1. Introduction
In the finance literature, there has been a general consensus that volatility is highly persistent. There are numerous pieces of evidence that the price dynamics of financial products are consistent with fractional Brownian motion (fBM) volatility models with Hurst index
, which implies that the volatility has a long memory. See, e.g., [
1] for the existence of the long memory features in stock market volatilities. However, inconsistent with this stylized fact, [
2] recently find that the log-volatility behaves essentially as an fBM with
H close to zero at any reasonable time scale, by estimating the volatility from high frequency data. This puzzle (the word “puzzle” is used in the context of using a fractional volatility model in option pricing, but not used in the context of finance in general) has not been resolved, although one possible explanation may be the smoothing effect by sampling intervals of data. Recall that if
, the fBM is the standard Brownian motion (BM), which is a Markov process with short memory. Hence, the fact
implies that volatility is rough.
On the other hand, in the context of option pricing, there are also seemingly two inconsistent stylized facts. Namely, (i) the decrease in the smile amplitude is much slower than the standard stochastic volatility models; and (ii) the term structure of the at-the-money volatility skew is well approximated by a power-law function with the exponent close to zero. It is well recognized that the two phenomena cannot be captured by standard models. Nevertheless, in the option pricing literature, these problems have been studied separately.
The fact (i) seems a result of long memory feature of volatility and is indeed explained in [
3,
4] by using the fractional volatility model with
under a risk-neutral measure
. They start with a fractional volatility model with
under the physical measure
, and assuming that the market price of volatility risk is zero, they transform the model to that under
. While [
3] showed that, thanks to the long memory feature of volatility with
, the model can explain the slow decay of the smile amplitude, [
4] developed an approximation formula for option prices and confirm the result numerically when
.
The fact (ii) is also well-known from empirical observations and has been paid much attention in the finance literature. While there have been several attempts to explain this stylized fact, (see, e.g., [
5,
6,
7] for possible models that explain this stylized fact), Alòs et al. [
6] and Fukasawa [
8] proved that a fractional volatility model with
H close to zero under
can have this stylized fact for small
T. In other words, they show that the volatility is rough under the risk-neutral measure
for short maturity options.
The aim of this paper is to provide a solution to the time-scale fractional puzzle in the implied volatility. To this end, we adopt the fractional volatility model considered in [
4] and extend it by introducing another fractional volatility factor with Hurst index
. Following the same idea as in [
4], we develop an approximation formula for European option prices and confirm that our model can incorporate both persistence and roughness in the volatility under the risk-neutral measure
, when the correlations between the underlying asset process and the factors of rough volatility and persistence belong to a certain range.
An important finding in this paper is that, depending on the three correlation values, the implied volatility surface is classified into four types: (1) the roughness exists, but the persistence does not; (2) the persistence exists, but the roughness does not; (3) both the roughness and the persistence exist; and (4) neither the roughness nor the persistence exist. Hence, the coexistence of the two stylized facts requires the two-factor fractional volatilities of roughness and persistence in a non-trivial manner.
This paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we set up our two-factor fractional volatility model. By using the technique developed in [
4], we derive an approximation formula for option prices in
Section 3.
Section 4 is devoted to numerical examples to investigate the impact of the two Hurst indexes on option prices. Through our extensive numerical experiments, we confirm that our model can resolve the implied volatility puzzle mentioned above. The definitions of the functions contained in our approximation formula are given in
Appendix A.
2. The Setup
Inspired by the model proposed in [
4], we consider the following two-factor fractional volatility model. Namely, the underlying asset price
and its volatility
are modeled by the stochastic differential equations (SDEs):
under the physical measure
, where
is the instantaneous mean rate of return of the asset,
q is the (constant) dividend rate and
is some smooth function in
x and
y. Here, while
is a standard Brownian motion (BM),
denotes a fractional Brownian motion (fBM) with Hurst index
under
. The volatility
is formulated by using the two fractional mean-reverting processes
. Note that
represents the long-term average of
,
is the speed of mean reversion and
is the volatility of
. Later, we specify
and
, because we want to explain the persistent volatility and rough volatility simultaneously.
2.1. Integral Representation
The fBM
can be represented in terms of the stochastic integral with respect to another standard BM. In this study, we find it useful for the development of our approximation to employ the Mandelbrot–Van Ness representation of fBMs. Namely, we have:
where
denotes the gamma function and where
is a standard BM with constant correlations
and
,
. By defining:
and:
we then have the following representation:
Note that, given , the future behavior of , , is independent of the past, because the BM is a Markov process. Hence, supposing that the past , has been observed, the quantity is considered to be a deterministic function of time with .
The fractional mean-reverting process
given in (
1) can be solved as:
where:
By applying the integration-by-parts formula and changing the order of integration, the volatility can be rewritten as:
where:
See [
4] for the detailed derivation.
Now, we introduce the market prices of risks
and
to define the standard BMs
and
under a martingale measure
. Namely, define:
respectively. It follows from (
1) and the standard argument that the asset price
follows the SDE:
under
, where
r denotes the risk-free spot rate, which we assume to be constant for simplicity.
By applying Ito’s formula, we obtain:
where
is the forward price of the underlying asset with delivery date
t. On the other hand, the fractional mean-reverting process
is given by:
where:
Summarizing, our fractional volatility model is formulated as:
for
, where
and
,
.
2.2. Some Special Cases
Recall that we suppose the past
,
has been observed and the quantity
is a deterministic function of time
with
. However, it seems difficult to observe the whole past of
in the actual market, and so, we assume that
as in [
3] in the rest of this paper. Furthermore, following most of the previous research, we assume that the volatility risks are fully diversified, and so, the market prices of risks
are zero, i.e.,
, for the sake of simplicity. Under these specifications, the fractional mean-reverting process
is given by:
where
is defined in (
4). Given these processes
, the dynamics of the asset price
is determined by the SDE (
5).
We observe from (
8) that the process
is a sum of a deterministic function
and a stochastic convolution
, where:
respectively. For the purpose of Monte Carlo simulation, we consider the discrete-time process
,
, where
is the option maturity for sufficiently small
. The stochastic convolution
can be approximated by a discrete convolution such as
, where
and
.
The discrete convolution can be represented by a matrix product, and so, the mean-reverting process
,
, in discrete time can be expressed compactly in matrix form as:
In the following, thanks to the above specification, we adopt matrix Equation (
9) for Monte Carlo simulation (see, e.g., [
9] for Monte Carlo simulation methods for general fBMs).
3. Approximation Formula
The call option price written on
with strike
K and maturity
T is given by:
where
, and the expectation is taken over
under the martingale measure
. In this case, all we need to know is the distribution of asset price
at the maturity
T.
Let us define
. From (
10), the value of the European call option is given by:
With the density function
of
at hand, it follows that:
In this section, we derive an approximation formula for option prices by applying the technique used in [
4] for the fractional volatility model (
7). To this end, we expand the underlying asset into a sum of iterative stochastic integrals with deterministic integrands. In the following, we denote
and
The proof of the next result is given in
Appendix A.
Lemma 1. For , we approximate it by:where:with:and with being defined by: Following the idea given in [
10], the density function
can be approximated by
given in (A16) in
Appendix B. By computing (
11), the next result then follows. The proof is straightforward, although messy, and omitted.
Proposition 1. The value of a European call option with maturity T and strike K under the fractional volatility model (7) is approximated as:where is the density function of the normal distribution with mean μ and variance and denotes the cumulative probability function of the standard normal distribution. The definitions of
,
and
are provided in
Appendix B.
4. Numerical Examples
This section is devoted to numerical studies of our fractional volatility model by using the approximation formula given in Proposition 1. (The accuracy of our approximation formula is checked by the Monte Carlo simulation explained in
Section 2.2. We note that our approximation gets gradually worse for the high volatility, long maturity and deep in-the and out-of-the money cases. For example, when the percentage volatility defined by
is bigger than
, our approximation seems not enough for practical uses. For such cases, higher order approximation is required.) Throughout the numerical examples, we use the parameter values listed in
Table 1 as the base case. In particular, for the Hurst indexes
and
, Bollerslev and Mikkelsen [
1] observed long memory features in stock market volatilities, and so, we set
as the persistent volatility. On the other hand, Bayer et al. [
11] claimed (they report a good fit of their rough volatility model with
and the percentage volatility
) that
is of order 0.1, and so, we set
as the rough volatility. Finally, we assume that the volatility function is given by:
for the sake of simplicity.
In
Figure 1, we depict the ATM (at the money) implied volatility (
Figure 1a) and the ATM skew (
Figure 1b) with respect to the option maturity
T. It is observed that the term structure of the ATM volatility skew is a power-law function of time to maturity
T. This is a typical feature of rough volatility, which is observed in the S&P index options market reported by Bayer et al. [
11]. The model ATM skew is approximated by the power-law function with the order of
.
Next, based on our approximation formula, we investigate the effects of the model parameters on option prices.
4.1. Effect of
In
Figure 2, we plot the skew of the European options with respect to
. It is explicitly observed that, as
increases, the power-law index increases to be
,
,
and
for
and
, respectively. According to [
5], an empirical study shows that the index is typically given by about
, and so, our model is capable of capturing this stylized fact by setting the rough volatility
close to zero.
4.2. Effect of
We first check whether the Hurst index
of persistent volatility has the ability to capture the power-law of the ATM skew or not.
Figure 3 shows the ATM skew of the European options with respect to
. In contrast to the rough volatility index
given in
Figure 2, the effect of
on the ATM skew is very limited or almost has no effect. On the other hand,
Figure 4 shows the volatility smile with respect to the strike and maturity.
Figure 4a–d show the volatility smile of
,
,
and
, respectively. From
Figure 4, thanks to the long memory feature of the index
, the case of
exhibits a slower decrease of the volatility smile amplitude with respect to time to maturity
T than the short memory case
(the rough volatility case
shows a much faster decrease). This is a preferable feature, because the observed smile amplitude decreases much more slowly with respect to maturity than that explained by standard stochastic volatility models.
Summarizing, an important observation at this point is that, by setting and , we can realize both the long memory feature and the roughness of volatility simultaneously by using our model, which is the major contribution of this paper.
4.3. Effect of and
We examine the impact of on option prices. Recall that is the correlation between the persistent volatility and the rough volatility . Note that the ATM skew amplitude comes from the roughness of .
From
Figure 5, it is observed that, as the correlation decreases, the decrease of the smile amplitude is decelerated in the case of
. This means that the effect of the volatility persistence survives only when the correlation
is negative.
4.4. Effect of Correlations
Finally, we examine the effect of the correlations, (
,
,
), on the implied volatility surface.
Figure 6a–c and
Figure 7a–c, respectively) show the volatility smile (the ATM skew) at
with respect to
,
and
, respectively. The three correlations vary in the range of
,
and
, where the resulting correlation matrix is positive definite. The other parameters are set to be the same as the base case in
Table 1.
As we can see form the figures, depending on the correlation values, the volatility surface is classified into four types: (1) the roughness exists, but the persistence does not; (2) the persistence exists, but the roughness does not; (3) both the roughness and the persistence exist; and (4) neither the roughness nor the persistence exist.
Specifically, as
increases, it is observed from
Figure 6a and
Figure 7a that the volatility smile is preserved and the skew becomes greater, i.e., the power-law index of the ATM skew decreases, respectively. Form
Figure 6b and
Figure 7b, when the absolute value of
is small, say
, it is observed that the volatility smile is preserved, but the ATM skew disappears, respectively. On the other hand, when the absolute value of
is high, say
, we can see that the volatility smile gradually disappears, but the ATM skew becomes greater. Furthermore, from
Figure 6c and
Figure 7c, as
increases, the ATM skew becomes greater, but the volatility smile disappears, respectively.
5. Conclusions
In this study, we extend the fractional volatility model proposed in [
4] by introducing another factor of rough volatility. Through numerical experiments, we demonstrate that, when one of the Hurst indexes in fractional volatility is larger than 1/2 (volatility persistence) and the other is smaller than 1/2 (rough volatility), our model can explain both the slower decay of the smile amplitude decline and the term structure of the at-the-money volatility skew observed in the options market, simultaneously. However, the coexistence of the two stylized facts seems non-trivial. Namely, depending on the three correlation values between the underlying asset and the factors of rough volatility and volatility persistence, the implied volatility surface is classified into four types: (1) the roughness exists, but the persistence does not; (2) the persistence exists, but the roughness does not; (3) both the roughness and the persistence exist; and (4) neither the roughness nor the persistence exist.
As future work, we plan to apply our model to actual markets. Namely, we develop a fast algorithm to calibrate our model to the options market, because our model involves many parameters itself. Furthermore, it is of interest to develop a model under the physical measure to explain the volatility persistence and the volatility roughness simultaneously. An asymmetric model between the persistent volatility and the rough volatility may be of great importance.