Abstract
We present general conditions for the weak convergence of a discrete-time additive scheme to a stochastic process with memory in the space . Then we investigate the convergence of the related multiplicative scheme to a process that can be interpreted as an asset price with memory. As an example, we study an additive scheme that converges to fractional Brownian motion, which is based on the Cholesky decomposition of its covariance matrix. The second example is a scheme converging to the Riemann–Liouville fractional Brownian motion. The multiplicative counterparts for these two schemes are also considered. As an auxiliary result of independent interest, we obtain sufficient conditions for monotonicity along diagonals in the Cholesky decomposition of the covariance matrix of a stationary Gaussian process.
1. Introduction
The question of approximating prices in financial markets with continuous time using prices in markets with discrete time goes back to the approximation of Black–Scholes prices with prices changing in discrete time. For an initial acquaintance with the subject, we recommend a book, (), that starts with the central limit theorem for approximation of the Black–Scholes model by the Cox–Ross–Rubinstein model. However, this area of research is immeasurably wider, since there are many more market models. Of course, they are functioning in discrete time, but their analytical research is easier to carry out in continuous time. Therefore, we need various theorems on the convergence of random sequences to random processes with continuous time, and it is also desirable to produce the convergence of some connected functionals. For example, functional limit theorems make it possible to go to a limit in stochastic integrals and stochastic differential equations. Such equations are widely used for modeling in physics, biology, finance and other fields. Concerning finance, functional limit theorems allow us to investigate how the convergence of stock prices affects the convergence of option prices. The last of these questions is widely considered in many papers; we mention now only (). Concerning the weak limit theorems for financial market we mention the book (). Diffusion approximation of financial markets was described, in particular, in the papers (, , ), see references therein. All the above-mentioned works relate to the case when the ultimate stochastic process and the corresponding market model are Markov, that is, they have no memory. However, the presence of memory in financial markets has already been so convincingly recorded that for many years models have been studied that could well model this memory, and the question of approximation of non-Markov asset prices and other components of financial market processes by the discrete-time random sequences is also studied. As regards purely theoretical results on functional limit theorems in which the limit process is not Markov, we cite the papers (), where the limit process is stationary, and (), where the limit process is semi-stable and Gaussian. In turn, with regard to memory modeling, considering the processes with short- or long-range dependence, it is easiest to use fractional Brownian motion that is a Gaussian self-similar process with stationary correlated increments. There are two approaches to the problem: To model prices themselves using processes with memory, in particular, to consider the models involving fBm, or to concentrate the model’s memory in stochastic volatility. The first approach has the peculiarity that an ultimate market with memory allows arbitrage, while prelimit markets can be arbitrage-free. The existence of arbitrage was first established in the paper () and discussed in detail in the book (). However, such an approach has the right to exist, if only because regardless of possible financial applications, it is reasonable to prove functional limit theorems in which the limit process is a fractional Brownian motion or some related process. For the first time, a discrete approximation of fractional Brownian motion by a binomial market model was considered in the paper (), and a fairly thorough analysis of the number of arbitrage points in such a market was made in the paper (). However, even fractional Black–Scholes model can be approximated by various discrete-time sequences, and the purpose of this article is to formulate and illustrate by examples the functional limit theorem and its multiplicative version, in which both the prelimit sequence of processes and the limiting process are quite general, but simple to consider. Moreover, the fractional binomial market considered by () is a special case of our model.
Thus, the main objectives of this article and its novelty are as follows. To start with, we consider an additive stochastic sequence that is based on the sequence of iid random variables and has the coefficients that allow for this stochastic sequence to be dependent on the past. For such a sequence, we formulate the conditions of the weak convergence to some limit process in terms of coefficients and the characteristic function of any basic random variable. These conditions are stated in Theorem 1. This theorem is of course a special case of general functional limit theorems, but it has the advantages that it is formulated in terms of coefficients, that the coefficients are such that they immediately show the dependence on the past, and that the limit process in it is not required to have any special properties with respect to distribution, self-similarity etc. However, then, in order to apply our general theorem to more practical situations, in Theorem 2 we adapt the general conditions to the case where the limit process is Gaussian. Then we go to the multiplicative scheme in order to get the almost surely positive limit process that can model the asset price on the financial market. So, we assume that all multipliers in the prelimit multiplicative scheme are positive, and this imposes additional restrictions on the coefficients, and in addition, we consider only Bernoulli basic random variables. The next goal is to apply these general results to the case, where the limit processes in the additive scheme are fractional Brownian motion (fBm) and Riemann–Liouville fBm. In the case of the limit fBm we consider the prelimit processes that are constructed regarding to Cholesky decomposition of the covariance function of fBm. The result concerning fBm is new in the sense that nobody before considered the multiplicative scheme with exponent of fBm in the limit, and the result concerning Riemann–Liouville fBm is new in the sense that nobody before considered Riemann–Liouville fBm itself and in exponent as the limiting process. In both cases we were lucky in the sense that such coefficients are suitable also for the multiplicative scheme. Our proofs require deep study of the properties of the Cholesky decomposition for the covariance matrix of fBm. It turns out that all elements of the upper-triangular matrix in this decomposition are positive and moreover, the rows of this matrix are increasing. We also suppose that the columns of this matrix are decreasing. This conjecture is confirmed by numeric results, however its proof remains an interesting open problem. For the moment, we can only prove the uniform upper bound for the elements in each column, which is sufficient for our purposes.
As for stochastic volatility with memory, it is not considered in the present paper, but we can refer the reader to () and (), among many others.
The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we establish sufficient conditions for the weak convergence of continuous-time random walks of rather general form to some limit in the space . The case of Gaussian limit is studied in more detail. Multiplicative version of this result is also obtained. Section 3 and Section 5 are devoted to two particular examples of the general scheme investigated in Section 2. In Section 3 we consider a discrete process that converges to fractional Brownian motion. This example is based on Cholesky decomposition of the covariance matrix of fractional Brownian motion. In Section 4 we investigate possible perturbations of the coefficients in the scheme, studied in Section 3. Moreover, Section 4 contains a numerical example, which illustrates the results of Section 3; moreover, we discuss there some our conjectures and open problems. Section 5 is devoted to another example, where the limit process is a so-called Riemann–Liouville fractional Brownian motion. In Appendix A we establish auxiliary results concerning the Cholesky decomposition of the covariance matrix of a stationary Gaussian process. In particular, we explore the connection between this decomposition and time series prediction problems.
2. General Conditions of Weak Convergence
Let , be a stochastic basis, i.e., a complete probability space with a filtration satisfying standard assumptions.
2.1. Convergence of Sums
For any consider the uniform partition of . Let be a sequence of iid random variables with and .
Assume we are given for each a triangular array of real numbers . Define a stochastic process
let for , . Because of the dependence of the coefficients on k, the increments of may depend on the past, and the dependence may be strong.
Let us first establish general conditions of weak convergence of the sequence in terms of coefficients and characteristic function of the underlying noise. We use the Skorokhod topology in the space of càdlàg functions . A detailed discussion of the selection of topology can be found in (, Chapter 13).
Theorem 1.
Assume that the following assumptions hold:
- (A1)
- There exists a stochastic process such that , , in the sense of finite-dimensional distributions, that is for any ,
- (A2)
- There exist positive constants K and α such that for all integer and
Then the weak convergence of measures holds: , in .
Proof.
First, note that
Therefore, the convergence of finite-dimensional distributions is equivalent to Condition (1).
In order to prove the weak convergence, it suffices to establish the tightness of the sequence . To start with, let us mention that for ,
Further, let us prove that there exists such that
for all and for all . We consider two cases.
Case 1: . In this case we have that , which means that . This implies that at least one of the following equalities is true: or . If , then and Inequality (5) holds for any . Similarly, it holds in the case , because .
Case 2: . In this case
Then Condition (2) implies that
The same bound holds for . Therefore, we have
that is (5) holds with .
Consequently, the sequence of processes is tight (, Theorem 13.5). Hence, the statement follows. □
If X is a Gaussian process, we can formulate the sufficient conditions for the convergence of finite-dimensional distributions in terms of the covariance function.
Theorem 2.
Assume that there exists a stochastic process such that the following conditions hold:
- (C1)
- X is Gaussian and centered.
- (C2)
- For all ,
- (C3)
- , as .
Then the finite-dimensional distributions of converge to those of X as .
Proof.
Let us consider the characteristic function of l-dimensional distribution:
For every , the random variables , , are independent. We will apply Lindeberg’s CLT (see , Theorem 27.2) for the scheme of series . Let us calculate the variance:
Hence, by the assumption (C2), we have
Now we are ready to verify Lindeberg’s condition. We have for any
We can estimate for as follows
Therefore,
Note that due to (C3) and (6), , . Hence,
because , , are iid. Since , we see that
by the dominated convergence theorem.
2.2. Multiplicative Scheme
Consider now a multiplicative counterpart of the process considered above. Namely, let be a triangular array of real numbers. Define
where
To assure that the values of are positive, we assume that are iid Rademacher variables, i.e., , and that satisfy the following assumption:
Our aim is to investigate the weak convergence of to some positive process S. It is more convenient to work with logarithms, i.e. to consider
We will need a uniform version of the above boundedness assumption:
- (B1)
- .
We will also need the following assumption
- (B2)
- .
Theorem 3.
Assume (B1) and (B2). Let also the assumptions (A1) and (A2) hold for
with some process X. Then converges in to .
Proof.
Let .
By the Taylor formula, for ,
where . Therefore,
Write
By Theorem 1, in . Further,
Therefore, , , so , , in . By Slutsky’s theorem (see, e.g., , p. 318), we get , , in , whence the claim follows. □
Remark 1.
The statement of Theorem 3 remains valid, if we replace Rademacher random variables by any other sequence of iid random variables such that , , and for all . The latter condition along with the assumption (B1) ensures that for all , and consequently, the values of are positive.
3. Fractional Brownian Motion as a Limit Process and Prelimit Coefficients Taken from Cholesky Decomposition of its Covariance Function
Let , . Let be a fractional Brownian motion, i.e., a centered Gaussian process with covariance function
For we define the triangular array by the following relation:
It is known that such sequence exists and it is unique, since (8) is the Cholesky decomposition of positively definite matrix (the covariance matrix of fBm).
Define
Theorem 4.
Let be a sequence of iid random variables with and . Assume that are defined by (9) and
Then , , weakly in .
In order to prove Theorem 4, we need to verify the conditions of Theorem 1 in the particular case . Since fractional Brownian motion is a Gaussian process, we will use Theorem 2 in order to prove the convergence of finite-dimensional distributions. Let us start with assumption (A2).
Lemma 1.
Let be defined by (9). Then for all ,
Thus the assumption (A2) holds. In order to check the condition (A1), we will use Theorem 2. First, we will establish some further properties of the coefficients . Let us consider the discrete-time stochastic process , . It is a stationary process with covariance
In other words, is a centered Gaussian vector with covariance matrix
Lemma 2.
The Cholesky decomposition of , given by
has the following properties
Remark 2.
Similarly to (8), we can write the Cholesky decomposition of coordinatewise as follows
Proof.
In order to prove (12), we will apply (, Theorem 1). To this end we need to verify the following conditions on the sequence :
- (a)
- Monotonicity and positivity:
- (b)
- Convexity:
Now let us prove (16). By (17), . Applying (18), we may write
here we have used that the function is increasing for any . Similarly, for , we have
Hence, (16) is proved.
Then by applying (, Theorem 1) we get (12). Further, by (, Corollary 1), we have the following lower bound
whence
Finally, Equality (14) implies that
Therefore, and for all . □
It is not hard to see that the sequences and are related as follows
Indeed, by (8) we have
(here ), and comparing this expression with (14), we see that (20) holds. From (20) and Lemma 2, we immediately obtain the following result.
Lemma 3.
The coefficients , are increasing with respect to j and are positive:
moreover,
Lemma 4.
For all ,
where .
Proof.
By (8), for we have
Therefore, taking into account Inequality (21), we get
Note that the maximal value of the function , , is attained at the point and equals . Therefore
Using (21), we get
Similarly, in the case we have
Remark 3.
Lemma 4 claims that , as . Note that the asymptotic rate of convergence is exact, since
Moreover, we suppose that , however, the proof of this equality remains an open problem, Section 4 for further details.
Lemma 5.
Let be the process defined in Theorem 4. Then the finite-dimensional distributions of converge to those of .
Proof.
Let us check the conditions of Theorem 2. Evidently, the assumption (C1) holds, because fractional Brownian motion is a centered Gaussian process.
The verification of (C2) is straightforward. Applying (8), we get
Finally, using Lemma 4, we can estimate
Hence, the assumption (C3) also holds.
Thus, the result follows from Theorem 2. □
Multiplicative Scheme
Now let us verify the conditions of Theorem 3 for the sequence
Evidently
where the coefficients are defined by (9). Hence, the conditions of Theorem 1 for are satisfied. In the following Lemmas 6 and 7 we check the assumptions (B2) and (B1), respectively.
Lemma 6.
Let be defined by (27). Then
Lemma 7.
Let be defined by (27). Then
Proof.
Using the Cauchy–Schwarz inequality and equality (29), we obtain that for and ,
□
Thus, we have proved that all assumptions of Theorem 3 are satisfied. As a consequence, we obtain the following result.
Theorem 5.
Assume that is a triangular array of real numbers defined by (27) and are iid Rademacher random variables. Then the sequence of stochastic processes
converge in to .
Remark 4.
Theorems 4 and 5 suggest one of possible ways to approximate fractional Brownian motion by a discrete model. Another scheme was proposed by (). It worth noting that his approximation is also a particular case of the general scheme described in Section 2, but with the following coefficients:
where
Note that assumptions (A1) and (A2) for such are verified in the proof of (, Theorem 1); in particular, the tightness condition (A2) is established in (, Equation (8)).
The coefficients of the corresponding multiplicative scheme are equal to
Then, by the Cauchy–Schwarz inequality, we have
The function is the kernel of the following Molchan–Golosov representation of the fractional Brownian motion as an integral with respect to Wiener process :
4. Possible Perturbations of the Coefficients in Cholesky Decomposition. Numerical Example and Discussion of Open Problems
4.1. Possible Perturbations of the Coefficients in Cholesky Decomposition
We now discuss the question how it is possible to perturb the coefficients (8) and (9) in the pre-limit sequence so that the convergence to fractional Brownian motion is preserved. In this sense, we estimate the rate of convergence of the perturbations to zero, sufficient to preserve the convergence.
Theorem 6.
1. Let the coefficients and the random variables be the same as in Theorem 4. Consider the perturbed coefficients
where a sequence satisfies the following conditions:
- (i)
- There exist positive constants C and α such that
- (ii)
- , as .
Then the processes
converge to , as , weakly in .
2. Assume, additionally, that the following assumption holds:
- (iii)
- There exists such that for all ,
and are iid Rademacher random variables. Let
Then the sequence of stochastic processes
converge in to .
Proof.
1. Let us prove that the conditions (A2), (C2) and (C3) remain valid, if we replace the coefficients by . Applying (i) and Lemma 1, we get
whence (A2) follows.
Further, for , we have
The first term in the right-hand side of (33) converges to by (25), as . The second term is bounded by the sum , which tends to zero according to assumption (ii). Using the Cauchy–Schwarz and (7), we can bound the third term as follows:
by (ii), since , as . Similarly, for the forth term we have
Thus, , as , i.e., the assumption (C2) is verified.
2. Now let us verify the conditions (B1) and (B2) for the convergence of the corresponding multiplicative scheme. Note that
Therefore,
Example 1.
The following sequences of satisfy the conditions (i)–(iii) of Theorem 6:
- , ,
- , , .
4.2. Numerical Example and Discussion of Open Problems
First, let us illustrate the results of Section 3 with a numerical example. Take , . In this case the covariance matrix of fractional Brownian motion equals
Then the upper-triangular matrix of its Cholesky decomposition is given by
We see that this example confirms the results of Lemmas 3 and 4. In particular, all elements of this matrix are non-negative and its rows are increasing. Moreover, all diagonal elements are less or equal than 1, and are bigger than . Furthermore, the bound (23) also holds. Indeed, for , . For example, for we have that is less than .
We suppose that the columns of the above matrix are decreasing. More precisely, our conjecture can be formulated as follows.
Conjecture A1.
For all ,
However, the proof of this fact is an open problem.
Further, the corresponding covariance matrix of the increments process , , is equal to
and the upper-triangular matrix of the corresponding Cholesky decomposition has the following form:
We observe that the values along all diagonals of this matrix decrease. These numerical results allows us to formulate the following conjecture.
Conjecture A2.
For all ,
Remark 5.
- 1.
- For the moment, we can proof only non-strict inequality for the case , i.e., the monotonicity along the main diagonal, see Remark A2 below.
- 2.
- Conjecture A2 implies Conjecture A1. This becomes clear, if we rewrite the relation (20) between and as follows
- 3.
- In Appendix A.3 below we formulate Conjecture A3, which is a sufficient condition for Conjecture A2.
5. Riemann–Liouville Fractional Brownian Motion as a Limit Process
Let , . Let us define
where is a Wiener process. The process X is known as Riemann–Liouville fractional Brownian motion or type II fractional Brownian motion, see, e.g., (); ().
Define
Theorem 7.
Let be a sequence of iid random variables with and . Assume that are defined by (37) and
Then , weakly in .
First, let us prove the convergence of finite-dimensional distributions.
Lemma 8.
Under assumptions of Theorem 7, the finite-dimensional distributions of converge to those of .
Proof.
In order to prove the lemma, we will verify the conditions of Theorem 2. Let us start with proving that the covariance function of converges to the covariance function of as . Indeed, for we have
By the Euler–Maclaurin formula,
Therefore
hence, the condition (C2) is satisfied.
Note that by (37) and (38),
and the condition (C3) also holds.
Thus the assumptions of Theorem 2 are satisfied. This concludes the proof. □
Now let us verify the tightness condition (A2).
Lemma 9.
Let the numbers be defined by (37). Then there exists a constant such that for all ,
Proof.
We estimate each of the sums in the left-hand side of (40). Using (37), we get
The inner sum can be bounded as follows
where we used the inequality for and . Then
Since for , we see that
Consequently, we have
Now we estimate the second sum in (40). By the change of variables , we get
We bound the inner sum using (41) and estimate . We obtain
Now let us verify the conditions of Theorem 3. We start with condition (B1).
Lemma 10.
Let be a triangular array of non-negative numbers defined by (36). Then for all and for all ,
Proof.
Now let us verify the condition (B2).
Lemma 11.
The numbers defined by (36) satisfy the condition (B2).
Proof.
We have
since and . □
Thus, we have proved that all assumptions of Theorem 3 are satisfied. As a consequence, we obtain the following result.
Author Contributions
All authors have read and agree to the published version of the manuscript. Conceptualization, Y.M.; investigation, Y.M., K.R. and S.S.; writing–original draft preparation, Y.M., K.R. and S.S.; writing–review and editing,Y.M., K.R. and S.S.
Funding
Y.M. and K.R. acknowledge that the present research is carried through within the frame and support of the ToppForsk project nr. 274410 of the Research Council of Norway with title STORM: Stochastics for Time-Space Risk Models.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
Appendix A. Monotonicity Along the Diagonal of a Triangular Matrix in the Cholesky Decomposition of a Positive Definite Toeplitz Matrix
In this appendix we establish the connection between the prediction of a stationary Gaussian process and the Cholesky decomposition of its covariance matrix. It turns out that the positivity of the coefficients of predictor implies the monotonicity along the diagonals of a triangular matrix in the Cholesky decomposition.
Let be a centered stationary Gaussian discrete-time process with the known autocovariance function:
Assume that all finite-dimensional distributions of X are non-degenerate multivariate normal distributions. In other words, we assume that for all , the symmetric covariance matrix of n subsequent values of X,
is non-degenerate.
Appendix A.1. Prediction of a Stationary Stochastic Process
Let us construct the predictor of by the observations . Since the joint distribution is Gaussian, we see that the conditional distribution is also Gaussian. (, Section 2.5). The parameters of this distribution are given by
Denote
Then
The following theorem claims that if the coefficients of the one-step-ahead predictor are positive, then the coefficients of the multi-step-ahead predictor are also positive.
Theorem A1.
Assume that the inequality holds for all . Then for all ,
Proof.
For a discrete-time stochastic process, the coefficients of the multi-step-ahead predictor are evaluated by the following recursive formula:
(Here, by convention, .)
Fix m and k, . By assumption, . According to (A6), if for all , then . Hence, by induction, for all . Inequality (A4) is proved.
Now let us establish Inequality (A5). Again, we prove it by induction. We use the following recursive formula from the Levinson–Durbin algorithm (; ):
It implies that
The induction hypothesis is the following: For all m and k, , and for all
Hence, we need to prove the inequality
Using (A6), we obtain
Thus, Inequality (A8) is proved. Hence, for all m and k, , and for all . Equivalently, Inequality (A5) holds for all n, m and k such that . □
Appendix A.2. Cholesky Decomposition of the Covariance Matrix
Fix N. Recall that, by assumption, the covariance matrix of the random vector is non-degenerate. In this case the matrix can be uniquely represented as a product
where is a lower-triangular matrix with positive diagonal elements. This representation is called Cholesky decomposition.
Remark A1.
The numbers do not depend on N:
where denotes an element of the matrix in Decomposition (A9) for a certain value of N.
Since is a zero vector and is an identity matrix, we see that the random vector
has N-dimensional standard normal distribution,
We have
Hence, the values of the stochastic process can be represented as follows:
where , , are independent standard normal random variables.
Taking into account Remark A1, Equalities (A10) and (A11) can be generalized for all k:
where for the matrix is a sub-matrix of ,
For all k the matrix is non-degenerate, and is the covariance matrix of the vector . This implies that the -algebra, generated by the random variables coincides with -algebra, generated by the random variables :
Theorem A2.
Assume that the condition of Theorem A1 is satisfied: For all k and m such that , the inequality holds. Then for all ,
Proof.
The standard Gaussian random variables are measurable with respect to -algebra for and independent of -algebra for . Therefore
Hence,
Further,
Here we have used that
where . Hence,
Moreover, note that
In the Levinson–Durbin method the conditional variance of one-step-ahead predictor is calculated as follows (; ):
Since and for all m, we get
Inequality (A14) is proved in the case .
It follows from orthonormality of the random variables and from the representation (A12) that
Since (as a diagonal element of the triangular matrix in the Cholesky decomposition) and (by Theorem A1), we see that . Hence, Inequality (A13) is proved.
Thus Inequality (A14) is proved in the case . This completes the proof. □
Remark A2.
It follows from (A23) that the following non-strict inequalities for the elements of the main diagonal
can be proved without the assumption for all .
Appendix A.3. Application to Fractional Brownian Motion
In order to prove Conjecture A2, it suffices to apply Theorem A2 to stationary Gaussian process with covariance matrix given by (11) (its Cholesky decomposition is considered in Lemma 2). To this end, we need to prove the positivity of the coefficients of the corresponding one-step-ahead predictor. According to (A2), these coefficients are given by
Consequently, in order to verify Conjecture A2, it suffices to establish the following result.
Conjecture A3.
For any , a solution to the linear system of equations
is positive.
For , we have an equation with the positive solution , see (17). Below we show that the above conjecture holds also in the particular case . The proof in the general case is an open problem.
Proof of Conjecture A3 for the particular case m = 2.
We have the following system:
where and , see (10). The determinant
since . The solution is given by
By (15), . Therefore, . In order to prove that , we need to establish the inequality , which is equivalent to
This inequality can be simplified to
Let . We need to prove that
Note that . The first and second derivatives are equal to
Hence, we need to prove that , which is equivalent to . Therefore, it suffices to show that , which is true and can be checked by straightforward calculation.
Thus, we have proved that for , i.e., the function f is convex for . Then f is negative for , since . Consequently, we have that . □
References
- Anderson, Theodore Wilbur. 2003. An Introduction to Multivariate Statistical Analysis. New York: Wiley. [Google Scholar]
- Berenhaut, Kenneth S., and Dipankar Bandyopadhyay. 2005. Monotone convex sequences and Cholesky decomposition of symmetric Toeplitz matrices. Linear Algebra and its Applications 403: 75–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bezborodov, Viktor, Luca Di Persio, and Yuliya Mishura. 2019. Option pricing with fractional stochastic volatility and discontinuous payoff function of polynomial growth. Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability 21: 331–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Billingsley, Patrick. 1995. Probability and Measure, 3rd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons. [Google Scholar]
- Billingsley, Patrick. 1999. Convergence of Probability Measures, 2nd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons. [Google Scholar]
- Cordero, Fernando, Irene Klein, and Irene Klein Perez-Ostafe. 2016. Asymptotic proportion of arbitrage points in fractional binary markets. Stochastic Processes and their Applications 126: 315–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef][Green Version]
- Davidson, James, and Nigar Hashimzade. 2009. Type I and type II fractional Brownian motions: A reconsideration. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis 53: 2089–106. [Google Scholar]
- Davydov, Yurii Aleksandrovich. 1970. The invariance principle for stationary processes. Theory of Probability & Its Applications 15: 487–98. [Google Scholar]
- Föllmer, Hans, and Alexander Schied. 2011. Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time, extended ed. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter & Co. [Google Scholar]
- Gatheral, Jim, Thibault Jaisson, and Mathieu Rosenbaum. 2018. Volatility is rough. Quantitative Finance 18: 933–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gorodetskii, Vasiliy V. 1977. On convergence to semi-stable Gaussian processes. Theory of Probability & Its Applications 22: 498–508. [Google Scholar]
- Grimmett, Geoffrey R., and David R. Stirzaker. 2001. Probability and Random Processes, 3rd ed. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Hubalek, Friedrich, and Walter Schachermayer. 1998. When does convergence of asset price processes imply convergence of option prices? Mathematical Finance 8: 385–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Marinucci, Domenico, and Peter M. Robinson. 1999. Alternative forms of fractional Brownian motion. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference 80: 111–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mishura, Yuliya. 2015a. Diffusion approximation of recurrent schemes for financial markets, with application to the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. Opuscula Mathematica. 35: 99–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mishura, Yuliya. 2015b. The rate of convergence of option prices on the asset following a geometric Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. Lithuanian Mathematical Journal 55: 134–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mishura, Yuliya. 2015c. The rate of convergence of option prices when general martingale discrete-time scheme approximates the Black-Scholes model. Banach Center Publications 104: 151–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mishura, Yuliya. 2008. Stochastic Calculus for Fractional Brownian Motion and Related Processes. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, vol. 1929. [Google Scholar]
- Prigent, Jean-Luc. 2003. Weak Convergence of Financial Markets. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. [Google Scholar]
- Rogers, Leonard C. G. 1997. Arbitrage with fractional Brownian motion. Mathematical Finance 7: 95–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shumway, Robert H., and David S. Stoffer. 2017. Time Series Analysis and Its Applications: With R Examples, 4th ed. Cham: Springer. [Google Scholar]
- Sottinen, Tommi. 2001. Fractional Brownian motion, random walks and binary market models. Finance and Stochastics 5: 343–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Subba Rao, Suhasini. 2018. A Course in Time Series Analysis. Available online: https://www.stat.tamu.edu/~suhasini/teaching673/time_series.pdf (accessed on 29 January 2020).
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).