3.1. Model Setup
Consider a supply chain scenario where a manufacturer (he) supplies a green product to two downstream firms, which subsequently sell the product to end consumers. The first downstream firm (she) is an online platform, and the manufacturer has two contract modes: resale and agency sales. The second downstream firm (she) starts as an online platform and then invests a fixed cost
F to open an offline experience, retail stores, or a VR (Virtual Reality) shopping experience (e.g., Taobao Buy+ and JD VR Industry Alliance) and establishes her own modern logistics system. The offline experience, retail stores, or VR shopping are set up to compensate for the shortcomings of consumers’ online shopping, such as visibility, audibility, touchability sensibility, usability, and other intuitive attributes. The purpose of establishing the modern logistics system is to deliver products quickly and accurately to consumers. Combined with the e-commerce capabilities of the online platform, the second downstream firm provides consumers with an immersive omni-channel shopping experience. To differentiate it from the first online platform, we refer to the second downstream firm as a new retailer that provides better shopping experiences to consumers than does the online platform. To maximize the service advantages, the new retailer labels the green product purchased from the manufacturer with her own brand trademark. That is, the manufacturer can offer only a reselling contract to the new retailer. Simultaneously, the manufacturer can offer an agency selling contract to the online platform if he wants to use the agency sales mode. Therefore, the manufacturer and new retailer reach an agreement using only the reselling contract mode. For convenience, subscripts
are adopted to represent the manufacturer, online platform, and new retailer accordingly. The main parameters are detailed in in
Table 1.
According to the above description, we focus on two modes: reselling contract mode (mode RR) and mixed contract mode (mode PR). In the mode RR, the manufacturer offers wholesale prices
and
to the two retailers who then sell the product at retail prices
and
in the end market. In the mode PR, after paying a proportion fee rate (PFR)
to the online platform, the manufacturer directly retails the product to consumers at price
. Simultaneously, he sells the product to the new retailer at price
, who then resells it to consumers at price
. We assume that
and
, meaning that a consumer prefers to spend more on the new retailer over the online platform due to better shopping experiences. To avoid redundancy, we focus on a low PFR with
, which aligns with both reality and the literature [
6].
Figure 1 illustrates the two modes.
The manufacturer producing the green product has the following two associated costs: unit production cost
c (for simplicity, it is normalized to zero) and green innovation cost, which is a quadratic function [
12,
37],
, where
and
h represent the product greenness and its cost coefficient of greenness per unit, respectively.
Consumers are strategic, and their purchase decision depends on utility maximization. We assume that the consumer valuation,
v, for green products purchased via online platforms is heterogeneous and follows a uniform distribution between 0 and 1. As a result of receiving better shopping experiences, consumer valuation of green product purchased from the new retailer is
(
). We call
k the omni-channel shopping experience factor (OSEF) of the product purchased from the new retailer.
indicates that the shopping experiences of consumers from the new retailer is higher than that from the online platform. This differentiated valuation approach is similar to Yenipazarli [
38] and Hong et al. [
39]. Consumers with eco-awareness gain uniform environmental benefits from purchasing green products. The environmental benefit is supposed to be
[
39,
40], where
r denotes the consumer sensitivity to the product greenness. Therefore, the utilities
and
that a consumer derives from the online platform and new retailer are
A consumer chooses to purchase the green product from the online platform if and , while they buy it through the new retailer if and . Finally, the consumer chooses not to purchase the green product if and . Using this logic, assuming that and , the following lemma is obtained.
Lemma 1. The demands and for the online platform and new retailer are listed below.
- (i)
When , we obtain
- (ii)
When , we obtain
The expression can be understood as the comprehensive purchase cost of consumers through the online platform (CPCP), because the positive utility of product greenness to consumers is , which can be considered as the environmental protection attributes of products reducing the purchase cost for consumers. Similarly, can be understood as the comprehensive purchase cost of consumers through the new retailer (CPCN). Therefore, the expressions and can be understood as the absolute and relative differences of consumers’ comprehensive purchase costs through the new retailer and online platform (ADCPC and RDCPC), respectively. Evidently, the CPCP, CPCN, ADCPC, and RDCPC are directly affected by the retailers’ pricing decision and manufacturer’s green strategy.
