Next Article in Journal
Multifactor Market Indexes
Previous Article in Journal
The Impact of ESG Ratings on the Systemic Risk of European Blue-Chip Firms
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The MAX Effect in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case of Norway

by
Muhammad Kashif
1,* and
Thomas Leirvik
1,2,3
1
Nord University Business School, Nord University, Universitetsaléen 11, 8049 Bodø, Norway
2
School of Business and Economics, UiT The Arctic University of Norway, Breivangveien 23, 9010 Tromsø, Norway
3
NTNU Business School, The Norwegian University for Science and Technology, Høgskoleringen 1, 7491 Trondheim, Norway
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15(4), 154; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040154
Submission received: 10 February 2022 / Revised: 12 March 2022 / Accepted: 26 March 2022 / Published: 29 March 2022
(This article belongs to the Section Applied Economics and Finance)

Abstract

:
This paper assesses the effects of investors’ lottery-seeking behavior on expected returns in the Norwegian equity market, a relatively small equity market dominated by the energy industry. We use the MAX factor defined as maximum daily return over the previous month as the proxy of investors’ preference for lottery-like stocks. Despite evidence from recent literature that MAX has a negative relationship with the expected returns in other developed European markets, we find that the relationship is generally insignificant in Norway; however, it becomes more nuanced when we control for the state of the oil market. The dominance of firms related to the oil industry, which have experienced tremendous growth over the last couple of decades, masks the effect to a large extent. Conditional regressions show that the MAX effect is only significant in the Norwegian stock market when the oil market is in the bearish state.

1. Introduction

In this paper, we investigate the impact of extreme positive returns over the previous one month on expected returns in an industry-concentrated stock market. The Norwegian market has, in the last three decades, been dominated by energy-related companies in general, and by oil companies, in particular. Thus, the state of the oil market plays an important role in shaping the investors sentiment. Numerous research studies have shown evidence of the relationship between the oil market and the stock market. Park and Ratti (2008) investigated the impact of oil price shock on real stock returns and found that increased volatility in oil prices has a negative effect on real stock returns in the U.S. and most of the European markets. However, an increase in the oil price significantly increases the stock returns in the Norwegian market. Wang et al. (2013) found that the relationship (positive/negative, strength, duration) of oil price movement on aggregate stock returns depends upon whether the country is a net exporter or importer of oil. Ahmadi et al. (2016) showed that the oil price is strongly related to the confidence index. Furthermore, Qadan and Nama (2018) showed that investor sentiments, as measured by augmented proxies of Baker and Wurgler (2006), are strongly related to oil prices and the stock returns of oil companies. However, we, in this paper, use the oil market state as a proxy for investor sentiment, and the results are promising. The maximum daily return over the previous month is termed as the MAX by Bali et al. (2011). The authors found a very strong negative relationship between the MAX and expected returns in the U.S. market. They termed this negative relationship between the MAX and expected returns as the MAX effect. Although the MAX effect is significant in a sample of European markets—see Annaert et al. (2013) and Walkshäusl (2014)—we find no evidence of such an effect in the Norwegian stock market. We find that the state of the oil market strongly affects the MAX effect in the Norwegian market. Conditional regressions suggest that the MAX effect is significant (insignificant) in the Norwegian stock market when the oil market is in the bearish (bullish) state. It shows that the state of the oil market masks the MAX effect in the Norwegian market. It suggests that the oil market state acts as a barometer of investor sentiment in the Norwegian market. These results are in alignment of the findings of Qadan and Nama (2018), Kumar (2009) and Fong and Toh (2014). We extend the literature by providing empirical evidence of the link between the MAX effect and the oil market in Norway.
Bali et al. (2011) argued that the MAX effect exists because investors, especially retail investors, enthusiastically seek high-MAX/lottery-like-stocks (stocks that experience extreme positive returns), that, in turn, have lower expected returns. We see in the descriptive statistics (Table 1) that high-MAX stocks seem to have higher skewness (1.44) and lower historical monthly average returns (0.53%) than low-MAX stocks (0.51% and 0.82%, respectively). These characteristics make high-MAX stocks lottery-like-stocks, even though portfolio and regression analyses show that the MAX effect is overall insignificant in Norway. However, the MAX effect is significant when the state of the oil market is bearish. It indicates that investors enthusiasm toward lottery-like-stocks increases during the period when the oil market is bearish.
Kumar (2009) explored the demand for lottery-like stocks and found that the preference for lottery-like stocks is more prevalent in individual investors and increases during economic downturns. Fong and Toh (2014) argued that the MAX effect is explained by the behavioral grounds and provided empirical evidence that the MAX effect becomes insignificant after controlling for past sentiments, demonstrating that the effect is a manifestation of the investors’ beliefs rather than risk. They found that the effect is significant only when consumer and investor sentiments are high. We principally confirm the findings of Kumar (2009) and Fong and Toh (2014) and find that the MAX effect is significant during the oil market downturns in the Norwegian market. We use the oil market as a proxy for investor sentiments because energy-related companies constitute a major chunk of the Norwegian market and there is evidence of the co-movement of investor sentiment and the crude oil market; see, for example, Zhang and Pei (2019).
We find that the MAX effect is insignificant, and a zero investment portfolio based on it does not guarantee abnormal returns in the Norwegian market. We show that this contrary result is due the concentration of energy-related stocks in the Norwegian market. We find that the MAX effect is significant when the oil market is bearish, and evaporates during a bullish stage in the oil market. We confirm the relationship between the oil market and the Norwegian stock market, which is consistent with the literature of Park and Ratti (2008), Wang et al. (2013), Ahmadi et al. (2016) and Qadan and Nama (2018). However, we also partly confirm the other key result of Bali et al. (2011) that inclusion of IVOL in the regression setting with MAX reverses the puzzling negative relationship between IVOL and expected returns described by Ang et al. (2006) and Ang et al. (2009). However, we find that the MAX effect does not fully subsume the IVOL effect in the Norwegian market similar to the Chinese market; see Wan (2018). We find that the IVOL-expected returns relationship remains positive and statistically significant in the Norwegian market. However, this relationship is not economically significant in the Norwegian market.
We perform both portfolio and regression analyses to obtain robust results. We also run firm-level Fama and MacBeth (1973) (FM) regressions to control for other firm-specific characteristics, such as firm size (SIZE), book-to-market ratio (BM), idiosyncratic volatility (IVOL), momentum (MOM), illiquidity (ILLIQ), short-term reversal (REV), and CAPM BETA. The results of both portfolio and FM regression analyses suggest that the MAX effect is not significant. We use the Harding and Pagan (2002) method to identify whether the Brent oil market is in a bullish or bearish state. We find that only when the Brent market is bearish, the MAX effect is significantly consistent with Fong and Toh (2014). However, we use the oil market state as the proxy for investor sentiment; Fong and Toh (2014) used the proxies of Baker and Wurgler (2006) for investor sentiment based on the U.S. market data. By doing so, we confirm the link between the Norwegian market and the oil market and show that the oil market plays a consequential role in shaping investor sentiment.

2. Literature Review

The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965) and Mossin (1966) give financial researchers the mean–variance paradigm. According to the CAPM, the expected return on any security should be equal to the risk-free rate with the addition of a risk premium, which is equal to the security’s market beta times the market risk premium. However, the empirical failures of CAPM—see, for example, Friend and Blume (1970), Jensen et al. (1972), Blume and Friend (1973), Fama and MacBeth (1973) and Fama and French (1993)—prompt researchers to look for other approaches to explain expected returns’ behavior. Fama and French (1996) introduced two factors in addition to the CAPM market risk factor, SMB and HML. SMB stands for “small minus big” and HML stands for “high minus low”. They provided a risk-based justification of these two factors and branded them as proxies for systematic risk. They showed that stocks of small firms outperform stocks of big firms and argue that it is because small firms are more risky due to the additional risk that they face in acquiring resources in comparison with big firms, and small firms are more likely to fail than big firms due to little asset holdings. They also showed that stocks of firms with a high book-to-market value ratio (value stocks) earn higher returns on average than stocks of firms with a low book-to-market value ratio (growth stocks). They argued that it is due to the value stocks being riskier than the growth stocks because the low market value in comparison to assets represents the bad performance or inefficiency of a firm.
The opponents of a risk-based justification—see, for example, Lakonishok et al. (1994), Griffin and Lemmon (2002) and Hirshleifer et al. (2012)—of these two factors claim that this out-performance of small stocks and value stocks over big stocks and growth stocks, respectively, is because of the mispricing of assets. They argued that the out-performance of small stocks over big stocks is because small stocks receive limited analysts’ coverage and these small firms’ weak fundamentals and non-availability of data make them difficult to price correctly. They termed these factors as anomalies and argued that these factors are discovered through data mining or by generalizing a certain human behavior. There are numerous factors or anomalies in the finance literature that claim to have pricing implications for stocks in the cross section; see, for example, Harvey et al. (2016) and Jensen et al. (2022).
Kane (1982) identified that the higher proportion of wealth invested in risky securities is associated with investors’ preference toward higher profits or positive skewness. Tversky and Kahneman (1992) documented this preference for higher gains in their cumulative prospect theory and argued that people often assign more weight to extreme events, as they often prefer a small probability of winning a large prize; they termed the prospect as lottery. Bali et al. (2011) proxied this skewness preference as daily maximum return over the last month—MAX. The MAX factor is based on investors’ behavior rather than a risk-based theory. They argued that investors seek stocks that offer very low probability of extreme positive returns in exchange for lower average expected returns. These stocks lie in the right tail of the returns distribution that earn lower average returns and contain some probability of extreme higher returns; these characteristics make them lottery-like stocks.
Walkshäusl (2014) and Annaert et al. (2013) investigated the MAX effect in a sample of European markets and found that it is statistically and economically significant. They argued that the MAX effect is derived from investors’ preference toward lottery-like-stocks. Nartea et al. (2014) and Nartea et al. (2017) studied the MAX effect in the Asian emerging markets and found that the relationship between the MAX and expected returns is negative and significant. They argued that this relationship is significant because of the risk-seeking behavior of investors in the Chinese and South Korean markets. Yang and Nguyen (2019) studied skewness preference in the Japanese market and found that investors’ preference toward stocks that have positive skewness is significant during bear periods of the market. Cueto et al. (2020) proposed that skewness as well as kurtosis should be added to the CAPM market factor to form a multi-factor asset pricing model. They tested this model on the European stocks and found significant results. We investigate if the MAX effect is prevalent in the Norwegian market and find that it is not significant. This means that investors are not as risk tolerant as in the other European or Asian markets and the preference toward lottery-like-stocks is not at the level that leads to significantly lower expected returns on these stocks.
Kumar (2009) studied the behavior of investors in the U.S. market in the context of lottery demand and found that the demand for lotteries and assets that resemble lottery-like features increases during economic downturns or when the sentiments run high among investors. Motivated by these findings, Fong and Toh (2014) found that if we control for past sentiment in the U.S., then the MAX effect becomes insignificant. It validates the idea that the MAX is a manifestation of investor sentiments. They used investor sentiment index created by Baker and Wurgler (2006); however, there is no such index for the Norwegian market. The Norwegian market is peculiar in a way that, historically, it is claimed to be dominated by energy-related firms. Nevertheless, the widely documented influence of the oil market on the Norwegian stock market by Park and Ratti (2008) and Wang et al. (2013), the relation between oil market and investor sentiment documented by Qadan and Nama (2018) and Song et al. (2019), and the anecdotal history of the Norwegian stock market documented by Von Brasch et al. (2018), Bjørnland (2009) and Cappelen et al. (2014) make the case to control for the oil market state as a proxy for investor sentiment in the Norwegian market.

3. Data

We collect high-quality Norwegian stock data from the TITLON1 database. TITLON contains financial data for all firms that are, or have been, listed on the Oslo Stock Exchange (OSE). It contains detailed daily, survivorship-bias-free financial data with fully adjusted prices from 1980 until the current year. We define Norwegian stocks as stocks that are traded on the OSE in Norwegian currency and are registered as A shares, ordinary shares, or converted A shares.2 We collected daily observations of all stocks registered on the OSE from 1980 until 2016. However, we apply data from January 1996 until December 20163 to all common Norwegian stocks for two reasons: First, very few stocks were registered on the OSE before 1996, and trading activity was low.4 Second, the OSE benchmark index was introduced in January 1996. Stocks that are traded for fewer than 10 days in the past one month are treated as missing. We use Norwegian Fama and French (1993) factors data from the Bernt Arne Ødegaard data library.5 We collect book-to-market ratio data from the Thomson Reuters Datastream.6 We obtain oil spot prices data from www.eia.gov (accessed on 30 August 2019).

4. Discussion, Analysis and Results

This section presents the analyses performed to scrutinize the relationship between MAX and cross-sectional expected returns. We perform univariate sort portfolio analysis, unconditional Fama–MacBeth cross-sectional regressions and conditional regressions dependent on the state of the oil market.

4.1. Univariate Portfolio Analysis

Compared to the U.S. market, the Norwegian market comprises only a few stocks. Therefore, a decile portfolio analysis would be challenging, as each decile will be left with about 10–15 stocks. Stocks that are priced at less than NOK 10 on the portfolio formation date are also treated as missing due to micro structure noise.7 Another reason to exclude these low priced and infrequently traded stocks is that Zhang et al. (2018) argued that micro structure noise partly explains the MAX effect. We perform two portfolio analyses: (1) quartile portfolio analysis and (2) tercile portfolio analysis. In the quartile portfolio analysis, each portfolio consists of 25 percent of the stocks available. This means, on average, 22 stocks in one portfolio each month. In the tercile portfolio analysis, high- and low-MAX portfolios contain 34 percent of stocks (30 stocks on average in a month) while the middle portfolio contains 32 percent. Table 1 shows descriptive statistics for both portfolio analyses. It reports the monthly average number of stocks in a portfolio, monthly average/median returns, skewness/standard deviation of monthly average returns, and percentiles of monthly stock returns.
Portfolios are formed and re-balanced each month on the first trading day based on the sort variable MAX. Table 1 shows that high-MAX stocks have lottery-like characteristics; for example, they have, on average, lower mean returns but higher levels of skewness than low-MAX stocks. High-MAX stocks in both quartile and the tercile analyses have a higher level of volatility as well. Percentile values of stock returns are, on average, indicative of lower expected returns and higher volatility and skewness for high-MAX stocks than low-MAX stocks.
We perform both quartile and tercile portfolio analyses. The results of both quartile and tercile portfolio analyses are very similar; however, the tercile analysis is more robust, as each portfolio contains more stocks to damp down individual stocks’ idiosyncratic effects. For brevity, however, we only report the results of the tercile portfolio analysis here onwards. Table 2 reports average returns of portfolios sorted on MAX(N), where N represents the average of the N highest daily returns in the past one month. Table 2 further reports mean differences, CAPM-alpha differences, and (Fama and French 1996; Carhart 1997) four-factor alpha differences. Panel A reports the results of equally weighted portfolio analysis, and panel B reports the results of value-weighted portfolio analyses. We use the previous month’s market capitalization in the value-weighted portfolio analyses. All the t-statistics, estimated by the adjustment of Newey and West (1994), are reported in parentheses.
None of the t-statistics in Table 2 are significant, except for the four-factor alpha difference in the equally weighted setting. We cannot claim that the MAX effect is present based only on four-factor alpha differences because the effect is absent in mean return differences and even in CAPM-alpha differences. The absolute values of t-statistics are higher in the equally weighted portfolio setting than in the value-weighted portfolio setting. The difference between high-low MAX portfolio has a negative sign in an equally weighted setting; however, the sign is positive in the value-weighted setting. This result is an affirmation that the MAX effect is more likely to be present in small-cap stocks. Most of the big value firms, listed on OSE, are oil-related firms; therefore, it also signals the influence that oil-related firms have on the significance of the MAX effect in the Norwegian market. The average return and CAPM-alpha differences between high- and low-MAX(N) portfolios are mostly negative, but low t-statistics compel us to infer that the MAX effect is overall not significant in the Norwegian market.
High-MAX/lottery-like stocks are priced at a premium due to their small probability of producing extreme positive returns. However, if high-MAX stocks do not continue to remain in the high-MAX portfolio, investors would not show enthusiasm for high-MAX stocks in the future, and they would then cease to command a price premium. This lottery-like characteristic of a stock should be persistent to make it a premium-priced stock. We check for this property in high-MAX stocks by examining whether they remain in the high-MAX portfolio in the next month as well. We estimate the month-to-next month transition matrix to find the probability that high-MAX/lottery-like stocks remain in the high-MAX portfolio in the next month or move to another portfolio (middle or low-MAX portfolio).
Table 3 shows that stocks in a high-MAX (low-MAX) portfolio in a month have a 48.8% (50.5%) probability of staying in the high-MAX (low-MAX) portfolio in the next month. This means that the MAX characteristic is fairly persistent in the Norwegian market. However, the effect is insignificant.8

4.2. Fama–MacBeth Regressions

In this section, we examine the cross-sectional relationship between MAX and expected returns at the firm level, using Fama and MacBeth (1973) (FM) regressions, as well as the relationship between MAX and expected returns, controlling for other effects. We follow the traditional FM process, where we run cross-sectional regressions each month where the dependent variable is excess returns and the dependent variables are in three settings. By running these cross-sectional regressions each month, we get the time series of each slope coefficient of the dependent variables. After getting these times series of coefficients, we test that the means of these times series are different from zero. In these tests, we adjust the standard errors using Newey and West (1994) adjustments for possible auto-correlation and heteroscedasticity in the residuals, which leads to robust t-statistics. First, we run month-by-month firm-level univariate FM regressions between MAX and expected returns. We then run FM regressions in a bivariate setting by adding one control variable at a time. Lastly, we run month-by-month firm-level full specification FM regressions between MAX and expected returns, simultaneously controlling for BETA, SIZE, BM, MOM, ILLIQ, and REV. Bivariate regressions are important for a deep understanding of the MAX effect because, considering the size of the Norwegian stock market, the MAX effect could conceivably proxy some other effect that can go unnoticed in a full-specification multiple regression.
r i , t = λ 0 + j = 1 k λ j X i , j , t 1 + ϵ i , t
Equation (1) represents the FM regression setting. Here, r i , t represents the excess return on stock i in month t, the lambdas represent the means of the time series of firm-level cross-sectional regression coefficients, and X represents the lagged explanatory variable of stock i. In a univariate regression setting, k = 1 (MAX only); in a bivariate setting, k = 2 (MAX and one control variable); and in a full specification setting, k = 7 (MAX and all six control variables).
Table 4 provides the standard Fama and MacBeth (1973) test coefficient estimates. We run regressions of the following specification:9 In a univariate regression setting, the t-statistic of the MAX coefficient is just −0.86, which is insignificant though negative. We find a negative relationship between Amihud (2002) illiquidity and expected returns in the Norwegian market, which is puzzling, although this negative relationship is similar to the findings of Annaert et al. (2013) from other European markets. Following these regressions, we reject the existence of a negative relationship between the MAX and expected returns in the Norwegian market.

4.3. The MAX Effect and Brent Returns

The Norwegian market consists of a limited number of stocks, and is dominated by energy-related firms’ stocks; historically, the Norwegian market is highly influenced by oil prices (Park and Ratti 2008; Wang et al. 2013; Wang and Liu 2016). Therefore, it is possible that the common dependence on oil prices produces unexpected results of the MAX effect. For example, if a firm sells oil or oil-related products or services, an increase in oil price leads to higher returns for that firm and, subsequently, to higher returns on the stock of that firm. If oil prices are on the rise (bull phase), a high-MAX stock, which should provide lower returns in the future, may provide higher returns if the firm sells oil or oil-related products or services. Similarly, the magnitude of oil prices/returns increases, and the duration of bull phases may affect the significance of the MAX effect in the Norwegian market because the market is dominated by energy-related firms. Therefore, we investigate the MAX effect separately, first on the whole sample and then conditional on bullish and bearish states of the Brent oil market at the time of investment decision. We split the sample on the basis that at the time t 1 of investment the oil market state was bullish or bearish; however, we do not control for the state of the oil market at time t. We run ordinary least square (OLS) regressions, as well as weighted least square (WLS) regressions with market capitalization as the weight, to see the MAX effect corresponding to equally weighted and value-weighted portfolio settings. We use WLS also as a robustness check, as Cochrane (2011) pointed out that OLS puts more weightage on small stocks that are known to be anomalous. Equation (2) represents the regression setting.
r i , t = β 0 + j = 1 k β j X i , j , t 1 + ϵ t | O M S t 1
Here, r i , t represents excess returns on stock i in month t, the betas represent the time series coefficients of firm-level OLS and WLS regressions, X represents the lagged explanatory variable of stock i, and O M S t 1 is the oil market state during the month t 1 . We run regressions of Equation (2) in three settings: first, a univariate regression setting, where k = 1 (MAX only); second, a bivariate setting, where k = 2 (MAX and one control variable); third, a full-specification setting, where k = 7 (MAX and all six control variables). We repeat these three regression settings for both equally weighted and value-weighted (OLS and WLS) schemes with three datasets: a full sample and two sub-samples conditional on the oil market state. We use the Harding and Pagan (2002) method to divide the oil market into two states: bullish and bearish.
Table 5 presents the coefficient estimates and associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics from the regressions of Equation (2). Panel A in Table 5 reports the coefficient estimates and associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics from (1) univariate regressions—expected returns on MAX; (2) bivariate regressions—expected returns on MAX and one control variable at a time; and (3) full-specification multiple regressions—expected returns on MAX, controlling for BETA, SIZE, BM, MOM, ILLIQ, and REV, where the regression type is OLS, meaning that all returns are equally weighted throughout the chosen dataset (full sample (250 months of data) in panel A1, sub-sample when the oil market was bullish (115 months of data) in panel A2, and sub-sample when the oil market was bearish (135 months of data) in panel A3). The same results are reported in panel B of Table 5, but the regression type is WLS, meaning that all returns are weighted according to the market capitalization of the previous month throughout the chosen dataset.
The MAX effect is significant only when the oil market is bearish, producing t-statistics of −2.07 in equal-weighted and −2.15 in value-weighted univariate regression settings. The MAX effect also survives the addition of control variables BETA, SIZE, BM, MOM, ILLIQ, and REV, producing t-statistics of −2.74 in equally weighted and −2.37 in value-weighted full-specification regression settings. The MAX effect is not significant in full samples and sub-samples when the oil market is bullish. The insignificant MAX effect in panel A2 and the positive sign of the MAX relationship in panel B2 hint at the oil market influence on the Norwegian stock market. With MAX being a valid proxy of lottery-like-stocks, the results from panel A3 and B3 may be interpreted as increased investor enthusiasm for lottery-like stocks during downturns in the oil market. This increased demand for lottery-like stocks happens during the time when the oil market is bearish, which leads to the significant negative relation between the MAX and expected returns; however, there is no relation if, at the time of investment decision, the oil market is bullish. The oil market can be viewed as a proxy of investor sentiments considering the concentration of energy-related stocks in the Norwegian market.
Figure 1 illustrates the Brent price in the spot market and its monthly return averages. The grey color in the background of Figure 1 represents bearish periods. The grey and white colors in the background switch very frequently and after very short spans of time because the method of Harding and Pagan (2002) to determine market phases allows a minimum phase of two months. The thinnest grey or white background color represents two months at the minimum. Figure 1 clearly shows that prices and returns are on the rise in the white regions and are declining in the grey regions. The average monthly returns on Brent during the bearish and bullish phases are −1.83% and 4.96%, respectively. The longest bear (bull) phase in the Brent market is 13 months long, from November 2013 to December 2014 (May 1999 to January 2000). Table 6 presents descriptive statistics of the bull and bear periods of Brent. Mean returns in the bear (bull) periods are negative (positive), and the standard deviation is slightly higher in the bear periods than the bull periods.10

4.4. The MAX Effect and Idiosyncratic Volatility

We use Equation (2) to investigate the relationship between the MAX, MIN (minimum daily return in past one month) and IVOL in the Norwegian market.11 We run these regressions for the equally weighted setting and the value-weighted setting using the sub-sample when the oil market is bearish. We use this sub-sample because the MAX effect is present only in the bearish state of the oil market. Table 7 presents the beta coefficients and associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics of these regressions.
In panel A of Table 7, IVOL has a negative and significant relationship with the expected returns. However, similar to Bali et al. (2011), adding MAX to the regression (third and fourth rows of Table 7) reverses the sign of the relationship. In Panel A, MAX remains significant at 10 percent with IVOL as a control variable and at 5 percent with IVOL and MIN as control variables. The MAX effect remains highly significant in value-weighted regression settings. However, IVOL loses its significance in value-weighted settings. We see in Table 7) panel A that the MAX does not fully subsume IVOL; IVOL remains statistically significant but the relationship is positive with expected returns.

5. Conclusions

The empirical results show that MAX is not significant in the Norwegian market, owing to the strong association between the Norwegian market and the oil market. However, when we control for different states of the oil market, the MAX effect seems to appear only in bearish periods of the oil market. Oil market states can be viewed as a proxy of investor sentiments for the Norwegian stock market and this result has implication for other oil exporting countries’ markets. Our results are in line with the findings of Kumar (2009) and Fong and Toh (2014) that the investors’ tendency to seek lottery-like stocks increases during adverse economic conditions and when the investor sentiments are high. Our results are consequential in the sense that most of the small equity markets are usually influenced by one or a couple of industrial sectors or commodity markets. Therefore, controlling for these specific influence factors could open new doors for further research. Our results are relevant for other oil exporting countries, such as Canada and Saudi Arabia, because a bullish (bearish) oil market is good (bad) news for these countries similar to Norway. These results imply that an investment strategy based on the MAX factor (long on low-MAX stocks and short on high-MAX stocks) does not produce positive returns in the Norwegian market at least during normal market conditions. Investors need to adjust the influence of the oil market in the Norwegian market to conduct a successful investment strategy based on the MAX factor. The limitations of the findings are that the Norwegian market is changing, with investments going into firms other than those that are oil related. It means a lower percentage of capital out of the total Norwegian market capitalization in oil-related firms in the future, which will decrease the influence of the oil market on the Norwegian stock market. Another limitation on the exploitation of the investment strategy based on the MAX is that it is difficult to short high-MAX stocks because they are relatively illiquid and small. Moreover, we partly confirm the findings of Bali et al. (2011) that controlling for MAX reverses the negative relationship between IVOL and expected returns; however, IVOL remains significant in the Norwegian market.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.K. and T.L.; methodology, formal analysis, data curation and writing—original draft preparation, M.K.; writing—review, validation, editing and supervision, T.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Restrictions apply to the availability of these data. Data were obtained from https://titlon.uit.no/ (accessed on 11 January 2018). and Thomson Reuters Datastream (Now called Refinitiv Datastream) and are available from the authors with the permission of Rfinitiv and TITLON.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Variables Definitions

MAX(N):
M A X ( N ) i , t = ( N = 1 ) N M A X ( R i , N ) N
where R i , N is the daily return on stock i and N represent number of highest daily returns selected.
IVOL: To estimate the individual idiosyncratic volatility of an individual stock, we use the same definition as in Bali et al. (2011), where the return generating process is
R i , d r f , d = α i + β i ( R m , d r f , d ) + ϵ i , d
where ϵ i , d is the idiosyncratic return on day d. The idiosyncratic volatility of stock i in month t is defined as the standard deviation of daily residuals in month t.
I V O L i , t = v a r ( ϵ i , d )
ILLIQ: Following Amihud (2002), we measure stock illiquidity for each stock in month t as the ratio of the absolute monthly stock return to its NOK trading volume
I L L I Q i , t = | R i , t | V o l u m e ( N O K ) i , t
where R i , t is the return on stock i in month t and V o l u m n ( N O K ) i , t is the respective monthly trading volume in NOK divided by NOK 100 million.
SIZE: SIZE is natural log of average market capitalization of stock i during the month t 1 .
REV: REV of stock i is the return on stock i on month t 1 .
BETA: We use the same definition as in Bali et al. (2011) did. We follow Scholes and Williams (1977) and Dimson (1979) to measure beta.
R i , d r f , d = α i + β 1 ( R m , d 1 r f , d 1 ) + β 2 ( R m , d r f , d ) + β 3 ( R m , d + 1 r f , d + 1 ) + ϵ i , d
To measure market beta, we run this regression each month and extract beta coefficients β 1 , β 2 and β 3 and then take their average.
β i = β 1 + β 2 + β 3 3

Appendix B

Table A1. Number of common stocks registered at OSE over the years.
Table A1. Number of common stocks registered at OSE over the years.
YearTotal Common Stocks Registered at OSETotal Norwegian Common Stocks
19807878
19818585
19829191
19839797
1984111111
1985124124
1986131131
1987128128
1988126126
1989126126
1990135134
1991122120
1992123121
1993138132
1994144135
1995159148
1996172160
1997214192
1998231203
1999228202
2000226197
2001210179
2002196167
2003190164
2004183156
2005217184
2006238197
2007272217
2008266211
2009247191
2010238184
2011231177
2012221174
2013220171
2014216167
2015208158
2016198153
Table A2. Bull and bear phases and monthly return averages of Brent oil.
Table A2. Bull and bear phases and monthly return averages of Brent oil.
StartEndPhaseMonthly Average Return
January 1996August 1996Bull4.53
September 1996February 1997Bear−2.17
March 1997May 1997Bull0.21
June 1997February 1998Bear−3.71
March 1998April 1998Bull4.52
May 1998June 1998Bear−9.55
July 1998September 1998Bull6.97
October 1998November 1998Bear−17.32
December 1998March 1999Bull11.44
April 1999May 1999Bear0.02
June 1999January 2000Bull8.86
February 2000December 2000Bear0.28
January 2001April 2001Bull4.60
May 2001September 2001Bear−4.31
October 2001March 2002Bull3.87
April 2002May 2002Bear−5.35
June 2002December 2002Bull4.29
January 2003March 2003Bear−2.12
April 2003May 2003Bull0.50
June 2003September 2003Bear0.45
October 2003February 2004Bull3.63
March 2004November 2004Bear2.82
December 2004February 2005Bull7.17
March 2005April 2005Bear0.63
May 2005June 2005Bull5.47
July 2005October 2005Bear0.48
November 2005December 2005Bull4.64
January 2006September 2006Bear−0.09
October 2006November 2006Bull5.36
December 2006August 2007Bear1.74
September 2007October 2007Bull10.45
November 2007January 2008Bear0.63
February 2008May 2008Bull9.20
June 2008October 2008Bear−12.89
November 2008May 2009Bull2.50
June 2009August 2009Bear1.21
September 2009October 2009Bull5.08
November 2009January 2010Bear−1.62
February 2010March 2010Bull7.45
April 2010May 2010Bear−5.22
June 2010July 2010Bull6.19
August 2010May 2011Bear3.77
June 2011July 2011Bull0.26
August 2011September 2011Bear−5.48
October 2011February 2012Bull4.03
March 2012May 2012Bear−7.49
June 2012July 2012Bull4.34
August 2012October 2012Bear0.76
November 2012January 2013Bull2.01
February 2013April 2013Bear−5.17
May 2013July 2013Bull3.81
August 2013September 2013Bear−1.01
October 2013November 2013Bull1.98
December 2013December 2014Bear−4.95
January 2015February 2015Bull5.42
March 2015July 2015Bear−3.36
August 2015October 2015Bull−1.06
November 2015December 2015Bear−12.94
January 2016April 2016Bull6.82
May 2016December 2016Bear2.41

Notes

1
TITLON contains financial data from 1980 until present, for further details, see https://titlon.uit.no/ (accessed on 11 January 2018).
2
They are categorized as “A-aksjer”, “Ordinære aksjer”, and “Konverterte A” in the TITLON database.
3
We also performed all analyses on datasets for different periods—1982–2016, 1985–2016, and 1990–2016, for example; however, the results were similar to those for the 1996–2016 dataset. For brevity, therefore, we report most results for the 1996–2016 data.
4
Table A1 in Appendix B reports the number of stocks registered on the OSE over the years.
5
6
Book-to-market data before 1998 are rarely available for all firms. Therefore, we report results for 1998–2016 data where book-to-market-characteristic data are involved.
7
Even if we include these stocks, the results remain similar.
8
A minimum transition probability of 33.3% is required in tercile portfolio analysis to show persistence.
9
As Bali et al. (2011) did in their paper, we also winsorize the right-hand-side variables at the 0.5 % and 99.5% levels before running all regressions.
10
Duration of bull and bear periods are presented in detail in Table A2.
11
Following Bali et al. (2011), we orthogonalize IVOL with respect to MAX and MIN when we use any two of these three variables in regressions to avoid the multicollinearity problem. MAX-IVOL and MIN-IVOL are 88% and 82% correlated, respectively, in the Norwegian market.

References

  1. Ahmadi, Maryam, Matteo Manera, and Mehdi Sadeghzadeh. 2016. Global oil market and the us stock returns. Energy 114: 1277–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Amihud, Yakov. 2002. Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series effects. Journal of Financial Markets 5: 31–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Ang, Andrew, Robert J. Hodrick, Yuhang Xing, and Xiaoyan Zhang. 2006. The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. The Journal of Finance 61: 259–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Ang, Andrew, Robert J. Hodrick, Yuhang Xing, and Xiaoyan Zhang. 2009. High idiosyncratic volatility and low returns: International and further U.S. evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 91: 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Annaert, Jan, Marc De Ceuster, and Kurt Verstegen. 2013. Are extreme returns priced in the stock market? european evidence. Journal of Banking & Finance 37: 3401–11. [Google Scholar]
  6. Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2006. Investor sentiment and the cross-section of stock returns. The Journal of Finance 61: 1645–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Bali, Turan G., Nusret Cakici, and Robert F. Whitelaw. 2011. Maxing out: Stocks as lotteries and the cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial Economics 99: 427–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Bjørnland, Hilde C. 2009. Oil price shocks and stock market booms in an oil exporting country. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 56: 232–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Blume, Marshall E., and Irwin Friend. 1973. A new look at the capital asset pricing model. The Journal of Finance 28: 19–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Cappelen, Ådne, Torbjørn Eika, and Joakim Blix Prestmo. 2014. Virkninger på norsk økonomi av et kraftig fall i oljeprisen (rapport nr. 46/2010). Oslo: Statistisk Sentralbyrå. [Google Scholar]
  11. Carhart, Mark M. 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. The Journal of Finance 52: 57–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Cochrane, John H. 2011. Presidential address: Discount rates. The Journal of Finance 66: 1047–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Cueto, José Manuel, Aurea Grané, and Ignacio Cascos. 2020. Models for expected returns with statistical factors. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Dimson, Elroy. 1979. Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading. Journal of Financial Economics 7: 197–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33: 3–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1996. Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies. The Journal of Finance 51: 55–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy 81: 607–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Fong, Wai Mun, and Benjamin Toh. 2014. Investor sentiment and the max effect. Journal of Banking & Finance 46: 190–201. [Google Scholar]
  19. Friend, Irwin, and Marshall Blume. 1970. Measurement of portfolio performance under uncertainty. The American Economic Review 60: 561–75. [Google Scholar]
  20. Griffin, John M., and Michael L. Lemmon. 2002. Book-to-market equity, distress risk, and stock returns. The Journal of Finance 57: 2317–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Harding, Don, and Adrian Pagan. 2002. Dissecting the cycle: A methodological investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 365–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Harvey, Campbell R., Yan Liu, and Heqing Zhu. 2016. … and the cross-section of expected returns. The Review of Financial Studies 29: 5–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Hirshleifer, David, Kewei Hou, and Siew Hong Teoh. 2012. The accrual anomaly: Risk or mispricing? Management Science 58: 320–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Jensen, Michael C., Fischer Black, and Myron S. Scholes. 1972. The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Tests. Edited by Michael C. Jensen. Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. New York: Praeger Publishers Inc., pp. 79–121. [Google Scholar]
  25. Jensen, Theis Ingerslev, Bryan T. Kelly, and Lasse Heje Pedersen. 2022. Is There a Replication Crisis in Finance? Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  26. Kane, Alex. 1982. Skewness preference and portfolio choice. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 17: 15–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Kumar, Alok. 2009. Who gambles in the stock market? The Journal of Finance 64: 1889–933. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Lakonishok, Josef, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1994. Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. The Journal of Finance 49: 1541–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Lintner, John. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. The Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Mossin, Jan. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34: 768–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Nartea, Gilbert V., Dongmin Kong, and Ji Wu. 2017. Do extreme returns matter in emerging markets? evidence from the chinese stock market. Journal of Banking & Finance 76: 189–97. [Google Scholar]
  32. Nartea, Gilbert V., Ji Wu, and Hong Tao Liu. 2014. Extreme returns in emerging stock markets: Evidence of a max effect in south korea. Applied Financial Economics 4: 425–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1994. Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. The Review of Economic Studies 61: 631–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Park, Jungwook, and Ronald A. Ratti. 2008. Oil price shocks and stock markets in the us and 13 european countries. Energy Economics 30: 2587–608. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Qadan, Mahmoud, and Hazar Nama. 2018. Investor sentiment and the price of oil. Energy Economics 69: 42–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Scholes, Myron, and Joseph Williams. 1977. Estimating betas from nonsynchronous data. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 309–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Sharpe, William F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance 19: 425–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Song, Yingjie, Qiang Ji, Ya-Juan Du, and Jiang-Bo Geng. 2019. The dynamic dependence of fossil energy, investor sentiment and renewable energy stock markets. Energy Economics 84: 104564. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman. 1992. Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5: 297–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Von Brasch, Thomas, Håvard Hungnes, and Birger Strøm. 2018. Ringvirkninger av petroleumsnæringen i norsk økonomi. (rapport nr. 2018/18). Oslo: Statistisk Sentralbyrå. [Google Scholar]
  41. Walkshäusl, Christian. 2014. The max effect: European evidence. Journal of Banking & Finance 42: 1–10. [Google Scholar]
  42. Wan, Xiaoyuan. 2018. Is the idiosyncratic volatility anomaly driven by the max or min effect? evidence from the chinese stock market. International Review of Economics & Finance 53: 1–15. [Google Scholar]
  43. Wang, Yudong, and Li Liu. 2016. Crude oil and world stock markets: Volatility spillovers, dynamic correlations, and hedging. Empirical Economics 50: 1481–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Wang, Yudong, Chongfeng Wu, and Li Yang. 2013. Oil price shocks and stock market activities: Evidence from oil-importing and oil-exporting countries. Journal of Comparative Economics 41: 1220–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Yang, Sheng-Ping, and Thanh Nguyen. 2019. Skewness preference and asset pricing: Evidence from the japanese stock market. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  46. Zhang, Xindong, Lixu Xie, Yue Zhai, and Dong Wang. 2018. Can microstructure noise explain the max effect? Finance Research Letters 26: 185–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Zhang, Yue-Jun, and Jia-Min Pei. 2019. Exploring the impact of investor sentiment on stock returns of petroleum companies. Energy Procedia 158: 4079–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Brent price and monthly return averages.
Figure 1. Brent price and monthly return averages.
Jrfm 15 00154 g001
Table 1. The table reports descriptive statistics of high- and low-MAX portfolio stocks. The data are obtained from the TITLON database from January 1996 until December 2016. Portfolios are formed and re-balanced each month on the first trading day based on the maximum daily return in the past one month. All figures are percentages except skewness and avg. stocks/month.
Table 1. The table reports descriptive statistics of high- and low-MAX portfolio stocks. The data are obtained from the TITLON database from January 1996 until December 2016. Portfolios are formed and re-balanced each month on the first trading day based on the maximum daily return in the past one month. All figures are percentages except skewness and avg. stocks/month.
PortfolioAvg. Stocks/
Month
MeanMedianStandard
Deviation
SkewnessPercentile
(1%)
Percentile
25%)
Percentile
(75%)
Percentile
(99%)
Quartile Portfolio Analysis: 25% stocks in each portfolio
High MAX220.59−0.4316.721.47−39.02−7.497.4452.89
Low MAX220.660.2910.620.56−26.00−4.425.7030.94
Tercile Portfolio Analysis: 35% of stocks in high- and low-MAX portfolios and 30% in middle portfolios
High MAX300.53−0.3116.131.44−39.44−7.157.4149.51
Low MAX300.820.4010.970.51−27.74−4.475.9732.10
Table 2. The table reports mean returns on MAX(N)-sorted portfolios and the difference between mean returns and risk-adjusted returns of high- and low-MAX portfolios with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics. We use the Oslo all-share index as the market factor in CAPM and the four-factor model of Fama and French (1996) and Carhart (1997). Three portfolios are formed and re-balanced on the first trading day each month, sorted on MAX(N). All figures are percentages.
Table 2. The table reports mean returns on MAX(N)-sorted portfolios and the difference between mean returns and risk-adjusted returns of high- and low-MAX portfolios with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics. We use the Oslo all-share index as the market factor in CAPM and the four-factor model of Fama and French (1996) and Carhart (1997). Three portfolios are formed and re-balanced on the first trading day each month, sorted on MAX(N). All figures are percentages.
MAXMAX(2)MAX(3)MAX(4)MAX(5)
Panel A: Equal weighted portfolio
High MAX0.680.600.620.600.66
Middle Portfolio0.700.910.910.920.82
Low MAX0.930.820.800.820.85
Return difference (High-Low)−0.25−0.22−0.18−0.22−0.19
(t-statistic)(−0.73)(−0.61)(−0.50)(−0.60)(−0.52)
CAPM alpha difference−0.33−0.32−0.30−0.34−0.32
(t-statistic)(−1.11)(−1.04)(−1.01)(−1.19)(−1.13)
FF + Carhart alpha difference−0.59−0.57−0.52−0.52−0.49
(t-statistic)(−2.31)(−2.14)(−2.04)(−2.17)(−1.96)
Panel B: Value weighted portfolio
High MAX1.090.980.830.660.86
Middle Portfolio0.790.911.021.030.87
Low MAX0.940.930.970.960.95
Return difference (High-Low)0.150.04−0.14−0.3−0.09
(t-statistic)(0.38)(0.11)(−0.32)(−0.66)(−0.18)
CAPM alpha difference0.00−0.18−0.42−0.61−0.42
(t-statistic)(0.00)(−0.47)(−1.16)(−1.60)(−1.08)
FF + Carhart alpha difference0.00−0.12−0.30−0.42−0.25
(t-statistic)(0.01)(−0.30)(−0.79)(−1.08)(−0.61)
Table 3. This table presents the transition matrix for tercile portfolio analysis. The figures represent the transition probabilities that a stock remains in the same tercile portfolio or switches to another tercile portfolio.
Table 3. This table presents the transition matrix for tercile portfolio analysis. The figures represent the transition probabilities that a stock remains in the same tercile portfolio or switches to another tercile portfolio.
Month (t)Month (t + 1)
PortfolioHigh-MAXMiddle PortfolioLow-MAX
High-MAX0.4880.3080.209
Middle Portfolio0.3120.3520.336
Low-MAX0.1990.2960.505
Table 4. This table reports the lambda coefficients, with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics in parenthesis, of firm-level cross-sectional FM regression results. The first panel reports univariate and bivariate regressions results, and the last row reports results of the full-specification multiple regression. The data are from January 1998 to December 2016.
Table 4. This table reports the lambda coefficients, with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics in parenthesis, of firm-level cross-sectional FM regression results. The first panel reports univariate and bivariate regressions results, and the last row reports results of the full-specification multiple regression. The data are from January 1998 to December 2016.
MAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREV
−0.032
(−0.86)
−0.0290.003
(−0.76)(0.70)
−0.032 0.001
(−0.86) (0.99)
−0.030 −0.000
(−0.79) (−0.75)
−0.026 0.015
(−0.76) (3.92)
0.004 −0.043
(0.12) (−3.51)
−0.045 0.009
(−1.20) (0.59)
−0.0170.0020.0 000.0000.013−0.0310.007
(−0.44)(0.53)(0.04)(−0.51)(3.42)(−2.40)(0.48)
Table 5. This table reports the beta coefficients, with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics in parentheses of firm-level OSL and WLS regression results. Panel A (Panel B) reports OLS (WLS) coefficient estimates of univariate, bivariate and full-specification multiple regressions, first for the whole sample, second for time periods when the oil market is bullish at the time of investment decision, and third for time periods when the oil market is bearish at the time of investment decision. The data are from January 1998 to December 2016.
Table 5. This table reports the beta coefficients, with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics in parentheses of firm-level OSL and WLS regression results. Panel A (Panel B) reports OLS (WLS) coefficient estimates of univariate, bivariate and full-specification multiple regressions, first for the whole sample, second for time periods when the oil market is bullish at the time of investment decision, and third for time periods when the oil market is bearish at the time of investment decision. The data are from January 1998 to December 2016.
Panel A: Equal-Weighted/OLS
A1: All SampleA2: Bullish Oil MarketA3: Bearish Oil Market
MAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREVMAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREVMAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREV
−0.068 −0.041 −0.134
(−1.22) (−0.54) (−2.07)
−0.059−0.007 −0.0460.004 −0.115−0.014
(−1.10)(−1.41) (−0.60)(0.52) (−1.88)(−2.82)
−0.064 0.000 −0.024 0.002 −0.135 0.000
(−1.10) (0.39) (−0.29) (0.98) (−2.05) (−0.14)
−0.068 0.000 −0.041 0.000 −0.134 0.000
(−1.72) (0.09) (−0.73) (0.03) (−3.30) (0.04)
−0.056 0.016 −0.007 0.022 −0.136 0.018
(−1.04) (2.80) (−0.10) (2.91) (−2.21) (2.80)
−0.037 −0.035 0.011 −0.049 −0.116 −0.023
(−0.72) (−3.93) (0.15) (−3.89) (−1.92) (−1.98)
−0.115 0.089−0.077 0.084−0.206 0.111
(−2.04) (3.74)(−1.05) (2.86)(−3.04) (3.80)
−0.082−0.006−0.0010.0000.014−0.0240.080−0.0140.004−0.0010.0000.019−0.0360.069−0.191−0.013−0.0010.0000.017−0.0130.105
(−1.36)(−1.16)(−0.91)(0.00)(2.42)(−2.76)(3.27)(−0.16)(0.51)(−0.27)(−0.07)(2.40)(−2.70)(2.16)(−2.74)(−2.55)(−1.06)(−0.03)(2.68)(−1.13)(3.63)
Panel B: Value-Weighted/WLS
B1: All SampleB2: Bullish Oil MarketB3: Bearish Oil Market
MAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREVMAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREVMAXBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREV
−0.088 0.038 −0.239
(−0.81) (0.22) (−2.15)
−0.069−0.012 0.050−0.008 −0.219−0.012
(−0.67)(−1.47) (0.30)(−0.56) (−2.03)(−1.26)
−0.076 0.001 0.072 0.002 −0.228 0.001
(−0.71) (0.69) (0.42) (1.22) (−2.08) (0.51)
−0.088 0.000 0.038 0.000 −0.239 0.000
(−1.09) (−0.08) (0.30) (0.08) (−2.47) (−0.59)
−0.088 0.004 0.063 0.015 −0.249 0.008
(−0.88) (0.46) (0.42) (1.34) (−2.29) (0.90)
−0.083 −0.041 0.047 −0.060 −0.236 −0.032
(−0.75) (−3.15) (0.27) (−2.65) (−2.11) (−2.11)
−0.113 0.0540.030 0.027−0.304 0.107
(−1.03) (1.61)(0.17) (0.62)(−2.76) (2.65)
−0.074−0.0120.0010.0000.003−0.0330.0500.117−0.0110.0030.0000.016−0.0430.022−0.281−0.0110.0010.0000.008−0.0170.103
(−0.63)(−1.51)(0.78)(0.10)(0.44)(−2.35)(1.49)(0.64)(−0.80)(1.32)(0.23)(1.38)(−1.86)(0.52)(−2.37)(−1.21)(0.43)(−0.33)(0.86)(−1.07)(2.58)
Table 6. This table presents some descriptive statistics of bull and bear states of Brent. All figures are percentages.
Table 6. This table presents some descriptive statistics of bull and bear states of Brent. All figures are percentages.
StatisticBear PeriodsBull Periods
Monthly ValuesAnnualized ValuesMonthly ValuesAnnualized Values
Mean Return−1.83−24.344.9678.71
Median Return−1.96−26.273.2446.66
Standard Deviation10.4636.239.5933.23
Minimum Return−34.57-−21.12-
Maximum Return39.03-38.78-
Table 7. This table reports the beta coefficients, with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics in parenthesis, of firm-level OSL and WLS regressions. The dataset comprises time periods between 1998 and 2016 when the Brent oil market was bearish.
Table 7. This table reports the beta coefficients, with the associated Newey and West (1994) adjusted t-statistics in parenthesis, of firm-level OSL and WLS regressions. The dataset comprises time periods between 1998 and 2016 when the Brent oil market was bearish.
Panel A: Equal-Weighted/OLS
IVOLMAXMINBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREV
−0.007
(−3.20)
0.004−0.127
(2.52)(−1.93)
0.004−0.1260.288
(2.47)(−1.95)(3.23)
0.005−0.2000.095−0.014−0.0030.0000.017−0.0050.098
(3.60)(−2.91)(1.32)(−2.68)(−2.49)(−0.10)(2.68)(−0.43)(3.48)
Panel B: Value-Weighted/WLS
IVOLMAXMINBETASIZEBMMOMILLIQREV
−0.011
(−3.36)
0.002−0.244
(0.93)(−2.31)
0.003−0.2650.288
(1.22)(−2.64)(3.23)
0.005−0.3300.267−0.010−0.0020.0000.0100.0000.075
(1.86)(−2.76)(1.89)(−1.01)(−1.03)(−0.21)(1.09)(−0.02)(1.74)
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kashif, M.; Leirvik, T. The MAX Effect in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case of Norway. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15, 154. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040154

AMA Style

Kashif M, Leirvik T. The MAX Effect in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case of Norway. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2022; 15(4):154. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040154

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kashif, Muhammad, and Thomas Leirvik. 2022. "The MAX Effect in an Oil Exporting Country: The Case of Norway" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 15, no. 4: 154. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040154

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop