1. Introduction
In actuarial risk theory, the surplus of an insurance company is typically modeled by a compound Poisson process with a positive drift and negative jumps (Cramér–Lundberg model) or more generally by a spectrally-negative Lévy process. Thanks to the recent developments of the fluctuation theory of Lévy processes, there now exists a variety of tools available to compute various quantities that are useful in insurance mathematics.
By the existing fluctuation theory, it is relatively easy to deal with (classical) reflected Lévy processes that can be written as the differences between the underlying and running supremum/infimum processes.
The known results on these processes can be conveniently and efficiently applied in modeling the surplus of a dividend-paying company: under a barrier strategy, the resulting controlled surplus process becomes the process reflected from above. The work in
Avram et al. (
2007) obtained the expected net present value (NPV) of dividends until ruin; a sufficient condition for the optimality of a barrier strategy is given in
Loeffen (
2008). Similarly, capital injection is modeled by reflections from below. In the bail-out case with a requirement that ruin must be avoided,
Avram et al. (
2007) obtained the expected NPV of dividends and capital injections under a double barrier strategy. They also showed that it is optimal to reflect the process at zero and at some upper boundary, with the resulting surplus process being a doubly-reflected Lévy process.
These seminal works give concise expressions for various fluctuation identities in terms of the scale function. In general, conciseness is still maintained when the underlying spectrally one-sided Lévy process is replaced with its reflected process. This is typically done by using the derivative or the integral of the scale function depending on whether the reflection barrier is higher or lower. For the results on a variant called refracted Lévy processes, see, e.g.,
Kyprianou (
2010),
Kyprianou et al. (
2014).
In this paper, we consider a different version of reflection, which we call the Parisian reflection. Motivated by the fact that, in reality, dividend/capital injection decisions can only be made at some intervals, several recent papers consider periodic barrier strategies that reflect the process only at discrete observation times. In particular,
Avram et al. (
2018) consider, for a general spectrally-negative Lévy process, the case capital injections can be made at the jump times of an independent Poisson process (the reflection barrier is lower). This current paper considers the case when dividends are made at these Poisson observation times (reflection barrier is upper). Other related papers in the compound Poisson cases include
Albrecher et al. (
2011);
Avanzi et al. (
2013), where in the former, several identities are obtained when the solvency is also observed periodically, whereas the latter studies the case where observation intervals are Erlang-distributed.
This work is also motivated by its applications in de Finetti’s dividend problems under Poisson observation times. In the dual (spectrally positive) model,
Avanzi et al. (
2014) solved the case where the jump size is hyper-exponentially distributed;
Pérez and Yamazaki (
2017) generalized the results to a general spectrally-positive Lévy case and also solved the bail-out version using the results in
Avram et al. (
2018). An extension with a combination of periodic and continuous dividend payments (with different transaction costs) was recently solved by
Avanzi et al. (
2016) when the underlying process is a Brownian motion with a drift. In these papers, optimal strategies are of a periodic barrier-type. On the other hand, this paper provides tools to study the spectrally-negative case. Recently, our results have been used to show the optimality of periodic barrier strategies in (
Noba et al. 2017,
2018); see Remarks 2 and 8.
In this paper, we study the following four processes that are constructed from a given spectrally-negative Lévy process X and the jump times of an independent Poisson process with rate :
The process with Parisian reflection from above : The process is constructed by modifying X so that it is pushed down to zero at the Poisson observation times at which it is above zero. Note that the barrier level zero can be changed to any real value by the spatial homogeneity of X. This process models the controlled surplus process under a periodic barrier dividend strategy.
The process with Parisian and classical reflection from above
: Suppose
is the reflected process of
X with the classical upper barrier
. The process
is constructed in the same way as
in (1) with the underlying process
X replaced with
. This process models the controlled surplus process under a combination of the classical and periodic barrier dividend strategies. This is a generalization of the Brownian motion case as studied in
Avanzi et al. (
2016).
The process with Parisian reflection from above and classical reflection from below : Suppose is the reflected process of X with the classical lower barrier . The process is constructed in the same way as as in (1) with the underlying process X replaced with . By shifting the process (by ), it models the surplus under a periodic barrier dividend strategy with classical capital injections (so that it does not go below zero).
The process with Parisian and classical reflection from above and classical reflection from below : Suppose is the doubly-reflected process of X with a classical lower barrier and a classical upper barrier . The process is constructed in the same way as in (1) with the underlying process X replaced with . By shifting the process (by ), it models the controlled surplus process under a combination of the classical and periodic barrier dividend strategies as in (2) with additional classical capital injections.
For these four processes, we compute various fluctuation identities that include:
- (a)
the expected NPV of dividends (both corresponding to Parisian and classical reflections) with the horizon given by the first exit time from an interval and those with the infinite horizon,
- (b)
the expected NPV of capital injections with the horizon given by the first exit time from an interval and those with the infinite horizon,
- (c)
the two-sided (one-sided) exit identities.
In order to compute these for the four processes defined above, we first obtain the identities for the process (1) killed upon exiting . Using the observation that the paths of the processes (2)–(4) are identical to those of (1) before the first exit time from , the results for (2)–(4) can be obtained as corollaries, via the strong Markov property and the existing known identities for classical reflected processes.
The identities for (1) are obtained separately for the case that
X has paths of bounded variation and for the case that it has paths of unbounded variation. The former is done by a relatively well-known technique via the strong Markov property combined with the existing known identities for the spectrally-negative Lévy process. The case of unbounded variation is done via excursion theory (in particular excursions away from zero as in
Pardo et al. (
2018)). Thanks to the simplifying formulae obtained in
Avram et al. (
2018) and
Loeffen et al. (
2014), concise expressions can be achieved.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In
Section 2, we review the spectrally-negative Lévy process and construct more formally the four processes described above. In addition, scale functions and some existing fluctuation identities are briefly reviewed. In
Section 3, we state the main results for the process (1) and, then, in
Section 4, those for the processes (2)–(4). In
Section 5 and
Section 6, we give proofs for the main results for (1) for the case of bounded variation and unbounded variation, respectively.
Throughout the paper, for any function f of two variables, let be the partial derivative with respect to the first argument.
2. Spectrally-Negative Lévy Processes with Parisian Reflection above
Let
be a Lévy process defined on a probability space
. For
, we denote by
the law of
X when it starts at
x and write for convenience
in place of
. Accordingly, we shall write
and
for the associated expectation operators. In this paper, we shall assume throughout that
X is spectrally negative, meaning here that it has no positive jumps and that it is not the negative of a subordinator. It is a well-known fact that its Laplace exponent
, i.e.,
is given by the Lévy–Khintchine formula:
where
,
and
is a measure on
called the Lévy measure of
X that satisfies:
It is well known that
X has paths of bounded variation if and only if
and
; in this case,
X can be written as:
where:
and
is a driftless subordinator. Note that necessarily
, since we have ruled out the case that
X has monotone paths; its Laplace exponent is given by:
Let us define the running infimum and supremum processes:
Then, the processes reflected from above at
b and below at
a are given, respectively, by:
where:
are the cumulative amounts of reflections that push the processes downward and upward, respectively.
2.1. Lévy Processes with Parisian Reflection above
Let be an increasing sequence of jump times of an independent Poisson process with rate . We construct the Lévy process with Parisian reflection above as follows: the process is only observed at times and is pushed down to zero if and only if it is above zero.
More specifically, we have:
where:
here and throughout, let
. The process then jumps downward by
so that
. For
, we have
, and
. The process can be constructed by repeating this procedure.
Suppose
is the cumulative amount of (Parisian) reflection until time
. Then, we have:
with
where
can be constructed inductively by (
4) and:
2.2. Lévy Processes with Parisian and Classical Reflection above
Fix
. Consider an extension of the above with additional classical reflection from above at
, which we denote by
. More specifically, we have:
where
. The process then jumps downward by
so that
. For
, it is the reflected process of
(with classical reflection above at
b as in (
2)) and
. The process can be constructed by repeating this procedure.
Suppose
and
are the cumulative amounts of Parisian reflection (with upper barrier zero) and classical reflection (with upper barrier
b) until time
. Then, we have:
2.3. Lévy Processes with Parisian Reflection above and Classical Reflection below
Fix
. The process
with additional (classical) reflection below can be defined analogously. We have:
where
. The process then jumps downward by
so that
. For
,
is the reflected process of
(with the classical reflection below at
a as in (
2)), and
. The process can be constructed by repeating this procedure. It is clear that it admits a decomposition:
where
and
are, respectively, the cumulative amounts of Parisian reflection (with upper barrier zero) and classical reflection (with lower barrier
a) until time
t.
2.4. Lévy Processes with Parisian and Classical Reflection above and Classical Reflection below
Fix
. Consider a version of
with additional classical reflection from above at
. More specifically, we have:
where
is the classical doubly-reflected process of
X with lower barrier
a and upper barrier
b (see
Pistorius (
2003)) and:
The process then jumps downward by so that . For , it is the doubly-reflected process of (with classical reflections at a and b), and . The process can be constructed by repeating this procedure.
Suppose
and
are the cumulative amounts of Parisian reflection (with upper barrier zero) and classical reflection (with upper barrier
b) until time
, and
is that of the classical reflection (with lower barrier
a). Then, we have:
2.5. Review of Scale Functions
Fix
. We use
for the scale function of the spectrally-negative Lévy process
X. This is the mapping from
to
that takes the value zero on the negative half-line, while on the positive half-line, it is a strictly increasing function that is defined by its Laplace transform:
where
is as defined in (
1) and:
We also define, for
,
Noting that
for
, we have:
Define also:
and its partial derivative with respect to the first argument:
In particular, for
,
and, for
,
Remark 1. 1. If X has paths of unbounded variation or the Lévy measure is atomless, it is known that is ; see, e.g., (Chan et al. 2011, Theorem 3). In particular, if , then is ; see, e.g., (Chan et al. 2011, Theorem 1). 2. Regarding the asymptotic behavior near zero, as in Lemmas 3.1 and 3.2 of Kuznetsov et al. (2013),On the other hand, as in Lemma 3.3 of Kuznetsov et al. (2013), where in the case , the right-hand side, when , is understood to be infinity. Below, we list the fluctuation identities that will be used later in the paper.
2.6. Fluctuation Identities for X
Let:
Then, for
and
,
By taking
in the latter, as in (
Albrecher et al. 2016, (7)) (see also the identity (3.19) in
Avram et al. (
2007)),
where, for the case
, it is understood as the limiting case. In addition, it is known that a spectrally-negative Lévy process creeps downwards if and only if
; by Theorem 2.6 (ii) of
Kuznetsov et al. (
2013),
where we recall that
is differentiable when
as in Remark 1 (1). By this, the strong Markov property and (
10), we have for
and
,
where:
2.7. Fluctuation Identities for
Fix
. Define the first downcrossing time of
of (
2):
The Laplace transform of
is given, as in Proposition 2 (ii) of
Pistorius (
2004), by:
As in Proposition 1 of
Avram et al. (
2007), the discounted cumulative amount of reflection from above as in (
3) is:
2.8. Fluctuation Identities for
Fix
. Define the first upcrossing time of
of (
2):
First, as on page 228 of
Kyprianou (
2006), its Laplace transform is concisely given by:
Second, as in the proof of Theorem 1 of
Avram et al. (
2007), the discounted cumulative amount of reflection from below as in (
3) is, given
,
where:
2.9. Some More Notations
For the rest of the paper, we fix and use for the first observation time, or an independent exponential random variable with parameter r.
Let, for
and
,
where the case
is understood as the limiting case.
We define, for any measurable function
,
In particular, we let, for
,
and
,
with
.
Thanks to these functionals, the following expectations admit concise expressions. By Lemma 2.1 in
Loeffen et al. (
2014) and Theorem 6.1 in
Avram et al. (
2018) , for all
,
and
,
Lemma 1. For , , , and , 3. Main Results for
In this section, we obtain the fluctuation identities for the process
as constructed in
Section 2.1. The main theorems are obtained for the case killed upon exiting an interval
for
. As their corollaries, we also obtain the limiting cases as
and
. The proofs for the theorems are given in
Section 5 and
Section 6 for the bounded and unbounded variation cases, respectively. The proofs for the corollaries are given in the
Appendix B.
Define the first down-/up-crossing times for
,
Define also for
,
and
,
Note in particular that:
and that:
We shall first obtain the expected NPV of dividends (see the decomposition (
5)) killed upon exiting
.
Theorem 1 (Periodic control of dividends)
. For , and , we have: By taking and in Theorem 1, we have the following.
Corollary 1. (i) For , and , we have: where: (ii) For , and , we have: where, by (7), (iii) Suppose or with . Then, for ,Otherwise, it is infinity for . Remark 2. Recently, in Noba et al. (2018), Corollary 1 (ii) was used to show the optimality of a periodic barrier strategy in de Finetti’s dividend problem under the assumption that the Lévy measure has a completely monotone density. Thanks to the semi-analytic expression in terms of the scale function, the selection of a candidate optimal barrier, as well as the verification of optimality are conducted efficiently, without focusing on a particular class of Lévy processes. We shall now study the two-sided exit identities. The main results are given in Theorems 2 and 3, and their corollaries are obtained by taking limits. We first obtain the Laplace transform of the upcrossing time on the event .
Theorem 2 (Upcrossing time)
. For , , and , we have: The following technical result will be helpful for obtaining the Laplace exponent of the upcrossing time , as a corollary to Theorem 2.
Remark 3. Fix and . By Lemma 3 below, we see that
. Because and by (
9)
,Hence, we see that vanishes in the limit as . By taking in Theorem 2, we have the following.
Corollary 2. (i) For , and , we have where is given as in (
28)
. (ii) In particular, when , then -a.s. for any . For
,
,
and
, let:
which satisfies:
and, by (
26),
Using these, we express the Laplace transform of the downcrossing time on the event .
Theorem 3 (Downcrossing time and overshoot)
. For , , , and , we have: By taking in Theorem 3, we obtain the following.
Corollary 3. (i) For , , and ,where in particular: (ii) For and , -a.s. By taking in Theorem 3 and Corollary 3, we have the following identities related to the event that the process goes continuously below a level.
Corollary 4 (Creeping)
. (i) For , and , we have:where (recall that is differentiable when as in Remark 1 (1)): (ii) For , and , we have: In Theorem 3, by taking the derivative with respect to and taking , we obtain the following. This will later be used to compute the identities for capital injection in Proposition 5.
Corollary 5. Suppose . For , and ; we have: withwhere , . By taking in Corollary 5, we have the following.
Corollary 6. Suppose . For , and , we have: The following remark states that as the rate r of the Poisson process associated with the Parisian reflection goes to zero, we recover classical fluctuation identities.
Remark 4. Note that, for , and ,Hence, as , we have the following. - 1.
By Theorem 1, vanishes in the limit.
- 2.
By Theorems 2 and 3, and converge to the right-hand sides of (
10)
. - 3.
By Corollary 4 (i), converges to the right-hand side of (
12)
.
The convergence for the limiting cases and/or hold in the same way.
4. Main Results for the Cases with Additional Classical Reflections
In this section, we shall extend the results in
Section 3 and obtain similar identities for the processes
,
and
as defined in
Section 2.2,
Section 2.3 and
Section 2.4, respectively. Again, the proofs for the corollaries are deferred to the
Appendix B.
4.1. Results for
We shall first study the process
as constructed in
Section 2.2. Let:
and
be the right-hand derivative of (
25) with respect to x given by:
Recall the classical reflected process
and
as in (
13). We shall first compute the following.
Lemma 2. For and , Proof. We first note that, by (
14),
By summing this and (22), the result follows. ☐
In order to obtain the results for , we shall use the following observation and the strong Markov property.
Remark 5. (i) For , and . (ii) For , and . (iii) For , .
We shall first compute the expected NPV of the periodic part of dividends using Lemma 2 and Remark 5. It attains a concise expression in terms of the function and its derivative.
Proposition 1 (Periodic part of dividends)
. For , and , we have: Proof. By Remark 5 (i) and the strong Markov property, we can write:
For
, by Remark 5 (ii) and the strong Markov property,
. This together with (
10) gives:
On the other hand, by the resolvent given in Theorem 1 (ii) of
Pistorius (
2004),
Substituting (
34) and (
35) in (
33) and applying Lemma 2,
Now, by Remark 5 (iii), the strong Markov property and Theorems 1 and 2, for all
,
Setting
and solving for
(using (
26)), we have
. Substituting this back in (
36), the proof is complete. ☐
By taking in Proposition 1, we have the following.
Corollary 7. (i) For or with , we have, for and ,where is the derivative of of (
28)
given by:(ii) If with , it becomes infinity. Now, consider the singular part of dividends. We see that the related identities can again be written in terms of and its derivative.
Proposition 2 (Singular part of dividends)
. For , and , we have: Proof. By Remark 5 (i) and the strong Markov property,
By (
15) and the computation similar to (
34) (thanks to Remark 5 (ii)),
For
, because Remark 5 (iii) and the strong Markov property give
, Theorem 2 and (
37) give:
Setting
and solving for
(using (
26)), we have
. Substituting this in (
38), we have the result. ☐
By taking in Proposition 2, we have the following.
Corollary 8. Fix and . (i) For or with , we have . (ii) If with , it becomes infinity.
Finally, we obtain the (joint) identities related to and the position of the process at this stopping time. We first compute their Laplace transform.
Proposition 3 (Downcrossing time and overshoot)
. Fix and . (i) For and ,(ii) We have , -a.s. Proof. (i) By Remark 5 (i) and the strong Markov property, we can write:
For
, by Remark 5 (ii), the strong Markov property and (
10),
and hence, together with (22) and Lemmas 1 and 2,
On the other hand, by Remark 5 (iii), the strong Markov property and Theorems 2 and 3, we have that, for all
,
Setting
and solving for
(via (
26) and (
30)),
. Substituting this back in (
40), we have:
Using (
29), it equals the right-hand side of (
39).
(ii) In view of (i), it is immediate by (
27) by setting
. ☐
Similar to Corollary 5, we obtain the following by Proposition 3.
Corollary 9. Suppose . For , and ; we have that: Similar to Remark 4, in the following result, we see how we can recover classical fluctuation identities by taking the rate r, related to the Parisian reflection, to zero.
Remark 6. Recall (
32)
. As , we have the following. - 1.
By Proposition 1, vanishes in the limit.
- 2.
By Proposition 2, converges to the right-hand side of (
15)
. - 3.
By Proposition 3, converges to:which is given in Theorem 1 of Avram et al. (2004). - 4.
By Corollary 9, converges to:which is given in (3.16) of Avram et al. (2007).
The convergence for the limiting case holds in the same way.
4.2. Results for
We shall now study the process
as defined in
Section 2.3. We let:
Remark 7. Recall the classical reflected process and as in (
16)
. (i) For , we have and . (ii) For , we have . Using this remark, we obtain the following identity related to Parisian reflection (periodic dividends).
Proposition 4 (Periodic part of dividends)
. For , and , Proof. By an application of Remark 7 (i), (
17) and the strong Markov property,
By this, Remark 7 (ii) and the strong Markov property, together with Theorems 1 and 3, we have for
:
Setting
and solving for
(using (
26)), we get
. Substituting this in (
41), we have the claim. ☐
By taking in Proposition 4, we have the following.
Corollary 10. Fix and . (i) For , we have:(ii) For , it becomes infinity. For
and
, let:
In particular,
For the identities related to classical reflection below (capital injections), we will write them in terms of the functions and .
Proposition 5 (Capital injections)
. For , and , Proof. First, by Remark 7 (i), (
17), (
18) and an application of the strong Markov property,
This, together with Remark 7 (ii), Corollary 5, Theorem 3 and the strong Markov property, gives, for
,
Setting
and solving for
(using (
26) and (
42)),
.
Substituting this back in (
44), we have the claim. ☐
By taking in Proposition 5, we have the following.
Corollary 11. For , , and , we have Remark 8. Recently, in Noba et al. (2017), Corollaries 10 and 11 were used to show the optimality of a mixed periodic-classical barrier strategy in de Finetti’s dividend problem with periodic dividends and classical capital injections. The candidate optimal barrier is chosen so that the slope at the barrier becomes one. The optimality is shown to hold for a general spectrally-negative Lévy process by the observation that the slope of the candidate value function is proportional to the Laplace transform of the stopping time given in Corollary 3. Finally, we compute the Laplace transform of the upcrossing time .
Proposition 6 (Upcrossing time)
. Fix . (i) For and , we have:(ii) For all , we have , -a.s. Proof. (i) By Remark 7 (i) and the strong Markov property, together with (
17),
By this, Remark 7 (ii) and the strong Markov property, together with Theorems 2 and 3,
Setting
and by (
26), we obtain
. Substituting this in (
45), we have the claim. (ii) This is immediate by setting
in (i) by (
27). ☐
In the next remark, we recover classical fluctuation identities found in
Avram et al. (
2007) and
Kyprianou (
2006), by taking the rate associated with the Parisian reflection to zero.
Remark 9. Recall (
32)
. As , we have the following. - 1.
By Proposition 4, vanishes in the limit.
- 2.
By Proposition 5, converges to the right-hand side of (
18)
. - 3.
By Proposition 6, converges to the right-hand side of (
17)
.
The convergence for the limiting case holds in the same way.
4.3. Results for
We conclude this section with the identities for the process
as constructed in
Section 2.4. We use the derivative of
as in (
25):
We shall use the following observation and the strong Markov property.
Remark 10. (i) For , we have , and .
(ii) For all , we have , and .
In view of this remark, we obtain the following identities related to the three types of reflections , and in Propositions 7–9, respectively.
Proposition 7 (Periodic part of dividends)
. Fix and . (i) For , we have:(ii) If , it becomes infinity. Proof. By Remark 10 (i), (
17) and the strong Markov property,
. By this, Remark 10 (ii) and the strong Markov property, together with Propositions 1 and 3, for
,
Now taking
and by (
26), we get
. Substituting this in (
46), we have the claim. ☐
Proposition 8 (Singular part of dividends)
. Fix and . (i) For any , we have that:(ii) If , it becomes infinity. Proof. (i) By Remark 10 (i), (
17) and the strong Markov property,
. By this, Remark 10 (ii) and the strong Markov property, together with Propositions 2 and 3, for
,
Now, taking
and solving for
(using (
26)), we get
. Substituting this in (
47), we have the claim.
(ii) It is immediate by (
27) upon taking
in (i). ☐
Proposition 9 (Capital injections)
. Fix and . (i) For any , we have:(ii) When , it becomes infinity. Proof. (i) First, by Remark 10 (i), by modifying (
43),
. In view of this, by Remark 10 (ii), Corollary 9 and the strong Markov property, we obtain a modification of (
44): for
,
Setting
and solving for
(using (
26) and (
42)),
. Substituting this back in (
48), we have the claim
(ii) It is immediate by (
27) upon taking
in (i). ☐
Remark 11. The results given in Propositions 7–9 can potentially be used to prove the optimality of a hybrid continuous and periodic dividend payment strategy, for an extension of Pérez and Yamazaki (forthcoming) with additional capital injections in the spectrally-negative model. Finally, by taking the rate of the Parisian reflection r to zero, we recover the results obtained in
Avram et al. (
2007).
Remark 12. Recall (
32)
. As , we have the following. - 1.
By Proposition 7, vanishes in the limit.
- 2.
By Proposition 8, converges to Identity (4.3) in Theorem 1 of Avram et al. (2007). - 3.
By Proposition 9, converges to Identity (4.4) in Theorem 1 of Avram et al. (2007).
6. Proofs for Theorems for the Unbounded Variation Case
In this section, we shall show Theorems 1–3 for the case X has paths of unbounded variation. The proof is via excursion theory. We in particular use the recent results obtained in
Pardo et al. (
2018) and the simplifying formula given in
Avram et al. (
2018). We refer the reader to Chapter IV in
Bertoin (
1996) and to
Pardo et al. (
2018) for a detailed introduction and definitions regarding excursions away from zero for the case of spectrally-negative Lévy processes.
Fix
and
. Let us consider the event:
where
is an independent exponential clock with rate r and ζ is the length of the excursion from the point it leaves zero and returns back to zero. Due to the fact that X is spectrally negative, once an excursion gets below zero, it stays until it ends at ζ. That is,
is the event to which (1) the exponential clock
that starts once the excursion becomes positive rings before it downcrosses zero, (2) the excursion exceeds the level
or (3) it goes below
.
Now, let us denote by
the first time an excursion in the event
occurs and also denote by:
the left extrema of the first excursion on
. In the event
, we have:
where we denote by
the shift operator at time
.
Let
be the point process of excursions away from zero and
By, for instance, Proposition 0.2 in
Bertoin (
1996),
is independent of
. The former is a Poisson point process with characteristic measure
, and V follows an exponential distribution with parameter
Moreover, we have that
, where
denotes the lifetime of the excursion
. Therefore, the exponential formula for Poisson point processes (see for instance, Section 0.5 in
Bertoin (
1996) or Proposition 1.12 in Chapter XII in
Revuz and Yor (
1999)), and the independence between
and
imply:
where
is an exponential random variable with parameter
q that is independent of
and
X, and:
To see how the last equality of (
55) holds, we have:
- (i)
,
- (ii)
.
On the other hand, we have the following; the proof is deferred to
Appendix A.2.
Hence,
. This together with (
55) gives:
We now show the following lemma using the connections between
and the excursion measure of the process reflected at its infimum
, as obtained in
Pardo et al. (
2018).
Lemma 6. Fix . (i) We have .
(ii) We have .
Proof. Similarly, we have using Lemma 4 and (
58),
☐
We are now ready to show the theorems. We shall show for the case ; the case holds by monotone convergence. For the rest of this section, let .
6.1. Proof of Theorems 1
By the definition of
, in the event
, the excursion goes below a, and hence, there is no contribution to
. Therefore, by the strong Markov property,
where
By the Master’s formula in excursion theory (see for instance excursions straddling a terminal time in Chapter XII in
Revuz and Yor (
1999)), Lemma 6 and (
57) and because
,
Substituting these in (
59), we obtain
. Substituting this in (
52) (which also holds for the unbounded variation case), we complete the proof.
6.2. Proof of Theorem 2
Similarly to (
59),
By the Master’s formula, Lemma 5.1 (iv) in
Avram et al. (
2018) and (
57) and because
,
Substituting this and (
60) in (
61), we have
. Substituting this in (
53) (which also holds for the unbounded variation case), we complete the proof.
6.3. Proof of Theorems 3
Lemma 7. For , and , Using Lemma 7, we shall now give the proof of the theorem for
; the case
holds by analytic continuation. Using the strong Markov property, we have that:
By the Master’s formula and (
57),
Here, by the strong Markov property, (
10) and Lemma 7,
Substituting these and (
60) in (
62), we obtain that
. Using this expression in (
54) (which also holds for the unbounded variation case), we complete the proof.