Lemma 1 shows that the interaction among consumers’ shopping experience differences, the retailers’ pricing decisions, and manufacturer’s green strategy has a direct effect on consumers’ purchasing channel choice and market demands. A CPCP below zero implies that the the positive effect of product greenness on consumer utility exceeds the negative effect of retail price on consumer utility, which results in positive utility for any consumer when buying products from the online platform. Therefore, when the CPCP is no more than zero (), the whole market is either monopolized by the online platform or shared by the two retailers. Specifically, if the shopping experience difference is small relative to the ADCPC (i.e., ), then each consumer chooses the online platform, because the small difference in the shopping experience relative to the ADCPC indicates that the comprehensive purchase cost of consumers through the new retailer is so large that consumers ignore the service advantages of the new retailer. Otherwise, the online platform and new retailer share the whole market if the shopping experience difference is large (i.e., ), which means that the new retailer encroaches on the online platform’s monopoly market to take advantage of the better service advantages. Moreover, when the CPCP is no more than zero, the green product covers the whole market (because ).
When the CPCP is greater than zero (), the below three scenarios occur. If the difference in the shopping experience of consumers from the new retailer and online platform is large relative to the RDCPC (i.e., ), then the new retailer monopolizes the market. If the difference in the shopping experience is small relative to the RDCPC (i.e., ) and large relative to the ADCPC (i.e., ), then the new retailer and online platform compete for market share. Otherwise, if the difference in the shopping experience is small relative to the ADCPC (i.e., ), then the market is monopolized by the online platform. These conclusions are justified for the following reasons. The small difference in the shopping experience relative to the ADCPC indicates that the comprehensive purchase cost of consumers through the new retailer is so large that consumers ignore the service advantages of the new retailer and choose her competitor channel. As the difference in the shopping experience increases ( increases), the service advantages of the new retailer gradually come into play. When the difference in the shopping experience exceeds the ADCPC, the new retailer erodes the online platform’s market percentage. When the difference in the shopping experience is large enough to exceed the RDCPC, the new retailer occupies a monopoly position in the market. Furthermore, in the above three scenarios, the green product covers part of the market (because ).
3.2. Mode RR
In this subsection, we investigate the RR model, and the sequence of decisions is described as follows. First, the manufacturer determines the level of greenness, which is denoted by . Second, the manufacturer offers the prices and to the online platform and the new retailer, respectively. Third, the online platform and new retailer announce the prices and to consumers at the same time. Finally, consumers determine their purchasing selection according to the retail prices and greenness. For simplicity, the superscript is used to identify this mode.
Given the demand functions, the manufacturer, online platform, and new retailer’s profit functions are expressed as
,
, and
. All the proofs of the propositions and corollaries in the following text are presented in the
Appendix A.
Proposition 1. Under the RR mode, the equilibrium exhibits the following characteristics:
- (i)
When , where , there exists a unique equilibrium define as where , and .
Moreover, if ; otherwise, if ; , and .
- (ii)
When , the equilibrium is attained at , and the results are as follows:
- (iia)
If and , where , then Moreover, .
- (iib)
If and , then Moreover, .
- (iic)
If and , where , the results are the same as those in case (iia).
- (iid)
If , and , then Moreover, .
The parameter comprehensively reflects the green sensitivity of consumers and the difficulty of product green innovation, and we refer to it as the green product utility (GPU). A smaller value of h implies a lower unit cost of green innovation, which is more conducive to the promotion of the green product. A larger value of r implies that consumers are more sensitive to the product greenness. As a result, the positive utility of unit greenness to consumers is higher, and then the consumers prefer to spend more on the product with higher greenness. Therefore, a smaller value of h and/or a larger value of r mean(s) a higher GPU t, because t increases with r and decreases with h, and vice versa.
Proposition 1 obtains the optimum solution, profits, manufacturer’s selling channel choice, and consumer purchasing channel choice for different conditions with respect to the GPU t and consumers’ omni-channel shopping experience factor k under the mode RR. Only when the green product utility, consumers’ OSEF, and retail price of the new retailer are large (case (iid)), the manufacturer retails the green product using just one channel, because the new retailer setting an exorbitant retail price results in the online platform cornering the whole market. However, in reality, these findings do not hold because the rational new retailer has no incentive to set her retail price so high that her demand is zero, and thus, this case can be omitted.
For the other cases (i), (iia), (iib), and (iic), the manufacturer favors selling the green product via both channels instead of relying on just one, essentially providing a product service differentiation strategy to consumers. (
Figure 2 graphically depicts the effect of GPU on the demands, where
and
.) This is because through the green contract design, the manufacturer can induce both the retailers’ price competition behavior (different pricing) to obtain more profits (see the proof of Proposition 1), which is consistent with intuition that the competition of downstream enterprises is beneficial to upstream enterprises. Correspondingly, those consumers who buy the green product from the new retailer and online platform are divided, and the green product covers part or all of the demand market (
). From the consumers’ point of view, the manufacturer’s green contract design increases the variety of product services in the end market.
Specifically, when the GPU t is small relative to the OSEF k ( increasing with k), a unique equilibrium exits, and the optimal green contract of the manufacturer induces the price competition between the two retailers, which makes the green product cover part of the demand market rather than the whole demand market (). The reason for this is that the online platform sets a high retail price to respond to the green decision of the manufacturer (i.e., ). Moreover, if the GPU t is above the critical value 1, then more consumers purchase the product from the online platform (). Otherwise, more consumers choose the new retail channel (). This findings shows that for the consumers, the GPU is superior to the new retailer’s service advantage, and only when the GPU is low is the service advantage of the new retailer reflected.
When the GPU t is large relative to the OSEF k (), the green product covers the whole demand market () because the price decision of the online platform and green decision of the manufacturer satisfy the boundary condition . Moreover, if the GPU t is medium (cases (iia) and (iic)), more consumers purchase the product from the online platform (); otherwise, the demand market is equally divided (case (iib)). The reason that the same boundary condition leads to the above two different results is that the two green decisions of manufacturer are determined under the first subcase of case (i) and the second subcase of case (ii) in Lemma 1.
Since the optimal solution in case (ii) of Proposition 1 is reached on the boundary, to avoid redundant processing, the following sensitivity analyses are performed on t and k only for the results in case (i) of Proposition 1.
Corollary 1. When under the mode RR, all decision variables, demands, and profits increase with the green product utility.
Corollary 1 indicates that under the RR mode, when
, the GPU positively influences all decision variables, demands, and profits for the following reasons.
Figure 3 and
Figure 4 graphically depict the effect of the GPU on the equilibrium solution and profits, with the parameter values identical to those shown in
Figure 2. With increasing the green product utility, the manufacturer increases the product greenness, leading to a rise in the positive utility of product greenness to consumers (
increases with
t). As a result, the manufacturer increases the two wholesale prices, and both retailers set higher retail prices. Because the increase in the online platform’s retail price is greater than that of new retailer, but lower than the positive utility increase of product greenness to consumers, the ADCPC and CPCP decrease (
and
decrease with
t). Hence, the new retailer’s market demand increases. Simultaneously, the market demand of the online platform increases because the decrease of the CPCP is lower than that of the ADCPC. The increase in both the demands eventually leads to the increase in the two retailers’ profits. Although the greenness increases, the increase in demands and wholesale prices eventually results in the growth of manufacturer’s profit. Specifically, the conclusion that the demands and retail prices simultaneously increase with the GPU is interesting because it is in contrary to high retail prices, meaning low demands. In particular, when the GPU increases to the maximum value (
), both of the demands increase, and the green product covers the whole demand market (
).
Based on the above analysis, Corollary 1 implies that increasing the GPU is beneficial to consumers, the environment, and the manufacturer and two retailers and that it is most beneficial for the five parties when the GPU reaches a threshold (). In reality, the GPU can be increased by raising the green sensitivity of consumers or/and reducing the difficulty of green product innovation because t increases with r and decreases with h. Retailers can improve consumers’ awareness of environmental protection (consumers can also raise their own environmental awareness) to raise their green sensitivity through certain activities or publicity methods, like showcasing the standout features of green products through advertisement and promotions. Manufacturers can reduce the green cost coefficient through technological innovation, which implies that the cooperation among manufacturer, two retailers, and consumers can be more conducive to the promotion of green product because it can improve the GPU and thus benefit all parties.
Corollary 2. When under the mode RR, we have the following outcomes:
- (i)
and decrease with k, while increases with k.
- (ii)
increases with k. increases with k if ; otherwise, it decreases with k if .
- (iii)
and decrease with k.
- (iv)
increases with k. When , increases with k. When , increases with k if ; otherwise, it decreases with k. When , increases with k. When , increases with k if ; otherwise, it decreases with k, where , and .
Corollary 2 characterizes how the OSEF
k affects the decisions, demands, and profits when
under the mode RR. (
Figure 5 and
Figure 6 graphically depict the effect of OSEF on demands, greenness, and profits, where
and
.) First, it is not expected that as the OSEF increases, the greenness and demands of both the online platform and new retailer decrease. Put differently, the new retailer enhancing the consumers’ shopping experience reduces not only her competitor’s market demand but also her own market demand and product greenness. Furthermore, this conclusion implies that the increase in the OSEF makes more consumers unwilling to purchase the green product and is disadvantageous to environmental protection, which is not intuitive for the following reasons. As the OSEF increases, the new retailer raises her retail price. When the GPU is high (
), the online platform increases her market competitiveness to obtain more market share than the new retailer only by reducing her retail price. When the GPU is low (
), because of the service advantage of the new retailer, the online platform cannot obtain a greater market share through price competition (see the analysis of Proposition 1); thus, she increases her retail price, but this increase is lower than that in the new retailer’s retail price to achieve higher profit. As a result, the increase in the absolute difference of consumers’ comprehensive purchase costs (
) leads to a reduction in market demand for the new retailer. Essentially, as the OSEF increases, price competition weakens across the online platform and new retailer; this causes the new retailer to preferentially target “high-end customers”, culminating in a drop in demand for the new retailer. To encourage price competition between the two retailers, the manufacturer lowers the wholesale price to the online platform while raising the wholesale price to the new retailer. At the same time, the manufacturer reduces the level of product greenness to cut down on green innovation costs, which is driven by the decreased wholesale price to the online platform and the reduced market demand of the new retailer. Regardless of whether the online platform’s retail price decreases or increases, the CPCP (
) still increases more than does the RDCPC (
) because of the decrease in the greenness. Therefore, the market demand of the online platform decreases. Intuitively, although an increase in the OSEF weakens the price competition between the online platform and new retailer, the manufacturer, acting in its own interest, stimulates downstream price competition through green contract design (by reducing the greenness and adjusting the wholesale prices). This stimulus raises the threshold for purchasing green products on the online platform, leading the online platform to abandon the “lowest-end customers” and ultimately resulting in a decline in her market demand.
Second, as the OSEF increases, the new retailer’s profit grows, whereas the online platform’s profit may fall or rise. The enhancement of consumers’ shopping experience from the new retailer increases her profit and may decrease that of the online platform, which is intuitive. Interestingly, the profit of the online platform may increase as the OSEF increases. This result occurs when the OSEF is small () or the GPU is low (). The former occurs because the service advantage of the new retailer is not obvious (see the analysis of Proposition 1). The latter occurs because, although the online platform’s market demand decreases, when the GPU is small, the online platform increases her selling price, and her purchased price offered by the manufacturer decreases, producing a substantial increase in the product’s per-unit profit margin.
Third, the manufacturer’s profit may decrease or increase with the OSEF. It is expected that the profit of manufacturer may increase due to her first-mover advantage and the competition between the two retailers. Unexpectedly, raising the OSEF may lead to a reduction in the manufacturer’s profit for the following reasons. On the one hand, the profit growth of new retailer occupies the space of profit growth of the manufacturer due to the increase in the OSEF. On the other hand, the profit of manufacturer from the online platform is determined mainly by the GPU when the GPU is high (see the analysis of Proposition 1). Therefore, when the OSEF is low and the GPU is high ( and ), as the OSEF increases, although both the profit of the manufacturer from sales on the online platform and green innovation cost due to the reduction of greenness decrease, the decrease of the former is larger than that of the latter. These two factors eventually produce a drop in the manufacturer’s profit in this case.
Based on the above analyses, the triple-win conditions of manufacturer and two retailers with increasing the OSEF are obtained as follows.
Corollary 3. When under the mode RR, the profits of manufacturer and two retailers increase with the OSEF, while the greenness and both the demands decrease with it if (i) and , or (ii) and , or (iii) and .
Corollary 3 shows that under certain conditions (condition (i), (ii), or (iii)), increasing the OSEF is beneficial only to the manufacturer and two retailers, but it is disadvantageous to the environment and consumers because the profits of the three enterprises increase, whereas the greenness and the degree of willingness among consumers to purchase the product decrease.
Figure 7 graphically depicts the increasing conditions of the profits of three parties with increasing the OSEF. Based on Corollaries 1 and 3, when the GPU and OSEF satisfy the given conditions (take the values in areas (i), (ii), and (iii) of
Figure 7), increasing the GPU is beneficial to the five parties of manufacturer, two retailers, environment, and consumers, but increasing the OSEF is beneficial to only the first three parties and is disadvantageous to the environment and consumers. Since the manufacturer can use the technological innovation to reduce the green cost coefficient and the retailers can use certain activities or publicity methods to increase consumers’ green sensitivity (consumers can also increase their own environmental awareness), the increase in the GPU requires the cooperation of the manufacturer, two retailers, and consumers. In addition, increasing the OSEF requires the new retailer to increase her offline investment. Therefore, it can be intuitively seen from
Figure 7 that point
A is a satisfactory point for the five parties. The reason for this is that in areas (i), (ii), and (iii), point
A is the closest point to the curve
, that is,
t takes the maximum (
) at point
A, which is most beneficial to the five parties. Simultaneously,
k is not too big (
), which is acceptable for the new retailer due to less investment being needed in the offline experience store or VR shopping and is good for the environment and consumers. This is the result of the trade-off between the profits of the manufacturer and two retailers, consumer scale, service difficulty of the new retailer, and difficulty with respect to increasing the GPU.
The above analyses also imply that under the mode RR, the promotion of green products requires the cooperation of the manufacturer, retailers, and consumers to achieve the goal of low-carbon environmental protection because, as analyzed in Corollaries 1 and 2, the increases in the GPU and OSEF require the joint efforts of four parties.
3.3. Mode PR
In this subsection, we research the mode PR, and the order of decisions is detailed below. First, the manufacturer determines the greenness . Second, the manufacturer supplies to the new retailer at price and pays a PFR, , to the online platform. Third, the manufacturer and new retailer unveil their retail prices, and , to consumers concurrently (for simplicity, the manufacturer’s retail price through the online platform remains ). Finally, consumers determine their purchase decision based on the retail prices and greenness. For convenience, we use the superscript to represent this mode.
Given the demand functions and PFR, the profits earned by the manufacturer, online platform, and new retailer are denoted as , , and .
Due to the fact that under the mode PR, the method of solving the model is similar to that under the mode RR, and the equilibrium achieved on the boundary is omitted, Proposition 2 focuses on characterizing the unique equilibrium reached at the interior point to avoid redundancy.
Proposition 2. When under the mode PR, where , there exists a unique equilibrium where . Moreover, ; , and .
In comparison to the mode RR, since the agency contract offered to the online platform replaces the resale contract, the existence condition for the unique optimal solution under the mode PR becomes , which is more stringent because if . The condition signifies that the GPU t is relatively small compared to both the OSEF k and PFR because increases with k and .
Proposition 2 presents the equilibrium decisions, profits, manufacturer’s selling channel choice, and consumers’ purchasing channel choice when t is small relative to k and under the mode PR. In this case, similar to the analysis of Proposition 1, the optimal green contract provided by the manufacturer leads to the green product covering part of the demand market. However, for any given t, k, and satisfying the condition , more consumers show a preference for buying the green product from the online platform than from the new retailer (). Recall the conclusion of case (i) of Proposition 1; the market shares of two retailers are affected by the GPU. This finding implies that the manufacturer can use different contract modes to adjust the market share of the two marketing channels.
When , the below three corollaries characterize how the parameters t, k, and affect the optimal decisions, demands, and profits.
Corollary 4. When under the mode PR, the market demand and profit of the new retailer increase with the GPU if ; otherwise, they decrease with it, and all the other demand, decision variables, and profits increase with the green product utility.
Corollary 4 reveals the role of the GPU in shaping the optimal decisions, demands, and profits when
under the mode PR. (
Figure 8 and
Figure 9 graphically depict the effect of the GPU on demands, greenness, and profits, where
, and
, satisfying the condition
.) As the contract mode between the manufacturer and online platform changes from reselling to agency selling, the GPU may negatively influence the market demand and profit of the new retailer (
), whereas it still has a positive effect on all the other demands, decision variables, and profits. The analyses of the latter are similar to those of Corollary 1, and only the former is analyzed below. As the GPU increases, the manufacturer increases the product greenness, resulting in the increase in retail prices. Since agency selling is introduced, the monotonicity of the new retailer’s market demand for the GPU is affected by the PFR. In fact, with the increasing GPU, when the product of the GPU and OSEF is small (
), the increase in the retail price of the new retailer surpasses that of the online platform. As a result, the ADCPC increases, and then the market demand of the new retailer decreases, causing the new retailer’s profit to decline. From the perspective of the impact of the GPU (when the GPU increases), this conclusion implies that such a low PFR and/or low OSEF essentially increase(s) the competitive advantage of the online platform in terms of market share and profit.
Corollary 5. When under the mode PR, we have the following outcomes:
- (i)
, , , and decrease with α.
- (ii)
and decrease with α, while increases with α.
- (iii)
decreases with α, while increases with α. When , increases with α. When , increases with α if ; otherwise, it decreases with α, where and are shown in the proof.
Corollary 5 reveals the role of the PFR in shaping the optimal decisions, demands, and profits when
under the mode PR. (
Figure 10 and
Figure 11 graphically depict the effect of PFR on demands, greenness, and profits, where
, and
.) First, as the PFR increases, the greenness and market demand of online platform decrease, whereas the market demand of the new retailer increases. That is, an increase in the PFR negatively influences the environment and market demand of the online platform but positively influences the market demand of the new retailer. In fact, as an increase in the PFR squeezes the manufacturer’s marginal profit from the online platform, the manufacturer reduces his retail price and the greenness. Influenced by price competition and a decreased greenness, the new retailer lowers her retail price. Since the drop in the manufacturer’s retail price is lower than the drop in both the new retailer’s retail price and the positive utility of product greenness to consumers, the ADCPC decreases, and the CPCP increases (
decreases with
, and
increases with
). As a result, the market demand of the online platform decreases significantly, whereas that of the new retailer increases slightly, causing a decline in the overall market demand. From the above analyses, we know that the increase in the PFR amplifies the pricing conflict between the manufacturer and new retailer, which is not conducive to environmental protection but also reduces consumer interest in buying the green product.
Second, when the PFR grows, the new retailer’s profit grows, whereas the online platform’s profit may increase or decrease. It is expected that an increase in the PFR may increase the online platform’s profit. Unexpectedly, the online platform raising the PFR indirectly boosts the new retailer’s profit while potentially reducing her own for the following reasons. As the PFR increases, the new retailer’s market demand increases slightly, and her margin profit increases because her retail price decreases to less than her purchase price, ultimately causing her profit to grow. Since the PFR’s growth reduces the retail price and market demand for the manufacturer’s products on the online platform, the platform’s profit decreases when the increase of the former has a weaker impact than the combined impact of the decrease of the latter two on her profit. (When
and
,
Figure 12 graphically depicts this case, where
, and
.) This conclusion implies that the online platform cannot set the PFR too high.
Third, the manufacturer experiences a reduction in profit as the PFR grows. In fact, as the PFR increases, although the new retailer’s market demand increases and the green innovation cost decreases, the manufacturer’s profit from the online platform substantially reduces, owing to the shrinking of marginal profit and market demand, which ultimately causes a reduction in the manufacturer’s profit.
Corollary 6. When under the mode PR, we have the following outcomes:
- (i)
, , , and increase with k.
- (ii)
decreases with k. When , increases with k. When , increases with k if ; otherwise, it decreases with k.
- (iii)
and increase with k. decreases with k if and ; otherwise, it increases with k, where the expressions for and are shown in the proof.
Corollary 6 describes how the OSEF
k affects decisions, demands, and profits when
under the mode PR. (
Figure 13 and
Figure 14 graphically depict the effect of the OSEF on demands, greenness, and profits, where
, and
.) On the one hand, increasing the OSEF lowers the market demand of the online platform, the greenness increases, and this may increase or decrease the market demand of the new retailer. This finding implies that the increase in the OSEF is beneficial to the environment and leads to fewer consumers interested in purchasing the green product because of the decease in the whole market demand. Similar to the results under the mode RR, as the OSEF increases, the new retailer also raises her retail price, and the market demand of her competitor reduces due to the increase of new retailer’s service advantage. Owing to the contract change, the manufacturer directly competes with the new retailer on price online. To restrain the increased service advantage of the new retailer, the manufacturer increases the greenness and then raises the prices for sales through the online platform and to the new retailer. At the same time, as the OSEF rises, the selling price of new retailer increases faster than does her competitive price, resulting in the increase of the ADCPC, which implies an easing of price competition between the two channels. However, the shopping experience difference between the two channels becomes large, causing a potential increase or decrease in the market demand of the new retailer (because
).
On the other hand, similar to the results under the mode RR, the growth of the OSEF leads to a higher profit for the new retailer and may result in a profit increase or decrease for the online platform (
Figure 15 graphically depict this case), although the contract mode is changed under the mode PR. Unlike the result under the mode RR, where the increase in the OSEF may raise or lower the profit of the manufacturer, its rise raises his profit under the mode PR. This is because the coopetition relationship with the new retailer grants the manufacturer greater latitude in designing his green contract (determining the greenness, wholesale, and retail pricing), which enables the manufacturer to gain more profit by coordinating competition and cooperation with the new retailer.
According to the analyses above, a four-win condition of manufacturer, online platform, new retailer, and environment as the OSEF increases is characterized by the following corollary.
Corollary 7. When under the mode PR, the greenness and the profits of manufacturer, online platform, and new retailer increase with the OSEF, while the total market demand decreases with it if .
Corollary 7 implies that under certain conditions (), the growth of the OSEF is advantageous for the manufacturer, online platform, new retailer, and environment, while it is disadvantageous to consumers because the greenness and the profits of the three enterprises increase, while the total purchase intention of consumers decreases.
Figure 16 graphically depicts a four-win condition of the manufacturer, two retailers, and environment for different PFRs. Based on Corollaries 4 and 7, we from in the shaded area of
Figure 16 that raising the GPU is beneficial to the five parties of manufacturer, online platform, new retailer, environment, and consumers, but raising the OSEF is only beneficial to the first four parties, while it is disadvantageous to the consumers. As with the analyses of
Figure 7,
Figure 16 visually demonstrates that point
A is a satisfied one for the five parties. This is because point
A is on the curve
, that is,
t takes the maximum at point
A (
t equals
in
Figure 16a and
in
Figure 16b), which is most beneficial to the five parties. Simultaneously,
k is not too big (
k respectively equals 5 and
in the
Figure 16a,b), which is acceptable for the new retailer due to less investment in the offline experience store or VR shopping and is good to consumers due to the highest market demand. This is the result of the trade-off between the profits of the manufacturer, online platform and new retailer, greenness, consumer scale, service difficulty of the new retailer, and difficulty of increasing green product utility. Comparing the two subgraphs, we find that with the increase in the PFR, the value of
t corresponding to the satisfied point
A decreases slightly, and the value of
k corresponding to point
A decreases greatly. This implies that the online platform raising the PFR has little effect on the satisfying green product utility and expands the service competitive advantage of the new retailer due to the smaller OSEF.
According to the analyses of Corollary 5, the PFR could not be set too high, because this decreases the profit of the manufacturer, greenness, and total market demand and may decrease the profit of the online platform herself. Moreover, the increase in the GPU and OSEF requires the joint efforts of the manufacturer, online platform, new retailer, and consumers (see the analyses of Corollaries 1 and 2). Therefore, under the mode PR, the promotion of green products still requires the cooperation of the manufacturer, retailers, and consumers to achieve the goal of low-carbon environmental protection.