sizes, maritime access, port capacity and efficiency, maritime access, and hinterland transport. The maritime model component consists of sea transport cost and times between port of origin and destination and uses time cost and distance cost values for six ship size categories.
Dekker [28] and Sanders [29] viewed port competition from the perspective of investments in port capacities. A dynamic port investment modelling addresses scale effects, congestion, competition, and development aspects of the transport network. Determination of demand for port services is essentially based on competition between alternative routes. In the analysis of economic impacts of port capacity investments in the port of Rotterdam [30], it is underlined that a capacity shortage will result in route changes of a part of the potential cargo flows through the port of Rotterdam to other ports, for instance, to Antwerp and Hamburg/Bremen. There is a constant threat that (parts of) cargo flows will shift to competing ports that offer more efficient (cheaper and/or faster) services. Substantial port investments are necessary to accommodate larger vessels and to meet the demand for shorter turnaround times. In most cases, delays in investment process by port authorities may result in a loss of market share [30].
Van Hassel et al. [31] developed a model that allows for estimating the impact of an increase in container vessel size on the generalized chain costs from a point of loading landside, through a port and maritime freight transport to another port and a point of unloading in the other hinterland. Scholars focused on the impact of larger container ships on the generalized costs of the sea–land transportation chain. The maritime component of the model consists of three main parts: a routing module, ship size module, and a cost module. In the maritime leg of the transportation chain, the model was applied to two different container routings (loops) with different ship sizes based on which generalized maritime transport costs were calculated. Jensen and Bergquist [32] calculated cost effects of several scenarios in intermodal chain by, among others, differing liner service direct traffic for a given container flow versus where the feeder traffic is replaced by direct traffic and vice versa. As for the maritime leg, they included in the cost function time-dependent vessel costs and distance-dependent vessel costs, costs of feeder and large deep-sea vessels, and changing vessel size and frequency.
From the review of related research, the relations between port investment, maritime costs, and trade flows have not been sufficiently addressed. There is a lack of research oriented on effects of port infrastructure capacity expansion on maritime trades, vessels, ports, and alternative routes, as well as maritime transport costs elements. When investigating the impact of improved nautical access on port users, the research should be conducted at disaggregated level referring to trade routes, freight types, vessel size, and costs of shipping and time.
This manuscript explores the impact of the improved port nautical access on port users, shipping operators, and shippers, and contributes to the existing literature in several ways.
First, it elaborates the direct economic link between the provision of port infrastructure and the performance of the shipping industry, the latter one being from the sea-leg perspective of the supply chain.
Second, the economic analysis resulting from port capacity expansion is distinguished for these effects coming from the spatial distribution of trades and shipping re-routings, and for those effects resulting from the increased vessel size (economies of scale).
Third, it quantifies the impact of port infrastructure improvements explicitly on port users, namely shipping operators and shippers, and thus creates sound grounds for port investment evaluation and policy decision making.
This manuscript contributes to the literature on problems of maritime logistics chain and relates to discussion on issues of energy consumption and savings in CO2 emissions from ships [33,34,35,36], and sustainable developments of (circular) maritime logistics chains [37,38,39,40,41,42].
The research also gives insight into the broader perspective and global problems of sustainable management, as well as the development of supply chains in terms of dynamic capabilities, role of organizational learning and innovation, and supply chain management [43,44,45].
Our study elaborates on the Baltic and regional port of Szczecin (Poland). The port is a universal port and the cargo volume of 9 million tons per year qualifies it as a small and medium-sized Baltic seaport. The main deficiency of the port is its poor maritime accessibility. Recently, large-scale investments were made in the port of Szczecin, with the goal of improving nautical access to the port. The investments include deepening of a 67.35 km long waterway leading from the Baltic Sea to the port of Szczecin, as well as the expansion in port transshipment capacity. This will enable the port to handle larger vessels and will also increase the cargo handling capacity.
The effects are identified for maritime transport by comparing transport performance in two scenarios: with the investment and without the investment. Only the difference in-between two scenarios is considered, while the analysis addresses the flow of containers, dry bulk and cereals, changes in size of vessels, and shipping route alternatives vis-a-vis adjacent ports in the range. The economic impact of port investment concerns savings in generalized maritime transport cost, i.e., in shipping operating costs (energy consumption included), in the port-to-port transit time costs, and in environmental costs of maritime transport.
The research questions addressed by this study are as follows:
  • How does the improved port maritime excess affect foreland (maritime) transport performance?
  • What is the impact of improved port nautical excess on costs of sea freight transport?
  • What is the structure of port users cost efficiency gains?
To answer these questions, several net effects in maritime transport performance were identified, namely maritime transport distances and volumes of containers, dry bulk and cereals traded to and from port, changes in port competitiveness in the port range, and shipping route alternatives for trades and dispersion in sea distances. To capture economic effects, daily and unit dry bulk and container shipping cost, as well as values of time and marginal external costs, were revealed in freight sea transport. Next, as result of reduced maritime distance, savings in shipping and transit time costs for given cargo flows, as well as in externalities, were quantified. Finally, we estimated cost economies resulting from the increased size of container ship and dry bulk carriers, as well as account shipping operating cost savings for maritime freight trades.
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the research concept and methodological framework. Section 3 refers to inputs and parameters of calculation. Section 4 measures cost savings as a result of reduced freight travel distance and increased vessels size and provides research results. Section 5 draws conclusions while Section 6 includes a discussion as well as further research needs.

2. Research Concept and Methodological Framework

We assume the shipping operators (carriers) and shippers seek to minimize the generalized maritime transport cost, which consists of shipping operating costs and transit time costs. Cost economies of ship size at sea, voyage distance covered by ships, as well as the transit time are crucial factors influencing sea freight transport costs. The development of generalized maritime transport cost with respect to sea distance, re-routings of freight flows, and changes in vessels size in view of the improved port maritime accessibility and transshipment capacity are analyzed. It distinguishes effects resulting from the reduced shipping distance and from the increased vessel size (economies of scale).
The main research problem is to identify the impact of the improved port maritime accessibility and transshipment capacity expansion on the sea freight transport performance and costs. We elaborate a scenario with the investment and a counterfactual scenario without the investment. In the latter, it defines what would happen in the absence of the investment. We compare freight sea transport performance in the port foreland that appears in the scenario: with deepening the fairway and transshipment capacity expansion (in the rest of this paper, this scenario is abbreviated to WI) and with the scenario without deepening the fairway and capacity expansion (in the rest of this paper, this scenario is abbreviated to W0). Finally, we only consider the net difference in transport performance in the scenarios: with the investment and without the investment. This approach is widely recognized in assessing the impacts of infrastructure projects and of large-scale transport projects (e.g., [46,47]).
In the research, a microeconomic approach is applied, which means the effects are measured directly in the transport system, named as internal or direct impacts of infrastructural improvements [48,49,50]. Port infrastructure investments either reduce distances and thereby travel time in sea freight shipping, and/or reduce congestion in port, and/or allow for accommodating larger ships. Either way, they make it possible to offer freight transportation services that are more efficient or more reliable, or both [50]. Direct benefits for shipping carriers and shippers are time related (time savings and reliability) and money related (ship’s operating costs) [50]. Savings in operating and time costs in sea transport increase the surplus of consumers, shipping carriers, and shippers, and hence the welfare.
In the calculus of economic impact of investment, we used the concept of transport generalized cost, a notion that is widely recognized in transport economics (e.g., [31,51,52,53,54]), however, it means differing things according to research context and aims.
Limited to the main components and adopted to freight maritime transport, the generalized transport costs are the sum of the shipping operating costs (maritime carriers operating costs) and the value of transit time in port-to-port relations. In the cost function, the shipping cost and the monetary value of time are homogeneous and addable elements. The generalized sea freight transport costs GC may be defined as below [55]:
GC ( D ) = P ( D ) + H × T ( D ) ,   where :   P D > 0 ,   HT D > 0     GC D > 0 ,   and
where:
  • GC(D)—generalized transport cost,
  • P(D)—shipping operating cost,
  • H—time cost per hour,
  • T(D)—port-to-port transit time.
Generalized transport cost in (1) is the sum of pecuniary costs that are related to the shipping operating cost (P) and time cost (HT), whereas the latter is the product of time cost per hour H and port-to-port transit time (T). It is assumed that P and T, and thereby also GC, are positively correlated to transport distance (D) measured in kilometers (km), while H is independent of the transport distance. We assume shippers and shipping operators choose the transport solutions that give the lowest generalized costs.
The economic effects are quantified using the GC I and GC 0 , being the generalised costs of freight sea transport, respectively, in scenario WI and W0. When the difference in the economic account takes negative values, i.e., GC I   GC 0 < 0 , it is interpreted as an advantage related to the reduction (savings) in generalized costs resulting from improved port infrastructure. The incremental approach was adopted to all transport performance and economic effects in the assessment.
This case study considers the small-and-medium-sized universal port of Szczecin located in the Baltic sea, whereas adjacent and competing ports located in the range consist of two major Polish ports of Gdynia and Gdańsk, and the German port of Rostock. Recently, large-scale investments were made in the port of Szczecin, with the goal of improving port maritime accessibility. This will enable the port to handle larger sea-going vessels and will also increase the cargo handling capacity. Effects of the investments are specified in Table 1.
The implementation of the project will enable handling a container vessel with a loading capacity of 1800 TEU and dry bulk carrier with a loading capacity of 40,000 tonnes. The annual throughput capacity of the port will increase in dry bulk, containers, and cereals, in total, by 3,380,000 tonnes.
Incremental calculus addresses volumes of freights (containers, dry bulk, and grain) traded to and from the port of Szczecin, changes in size of vessels, and the shipping route distance variation vis-a-vis adjacent ports in the range.
Inter-port competition in the range is analyzed straightforwardly, by comparing the following factors in the ports under study: (1) maximum vessel draft, which determines the size of vessel, and (2) the transshipment capacities for given cargo groups. Ship speed is constant regardless of the scenario and size of the ship. The size of sea-going vessels is classified according to the deadweight tonnage (abbr. DWT, or dwt), which is a measure of weight that a ship can carry. This is a total sum of cargo, fuel, both fresh water and ballast water, provisions, crew, and passengers expressed in tonnes. In the case of ships for the transport of containers, the size of such ships is measured by the number of equivalent 20-foot containers (TEUs) that they can transport at one time.
We established alternative sea routes and differences in maritime distance in the context of the port nautical access and capacity, which are sufficient to accommodate traffic and ships.
Only diverted traffic from other routes is considered, which means no generated (induced) traffic is assumed. Because of the difficulty in estimation, the problem of induced traffic is not incorporated in the standard freight demand forecasting procedure [56,57].
To capture economic effects, the long-term transshipment forecast in the port of Szczecin was elaborated to provide reasonable data input reflecting the expected development of good flow volumes over time designed for maritime trades. Also, daily and unit dry bulk and container shipping cost for a given size of vessels is estimated as well as values of time and marginal external costs in freight sea transport. With reference to alternative sea routes, incremental calculus (WI-W0) in maritime generalized transport costs in containers, grain, and dry bulk trades were made, as well as in external costs. Then, we calculated cost economies resulting from deploying larger container vessels and dry bulk carriers. We distinguished effects resulting from the reduced travel distance and from the increased vessel size (economies of scale), which resulted in savings of shipping operation and time costs also in maritime transport externalities.
The article draws a lot from the complex cost–benefit analysis performed by the Authors for the investment assessment in the port of Szczecin. Thus, both the developed port forecasts, values of inputs, and coefficients refer to year 2018 as a base year for calculations. Consequently, the period for which the analysis was carried out includes the waterway operation phase, which is 21 years (2023–2043). The social discount rate used in the analysis is 4.5%, with fixed prices from the account year and without considering inflation throughout the analysis period. In the calculation, unit values of economic benefits are presented in net terms (excluding VAT). The first year of operation of the deepened waterway is 2023, and from this year, economic benefits are calculated.

3. Inputs and Parameters

3.1. Forecasted Demand for Port Transhipment

Investment decisions require the development of long-term forecasts since ports generally have a long technical and economic lifetime, and investments made in port infrastructure have a long pay-back period [58].
Due to structural limitations related to its low transport accessibility, the port of Szczecin is facing barriers to its development and its transport importance has been diminishing. The crucial bottleneck in port of Szczecin accessibility is the depth of the Świnoujście–Szczecin waterway. The freight flow forecasting referred directly to trends and internal conditions at Szczecin’s port, which is burdened with structural limitations of port growth and ignores relations with major ports. Following numerous studies on the dynamics of the development of multi-port systems, e.g., [59,60,61,62,63,64,65,66], it is generally acknowledged that the development of small and medium-size ports (SMPs) is determined by their relationships with major ports which, in turn, are based on the competition and complementarity of handling the growing demand for services in large ports. In our case, the port of Szczecin has a relationship with three other major Polish ports (Świnoujście, Gdańsk, and Gdynia). The method of forecasting the demand in port of Szczecin is therefore relative as it estimates the demand for transshipments in major ports and then uses the indices of the transshipment dynamics to develop forecasts of freight turnover in Szczecin port.
The regression equations for groups of cargo in major ports were estimated with the use of the long-term GDP forecasts of the Ministry of Development and Finance recommended for long-term forecasts in the Polish transport sector. However, the GDP forecasts did not consider the economic impact of the COVID-19 pandemic.
The projected volumes of cargo group throughput in major Polish seaports were converted into dynamics indices. The matrix of indices of demand dynamics for the transshipment of individual cargo groups, as established for Polish major ports, was used to predict demand for services of the port of Szczecin, whereas the starting year for the forecasts was 2018. Given the knowledge of average cargo groups throughput volumes recorded from 2007–2017 in the port of Szczecin and the chain indices of the forecasted increases in cargo throughput in major ports, the following recursive equation was used to produce cargo throughput forecasts for Szczecin’s port:
C t , j * = C t 1 , j * · i t t 1 , j + T ¯ t k 1 , j
where:
  • C t , j * —forecasts for j-th cargo group in time t,
  • C t 1 , j * —forecasts for j-th cargo group in time t − 1,
  • i t t 1 , j —the annual chain indexes of dynamics of cargo throughput growth in j-th cargo group, and
  • T ¯ t k 1 , j —the average level of transit in j-th cargo group determined from k time periods.
The waterway depth does not prevent multi-purpose ships and tankers from calling at the port in Szczecin. According to the information provided by forwarders, the carriage of general cargo, chemical products, and oil products is carried out by ships with a maximum carrying capacity of 12,000 tons and a draught not exceeding 9.15 m. Regarding sea relations to and from the port of Szczecin, no increase in shipment size of these cargoes is expected in the future and, consequently, in the size of the ships. Therefore, for the purpose of forecasting, it was assumed that the transshipments of general cargo and oil will not change and will remain at their average throughput volumes recorded from 2007–2017. Predicted cargo throughput volumes were additionally limited by the handling capacity of the port of Szczecin (Table 2).
In the scenario without the investment, it is considered that the cargo traffic will remain constant around the average volumes of the previous period (2007–2017) for all types of cargo.
The growth indices vary among types of cargo. Container cargo is the most prospective group of freight in the port of Szczecin. It is estimated that due to the Świnoujście–Szczecin waterway deepening, container transshipment will increase by 87.1% in 2043 in comparison to 2023 (first year of waterway operation). Grain will be the second cargo type with a growth rate of +40.3% in the same period. Coal is the least increasing cargo type. It is estimated that coal will increase by 12.1% till 2043. Total cargo transshipment in the port of Szczecin will increase by 28.3% in the next 20 years.
Incremental throughput forecast is depicted in Table 3.
The overview of the projected total freight traffic in the port of Szczecin is depicted in Figure 1.
The produced forecasts in the port of Szczecin anticipate a long-term increase in transshipment by +4.6 million tonnes. The forecasts indicate that the port in Szczecin will retain its universal character in the future, and a moderate increase in transshipment confirms that it will serve as a complementary port to the major Polish ports in the region.

3.2. Sea Distances of Freights Traded to and from Port of Szczecin

A detailed analysis of the volumes and distances of sea transport of dry bulk cargo, grain, and containers handled at the port of Szczecin was computed in Excel sheets, while the aggregated results are depicted in Table 4.

3.3. Port Competitiveness in the Range

When assessing port competitiveness in the range, maritime port accessibility transferred into the maximum draft of the ships, and transshipment capacity for containers, grain, and dry bulk freights were compared.
In the handling of containers, the closest to the port of Szczecin is the port of Gdynia, which has two terminals for handling containers. In the handling of bulk cargo (coal, ore, other bulk), the port of Gdańsk, which is the closest to the port of Szczecin, has an extensive capacity for transshipment of bulk cargo. In terms of the sea transport of grain, competing with the port of Szczecin are the ports of Rostock and Gdynia. Both ports have sufficient capacity for transshipment of grains. The navigation conditions for accommodating container ships, dry bulk carriers, and vessels with grain in the respective ports are presented in Table 5.

3.4. Shipping Route Alternatives and Dispersion of Sea Distances

The diversification of sea transport routes to the analyzed ports will occur in the Baltic Sea. The fairway to the Malmö port, located at the entry of sea-going vessels to the Baltic Sea, is used as a reference point. It is a common navigational position for ships serving the Baltic Sea freights. From this point on, the hypothetical distribution of sea transport is determined for the distinguished groups of cargo in the scenarios WI and W0 (Figure 2).
In the W0 scenario, the forecasted volumes of freights will be directed to Rostock (for grain), Gdynia (for containers and grain), and Gdańsk (for dry bulk cargo). This is because the ports have sufficient conditions to handle larger ships and the capacity to reload cargo groups (point 3.3). In the WI scenario, the forecasted volumes of cargo are directed to the port of Szczecin. The differences in sea distances between the fairway to port in Malmö and the ports of Szczecin, Rostock, Gdynia, and Gdańsk are presented in Table 6.
Cruising speeds of ships in both scenarios (WI, W0) are constant and amount to 25.93 km/h for a container ship, and 22.22 km/h for a bulk carrier. The transit time is defined as the number of sailing hours in relation to the reference point Malmö port to destination ports: Rostock, Szczecin, Gdynia and Gdańsk, respectively.
In the WI scenario, the increased flow of containers (WI-W0) will be redirected from the port of Gdynia to the port of Szczecin, and thus the distance of sea transport of containers will reduce by 194 km. The increased grain flow (WI-W0) will be re-routed from the ports in Rostock and Gdynia to the port of Szczecin. Compared to the port of Rostock, the voyage distance will increase by 107 km, while compared to the port of Gdynia, the distance will shorten by 194 km. Further, the increased flow of bulk cargo (WI-W0) will be redirected from the port of Gdańsk to the port of Szczecin, and thus the distance of sea bulk cargo transport will shorten by 202 km.

3.5. Daily and Unit Shipping Cost of Dry Bulk and Container Cargo

The transport costs of sea voyage in the port-to-port relation that are incurred by vessels include [67]:
-
operating costs (administration, repairs and maintenance, staffing, stores and lubricants, and insurance),
-
voyage expenses (fuel cost and port dues), and
-
capital costs (interest and capital repayments).
The daily shipping cost (expressed in EUR/day) is calculated as follows:
DSC = DOC + DVC + DCC ,
where:
  • DSC—the daily shipping cost,
  • DOC—the daily operating cost,
  • DVC—the daily voyage cost (fuel cost and port dues), and
  • DCC—the daily capital cost.
Components of the daily shipping costs of bulk carriers and container ships in the operation stage were taken from [68]. The authors presented the average daily shipping costs by selected groups of ships sizes. Thanks to the form of data presentation in the mentioned paper, a detailed structure of daily shipping costs is able to be presented. This is because the costs were calculated for the average vessel size in each vessel size group. The analysis was carried out for bulk carriers with guide deadweights of 25,000, 70,000, 85,000, and 155,000 dwt (Table 7), and for container ships with guide deadweights of 7308, 18,270, 66,991, 103,532, and 133,982 dwt (Table 8).
Marine fuel and capital costs are the main components of the shipping costs of a bulk carrier where capital costs mean instalments and interest on capital for financing the purchase of ships. Together, both cost categories account for nearly 80% of bulk carrier travel costs. Their share in total costs is independent of a ship’s deadweight. The personnel costs related to ship staffing decrease in importance as the size of the vessel increases. Moreover, in relation to total cost, the personnel costs range from 5.4% for Handy size to 4.8% for large Capesize bulk carriers. It is important to note that shares of the other costs by type in total operating costs of bulk carriers are independent of ship size.
As with bulk carriers, marine fuel costs and capital costs with instalments and interest on the capital are a major component of container ship travel costs. Together, they amount from 68% to 74% of the total shipping costs, including small and large ships. In turn, unlike bulk carriers, there are significant changes in cost structure, as the size of a container ship increases. Namely, for small container ships, the share of fuel costs is 47% of total costs and as the size of ship gets larger, the share of fuel cost decreases down to 36.8%. This results in an increase of the share of capital costs from 21% up to 37% of the total shipping costs as the size of ship gets larger. The increase in size of the container ship leads to higher port costs and to lower ship management costs in the total costs of ship operation. Other types of container shipping costs such as insurance, repairs and overhauls, supplies, and oils, are independent of container ship size.
The daily shipping cost can be described by regression models. The power function is used for such models. Parameters are estimated due to ordinary least squares (OLS) estimator but for a linearized form. The daily shipping cost models with estimates can be written as follows: [69]:
  • for dry bulk carrier
    C ^ i = 1336.6 ( 1.0785 ) × D W T i 0.2909 ( 0.0068 ) ,
    where:
    1336.6 is the estimate of the parameter of the cost model and
    0.2909 is the average elasticity of the ship-day operation cost in relation to the i-th bulk carrier deadweight.
  • for container ship
    K ^ i = 121.974 ( 1.147 ) × D W T i 0.565 ( 0.013 ) ,
    where:
    121.974 is parameter of the cost model and
  • 0.565 is the average elasticity of the ship-day operation cost in relation to the i-th container ship deadweight.
Based on the established functional relationships, the daily cost of operation was calculated for the maximum load capacity (DWT) of the bulk carrier and container ship in the port of Szczecin in W0 and WI scenarios (Table 9).
Two crucial assumptions underpin the calculation of the unit shipping cost of bulk carriers and container ships per tonne-kilometer. These assumptions are as follows:
  • The ship capacity is fully used (in tonnes of cargo).
  • Sailing speed for a given ship size is constant; consequently, the travel distance that the ship can cover in a 24-h period is constant too (in km).
Therefore, the unit shipping cost (in EUR/tkm) is defined as:
USC = DSC   ( DOC + DVC + DCC ) FCW   ×   DD
where:
  • USC —the unit shipping costs,
  • DSC —the daily shipping cost,
  • DOC —the daily operating cost,
  • DVC —the daily voyage cost (fuel cost and port dues),
  • DCC —the daily capital cost,
  • FCW —the full cargo weight (tonne)/vessel,
  • DD —the maximum daily distance (km),
  • S —speed (km/h, constant), and
  • DD = S × 24 h.
It means when calculating economies of scale, the additional effect resulting from economies of distance is disregarded.
The unit cost of a tonne-kilometer for ships (Table 10) is calculated as follows:
  • The maximum distance of a sea voyage that a vessel can cover in 24 h was established. The cruising speed of a vessel was in use. Sea knots were converted into kilometers per hour. Then, the daily shipping cost was divided by the maximum voyage distance per day to obtain the cost of operating the ship per kilometer.
  • The 1 tonne-kilometer cost of ship travel was calculated by dividing the operating cost per 1 kilometer of a ship’s voyage by its full cargo weight.
  • The operating cost data for bulk carriers and container ships were obtained for 2010; the nominal GDP growth rate in 2010–2018 at 28.07% was used to update operating costs for 2018. Applying indexing gives plausible values of unit shipping costs, although some operating costs are quite volatile (e.g., fuel costs), while others tend to increase at an inflationary rate (e.g., crewing and administration costs).
Estimates of unit shipping cost of dry bulk carrier and container ship are applied in further investigation.

3.6. Value of Time (VOT) and External Cost Coefficients in Freight Sea Transport

The unit time values applied in the study were originally estimated for the Netherlands [70,71]. Survey data on freight users’ actual and hypothetical (stated preferences) choices between alternatives was used to measure willingness-to-pay (WTP) for freight time savings. The savings consist of two components—the time costs of transport (carrier component of VOT) and time costs related to cargo (shipper component of VOT). In our calculations, the indexes for 2018 values of time for containerized and non-containerized shipments are respectively 0.102 EUR/ton-hour, and 0.114 EUR/ton-hour (CUPT 2019).
To calculate environmental externalities in freight sea transport, we used external costs coefficients calculated in 2011 for general cargo/bulk carrier and container ships using low Sulphur fuel [72].
Marginal environmental costs were indexed by the nominal GDP growth index for the EU 27 calculated for the period 2011–2018 and multiplied by the elasticity-to-GDP index of 0.8. The values of unit environmental costs were expressed in EUR for 2018. The calculations are shown in Table 11.
Used in research of the total marginal environmental cost, coefficients for dry bulk carrier and containership amounted, respectively, to 5.41 EUR/1000 tkm and 4.03 EUR/1000 tkm.

3.7. Estimates of Marine Fuel Consumption and CO2 Emission

Table 12 and Table 13 are used to estimate fuel consumption by ships with data retrieved from 2010, while the fuel technology in shipping, on average, does not change in 2018 and consequently does not reduce marine fuel consumption per ship on average, as assumed.
Volumes of CO2 emission per marine fuel tonne for dry bulk carrier and container ship are presented in Table 14.

4. Measurements and Results

4.1. Cost Savings as Result of Reduced Freight Travel Distance

There are three main sources of savings identified in the research induced by improved access to the port, namely:
  • externalities,
  • time travel, and
  • travel costs.
Savings in external transport costs resulting from shortening of the travel distance are calculated as follows:
Δ E t = i = 1 n C t i · Δ d i · e t i ,
where:
  • Δ E t —reducing of externalities due to the shortening of the travel distance in time t,
  • C t i —forecasts of i-th cargo category (containers, dry bulk cargo, and grain) in time t,
  • Δ d i —the reduction of freight travel distance for i-th cargo category (constant in time), and
  • e t i —marginal environmental transport costs of air pollution and climate change for i-th cargo type in time t.
The subscript i that appears in Formula (7) requires more explanation. The subscript means the type of cargo in combination with an alternative destination of transport of this cargo. It means that i varies from 1 to 4, i.e., i = 1 means transport of containers to/from Szczecin instead of Gdynia; i = 2 means transport of grain to/from Szczecin instead of Rostock; i = 3 means transport of grain to/from Szczecin instead of Gdynia; and i = 4 means dry bulk cargo transport to/from Szczecin instead of Gdańsk.
Reducing freight travel distance causes, at the same time, a diminishing of time travel costs. Such savings are calculated as follows:
Δ T T C t = i = 1 n C t i · Δ T i · u t c t ,
where:
  • Δ T T C t —reducing of time travel costs due to the shortening of the travel time in time t,
  • C t i —forecasts of i-th cargo category (containers, dry bulk cargo, and grain) in time t,
  • Δ T i —the reduction of freight travel time for i-th cargo category (constant in time), and
  • u t c t —unit time costs of freight travel in time t.
Finally, reducing freight travel distance has an impact on freight transport cost that can be calculated in such a way:
Δ F T C t = i = 1 n C t i · Δ d i · u f t c i ,
where:
  • Δ F T C t —reducing freight travel costs due to the shortening of the travel distance in time t,
  • C t i —forecasts of i-th cargo category (containers, dry bulk cargo, and grain) in time t,
  • Δ d i —the reduction of freight travel distance for i-th cargo category (constant in time), and
  • u f t c i —unit freight travel costs for i-th cargo type.
Ultimately, the transport savings due to the shortening of the travel distance consist of the savings in externalities, savings in travel time, and savings in travel costs, which can be written as follows:
Δ T S D S t = Δ E t + Δ T T C t + Δ F T C t ,
where:
  • Δ T S D S t —the transport savings due to the shortening of the travel distance in time t,
  • Δ E t —reducing externalities due to the shortening of the travel distance in time t,
  • Δ T T C t —reducing time travel costs due to the shortening of the travel time in time t, and
  • Δ F T C t —reducing freight travel costs due to the shortening of the travel distance in time t.
Nominal total savings of shortening the travel distances amounted to EUR million 186.1 in the period of economic analysis, with externalities accounting for 49.2% of total savings, travel time savings 37.0% of total savings, and travel costs 13.8% of total savings.

4.2. Cost Savings as Result of Economies of Vessel Size

To calculate the cost savings associated with the transport of cargo by larger ships (economies of scale and economies of vessel size), we used average sea distances for dry bulk, grain, and containers weighted by volume in the port of Szczecin foreland and already computed for the WI and W0 size of ships unit operating costs for dry bulk carriers and container ships (Table 9).
Contrary to the savings caused by the shortening of the transport distance, which arose from the distance increments, the economies of scale occur along the entire freight travel distance. Hence, the determination of average travel distances was necessary (Table 3).
Savings in transport costs of containers and dry bulk carriers resulting from the increased size of the ship were calculated as follows:
Δ E S S t = i = 1 n C t i · ( D i + Δ d i ) · u f t c i W 0 i = 1 n C t i · D i · u f t c i W I .
Transforming the above equation, we get
Δ E S S t = i = 1 n C t i · D i · u f t c i W 0 + i = 1 n C t i · Δ d i · u f t c i W 0 i = 1 n C t i · D i · u f t c i W I .
Finally, we get the economies of scale equation as follows:
Δ E S S t = C t i · D i · i = 1 n ( u f t c i W 0 u f t c i W I ) + i = 1 n C t i · Δ d i · u f t c i W 0 ,
where:
  • Δ E S S t —an increment of scale economies in time t,
  • C t i —forecasts of i-th cargo category (containers, dry bulk cargo, and grain) in time t,
  • Δ d i —the reduction of freight travel distance for i-th cargo category (constant in time),
  • D i —weighted average distance of freight travel to/from port of Szczecin,
  • u f t c i W 0 —unit freight travel costs for i-th cargo type in W0 scenario, and
  • u f t c i W I —unit freight travel costs for i-th cargo type in WI scenario.
The total nominal cost savings resulting from the operation of larger seagoing vessels accumulated for period of 2023–2043 will amount to EUR million 475.2.

4.3. Savings in Marine Fuel Consumption and in Emission of CO2

The total marine fuel consumption for container ships and dry bulk carriers was determined by multiplying the unit fuel consumption for container ships with a capacity of 1000 TEU and 1800 TEU, and for bulk carriers with a carrying capacity of 20,000 tons and 40,087 DWT by the amount of sea transport ships performance (in ton-kilometers) as for the W0 scenario.
Fuel consumption in the W0 and WI scenario is the product of the transport performance in W0 (cargo volume according to the demand forecast in W0 x sea distance to the port of Szczecin) and fuel consumption per kilometer for ships of W0 and WI size.
The savings in CO2 emissions were calculated by multiplying CO2 emissions per tonne of fuel by the total fuel consumption of ships of sizes W0 and WI.
As a result of the port investment, the total savings in fuel consumption in the years 2023–2043 will amount to: 24,613 tonnes for container ships, and 554,948 tonnes for dry bulk carriers. Savings in CO2 emissions in 2023–2043 will amount to: 78,760 tonnes for container ships, and 1,775,834 tonnes for dry bulk carriers. In total, CO2 emissions will be reduced by 1,854,594 tonnes during the analysis period.
As investigated, induced by investment in the port of Szczecin, the total economic effects in the sea leg of the supply chain include costs savings resulting from the operation of larger sea-going vessels (economies of scale) and caused by the shortening of the transport distance. The calculated total and discounted (with a discount rate of 4.5%) economic effects induced by the investment are summarized in Table 15.
Effects of shortening the transport distance include savings in environmental costs, in travel time cost, and in operating cost, and constitute, respectively, 15.0%, 11.0%, and 4.0% of the total discounted economic effects. Economies of scale amount to 70% of the total discounted economic effects, where the bulk freight and grains have a major impact. This is plausible as bulk and cereals are mostly transshipped in Szczecin port and their key impact is evident.

5. Conclusions

The final beneficiaries of seaport infrastructure provision will be:
  • shipping operators, who will benefit from the savings in operating costs resulting from shortening freight travel distance and, for most, from economies of vessel size, and in total, it accounts for 74% of the total effects the port investment;
  • shippers, exporters, and importers—because of shorter sea freight travel and thus time cost savings, and these benefits account for 11,0% of the total benefits of the port investment; and
  • the community—thanks to the decreased maritime transport-related environmental externalities as an effect of shorter sea freight travel, which amounts to 15% of port investment impact.
Total savings in operating and time costs also in externalities constitute the surplus of the consumer, and hence increase the welfare for the total value of EUR million 381.2.

6. Discussion

Improved maritime accessibility allows for accommodating larger ships in the port, and thus cost savings are technology sourced, i.e., related to increased sizes of vessels. At the same time, the number of ports adapted to handling large ships is growing in the region, which means that (1) more ports may be chosen and (2) more alternative routes are at disposal. Thus, cost savings are embedded in spatial distribution, because of trade re-routings and reduced voyage distance. Our study confirms that economies of scale predominate, and they are responsible for 70% of cost gains. Economies of shorter transport distance in the foreland account for 30% of cost savings. Also, cost economies of ship size at sea and voyage distance covered by ships are crucial factors influencing generalized costs in maritime transport.
There are several generalities that can be applied in further research, such as:
  • the concept of generalized transport costs in sea freight shipping as well as the concept of a reference point to research re-routings of trades and dispersion in distances, as well as their consequences in transport performance and costs;
  • models of daily operating cost estimates as a function of dry bulk carriers and container ship size; and
  • revealed values of time and external cost coefficients in freight sea transport.
However, due to forecasting port demand, setting port range and competitiveness of adjacent ports, as well as spatial distribution of freight flows in foreland, there are context-wise and case study issues.
The limitations of the study result from some assumptions made. In the analysis of changes in the trade routings and in the freight, volume is carried out with constant maritime accessibility and capacity in the neighboring ports, also with unchanged efficiency of port transshipments and hinterland connections. Similarly, in the port of Szczecin it is assumed that the duration of stay of a large ship under reloading operations will not be extended, and the efficiency of transport to the hinterland will not change. We also assumed that the total incremental volumes of freights (WI-W0) would be fully taken over by larger ships from the first year the investment is operational. These assumptions are rather strong in the context of the long-term horizon the analysis is performed over.
Additionally, this study’s limitations result from the prognostic data used. When forecasting port transshipment, we used a historical relationship with Polish GDP whilst, in the future, these relations may change with unknown magnitude and direction. Moreover, the Polish GDP forecast used is also questionable given the recent global Covid-19 pandemic. Furthermore, projected values of time in freight sea transport and cost of CO2 emission can be the subject of the future unpredictable structural, social, and economic changes and shocks. Also, we were not able to account for the ships’ fuel technology changes and the future results of the policy regulations aimed at reducing CO2 emissions.
Therefore, the question of the elaborated forecasts’ reliability and the projected economic effects as well as energy and CO2 savings remain valid.
Further, we assumed the shipping operators (carriers) and shippers make port choices to minimize the generalized maritime transport cost. However, factors other than generalized cost play a role in the choice for a particular logistic chain and port as e.g., reliability and strategic decisions. Also historical, psychological, political, and personal factors can result in the routing of cargo flows that diverge from the cost-efficient solutions. Bounded rationality, inertia, and opportunistic behavior are among the behavioral factors that could lead to a deviation from the optimal solution [73].
Further research should focus on spatial and traffic flows interactions, for example, with the use of gravity models. General maritime transport costs and the maritime freights distances are the main inputs in the modelling. Also, there are challenging issues of forecasting port demand and port choice, for example, with the use of discrete choice models. It is important to research the impact of port capacity expansion on port authority, terminal operators, and hinterland operators. Lastly, refinement of models measuring competition between ports and multifaceted research aimed at energy savings and reducing environmental costs in the shipping industry, is also encouraged.

Author Contributions

D.B.; Conceptualization, Writing—original draft, Methodology, C.L.; Data curation, Formal analysis, Review, and editing, D.B. and C.L.; Investigation and Resources. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was financed from a subsidy of the Polish Ministry of Science and Higher Education for statutory activities; Transport 4.0: 1/S/KGMiST/21 and Economics and Finance 503-0001-230000-ZS13.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Vigarie, A. Ports de Commerce et vie Littorale; Hachette: Paris, France, 1979. [Google Scholar]
  2. Hintjens, J. Cooperation between Seaports Concerning Hinterland Transport. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Antwerp, Antwerp, Belgium, 2019; p. 34. [Google Scholar]
  3. Weigend, G.G. Some elements in the study of port geography. Geogr. Rev. 1958, 48, 185–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Grzelakowski, A. Rynki Usług Portowych (Funkcjonowanie, Wartościowanie, Regulacja); Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Gdańskiego: Gdańsk, Poland, 1983; p. 13. [Google Scholar]
  5. Talley, W.K. Port Economics; Routledge: London, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2009; p. 13. [Google Scholar]
  6. Parola, F.; Risitano, M.; Ferretti, M.; Panetti, E. The drivers of port competitiveness: A critical review. Transp. Rev. 2016, 37, 116–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Ferrari, C.; Benacchio, M. Recent trends in the market structure of terminal services. Which way to integration? Pomorski Zbornik Ann. Marit. Stud. 2003, 40, 153–176. [Google Scholar]
  8. Haralambides, H.E. Gigantism, in container shipping, port and global logistics: A time-laps into the future. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2019, 21, 1–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Talley, W.K. Optimal Containership Size. Marit. Policy Manag. 1990, 17, 165–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Haralambides, H.E.; Benacchio, M.; Cariou, P. Dedicated terminals: Cost and benefits and pricing of dedicated container terminals. Int. J. Marit. Econ. 2002, 4, 21–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Musso, E.; Ferrari, C.; Benacchio, M. Port investment: Profitability, economic impact and financing. In Port Economics. Research in Transportation Economics 16; Cullinane, K., Talley, W., Eds.; Elsevier JAI Press: Oxford, UK, 2006; pp. 171–218. [Google Scholar]
  12. Dekker, S. Port Investment Towards an Integrated Planning of Port Capacity. Ph.D. Thesis, TRAIL Research School/Delft University of Technology, Delft, The Netherlands, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  13. Notteboom, T.; Yap, W.Y. Port competition and competitiveness. In The Blackwell Companion to Maritime Economics; Wayne, K., Talley, W., Eds.; Blackwell Publishing: Malden, MA, USA; Oxford, UK, 2012; pp. 549–570. [Google Scholar]
  14. Lin, C.L.; Tseng, C.C. Operational performance evaluation of major container ports in the Asia-Pacific region. Marit. Policy Manag. 2007, 34, 535–551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Wang, Y.; Cullinane, K. Measuring container port accessibility: An application of the Principal Eigenvector Method (PEM). Marit. Econ. Logist. 2008, 10, 75–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Low, M.J.; Lam, S.W.; Tang, L.C. Assessment of hub status among Asian ports from a network perspective. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2009, 43, 593–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Low, J.M. Capacity investment and efficiency cost estimations in major East Asian ports. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2010, 12, 370–391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Aronietis, R.; van de Voorde, E.; Vanelslander, T. Port competitiveness determinants of selected European ports in the containerized cargo market. In Proceedings of the IAME 2010 Conference, Lisbon, Portugal, 7–9 July 2010. [Google Scholar]
  19. Meersman, H.; van de Voorde, E.; Vanelslander, T. Port competition revisited. Rev. Bus. Econ. 2010, 55, 210–232. [Google Scholar]
  20. Magala, M.; Sammons, A. A new approach to port choice modelling. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2008, 10, 9–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Panayides, P.; Song, D.-W. Determinants of Users’ Port Choice. In The Blackwell Companion to Maritime Economics; Wayne, K., Talley, W., Eds.; Blackwell Publishing: Malden, MA, USA; Oxford, UK, 2012; pp. 599–622. [Google Scholar]
  22. Malchow, M.; Kanafani, A. A disaggregate analysis of factors influencing port selections. Marit. Policy Manag. 2001, 28, 265–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Malchow, M.; Kanafani, A. Disaggregate analysis of port selection. Transp. Res. Part E 2004, 40, 317–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Veldman, S.; Buckmann, E. A model on container port competition, an application for the West European container hub-ports. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2003, 5, 3–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Veldman, S.; Buckmann, E.; Saitua, R. River depth and container port market shares: The impact of deepening the Scheldt River on the West European container hub-port market shares. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2005, 7, 336–355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Veldman, S.; van Drunen, E. Measuring competition between ports. In International Handbook of Maritime Economics; Cullinane, K., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2011; pp. 322–347. [Google Scholar]
  27. Zondag, B.; Bucci, P.; Gutzkow, P.; de Jong, G. Port competition modelling including maritime, port, and hinterland characteristics. Marit. Policy Manag. 2010, 37, 179–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Dekker, S.; Verhaeghe, R.J.; Pols, A.A.J. Economic impacts and public financing of port capacity investments: The case of Rotterdam port expansion. Transp. Res. Rec. J. Transp. Res. Board 2003, 1820, 55–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Sanders, F.M.; Verhaeghe, R.J.; Dekker, S. Investment dynamics for a congested transport network with competition: Application to port planning. In Proceedings of the 23rd International Conference of the System Dynamics Society, Boston, MA, USA, 17–21 July 2005. [Google Scholar]
  30. Dekker, S.; Verhaeghe, R.J. Port investment and Finance. In The Blackwell Companion to Maritime Economics; Wayne, K., Talley, W., Eds.; Blackwell Publishing: Malden, MA, USA; Oxford, UK, 2012; pp. 623–637. [Google Scholar]
  31. Van Hassel, E.; Meersman, H.; van de Voorde, E.; Vanelslander, T. Impact of scale increase of container ships on the generalized chain costs. Marit. Policy Manag. 2006, 43, 192–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Jensen, A.; Bergqvist, R. The value of direct call services by container shipping lines in Northern Europe: Support model for strategic scenario development and case study. In International Handbook of Maritime Economics; Cullinane, K., Ed.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2011; pp. 256–283. [Google Scholar]
  33. Czermanski, E.; Cirella, G.T.; Oniszczuk-Jastrzabek, A.; Pawłowska, B.; Notteboom, T. An Energy consumption approach to estimate air emission reductions in container shipping. Energies 2021, 14, 278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Carriou, P.; Parola, F.; Notteboom, T. Towards low carbon global supply chains: A multi-trade analysis of CO2 emission reductions in container shipping. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 208, 17–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Eide, M.S.; Tore, L.; Hoffman, P.; Øyvind, E.; Dalsøren, S. Future cost scenarios for reduction of ship CO2 emissions. Marit. Policy Manag. 2011, 38, 11–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Stevens, L.; Sys, C.; Vanelslander, T.; van Hassel, E. Is new emission legislation stimulating the implementation of sustainable and energy-efficient maritime technologies? Res. Transp. Bus. Manag. 2015, 17, 14–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Lähdeaho, O.; Hilmola, O.-P.; Kajatkari, R. Maritime supply chain sustainability: South-East Finland case study. J. Shipp. Trade 2020, 5, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. De Langen, P.; Sornn-Friese, H. Ports and the Circular Economy. In Green Ports; Bergquist, R., Monios, J., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2019; pp. 63–84. [Google Scholar]
  39. Mankowska, M.; Kotowska, I.; Plucinski, M. Seaports as nodal points of circular supply chains: Opportunities and challenges for secondary ports. Sustainability 2020, 12, 3926. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Mankowska, M.; Kotowska, I.; Plucinski, M. Biomass Sea-Based Supply Chains and the Secondary Ports in the Era of Decarbonization. Energies 2021, 14, 1796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Oniszczuk-Jastrzabek, A.; Czermański, E. The evolution of the ship owner profile in global container shipping. Sci. J. Marit. Univ. Szczec. 2019, 58, 105–112. [Google Scholar]
  42. Notteboom, T.; van der Lungt, L.; van Saase, N.; Sel, S.; Neyens, K. The role of seaports in green supply chain management: Initiatives, Attitudes, and Perspectives in Rotterdam, Antwerp, North Sea Port, and Zeebrugge. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1688. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Mekhum, W. The impact of sustainability concept on supply chain dynamic capabilities. Pol. J. Manag. Stud. 2019, 20, 267–276. [Google Scholar]
  44. Bilan, Y.; Hussain, H.I.; Haseeb, H.I.; Kot, S. Sustainability and economic performance: Role of organizational learning and innovation. Eng. Econ. 2020, 31, 93–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  45. Kot, S.; Haque, U.; Baloch, A. Supply chain management in smes: Global perspective. Montenegrin J. Econ. 2020, 16, 87–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. European Commission. Guide to Cost-Benefit Analysis of Investment Projects. Economic Appraisal Tool for Cohesion Policy 2014–2020; European Commission Directorate-General for Regional and Urban Policy: Brussels, Belgium, 2014; p. 26. [Google Scholar]
  47. Van Exel, J.; Rienstra, S.; Gommers, M.; Pearman, A.; Tsamboulas, D. EU involvement in TEN developments: Network Effects and European Value Added. Transp. Policy 2002, 9, 299–311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Mackie, P.; Graham, D.; Laird, J. The Direct and Wider Impacts of Transport Projects: A Review. In A Handbook of Transport Economics; De Palma, A., Lindsey, R., Quinet, E., Vickerman, R., Eds.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2013; pp. 501–527. [Google Scholar]
  49. Borkowski, P. Bezpośrednie efekty ekonomiczne-podejście metodologiczne. In Infrastruktura Transportu a Konkurencyjność Regionów w Unii Europejskiej; Pawłowska, B., Ed.; Gdańsk University Press: Gdańsk, Poland, 2015; pp. 160–166. [Google Scholar]
  50. Lakshmanan, T.R.; Anderson, W.P. Transportation Infrastructure, Freight Services Sector and Economic Growth. A White Paper Prepared for The U.S. Department of Transportation Federal Highway Administration; U.S. Department of Transportation Federal Highway Administration: Washington, DC, USA, 2002.
  51. Button, K. Transport Economics; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2010; pp. 145–146. [Google Scholar]
  52. Combes, P.-P.; Lafourcade, M. Transport costs: Measures, determinants, and regional policy implications for France. J. Econ. Geogr. 2005, 5, 319–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Mackie, P.; Nellthorp, J. Cost-Benefit Analysis in transport. In Handbook of Transport Systems and Traffic Control; Button, K.J., Hensher, D.A., Eds.; Emerald Group Publishing: Bingley, UK, 2009; p. 149. [Google Scholar]
  54. Teodorovic, D.; Janic, M. Transportation Engineering. Theory, Practice, and Modeling; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2017; p. 642. [Google Scholar]
  55. Hansen Sandberg, T.-E.; Mathisen, T.A.; Jørgensen, F. Generalized transport costs in intermodal freight transport. Procedia Soc. Behav. Sci. 2012, 54, 189–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Rothengatter, W. Evaluation of infrastructure investments in Germany. Transp. Policy 2000, 7, 17–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Naess, P.; Nicolaisen, M.S.; Strand, A. Traffic forecasts ignoring induced demand: A shaky fundament for costs-benefit analyses. Eur. J. Transp. Infrastruct. Res. 2012, 12, 291–309. [Google Scholar]
  58. De Langen, P.W.; van Meijeren, J.; Tavasszy, J.A. Combining Models and Commodity Chain Research for Making Long-term Projections of Port Throughput: An Application to the Hamburg-Le Havre Range. Eur. J. Transp. Infrastruct. Res. 2012, 12, 310–331. [Google Scholar]
  59. Hayuth, Y.; Fleming, D.F. Concepts of Strategic Commercial Location: The Case of Container Ports. Marit. Policy Manag. 1994, 21, 187–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Notteboom, T. The Peripheral Port Challenge in Container Port Systems. In International Maritime Transport: Perspectives; Leggate, H., Mcconville, J., Morvillo, A., Eds.; Routledge: London, UK, 2005; pp. 173–188. [Google Scholar]
  61. Feng, L.; Notteboom, T. Small and Medium-Sized Ports (SMPs) in Multi-Port Gateway Regions: The Role of Yingkou in the Logistics System of the Bohai Sea. In Current Issues in Shipping, Ports and Logistics; Notteboom, T., Ed.; University Press Antwerp: Antwerp, Belgium, 2011; pp. 543–563. [Google Scholar]
  62. Feng, L.; Notteboom, T. Peripheral Challenge by Small and Medium Sized Ports (SMPs) in Multi-Port Gateway Regions: The Case Study of Northeast China. Pol. Marit. Res. Spec. Issue 2013, 20, 55–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Slack, B.; Wang, J.J. The Challenge of Peripheral Ports; An Asian Perspective. Geojournal 2002, 65, 159–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Wang, C.J.; Wang, J.; Ducret, C. Peripheral Challenge in Container Port System: A Case Study of Pearl River Delta. Chin. Geogr. Sci. 2012, 22, 97–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Wilmsmeier, G.; Monios, J. Counterbalancing Peripherality and Concentration: An Analysis of the UK Container Port System. Marit. Policy Manag. 2013, 40, 116–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Wilmsmeier, G.; Monios, J.; Pérez-Salas, G. Port System Evolution: The Case of Latin America and the Caribbean. J. Transp. Geogr. 2014, 39, 208–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  67. Stopford, M. Maritime Economics, 3rd ed.; Routledge: London, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  68. Delhaye, E.; Breemersch, T.; Vanherle, K. COMPASS. The Competitiveness of European Short-Sea Freight Shipping Compared with Road and Rail Transport; Final Report; European Commission DG Environment: Brussels, Belgium, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  69. Bernacki, D.; Lis, C. Cost-Benefit Analysis for the Project; Enhancement of Transport Accessibility to the Port of Szczecin in Debicki Canal Area; Municipality Office: Szczecin, Poland, 2019.
  70. De Jong, G.; Kouwenhoven, M.; Bates, J.; Koster, P.; Verhoef, E.; Taavasszy, L.; Warffemius, P. New SP-values of time and reliability for freight transport in the Netherlands. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2014, 64, 71–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  71. Significance; VU University of Amsterdam; John Bates Services. Values of Time and Reliability in Passenger and Freight Transport. in the Netherlands. Report for the Ministry of Infrastructure and the Environment; Significance, VU University of Amsterdam; John Bates Services: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  72. Brons, M.; Christidis, P. External Costs Calculator for Marco Polo Freight Transport. Project; Call 2013 Updated Version; Joint Scientific and Policy Reports; European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  73. Notteboom, T. Spatial and functional integration of container port systems and hinterland networks in Europe. In Land Access to Seaports; ECMT Report 113; Economic Research Centre ECMT-OECD: Paris, France, 2001; pp. 5–55. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Forecasted cargo throughput in the port of Szczecin (tonnes). Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 1. Forecasted cargo throughput in the port of Szczecin (tonnes). Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 14 03519 g001
Figure 2. Scenario-based shipping route alternatives and sea distances for containers, dry bulk, and grain. Source: own study, distances are based on http://www.sea-distances.org (accessed on 11 September 2020).
Figure 2. Scenario-based shipping route alternatives and sea distances for containers, dry bulk, and grain. Source: own study, distances are based on http://www.sea-distances.org (accessed on 11 September 2020).
Energies 14 03519 g002
Table 1. Effects of intervention in port of Szczecin.
Table 1. Effects of intervention in port of Szczecin.
SpecificationScenario without Investment W0Scenario with Investment WI
Max. vessel draft (m)9.1511.1
Dry bulk carrier deadweight (tonnes)20,00040,087
Container ship capacity (TEU)10001800
Transshipment capacity-grain (tonnes)1,400,0002,280,000
Transshipment capacity-containers (tonnes)2,800,0003,600,000
Transshipment capacity-dry bulk (coal, ore, other dry bulk) (tonnes)2,900,0004,600,000
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 2. Throughput forecast in the port of Szczecin in WI scenario (growth rates).
Table 2. Throughput forecast in the port of Szczecin in WI scenario (growth rates).
YearCoalIron Ore + Other BulkGrainContainer CargoTotal
20230.0%0.0%0.0%0.0%0.0%
20283.1%8.6%22.1%22.3%9.4%
20336.2%17.3%39.0%44.7%17.9%
20389.1%25.4%40.2%65.8%23.2%
204312.1%33.6%40.3%87.1%28.3%
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 3. Incremental (WI-W0) throughput forecast in the port of Szczecin (tonnes).
Table 3. Incremental (WI-W0) throughput forecast in the port of Szczecin (tonnes).
YearCoalIron Ore + Other BulkGrainContainer CargoTotal
2023110,363566,648737,518224,8461,639,375
2028170,390874,8521,164,006412,7192,621,966
2033230,8421,185,2351,488,387601,9203,506,383
2038287,8461,477,9181,512,801780,3324,058,897
2043345,1761,772,2751,514,552959,7644,591,767
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 4. Weighted average sea distances in containers, dry bulk, and grain traded to and from the port of Szczecin.
Table 4. Weighted average sea distances in containers, dry bulk, and grain traded to and from the port of Szczecin.
YearAnnual Weighted Average Sea Distance (km)
Container CargoDry Bulk CargoGrain
2011103719834085
201299324332900
2013101022624034
2014102427004308
201599728246925
201689623869882
Weighted average sea distances99224295772
Source: own study, sea transport distances were determined based on http://www.sea-distances.org/ (accessed on 11 September 2020) and Polish Ports Handbook 2007, Maritime Economy and Industry Guide, LINK Szczecin 2007.
Table 5. Maximum draft of vessels calling at the ports of Szczecin, Gdańsk, Rostock, and Gdynia.
Table 5. Maximum draft of vessels calling at the ports of Szczecin, Gdańsk, Rostock, and Gdynia.
Maximum Draft of Container Ships
ScenarioPort of Szczecin
Draft (m)
Port of Gdynia
Draft (m)
W09.15Gdynia Container Terminal 11.0 m
Baltic Container Terminal 12.7 m
WI11.1
Maximum Draft of Dry Bulk Carriers
Port of Szczecin
Draft (m)
Port of Gdańsk
Draft (m)
W09.15Outer port 15.0 m
Inner port 10.2 m
WI11.1
Maximum Draft of Vessels with Grain
Port of Szczecin
Draft (m)
Port of Rostock
Draft (m)
Port of Gdynia
Draft (m)
W09.15Berths (no 13, 17 and 18)
for grain handling 13.0 m
Baltic Grain Terminal 11.0 m
WI11.1
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 6. Differences in freight sea transport distance from the port of Malmö to ports of Gdynia, Gdańsk, Rostock, and Szczecin.
Table 6. Differences in freight sea transport distance from the port of Malmö to ports of Gdynia, Gdańsk, Rostock, and Szczecin.
PortGdyniaGdańskRostockSzczecin
Malmö (in nautical miles)269273106164
Malmö (in kilometers)498506196304
Difference in sea transport distance from Szczecin to other ports (in kilometers)194202(−107)0
Source: distances are based on http://www.sea-distances.org (accessed on 11 September 2020).
Table 7. Daily shipping cost of dry bulk carrier (EUR/day) (2010).
Table 7. Daily shipping cost of dry bulk carrier (EUR/day) (2010).
Vessel SizeHandy SizePanamaxPost PanamaxCapesize
Size range dwt10,000–40,00060,000–80,00080,000–110,000110,000–200,000
Guide dwt25,00070,00085,000155,000
Manning1389184718472069
Insurance473702756817
Repairs and maintenance1107145816561824
Stores and lube oil374511557611
Administration947109911601237
Capital repayments3847583761026898
Interest3162479850165671
Gross margin1921276329063251
Port2100280030003500
Fuel (tonne/day)32.038.042.055.0
Fuel (EUR/day)10,19812,11113,38517,528
Speed (knots)12.013.013.013.0
Full cargo weight (tonne)European relationsRelations via Panama CanalRelations via Suez CanalRelations via Cape of Good Hope
24,73969,25283,448151,931
Total daily shipping cost (EUR/day)25,51933,92736,38743,406
Source: Data from [68].
Table 8. Daily operation cost of container ships in 2010 (EUR/day).
Table 8. Daily operation cost of container ships in 2010 (EUR/day).
Vessel size (TEUs)500–7001000–20005000–60008000–900010,000–12,000
Average containership capacity (TEUs)60015005500850011,000
Guide dwt730818,27066,991103,532133,982
Manning15881588217623132466
Insurance31344393111681336
Repairs and maintenance802977260327863092
Stores and lube oil351580155718472122
Administration5045509319621008
Capital repayments2189437811,27616,84820,430
Interest17993599926913,85016,794
Gross margin12832059488667628032
Port12002500520068008300
Fuel (tonne/day)28.045.077.091.0116.0
Fuel (EUR/day)892414,34124,54029,00236,969
Speed (knots)14.014.018.018.018.0
Full cargo weight (tonne)European relationsEuropean relationsRelations via Panama CanalRelations via Suez CanalRelations via Cape of Good Hope
720018,00066,000102,000132,000
Total daily shipping cost (EUR/day)18,95231,01563.37082,337100,547
Source: Data from [68].
Table 9. Dry bulk carrier and container ship daily shipping cost (2010).
Table 9. Dry bulk carrier and container ship daily shipping cost (2010).
Ship TypeDWT (W0)Daily Shipping Cost
EUR
DWT (WI)Daily Shipping Cost
EUR
Dry bulk carrier20,00023,83340,08729,175
Feeder container shipTEU (W0)24,907TEU (WI)34,726
10001800
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 10. Dry bulk carrier and container ship unit shipping cost (EUR/tkm, 2018).
Table 10. Dry bulk carrier and container ship unit shipping cost (EUR/tkm, 2018).
Dry Bulk Carrier
W0WI
DWT20,00040,087
Daily shipping cost (EUR/day)23,83329,175
Maximum load coefficient 0.950.95
Full cargo weight (tonnes)19,00038,082
Cruising speed in knots (NM/h)1212
Speed converter knots/km 1.851.85
Cruising speed km/h22.2222.22
Maximum daily voyage distance (km/day)533.38533.38
Operating costs EUR/km44.6854.70
Operating cost EUR/tkm 20100.00240.0014
Operating cost EUR/tkm 20180.00290.0018
Container Ship
W0WI
Vessel size (TEUs)10001800
Daily shipping cost (EUR/day)24,90734,726
Maximum load per 1 TEU (tonnes)1010
Full cargo weight (tonnes)10,00018,000
Cruising speed in knots 1414
Speed converter knots/km 1.851.85
Cruising speed km/h25.9325.93
Maximum daily voyage distance (km/day)622.27622.27
Operating cost EUR/km40.0355.81
Operating cost EUR/tkm 20100.00400.0031
Operating cost EUR/tkm 20180.00490.0038
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 11. Marginal environmental cost coefficients for freight sea transport (fuel technology—low Sulphur fuel).
Table 11. Marginal environmental cost coefficients for freight sea transport (fuel technology—low Sulphur fuel).
ExternalityShip Type
General Cargo/Dry Bulk Carrier
EUR/1000 tkm
General Cargo/Dry Bulk Carrier
EUR/1000 tkm
Container Ship EUR/1000 tkmContainer Ship EUR/1000 tkm
2011201820112018
Air pollution4.485.173.093.56
Climate change0.210.240.400.46
Total4.695.413.494.03
Source: Authors’ calculations based on [72].
Table 12. Estimates of marine fuel consumption per container ship with a size of 1000 and 1800 TEU.
Table 12. Estimates of marine fuel consumption per container ship with a size of 1000 and 1800 TEU.
Container Ship
Average capacity of container ship (TEU)20005500
Fuel consumption (tonnes/day)4577
Scaling parameter a0.00914
Constant b26.71429
Container shipW0 (1000 TEU)WI (1800 TEU)
Fuel consumption (tonnes/day)35.8643.17
Fuel consumption (tonnes/kilometer)0.0580.069
Fuel consumption (tonnes/million tonne-kilometers)5.7623.854
Source: Authors’ calculations based on Table 8.
Table 13. Estimates of marine fuel consumption per bulk carrier with sizes of 20,000 DWT and 40,087 DWT.
Table 13. Estimates of marine fuel consumption per bulk carrier with sizes of 20,000 DWT and 40,087 DWT.
Bulk Carrier
Average capacity of bulk carrier (DWT)25,00070,000
Fuel consumption (tonnes/day)3238
Scaling parameter a0.00013
Constant b28.66667
Bulk carrierW0 (20,000 DWT)WI (40,087 DWT)
Fuel consumption (tonnes/day)31.3334.01
Fuel consumption (tonnes/kilometer0.0590.064
Fuel consumption (tonnes/million tonne-kilometers)3.0921.674
Source: Authors’ calculations based on Table 7.
Table 14. Volume of CO2 emission per marine fuel tonne for dry bulk carrier and container ship.
Table 14. Volume of CO2 emission per marine fuel tonne for dry bulk carrier and container ship.
Vessel TypeType of EngineCO2 (kg/t)
Dry bulk carrierlow speed diesel engine3200
Container shipmedium speed diesel engine3200
Source: Colls and Tiwary 2009.
Table 15. Total and discounted economic effects induced by the port investment (EUR).
Table 15. Total and discounted economic effects induced by the port investment (EUR).
Economic Effects Induced by Port Investment
Savings resulting from the shorter maritime travel distance in:Discounted Value Structure (%)
- external/environmental costs 57,240,487.1015.0
- shipping operating costs 15,125,027.644.0
- costs of travel time 41,962,390.7611.0
Savings in operating shipping costs resulting from the increased ship size (economies of scale)266,918,647.0670.0
Total381,246,552.56100.0
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Bernacki, D.; Lis, C. Investigating the Sustainable Impact of Seaport Infrastructure Provision on Maritime Component of Supply Chain. Energies 2021, 14, 3519. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123519

AMA Style

Bernacki D, Lis C. Investigating the Sustainable Impact of Seaport Infrastructure Provision on Maritime Component of Supply Chain. Energies. 2021; 14(12):3519. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123519

Chicago/Turabian Style

Bernacki, Dariusz, and Christian Lis. 2021. "Investigating the Sustainable Impact of Seaport Infrastructure Provision on Maritime Component of Supply Chain" Energies 14, no. 12: 3519. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123519

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop