Next Article in Journal
Cyber Insurance Ratemaking: A Graph Mining Approach
Previous Article in Journal
The Accuracy of Risk Measurement Models on Bitcoin Market during COVID-19 Pandemic
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Downside Beta and Downside Gamma: In Search for a Better Capital Asset Pricing Model

1
Department of Management Sciences, COMSATS University Islamabad, Islamabad 45550, Pakistan
2
College of Business Administration, Prince Sultan University, Riyadh 11586, Saudi Arabia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Risks 2021, 9(12), 223; https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9120223
Submission received: 11 September 2021 / Revised: 5 November 2021 / Accepted: 10 November 2021 / Published: 6 December 2021

Abstract

:
In the financial world, the importance of “downside risk” and “higher moments” has been emphasized, predominantly in developing countries such as Pakistan, for a substantial period. Consequently, this study tests four models for a suitable capital asset pricing model. These models are CAPM’s beta, beta replaced by skewness (gamma), CAPM’s beta with gamma, downside beta CAPM (DCAPM), downside beta replaced by downside gamma, and CAPM with downside gamma. The problems of the high correlation between the beta and downside beta models from a regressand point of view is resolved by constructing a double-sorted portfolio of each factor loading. The problem of the high correlation between the beta and gamma, and, similarly, between the downside beta and downside gamma, is resolved by orthogonalizing each risk measure in a two-factor setting. Standard two-pass regression is applied, and the results are reported and analyzed in terms of R2, the significance of the factor loadings, and the risk–return relationship in each model. The risk proxies of the downside beta/gamma are based on Hogan and Warren, Harlow and Rao, and Estrada. The results indicate that the single factor models based on the beta/downside beta or even gamma/downside gamma are not a better choice among all the risk proxies. However, the beta and gamma factors are rejected at a 5% and 1% significance level for different risk proxies. The obvious choice based on the results is an asset pricing model with two risk measures.

1. Introduction

Asset pricing models are used to estimate the cost of capital for firms and evaluate the performance of managed portfolios. They are based on the risk–return relationship, which is long established as the backbone of portfolio management. An asset pricing model offers a unique risk–return relationship where an investor tries to optimize an investment decision. One of the earliest and most widely used models comes in the form of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). It marks the birth of asset pricing theory1, and its simplicity makes it the most widely used in applications. As a result, the validity of the CAPM is tested, and the outcome reveals a weak risk–return relationship2.
Four major viewpoints provide an in-depth explanation of this weak risk–return relationship3. The first perspective led by Roll (1977); Ross (1977) completely rejected the CAPM on the basis that the true market portfolio in the CAPM is not observable; this led to the belief that the CAPM cannot be tested at all4. The second perspective does not reject the CAPM altogether but it argues that anomalies are present, and beta is not the only predictor, as outlined by the CAPM. Instead, the size, value, time effects, and momentum are additional factors to be added to the model5. Furthermore, as the CAPM is based on the dividend discount model, Fama and French (2015) add investment and profitability factors to further extend the CAPM as these factors are related to average returns.
The third perspective tries to overcome the theoretical weaknesses of the CAPM, thus leading to modified versions of the CAPM. Among them is the problem of the y-intercept or the CAPM without risk-free borrowing or lending. Fischer Black (1972) developed the zero-beta CAPM by allowing the unlimited short sales of risky assets, making the composition of market portfolios from efficient portfolios themselves, thus making market portfolios efficient6. Another possible solution is to replace the CAPM’s beta with a downside risk, based on Roy’s (1952) safety-first rule. This is because investors dislike downside risk and do not give equal weight to both upside and downside risk, as is assumed in the CAPM7. The last perspective addresses statistical issues, such as the issue of normality. Stock prices exhibit non-normality, which advocates the importance of higher moments in the CAPM world8.
The third perspective of replacing the beta with downside risk as downside beta is a challenging question. The proxy of downside risk in asset pricing models was first developed by the Hogan and Warren model based on semivariance (1974) as the first official version of a downside risk-based CAPM. The second breakthrough was made by Bawa (1975) who developed a proxy for downside risk, lower partial moment (LPM), based on stochastic dominance. Later, Fishburn in 1977 extended Bawa’s (1975) LPM into the unlimited scope of LPM. The Bawa–Fishburn LPM encompasses all classes of investors: risk-averse, risk-seeking, and risk-neutral. Additionally, it is not tied to the condition of normality and is flexible to include skewness and kurtosis.
Moreover, Bawa and Lindenberg (1977) extended symmetric partial moments to asymmetric generalized co-LPM or GCLPM for n-degree LPM structures accommodating asymmetric distributions. These methodologies use a risk-free rate as a benchmark of downside risk. Later, Harlow and Rao (1989) used mean returns as a benchmark for defining downside risk, while Estrada (2002, 2008) added endogenous semivariance matrix constructed on all the elements of the covariance matrix to deal with the heterogeneity problem. This gives us there three major types of downside risk to be used in this study outlined by Hogan and Warren (1974); Harlow and Rao (1989); Estrada (2002), resulting in three risk proxies to be compared: downside beta-Hogan and Warren (1974), downside beta-Harlow and Rao (1989), and downside beta-Estrada (2002).
Likewise, the fourth issue is addressed by incorporating higher moments: skewness, and kurtosis9. However, this solution is not restricted to the CAPM and is extended to the downside risk framework. Thus, the same combination applies for downside skewness/kurtosis as downside skewness/kurtosis-Hogan and Warren (1974), downside skewness/kurtosis-Harlow and Rao (1989), and downside skewness/kurtosis-Estrada (2002). Most studies concentrate on the third moment and place less emphasis on the fourth moment. The third moment is related to asymmetry that the investor is trying to stabilize and minimize. On the other hand, the fourth moment is related to the flatness of returns, which are considerably less important in the asset pricing world10.
The CAPM and DCAPM models and higher moments models have been tested before; however, this study addresses the limitations in the previous studies. In Pakistan, a study was conducted by Javid and Ahmad (2008); Javid (2009) on the Karachi stock market with a sample size of 49 stocks. They applied the CAPM and CAPM with skewness but on stocks instead of portfolios. This leads us to two major problems: selection bias and measurement error. The solution to these problems is proposed in the literature by constructing portfolios and testing the models on them11.
Furthermore, Galagedera and Brooks (2007) investigated the issue of co-skewness as a measure of risk in a downside framework. They argue that the downside beta and downside co-skewness between security returns and market portfolio returns may be alternative measures of downside risk. However, the sample of their study is emerging in market stock indices with the proxies of market return and risk-free rate taken from the US market. This again leads to the same problem mentioned above. Secondly, the study cannot be generalized to domestic individual stocks as they are different from international indices.
This motivates us to put forward our study, which addresses the last two perspectives to a robust asset pricing model based on beta/downside risk and higher moment, i.e., skewness/downside skewness only. The outcomes have three possibilities: replacing beta with downside beta; second, replacing beta/downside beta by skewness/downside skewness; and, lastly, adding skewness/downside skewness to the original risk measures of beta/downside beta, respectively. This yields six models to be tested: beta and downside beta, skewness and downside skewness, beta and skewness, and downside beta and downside skewness based-CAPM and DCAPM models.
However, there is the problem of the high correlation between the CAPM and DCAPM models from the dependent variable perspective as well as the high correlation between the second and third-moment risk measures on the independent variable side. The former is resolved by constructing double-sorted portfolios that are sorted first on the beta and then again on downside beta using the standard procedure following Ang et al. (2006) to disentangle the high correlation effect of the beta and downside beta in the regressands. Furthermore, the portfolios cater to the problems of selection bias and measurement error.
The problem of the correlation between the beta and skewness in the mean-variance framework and downside beta and downside skewness in the mean-downside risk framework is resolved by orthogonalizing one factor on the other factor following Galagedera and Brooks (2007). Next, the competitive models are tested using Fama and MacBeth’s (1973) methodology, and the best model is reported on the basis of the R2, adj R2, risk-factor significance in each model, and the risk–return relationship.
This makes this study the first of its kind for a single and highly volatile market such as the Pakistan Stock Exchange using all the possible models: beta/skewness based CAPM, downside beta skewness-Hogan and Warren (1974); downside beta skewness-Harlow and Rao (1989), and downside beta skewness-Estrada (2002). It uses the higher moment, i.e., skewness and downside skewness asymmetry, in the stock returns. The problem of the high correlation in the regressors and regressands is addressed in one study that was previously ignored. The double-sorted portfolios also add to the study the risk–return relationship.
This paper has four sections: Section 1 is related to the introduction and literature review, Section 2 comprises data and methodology, Section 3 is about the results and discussion, and Section 4 concludes the study.

2. Data and Methodology

Pakistan Stock Exchange (PSX) was formed in January 2016 by merging three stock exchanges: the Karachi Stock Exchange (KSE), the Lahore Stock Exchange (LSE), and the Islamabad Stock Exchange (ISE). FTSE classifies PSX as a secondary emerging market. PSX was reclassified as an MSCI emerging market in May 2017. There are around 559 companies with a market capitalization of $84 billion listed with PSX. Foreign institutional investors and domestic institutional investors stand at 1886 and 1883, respectively.
In 2002, KSE declared PSX the “Best Performing Stock Market of the World”, and, again, PSX was among the world’s best-performing stock markets between 2009 and 2015. With the promulgation of the Stock Exchanges (Corporatization, Demutualization, and Integration) Act 2012, the stock exchanges were successfully corporatized and demutualized on 27 August 2012. In December 2016, PSX sold 40% strategic shares to a Chinese consortium for $85 million. However, in 2017, PSX regressed to become the worst-performing in the region. Furthermore, it faced two crashes in 2005 and 2008 where, in the latter, the trading was halted for four months. This makes PSX a highly volatile market and a suitable market to test the alternative pricing models. This is because the asset pricing models are restrictive to stable markets. The monthly ending stock prices of those listed were taken with an estimation window from January 2000 to June 2018. KSE-100 index was used as a proxy for the market portfolio, while six months treasury bills rate was taken as a proxy for the risk-free rate. The reasons for employing the 6-mo T-bill rate as the risk-free are the availability of data, issuance of 6-mo T-bill rate in Pakistan regularly, and its ease to take into account in the calculations. Moreover, much previous research used 6-mo T-bill rate (Razzaq et al. 2012).
The data were taken from the PSX official website, State Bank of Pakistan website, and DataStream. The prices were converted into returns by using log returns following Ayub et al. (2015).
This study used the basic CAPM and DCAPM equations and extended the models to incorporate skewness and downside skewness following Galagedera and Brooks (2007). In this study, the three major types of downside risk used were outlined by Hogan and Warren (1974); Harlow and Rao (1989); Estrada (2002). This gives our four risk proxies: beta, downside beta-Hogan and Warren (1974); downside beta-Harlow and Rao (1989), adn downside beta-Estrada (2002). Likewise, there emerged four risk proxies for skewness as gamma, downside gamma-Hogan and Warren (1974); downside gamma-Harlow and Rao (1989), and downside gamma-Estrada (2002).
To compare alternative models, CAPM and DCAPM models and their extensions, it is important to disentangle the high correlation of beta and downside beta in the regress and following Ang et al. (2006). Furthermore, the problems of selection bias and measurement error need to be resolved. This was achieved by constructing double-sorted equal-weighted portfolios. The beta for the stock was estimated using 48 months regression over the sample period and split into two sub-samples as high (H) and low (L) beta. The downside beta of each sub-sample was estimated and ranked from high to low. Then, the sub-sample was split again to high (H) and low (L) downside beta. This yielded four sub-samples of stocks. Each sub-sample was used to construct equal-value portfolios to yield four sub-samples: high beta-high downside beta (HH), high beta-low downside beta (HL), low beta-high downside beta (LH), and low beta-low downside beta (LL)12. The rolling windows were constructed by moving one month plus rolling following Ayub et al. (2015).
The problem of correlation between different regressors, beta/gamma and downside beta/downside gamma, was addressed by using the orthogonalizing procedure following Galagedera and Brooks (2007). We isolated gamma from beta by projecting gamma on constant and beta. The residuals from this regression, which are orthogonal to beta, were effectively the orthogonalized component of gamma. Likewise, downside gamma was orthogonalized from downside beta by projecting downside gamma on constant and downside beta. The residuals from this regression were orthogonal to downside beta and were effectively the orthogonalized component of downside gamma.
Fama and MacBeth (1973) two-pass regression standard estimation procedure to test CAPM was followed in this study. Newey–West estimator adjusted for the problem of heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation. The first pass Fama and MacBeth (1973) equation for different combinations is:
R p t R f t = α + β p t ( R P S X t R f t ) + ϵ p t
for CAPM, where Rp is the portfolio returns as HH, HL, LH, and LL, Rf is the risk-free return taken like 3 months T-bills, β is the proxy of systematic risk, and RPSX is the KSE index returns.
R p t R f t = α + D β p t i ( R P S X t R f t ) + ϵ p t
for DCAPM, where i is the proxy of systematic downside risk and I = HW, HR, and E as D β p t H W downside beta-Hogan and Warren (1974); D β p t H R is downside beta-Harlow and Rao (1989), and D β p t E downside beta-Estrada (2002).
R p t R f t = α + γ p t ( R P S X t R f t ) 2 + ϵ p t
for CAPM, where γ is gamma (skewness) replacing β as a proxy of risk
R p t R f t = α + D γ p t i ( R P S X t R f t ) + ϵ p t
for DCAPM, where i is downside skewness (gamma) replacing i as a proxy of risk and i = HW, HR, and E as D γ p t H W downside gamma-Hogan and Warren (1974), D γ p t H R is downside gamma-Harlow and Rao (1989), and D γ p t E downside gamma-Estrada (2002).
R p t R f t = α + β p t ( R P S X t R f t ) + O γ p t ( R P S X t R f t ) 2 + ϵ p t
for CAPM, where is orthogonal skewness to β.
R p t R f t = α + O β p t ( R P S X t R f t ) + γ p t ( R P S X t R f t ) 2 + ϵ p t
for CAPM, where is orthogonal beta to γ.
R p t R f t = α + D β p t i ( R P S X t R f t ) + O D γ p t i ( R P S X t R f t ) 2 + ϵ p t
for DCAPM, where ODγ is orthogonal skewness to and i = HW, HR, and E as O D γ p t H W downside gamma-Hogan and Warren (1974), O D γ p t H R is downside gamma-Harlow and Rao (1989), and O D γ p t E downside gamma-Estrada (2002).
R p t R f t = α + O D β p t i ( R P S X t R f t ) + D γ p t i ( R P S X t R f t ) 2 + ϵ p t
For DCAPM, where Odβ is orthogonal beta skewness and I = HW, HR, and E as O D β p t H W downside beta-Hogan and Warren (1974), O D β p t H R is downside beta-Harlow and Rao (1989), and O D β p t E downside beta-Estrada (2002).
The β and γ are proxies for beta and gamma, while and are specified for different proxies of downside beta and downside gamma for Hogan and Warren (1974); Harlow and Rao (1989); Estrada (2002) defined as follows:
β p = E [ ( R p µ p ) ( R P S X µ P S X ) ] E [ ( R P S X µ P S X ) ] 2
for beta in CAPM framework.
γ p = E [ ( R p µ p ) ( R P S X µ P S X   ) ] 2 E [ ( R P S X µ P S X ) ] 3
for skewness in CAPM framework.
D β p H W = E [ ( R p R f ) m i n ( R P S X R f , 0 ) ] E [ m i n ( R P S X R f , 0 ) ] 2
for Hogan and Warren (1974) downside beta.
D β p H R = E [ ( R p µ p ) m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] E [ m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] 2
for Harlow and Rao (1989) downside beta.
D β p E = E [ m i n ( R p µ p , 0 ) m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] E [ m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] 2
for Estrada (2002) downside beta.
D γ p H W = E [ ( R p R f ) m i n ( R P S X R f , 0 ) ] 2 E [ m i n ( R P S X R f , 0 ) ] 3
for Hogan and Warren (1974) downside gamma.
D γ p H R = E [ ( R p µ p ) m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] 2 E [ m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] 3
for Harlow and Rao (1989) downside gamma.
D γ p E = E [ m i n ( R p µ p , 0 ) m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] 2 E [ m i n ( R P S X µ P S X , 0 ) ] 3
for Estrada (2002) downside gamma.
The second pass Fama and MacBeth (1973) equations were built correspondingly with the equations from (1)–(8). In Fama and MacBeth (1973), second pass for portfolio beta and portfolio return cross-sectional analysis for each month were performed. In the second pass, the parameter was converted to the coefficient. Finally, through two-pass regression, different risk measures and combinations of different risk measures were analyzed using t-stat as outlined in Fama and MacBeth (1973) methodology.

3. Results and Discussion

The results are reported in four tables, and each consists of four panels. The first two tables report the results for the single-factor asset pricing models of CAPM and DCAPM with risk proxies, namely, Sharpe’s beta, Hogan and Warren (1974); Harlow and Rao (1989); Estrada (2002) downside betas and the proxies of risk as the third moment, i.e., skewness (gamma) and downside skewness (downside gamma). The downside gamma risk proxies are based on the Hogan and Warren (1974); Harlow and Rao (1989); Estrada (2002) downside gammas. The last two tables report the two-factor asset pricing models based on the beta/downside beta with gamma/downside gamma. As the beta and skewness and, likewise, downside beta and downside gamma are highly correlated, so the two respective risk measures are orthogonalized each time, yielding two results: a beta with an orthogonalized gamma and then an orthogonalized beta with gamma. The same procedure is adopted in the downside framework.
Each table consists of four panels: A, B, C, and D, and each panel has five columns for Table 1 and Table 2 and six columns for Table 3 and Table 4. The first column is the type of portfolio: HH, H: LH, and LL. Column two is the returns for each portfolio type. Columns three in Table 1 and Table 2 and columns three and four in Table 3 and Table 4 are the risk proxies for beta/downside beta only and with gamma/downside gamma, respectively. The last two columns report the R2 and Adj R2 for each portfolio type. At the bottom, the differences between the HH and LL returns and risk proxies are given to assess the risk–return relationship. With each risk measure, the t-stats based on Fama and MacBeth (1973) are given in brackets. The risk–return relationship is measured by checking the risk measure greater than zero; thus, the t-test is one-tail. The acceptance of the null hypothesis validates the model. The rejection is set at a 5% significant level in this study. The significant levels are represented as *, **, and *** for the 10%, 5%, and 1% significant level, respectively.
There are four panels in Table 1: panel A, panel B, panel C, and panel D. Panel A illustrates the results of the CAPM with β as the risk proxy, R2, and Adj.R2, along with the HH, HL, LH, and LL portfolios. Panel B depicts the results of the DCAPM with downside β for Hogan and Warren (1974), R2 and Adj. R2, along with the HH, HL, LH, and LL portfolios. Panel C shows the results of the CAPM with downside β for Harlow and Rao (1989), and panel D explains the results of the CAPM with downside β for Estrada (2002).
In panel A, the HL and LH are rejected at a 1% significant level. For the LL, the t-stats have a value of −1.860 and are rejected at a 10% significant level. In panel B, where the CAPM with downside β for Hogan and Warren (1974) is applied, all the null hypotheses are accepted except the HH value that rejects the null hypothesis at a 10% significant level. As most of the research was conducted at a 5% significant level, we can ignore this one, but the R2 values are very low for this one as well. In panel B, as the null hypothesis is accepted, this model holds. The risk–return relationship is negative. In panel C, the null hypothesis is accepted for all except HH at a 10% significant level. In panel D, the null hypothesis is accepted for all except LL for a 10% significant level.
The risk–return relationship is represented as the difference of the returns and coefficient of risk measures of the HH and LL portfolios. The HH and LL return difference is 5.715 and has a value of 1.05, −0.474, 1.690, and −0.371 for β, DβHW, DβHR, and Dβ E, respectively. This relationship is positive for β and DβHR and negative for the other two risk measures. However, the value of R2 in all the panels ranges from 48% to 56%, which is very low. This advocates for incorporating a higher moment as a measure of risk.
In Table 2, regarding the results for panel A, in the first column of each panel, there are portfolio returns from 2000 to 2018; in the second column, the skewness is depicted, in the third column, the values for R2 are illustrated, and, in the last column, the Adj. R2 is given. For panel B, the downside skewness (DγHW) for Hogan and Warren (1974) is given. In panel C, the downside skewness (DγHR) for Harlow and Rao (1989) and panel D downside skewness (DγE) for Estrada (2002) are discussed. At the bottom of each panel, the differences between the HH and LL values for the skewness and returns are given, where a positive value shows that the skewness and returns are positively correlated and a negative value shows a negative correlation. Underneath each γ value, a λ value, as per the t-statistics, is given in (); here, * = 10% significant level, ** = 5% significant level, and *** = 1% significant level to accept or reject null hypothesis.
In panel A, when the beta is replaced with the skewness and co-skewness, the overall relationship is positive, but the null hypothesis is rejected at the HL and LH portfolios at a 5% significant level. This shows the model does not hold. Overall, the R2 values increased for this model. In panel B, the HH rejects the null hypothesis at a 10% significant level, and the LH rejects the null hypothesis at a 5% significant level. Overall, the R2 values have increased, but the model does not hold. In panel C, the null hypothesis is rejected for the LH at a 5% significant level, but, overall, the R2 values have increased. In panel D, the null hypothesis is rejected for the HH at a 10% significant level, but the 5% significant level is considered as a benchmark, so the null hypothesis is accepted and the downside skewness for the Estrada (2002) model holds. In Table 2, the R2 values have increased by significant levels ranging from 60% to 84% as compared to Table 1. This means, in comparison to the beta and downside beta, the skewness and co-skewness are better measures of risk. As per t-statistics, the performance of the model is not good, but, if we look at the R2 and Adj. R2 values, they have improved considerably.
In Table 3, we shift from a single-factor model to a double factor model: we are employing both the beta and skewness as measures for risk. As both the beta and skewness are highly correlated, we orthogonalize them, represented by O. Table 3 has 4 panels: panel A, panel B, panel C, and panel D, respectively. Each panel has five columns: the first column represents portfolios, the second column represents returns, the third column shows downside beta, the fourth column shows orthogonalize downside skewness, the fifth column has R2 values, and the last column has Adj.R2 values.
Panel A illustrates the results of the CAPM with β, orthogonalize downside skewness Oγ, R2, and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios. Panel B depicts the results of the CAPM with downside beta DβHW for Hogan and Warren (1974), orthogonalize downside skewness for Hogan and Warren (1974) ODγHW, R2 and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios. Panel C shows the results of the CAPM with downside beta for Harlow and Rao (1989) DβHR, orthogonalize downside skewness for Harlow and Rao (1989) ODγHR, R2 and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios. Panel D explains the results of the CAPM with downside beta for Estrada (2002) Dβ E, orthogonalize downside skewness for Estrada (2002) ODγE, R2 and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios.
If we look at the overall results, the values for R2 and Adj. R2 have increased, showing that combining the beta and downside beta provides a better measure of risk. In panel A, the null hypothesis is accepted for all except HL for orthogonalize downside skewness, where the null hypothesis is rejected at a 5% significant level. In panel B, the null hypothesis is rejected for HL and LL at a 5% significant level for downside beta for Hogan and Warren (1974). In panel C, the null hypothesis is accepted by all, so Harlow and Rao’s (1989) model holds. In panel D, the null hypothesis is rejected for downside beta at the HL and LH for a 10% significant level, but, as 5% is considered as a benchmark, the model holds. For orthogonalize, the downside skewness null hypothesis is rejected for HL at a 5% significant level, so the model does not hold. There is a positive relationship between the risk and return in all the models and increased values of R2 and Adj. R2, depicting the efficiency of combining downside beta and orthogonalize downside skewness.
Table 4 is also a double factor model; we are employing both beta and skewness as a measure for risk. As both beta and skewness are highly correlated, we orthogonalize them, represented by O. In Table 4, we orthogonalize beta instead of skewness; panel A illustrates the results of the CAPM with orthogonalize Oβ, downside skewness γ, R2, and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios. Panel B depicts the results of the CAPM with orthogonalize downside beta ODβHW for Hogan and Warren (1974), downside skewness for Hogan and Warren (1974) DγHW, R2 and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios. Panel C shows the results of the CAPM with orthogonalize downside beta for Harlow and Rao (1989) ODβHR, downside skewness for Harlow and Rao (1989) DγHR, R2 and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios. Panel D explains the results of the CAPM with orthogonalize downside beta for Estrada (2002) ODβE, downside skewness for Estrada (2002) DγE, R2 and Adj. R2, along with HH (high, high), HL (high, low), LH (low, high), and LL (Low, low) portfolios.
The overall values for R2 and Adj. R2 have increased, showing a positive outcome. In panel A, the null hypothesis is rejected for the HH and LL portfolios at a 1% significant level for orthogonalize Oβ, and downside skewness, the null hypothesis is rejected for the HH and LH at a 5% significant level and for LH at a 10% significant level; this model does not hold. In Hogan and Warren’s (1974) model, the null hypothesis is rejected for orthogonalize beta Oβ at a 10% significant level for the HH portfolios and a 5% significant level for the LL portfolios. The HH rejects the null hypothesis at a 5% significant level for downside skewness. Panel C illustrates that the null hypothesis is accepted and the high value results for R2 and Adj. R2 represent that Harlow and Rao’s (1989) model is the most efficient one. In panel D, the null hypothesis is rejected for the HL at a 10% significant level and 5% significant level for orthogonalizedownside beta and downside skewness, respectively.
These results state that the model with two risk proxies is the better choice among the given models, i.e., Harlow and Rao (1989) downside beta should be extended to include downside gamma. This model has better results in terms of the R2, risk–return relationship, and significance of factors. The importance of downside skewness follows with the results of Galagedera and Brooks (2007); Ang et al. (2006); Harvey and Siddique (2000). These studies advocate for the use of the third moment in asset pricing models; however, using it with the second moment is the question that is answered in this study.

4. Conclusions

The study examines the capital asset pricing model developed by Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) as the standard model in the asset pricing theory, which defines the first two moments as the target variable. The results show that the Sharpe–Lintner CAPM is inadequate for the equity market of Pakistan by explaining the economically and statistically significant role of the market risk for the determination of the expected return. In this paper, a detailed analysis identified a single risk factor instead of more risk factors. The returns on an asset in the equity market of Pakistan deviate from normality by indicating that investors are concerned about the higher moments return distribution. Two methods were carried out: first, the standard model was extended by taking the higher moments, and, second, investors put more weight on losses and less weight on gains; the lower moments are incorporated with the upside risk framework.
This research is to demonstrate the benefits of conditional non-linear pricing behavior, and, from the evidence, the results show that higher order pricing factors are associated with co-skewness and co-kurtosis. The results concluded that the investor is rewarded for the co-skewness risk for the higher moment model. However, the results provide marginal support for the reward of co-kurtosis risk. It is concluded that the improved form of the Sharpe–Lintner CAPM used by Kraus and Litzenberger (1976) is successful to some extent with data in the Karachi Stock Exchange. Finally, the empirical study states that the investigated conditional higher moments are used in explaining the cross-section of asset returns. The main aim of this research was to analyze which model performs better as the study estimates a multifactor asset pricing model with a downside risk based and higher moment based asset pricing model. It was thus demonstrated that the downside higher moments beat the downside risk. Under alternative assumptions, it was found out that the portfolio composition differs. The results indicate that the asset pricing relationship varies through time, and the conditional co-skewness is an important determinant for it. In general, the cross-sectional analysis discloses that, when the CAPM beta, downside beta, or downside gamma is included in the pricing model where the risk premium is associated with it, this is always positive, and the explanatory power varies in favor of downside gamma. When the downside gamma and downside beta are included together, the downside gamma appears to dominate the explanatory variable. Overall, from the statistical results, it was concluded that the downside gamma may be a more appropriate explanatory variable of asset price variation than the downside beta in emerging market data.
The study helps an investor in investment decisions about pricing an asset as well as forecasting returns. Subsequently, the investor can mitigate the risk to considerable limits using the Harlow and Rao (1989) extended two-factor model. Furthermore, a suitable asset pricing model helps in stabilizing the market by decreasing its volatility. Lastly, the proposed model in the study is conservative as it incorporates two risk measures at the same time. If the investor still wants to penalize the outcome, then the fourth moment, i.e., downside kurtosis, can be used. The decision, in this case, will be the most conservative for the investor. The emerging markets that are comparable to the market of Pakistan reveal different risk–return relationships, and the studies have found the existence of highly autocorrelated returns, volatile prices, and supernormal returns. This study will help portfolio managers investing in emerging markets and stocks to quantify the expected return and risk. This study also includes a downside risk perspective for risk averse investors who always avoid risk. There are some recommendations for a future study, such as the sample being divided into sub-samples from 2000–2002, 2003–2005, 2006–2008, 2009–2012, and 2013–2018. Furthermore, a comparative analysis is suggested with other developed countries to obtain better and more comprehensive results.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.K. and A.S.; methodology, M.K.; software, M.K.; validation, U.N., I.A.J. and A.S.; formal analysis, I.A.J.; investigation, A.S.; resources, U.N.; data curation, U.N.; writing—original draft preparation, M.K.; writing—review and editing, A.S.; visualization, I.A.J.; supervision, I.A.J.; project administration, A.S.; funding acquisition, U.N. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The authors would like to acknowledge the support of Prince Sultan University for paying the article processing charges (APC) of this publication.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
CAPM is independently developed by (Sharpe 1964; Lintner 1965; Mossin 1966; Treynor 1962). Treynor is considered by some as the pioneer for CAPM, but his first paper of 1962 “Toward a Theory of Market Value of Risky Assets” was not published until 1999. William Sharpe was eventually a winner of the 1990 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.
2
Initial tests favour the risk–return relationship as outlined by CAPM (Beaver et al. 1970; Hamada 1972). However, (Black et al. 1972; Blume and Friend 1973; Fama and MacBeth 1973) provide weak empirical evidence on this relationship. Later, Post and van Vliet (2004) and (Ang et al. 2006; Tahir et al. 2013) also report similar results.
3
The first three are presented by (Abbas et al. 2011).
4
However, (Shanken 1982, 1987; Kandel and Stambaugh 1987) argue that, even though the stock market is not true market portfolio, it must nevertheless be a highly correlated proxy for the true market.
5
6
However, (Gibbons 1982) rejects zero-beta CAPM.
7
8
For details on skewness, see (Adcock and Shutes 1998; Leland 1999; Harvey and Siddique 2000; Chen et al. 2001). For kurtosis, see (Fang and Lai 1997; Dittmar 2002; Chang et al. 2006).
9
(Rubinstein 1973) is the first to propose an assessment of financial asset price with more than two moments. His proposition is estimated by (Kraus and Litzenberger 1976; Ang and Chua 1979).
10
11
See for details (Elton et al. 2013).
12

References

  1. Abbas, Qaiser, Usman Ayub, Shahid Mehmmod Sargana, and Syed Kashif Saeed. 2011. From regular-beta CAPM to downside-beta CAPM. European Journal of Social Sciences 21: 189–203. [Google Scholar]
  2. Adcock, Chris, and Karl Shutes. 1998. Bayesian portfolio selection. In Northern Toronto: Finance Association Conference. [Google Scholar]
  3. Ang, Andren, Robert J. Hodrick, Yuhang Xing, and XIiaoyan Zhang. 2006. The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. The Journal of Finance 61: 259–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Ang, James S., and Jess H. Chua. 1979. Composite measures for the evaluation of investment performance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 14: 361–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ayub, Usman, Syed Zulfiqar Ali Shah, and Qaisar Abbas. 2015. Robust analysis for downside risk in portfolio management for a volatile stock market. Economic Modelling 44: 86–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Banz, Rolf W. 1981. The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. Journal of Financial Economics 9: 3–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Basu, Sanjoy. 1977. The investment performance of common stocks about their price-earnings ratios: A test of the efficient market hypothesis. The Journal of Finance 32: 663–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Basu, Sanjoy. 1983. The relationship between earnings’ yield, market value and return for NYSE common stocks: Further evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 129–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Bawa, Vijay S., and Eric B. Lindenberg. 1977. Capital market equilibrium in a mean-lower partial moment framework. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 189–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bawa, Vijay S. 1975. Optimal rules for ordering uncertain prospects. Journal of Financial Economics 2: 95–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Beaver, William, Paul Kettler, and Myron Scholes. 1970. The association between market determined and accounting determined risk measures. The Accounting Review 45: 654–82. [Google Scholar]
  12. Black, Fischer. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. The Journal of Business 45: 444–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Black, Fischer, Michael C. Jensen, and Myron Scholes. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests. Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets 81: 79–121. [Google Scholar]
  14. Blume, Marshall E., and Irwin Friend. 1973. A new look at the capital asset pricing model. The Journal of Finance 28: 19–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Chen, Gongmeng, Chuck C. Y. Kwok, and Oliver M. Rui. 2001. The day-of-the-week regularity in the stock markets of China. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 11: 139–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. De Bondt, Werner F. M., and Richard H. Thaler. 1987. Further evidence on investor overreaction and stock market seasonality. The Journal of Finance 42: 557–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Dittmar, Robert F. 2002. Nonlinear pricing kernels, kurtosis preference, and evidence from the cross section of equity returns. The Journal of Finance 57: 369–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Estrada, Javier. 2002. Systematic risk in emerging markets: The D-CAPM. Emerging Markets Review 3: 365–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Estrada, Javier. 2007. Mean-semivariance behavior: Downside risk and capital asset pricing. International Review of Economics & Finance 16: 169–85. [Google Scholar]
  20. Estrada, Javier. 2008. Mean-semivariance optimization: A heuristic approach. Journal of Applied Finance (Formerly Financial Practice and Education 18: 1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. The Journal of Finance 47: 427–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2015. A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy 81: 607–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Fang, Hsing, and Tsong-Yue Lai. 1997. Co-kurtosis and capital asset pricing. Financial Review 32: 293–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Galagedera, Don, and Robert Brooks. 2007. Is co-skewness a better measure of risk in the downside than downside beta?: Evidence in emerging market data. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 17: 214–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Gibbons, Michael R. 1982. Multivariate tests of financial models: A new approach. Journal of Financial Economics 10: 3–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Gul, Faruk. 1991. A theory of disappointment aversion. Econometrica 59: 667–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Hamada, Robert S. 1972. The effect of the firm’s capital structure on the systematic risk of common stocks. The Journal of Finance 27: 435–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Harlow, W. Van, and Ramesh K. S. Rao. 1989. Asset pricing in a generalized mean-lower partial moment framework: Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 24: 285–311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Harvey, Campbell R., and Akhtar Siddique. 2000. Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests. The Journal of Finance 55: 1263–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Hogan, William W., and James M. Warren. 1974. Toward the development of an equilibrium capital-market model based on semivariance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 9: 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Javid, Attiya Y., and Eatzaz Ahmad. 2008. Test of Multi-Moment Capital Asset Pricing Model: Evidence from Karachi Stock Exchange (No. 2008: 49). Institute of Development Economics: Available online: https://ideas.repec.org/p/pid/wpaper/200849.html (accessed on 5 January 2020).
  33. Javid, Attiya Yasmin. 2009. Test of Higher Moment Capital Asset Pricing Model in Case of Pakistani Equity Market. Available online: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/38059 (accessed on 6 January 2020).
  34. Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 43: 263–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Kandel, Shmuel, and Robert F. Stambaugh. 1987. On correlations and inferences about mean-variance efficiency. Journal of Financial Economics 18: 61–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Kraus, Alan, and Robert H. Litzenberger. 1976. Skewness preference and the valuation of risk assets. The Journal of Finance 31: 1085–100. [Google Scholar]
  37. Leland, Hayne E. 1999. Beyond Mean–Variance: Performance Measurement in a Nonsymmetrical World (corrected). Financial Analysts Journal 55: 27–36. [Google Scholar]
  38. Lintner, John. 1965. Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. The Journal of Finance 20: 587–615. [Google Scholar]
  39. Mossin, Jan. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 34: 768–83. [Google Scholar]
  40. Post, Thierry, and Haim Levy. 2005. Does risk seeking drive stock prices? A stochastic dominance analysis of aggregate investor preferences and beliefs. The Review of Financial Studies 18: 925–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Post, Thierry, and Pim van Vliet. 2004. Do Multiple Factors Help or Hurt? Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=582101 (accessed on 7 April 2019).
  42. Razzaq, Nasir, Sajid Gul, Muhammad Umair Sajid, Sumra Mughal, and Syeda Asma Bukhari. 2012. Performance of Islamic mutual funds in Pakistan. Economics and Finance Review 2: 16–25. [Google Scholar]
  43. Reinganum, Marc R. 1981. Misspecification of capital asset pricing: Empirical anomalies based on earnings’ yields and market values. Journal of Financial Economics 9: 19–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Roll, Richard. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests Part I: On past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4: 129–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Rosenberg, Barr, Kenneth Reid, and Ronald Lanstein. 1985. Persuasive evidence of market inefficiency. The Journal of Portfolio Management 11: 9–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ross, Stephen A. 1977. The capital asset pricing model (CAPM), short-sale restrictions and related issues. The Journal of Finance 32: 177–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Roy, Andrew Donald. 1952. Safety first and the holding of assets. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 10: 431–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Rubinstein, Mark E. 1973. A mean-variance synthesis of corporate financial theory. The Journal of Finance 28: 167–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Shanken, Jay. 1982. The arbitrage pricing theory: Is it testable? The Journal of Finance 37: 1129–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Shanken, Jay. 1987. A Bayesian approach to testing portfolio efficiency. Journal of Financial Economics 19: 195–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Sharpe, William F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance 19: 425–42. [Google Scholar]
  52. Sihem, Mansour, and Hellara Slaheddine. 2014. The impact of higher order moments on market risk assessment. Procedia Economics and Finance 13: 143–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  53. Stattman, D. 1980. Book values and stock returns. The Chicago MBA: A Journal of Selected Papers 4: 25–45. [Google Scholar]
  54. Tahir, Mohammad, Qaiser Abbas, Shahid Mehmood Sargana, Usman Ayub, and Syed Kashif Saeed. 2013. An investigation of beta and downside beta based CAPM-case study of Karachi Stock Exchange. American Journal of Scientific Research, 85–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  55. Treynor, Jack L. 1962. Jack Treynor’s’ Toward a Theory of Market Value of Risky Assets’. Available online: http://ssrn.com/abstract=447580 (accessed on 6 December 2019).
Table 1. Results for β, DβHW, DβHR, and DβE with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in ( ). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL for β, DβHW, DβHR, and DβE showing the risk–return relationship.
Table 1. Results for β, DβHW, DβHR, and DβE with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in ( ). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL for β, DβHW, DβHR, and DβE showing the risk–return relationship.
Panel APanel B
RpΒR2Adj R2 RpHWR2Adj R2
HH12.7071.9800.5230.506HH12.707−1.458 *0.5150.498
(−1.581)(−1.745)
HL8.3070.194 ***0.5110.550HL8.307−0.3690.5520.537
(−2.694)(0.024)
LH7.8590.214 ***0.5590.544LH7.859−0.4000.5560.541
(−2.836)(−0.220)
LL6.9920.930 *0.5060.489LL6.992−1.0870.5090.492
(−1.860)(0.803)
Diff5.7151.05 Diff5.715−0.371
Panel CPanel D
RpHRR2Adj R2 RpER2Adj R2
HH12.707−1.533 *0.5500.500HH12.7071.0280.4920.474
(−1.719)(−1.549)
HL8.307−0.3950.5510.535HL8.3070.2160.5300.514
(0.027)(−0.113)
LH7.859−0.4290.5550.539LH7.8590.2290.5500.534
(−0.213)(0.183)
LL6.992−1.0590.5080.492LL6.9920.978 *0.5300.514
(0.787)(−1.662)
Diff5.715−0.474 Diff5.7151.690
Note: *** = 1%, and * = 10% significant level.
Table 2. Results for γ, DγHW, DγHR, and DγE with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in ( ). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL for γ, DγHW, DγHR, and DγE showing the risk–return relationship.
Table 2. Results for γ, DγHW, DγHR, and DγE with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in ( ). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL for γ, DγHW, DγHR, and DγE showing the risk–return relationship.
Panel APanel B
RpγR2Adj R2 RpHWR2Adj R2
HH12.712.6580.6950.631HH12.71−1.895 *0.7940.751
(0.887)(−1.640)
HL8.311.615 **0.6880.623HL8.31−0.2980.7740.727
(1.963)(0.152)
LH7.861.794 **0.720.662LH7.86−0.702 **0.8140.775
(−2.041)(−2.199)
LL6.991.3290.76770.719LL6.99−1.3830.7840.739
(0.953)(0.054)
Diff5.721.329 Diff5.72−0.512
Panel CPanel D
RpHRR2Adj R2 RpER2Adj R2
HH12.71−1.7020.80840.768HH12.71−0.168 *0.7450.692
(0.109)(−1.743)
HL8.31−0.8480.810.770HL8.31−0.9370.7350.680
(0.148)(0.167)
LH7.86−0.174 **0.8140.775LH7.86−1.1960.7540.703
(−2.197)(−0.110)
LL6.99−1.2440.8390.805LL6.99−0.2170.7670.718
(0.103)(−0.292)
Diff5.72−0.457 Diff5.720.048
Note: ** = 5%, and * = 10% significant level.
Table 3. Results for β, DβHW, DβHR, and DβE with Oγ, ODγHW, ODγHR, and ODγE, respectively, with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in ( ). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL showing the risk–return relationship.
Table 3. Results for β, DβHW, DβHR, and DβE with Oγ, ODγHW, ODγHR, and ODγE, respectively, with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in ( ). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL showing the risk–return relationship.
Panel APanel B
RpβR2Adj R2 RpHWODγHWR2Adj R2
HH12.711.3211.1690.7850.740HH12.711.0231.0640.8350.801
(−1.232)(−1.435)(−1.624)(−0.310)
HL8.310.57230.921 **0.7640.715HL8.311.0133 **0.0680.8240.787
(−1.446)(−2.125)(−2.213)(−0.794)
LH7.860.77030.5420.7540.702LH7.861.53430.610.8140.775
(−1.200)−0.019(−1.290)(0.052)
LL6.990.4610.680.7680.719LL6.990.515 **0.6920.7840.739
(−1.388)(−1.122)(−2.312)(−1.230)
Diff5.720.8600.489 Diff5.720.5080.372
Panel CPanel D
RpHRODγHRR2Adj R2 RpEODγER2Adj R2
HH12.711.1081.0810.8480.817HH12.712.3511.1030.8100.770
(−1.166)(0.775)(−1.467)(−1.591)
HL8.310.91530.1440.8400.807HL8.311.5499 *0.234 **0.7920.749
(0.503)(−1.129)(−1.908)(−1.964)
LH7.861.06331.1450.8540.824LH7.860.6886 *0.55620.8130.774
(−1.263)(−1.221)(−1.650)(−0.823)
LL6.990.6470.7650.8560.826LL6.990.2361.65360.8260.790
(0.912)(−1.123)(−1.402)(−1.044)
Diff5.720.4610.316 Diff5.722.115−0.5506
Note: ** = 5%, and * = 10% significant level.
Table 4. Results for Oβ, ODβHW, ODβHR, and ODβE with γ, DγHW, Dγ HR, and DγE, respectively, with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in (). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL showing the risk–return relationship.
Table 4. Results for Oβ, ODβHW, ODβHR, and ODβE with γ, DγHW, Dγ HR, and DγE, respectively, with R2 and Adj R2 and their t-stat in (). Diff is the difference of returns between HH and LL showing the risk–return relationship.
Panel APanel B
RpγR2Adj R2 RpODβHWHWR2Adj R2
HH12.711.0010.612 **0.80.758HH12.711.121 *1.967 **0.8120.773
(−2.712) ***(−2.035)(−1.762)(−1.870)
HL8.310.9670.2110.7810.735HL8.311.3231.8000.80.758
(−0.234)(−1.425)(−1.123)(0.989)
LH7.860..4530.301 *0.7670.718LH7.861.4331.6120.8220.785
(−0.200)(−1. 90)(−0.564)(−1.121)
LL6.990.2010.322 **0.7990.757LL6.991.012 **1.7010.8230.786
(−2.765) ***(−2.101)(−2.221)(−1.675)
Diff5.720.8000.290 Diff5.720.5080.2662
Panel CPanel D
RpODβHRHRR2Adj R2 RpODβEER2Adj R2
HH12.711.5681.2320.8480.817HH12.711.2221.2310.8100.770
(−1.166)(0.775)(−1.467)(−1.591)
HL8.311.1001.3220.8400.807HL8.311.340 *1.001 **0.7920.749
(0.503)(−1.129)(−1.908)(−1.964)
LH7.861.2101.1110.8540.824LH7.861.1210.9870.8130.774
(−1.263)(−1.221)(−1.650)(−0.823)
LL6.991.2311.0120.8560.826LL6.991.1140.7680.8260.790
(0.912)(−1.123)(−1.402)(−1.044)
Diff5.720.3370.220 Diff5.720.1080.463
Note: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, and * = 10% significant level.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kazmi, M.; Noreen, U.; Jadoon, I.A.; Shafique, A. Downside Beta and Downside Gamma: In Search for a Better Capital Asset Pricing Model. Risks 2021, 9, 223. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9120223

AMA Style

Kazmi M, Noreen U, Jadoon IA, Shafique A. Downside Beta and Downside Gamma: In Search for a Better Capital Asset Pricing Model. Risks. 2021; 9(12):223. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9120223

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kazmi, Madiha, Umara Noreen, Imran Abbas Jadoon, and Attayah Shafique. 2021. "Downside Beta and Downside Gamma: In Search for a Better Capital Asset Pricing Model" Risks 9, no. 12: 223. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9120223

APA Style

Kazmi, M., Noreen, U., Jadoon, I. A., & Shafique, A. (2021). Downside Beta and Downside Gamma: In Search for a Better Capital Asset Pricing Model. Risks, 9(12), 223. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9120223

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop