1. Introduction
Under the usual conditions, a probability space
is equipped with a non-decreasing family of
-algebras
such that
is complete and right continuous for all
t. A wide class of processes adapted to
are right continuous with left limits paths (RCLL) semimartingales with a well defined stochastic calculus. Many fundamental results in probability theory and mathematical finance were proved with the use of the usual conditions and RCLL semimartingales. However, it is not difficult to give examples showing the existence of a stochastic basis without the usual conditions (see, for instance,
Fleming and Harrington (
2011, p. 24)). Therefore, in the middle of 1970, the famous expert of stochastic analysis
Dellacherie (
1975) initiated studies of stochastic processes without this convenient technical assumption. Dellacherie called this case the
unusual (
nonstandard) conditions. Further developments were done by many mathematicians:
Horowitz (
1978);
Lenglart (
1980);
Lepingle (
1977);
Mertens (
1972) but mostly by
Galchuk (
1980,
1982,
1985). In these publications, a theory of stochastic analysis was constructed for processes on
un usual probability spaces. It turns out that many processes on
unusual spaces are not
necessarily left or right continuous but have left and right limits. For a review of optional calculus and its applications to finance, see
Abdelghani (
2016);
Abdelghani and Melnikov (
2016,
2017a,
2017b). A short summary is given in the
Appendix A.
Defaultable markets are markets with the possibility of default events occurring. Research on default risk is concerned with modeling of default time, defaultable claims and recovery rules and with pricing and hedging strategies. The two main approaches to modelling default are the structural and the reduced form models. In structural models, the value of the firm determines if a default event occur. This approach was founded by
Black and Scholes (
1973) and
Merton (
1974,
1976) and extended by many (see
Cox and Ross (
1976);
Geske (
1977,
1979);
Geske and Johnson (
1984);
Leland (
1994);
Leland and Toft (
1996);
Longstaff and Schwartz (
1995)). The advantage of structural models is that one sees how the corporate conditions affect default. However, most often the firm’s value is not in itself a tradable asset, but the result of an accounting of all of the firm’s assets and liabilities where some are visible to the market and others are not. Hence, the parameters of structural models are difficult to estimate in practice. Moreover, in structural models where a boundary condition is used to demarcate the onset of default, it is difficult to define what the boundary condition should be.
In contrast to structural models, in reduced form models, the firm’s value plays only an auxiliary role and defaults arrive as a total-surprise to all counterparties. Therefore, default is the result of exogenous factors. In this case, the random time of default is defined as a totally inaccessible stopping time on an enlarged filtration that encompass all market information, assets and defaults. To compute pricing rules and hedging portfolios, a fundamental problem in a reduced form approach is the computation of the conditional probability of default given available market information. To compute the conditional probability of default, several approaches arose depending on whether or not the information about default-free market is available. If default-free market information is not given, then one must suppose the existence of an intensity process associated with the probability of default to be able to price a defaultable claim
Duffie and Singleton (
1999). This approach is known as the intensity based approach. The main problem with this approach is that the pricing rule is hard to compute
Jeanblanc and Yann (
2008). On the other hand, in the hazard process approach, the reference filtration of the default-free market is enlarged by the progressive knowledge of default events. It is more convenient to derive probability of default in this framework; however, one needs to assume knowledge of the default-free market information. Much of reduced form pricing theory has been elaborated by many mathematicians (see
Artzner and Delbaen (
1995);
Duffie and Singleton (
1997,
1999);
Belanger et al. (
2001);
Elliott et al. (
2000);
Lando (
1998) and
Bielecki and Rutkowski (
2002),
ElKaroui et al. (
2010),
Jeanblanc (
2010), for a good review).
The basic mathematics of structural and reduced form models is given here as a review and, to compare these models to models, we will present in this paper. Let us consider a usual probability space where the market evolves: asset, X, and default, . Associated with default time is the default process of . Let be the default-free -algebra generated by and be the -algebra generated by with and . Both and are sub--algebras of for all t. In structural form models, the process X is a determinant factor of . In other words, the filtrations and may have common elements for any time t. In addition, in structural models where default time is predictable, . On the other hand, in reduced form models, default is not measurable in the reference-filtration , i.e., for any time t. A way to analyze reduced form models is to consider to be an inaccessible stopping time with respect to the market filtration . With this consideration of , one can proceed to compute the conditional probability of default given using intensity-based techniques. If one is able to define , the default-free filtration, then a new filtration can be constructed by joining the filtration generated by to , i.e., and , then compute using hazard process based techniques. However, this enlargement of the filtration by leads to several problems in trying to establish a pricing theory based on no-arbitrage principle. Enlargement of filtration changes the properties of martingales and semimartingale. For example, if X is a martingale under , it might not be a martingale under or . To deal with these effects and to establish existence of local martingale measures for pricing, one has to invoke two invariance principles known as the and hypotheses. hypothesis states that every local martingale in the smaller filtration is a local martingale in the larger filtration , whereas the hypothesis states that a semimartingale under the smaller filtration remains a semimartingale under the larger filtration .
While there are still many open and interesting problems to consider in the classical approaches to credit risk, we choose to take another approach to the problem. Our approach is based on the calculus of processes on unusual probability spaces. Even though we are going to use a nonstandard calculus to approach the problem of default, it is possible to view our models as extension or enrichment of reduced form models by methods from the calculus of processes on usual probability spaces. Thus, our goal with this paper is to develop initial results and present applications of the calculus of optional processes to defaultable markets.
However, before we delve into our approach, let us motivate it by few examples where we take a closer look at the mechanics of default and how it affects the value of an asset X. Let us place ourselves on the usual probability space where the market evolves. In addition, suppose the asset, X, remains in existence after default while its value changes. Now, let us fix an instance of time t; if default time is predictable or a stopping time in , then —information about default is incorporated in . On the other hand, if , so that is not measurable, then the default time is a random time that is a result of external factors. However, after default takes place, the surprising information about it gets incorporated in future-values of the asset, X; if is RCLL and , then obviously and, loosely speaking, we may want to say for any such that to mean that the information about default time at t is part of a future-filtration of the market. In reduced form modeling, to be precise, an enlarged filtration is constructed, such that the view that information about default is incorporated in future values of the asset is subsumed in the definition of the enlarged market filtration . However, we are going to show in this paper that, with the use of the calculus of processes on unusual probability spaces, one needs not consider a filtration enlargement to incorporate default information in the dynamic changes of the value of the asset.
Let us consider default from a different viewpoint. Suppose that the event such that . Ideally, contains all events including defaults, for example, for the default time , . The expected value at some fixed time, t, is implicitly affected by a future default event . For example, consider for some fixed time u such that and where it is possible that . However, at time t, contains absolutely no information about the default event but the natural filtration generated by the process, a, is not default-free. Essentially, in a defaultable market processes that are affected by default at some point over their lifetime, their current value is “implicitly” affected by default even-though current information does not announce the existence of future default events. Therefore, the construction of a defaultable market filtration from a default-free filtration and a filtration associated with the default process is hard to realize in real defaultable markets. This issue can be circumvented by considering defaultable markets on unusual probability spaces.
Let us consider another example. Suppose the asset X that evolves according to , where W is a Wiener process and and are unknown constants to be estimated from market-traded values of X. In this market, even though default events might be future events beyond the current market time t are implicit in the psyche of the market, e.g., corporate bonds are riskier than US/Canadian Government bonds, and can weakly influence the current traded values of X. As a result, the estimated values of and from the traded values of X are inadvertently contaminated by default events. Therefore, in defaultable markets, assets and defaults are stitched together and are difficult to segregate.
To avoid difficulties of previous approaches, the reconstruction of
enlarged market filtrations, the requiring of
invariance properties to be satisfied as a way to get decomposition results, the
initial completion of filtration by all null sets from the final filtration, and the requirement that the
filtration be right continuous. Without all of these constructs, we propose a different and more
natural approach based on the stochastic calculus of optional processes on
unusual probability spaces. The paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 presents the essence of our approach to defaultable markets on
unusual stochastic basis.
Section 3 deals with defaultable claims and cash-flows.
Section 4 is devoted to the conditional probability of default. In
Section 5, we consider valuation of defaultable contingent claims and illustrative examples. Finally, in
Section 6, we discuss the important topic of no-arbitrage condition in markets on
unusual spaces.
2. Defaultable Markets on Unusual Spaces
To illustrate our approach, we begin with an example of a simple market that experiences default. Even though simple, the ideas we present here are general and can be carried over to other more delicate market structures. Let us consider
now the
unusual stochastic basis
and an asset whose value is given by the process
Y on this space. Assume that the asset final value,
, realized at the end of time is a strictly positive random variable measurable with respect to
. Let
represent the history of the market, the good, the bad and defaults. However bad, we assume that the asset never vanquishes, in other words,
for all time. All is well with the market except for a single default event
, i.e.,
, that happens at some time
. Notice that we have defined
default time,
, as an
inaccessible stopping time in the
broad sense. Furthermore, we assume that the value of the asset before default
follows
X and immediately after default evolves according to
x. Both
x and
X are optional semimartingales adapted to
however,
X is observable only up to default and
x is only observable after default. In addition, we define the default process
as a left continuous optional finite variation process with respect to
. Then,
Y is given by
Note that the filtration generated by
Y is the fusion by default of the filtrations generated by
X and
x, which is
. In the integral representation of
Y, we have,
See
Appendix A Equations (
A1) and (
A2) for the definition of stochastic integrals with respect to optional semimartingales on
unusual probability space. However, since
H has a single left jump but is otherwise continuous, then
and
Y reduces to
To highlight the effects of default
on the value of
Y, which will manifest itself as a left jump on the value of
Y at the time of default, we are going to assume that
x and
X are continuous; hence,
To summarize, the basic tenants to our approach are: (1) the market evolves in the unusual probability space ; (2) is the smallest right continuous enlargement of ; (3) the value of an asset or a defaultable cash-flow is an optional semimartingale; and (4) finally, but most importantly, is that default time, , is defined as is a totally inaccessible stopping time in the broad sense, i.e., , and the associated default process is , which is an optional left continuous process adapted to . The definition of default time as an inaccessible stopping time in the broad sense makes default events come as a surprise to the market given up to time t information, . However, as the market evolves to , the surprising information about default has been incorporated in . In this way, in unusual probability space models of defaultable market takes the place of filtration enlargement in reduced form models. Next, we consider defaultable cash-flow pricing and hedging in the context of unusual stochastic basis.
3. Defaultable Cash-Flow
Again, let the market evolve in the
unusual probability space
.
is the real-world probability, as opposed to the
local optional martingale measure , for which we
assume that at least one exists in this market or
choose one if many exists
Jacod and Protter (
2010). In addition, we have
the
smallest right continuous enlargement of
. The filtration
supports the following objects. The claim,
, is the payoff received by the owner of the claim at maturity time,
T, if there was
no default prior to or
at T. The process,
A, with
, is the promised dividends if there was
no default prior to or
at T. The recovery claim
represents the recovery payoff received at
T, if default occurs prior to the claims maturity date
T. The recovery process,
R, which specifies the recovery payoff at time of default, if it occurs prior to
T. Finally, default time,
, is a totally inaccessible stopping time in the broad sense, i.e.,
. In addition, we define the associated default process by,
, which is optional and a left continuous process with respect to
.
Furthermore, we assume that the processes
X,
, and
are progressively measurable with respect to the filtration
. In addition, the random variable
is
-measurable and
is at least
-measurable. Furthermore, we assume without mentioning that all random objects introduced above are
at least RLL and satisfy suitable integrability conditions that are needed for evaluating integrals, stochastic or otherwise. This brings us to the recovery rules; if default occurs after time
T, then the promised claim
is paid in full at time
T. Otherwise, default time
and depending on the agreed upon recovery rules either the amount
is paid at the time of default
, or the amount
is paid at the maturity date
T. Therefore, in its more general setting, we consider simultaneously both kinds of recovery payoff and thus define a defaultable claim formally as a quintuple,
. Notice that the date
T, the information structures
and
and the real-world probability
are intrinsic components of the definition of a defaultable claim (see
Bielecki and Rutkowski (
2002) for the usual case). For
, the dividend process is defined as
Definition 1. The dividend
process, D, of a defaultable claim equalswhere . The process D is optional and -measurable. Lemma 1. The process D is finite variation over finite time segments including .
Proof. By using Galchouk–Ito lemma and properties of the components of D. ☐
The risk neutral value of a defaultable claim in this market is the discounted value of the dividend process D.
Definition 2. The ex-dividend
price process of a defaultable claim which settles at time T is given bywhere B is the discounting process, an optional strictly positive RLL semimartingale. Under
, the ex-dividend process,
, is a local optional martingale,
, i.e.,
for all
. Expression (
3) is referred to as the risk-neutral valuation formula of a defaultable claim (see
Musiela and Rutkowski (
1997);
Duffie and Singleton (
1999);
Elliott and Kopp (
1999) for its definition in usual probability spaces). For brevity, write
Combine Definitions 1 and 2 and the fact that
H is left continuous, we obtain
Remark 1 (RCLL Cash-Flow)
We have considered a general model of defaultable cash-flow, namely that the components of the cash-flow are optional RLL processes affected by default. However, we should not think that we are limited by this generalization of defaultable cash-flow. We can consider that the underlying components of defaultable cash-flow be RCLL processes affected by default, which induces a left continuous optional jump on the resultant defaultable cash-flow, and the theory of defaultable markets on optional space remains the same.
From now on, we are going to work in the deflated probability space
and let the expectation operator
to mean
—expected values under
. Next, we provide a justification of definition (
3).
3.1. Portfolio with Default
Consider a portfolio of three primary securities
, the value process of a money market account,
a default free non-dividend-paying assets, and
a dividend paying asset,
D with
, with the possibility of default. Introduce the discounted price processes
by setting
. The market lifespan is the time interval
and
is an
-optional self-financing trading strategy on
(see
Abdelghani and Melnikov (
2016) for the definition of optional self-financing trading strategies). It is straightforward to generalize the three-asset portfolio to any number of assets.
To begin with, let us examine a simple trading strategy: suppose that at time
we purchase one unit of the 0
th asset at the initial price
and holds it until time
T; then, we invest all the proceeds from dividends in the money market account. More specifically, we consider a buy-and-hold strategy
. The associated wealth process
U equals
with initial wealth
. Since
is self-financing, then
and
, where
D is the dividend paid by
. Now, let us divide
by
B, and use the product rule,
where we have used Equations (
4) and (
5). However, since
,
Then, we are able to find the simple relation
Considering the difference between the value of a defaultable portfolio at time
t, i.e.,
, and its value at maturity
T,
, we arrive at the following difference equation:
Now, we are ready to derive the risk-neutral valuation formula for the ex-dividend price
. To this end, we have assumed that our model admits a local optional martingale measure
equivalent to
such that the discounted wealth process
of any admissible self-financing trading strategy
follow local optional martingales under
with respect to the filtration
. Moreover, we make an assumption that the market value at time
t of the 0
th security comes exclusively from the future dividends stream. This means that we have to postulate that
. This postulate makes sense because the value of a defaultable cash-flow at maturity, which has paid all its value in dividends, is essentially nothing. We shall refer to
as the ex-dividend price of the 0
th asset—the defaultable claim. Given that
and Equation (
6), we arrive at the definition of the value of defaultable claim,
Hence,
is an
local optional martingale under
and
Let us now examine trading with a general self-financing trading strategy
. The associated wealth process is
. Since
is self-financing, then it must be that
for every
, where the gains process
is
As before,
, the value of our money market account,
is the dividend,
D, paying asset and
is the default-free, non-dividend paying instrument. The term “
” of the gain process is the gain acquired as a result of trading
of the 0
th asset having current value
and paid dividend
.
Theorem 1. For any self-financing trading strategy, ϕ, and , are local optional martingales and the discounted wealth process follows a local optional martingale under .
Proof. Given
, then, by the product rule we get,
where the process
is given by
. The process
is the discounted cumulative dividend price at time
t of the defaultable dividend
D. The processes
,
are local optional martingales in
. To finalize this proof, observe that, using Equation (
7), the process
satisfies
, and thus follows a local martingale under
. Hence,
is a local optional martingale in
. ☐
4. Probability of Default
The essential component of the defaultable cash-flows,
D, Equation (
2) is the default process
where
is a time-horizon. The ex-dividend price process Equation (
3) relies implicitly on the conditional expected value of
given all known up to time
t market information
. Thus, our goal for this section is to understand the conditional probability of default
, also known as the
hazard process and its properties. Associated with the hazard process
F is the
survival process , for which we will discuss some of its properties too. This section is expository, where we will simply list a few interesting related results about
F and
G. We begin by the lemma.
Lemma 2. The process is a submartingale.
Proof. Established by conditioning on for any . ☐
Lemma 3. F and G are positive. Furthermore, for a fixed time horizon, both are optional martingales. However, for a fixed time t and variable time horizon, F is a submartingale and G a supermartingale.
Proof. F and
G are positive, and one can write
For a fixed time horizon
u and any
,
is a positive optional martingale. In addition, for
,
a constant. However, for
,
, again, an optional martingale. Essentially for any fixed
u,
is an optional martingale. The same is true for
G. For a fixed,
t, and any time horizons,
, where
u and
Then,
and
Hence,
is increasing along its time horizon. Moreover, for a fixed
t and any
,
Therefore, if
, then
is a submartingale; on the other hand, if
, then we re-label
v as
t and
t as
v to get
which is also a submartingale. Hence,
F is a submartingale in either case. It follows that
is a supermartingale. ☐
On a related note,
Galchuk (
1982) showed that for the process
, where
is
-measurable and integrable random variable and
is a stopping time in the broad sense, it can be decomposed to an optional martingale that is
measurable and an
measurable continuous finite variation process. Therefore,
Corollary 1. The default process has the following decomposition, , where is an optional martingale and μ is the -compensator of H that is an -measurable continuous finite variation process.
Using the above corollary, let us consider evaluating ; for a time horizon ,
Corollary 2. and .
Proof. therefore,
Consequently, one can write,
☐
Let us now understand the relation between the process , for a stopping time in the broad sense , and the default process as regards the filtration .
Remark 2. Recall that, under the usual conditions, is known as the default process; however, in the unusual conditions, it is replaced with the process . This choice of as the default process was motivated by the fact that the known market information up to time t is on which is adapted and optional while is not. Furthermore, the forward derivative marks the occurrence of default, which is in .
Proposition 1. Let τ be a stopping time in the broad sense and , where , is RCLL and measurable or . In addition, or . and are of right-limits and left continuous paths and are . Moreover, or that .
Proof. For every , so . On the other hand, . Thus, or that . By definition, is RCLL and . Furthermore, it can be easily seen that the the process can be decomposed as, . In addition, it is obvious that . Finally, for a stopping time in the broad sense, by definition, for any time t. Moreover, since for all n, then it must be that . ☐
Let us study the properties of the process Set and consider the following lemma.
Lemma 4. The ex-hazard process can be decomposed to the default process H and the jump hazard process δ. Both and δ are whereas H is .
Proof. The optional projection
can be reduced to
where
can be derived by formula,
. ☐
Corollary 3. .
Proof. The process
is evaluated as
or
☐
Next, we discuss the absence of arbitrage in markets on unusual spaces.
5. Valuation of Defaultable Cash-Flow and Examples
Our next goal is to establish a convenient representation of the value of a defaultable cash-flow. The
ex-dividend value of defaultable cash-flow is
and, in terms of
is
We begin valuation of with the value of . Let and be a martingale. can be thought of as the default-free contingent claim price at time t. Let . G can be thought of as the survival process, whereas is the associated default process on the interval .
Lemma 5. The value of at time t is given bywhere and . Proof. Using the product rule on
we find that
Since
H is a left continuous finite variation process, the quadratic variation
We have chosen the definition
. Thus, the conditional expected value of
is
and
where we have used the fact that
since
is a local martingale,
and
. Thus, we arrive at the result
☐
Remark 3. We have replaced the integral over with an integral over the process G as a result of the following statement:where . Remark 4. How do we evaluate ? Here is how: and . Therefore,where . Hence, . Note that the event is measurable so is the projection of on . For the second term, : let thus is a local martingale. In addition, we have the following lemma.
Lemma 6. The value is given bywhere . Proof. Applying a similar argument to the one used in the above lemma, we arrive at the result
where
since
is a local martingale. ☐
As for the value of the defaultable cash-flow recovery-stream, we have the following lemma.
Lemma 7. The value of the defaultable cash-flow recovery stream is Proof. Using the sum approximation of the left optional integral, the ex-dividend value of defaultable claim is derived as follows:
Note that is measurable. ☐
Finally, we look at the process
. Let
; then,
Now, let us apply the product rule to
from
,
Using the above equation, we can write
Without loss of generality, we are going to assume that
because any dividend payment made at time
T is going to be part of the claim
paid at maturity time
T. Hence, the equation above reduces to
We are going to use this equation to prove the next lemma.
Lemma 8. The value of dividend payout stream is Proof. Using Equation (
9), the sum approximation of the left optional integral and the fact that
is
measurable, we get
where
. ☐
Consequently, we arrive at the following theorem for the ex-dividend price process.
Theorem 2. The ex-dividend
price process that settles at time T iswhere , , and . Proof. Follows from the lemmas above. ☐
In the special case where components of the dividends process are RCLL processes, we get the following corollary.
Corollary 4. Suppose we are given a defaultable cash-flow A, and R and B are RCLL. Then, the ex-dividend
price process that settles at time T is Furthermore, if and have RCLL modifications, then and for all t and Proof. Follows from the definition of the ex-dividend price process. ☐
We were able to establish a convenient representation of the value of a defaultable claim in terms of the probability of default. Now, we provide some examples.
Example 1 (Zero-Coupon Defaultable Bond). The price of a zero-coupon bond with face-value at maturity date T is at time t. On the other hand, the price of a zero-coupon bond that may experience default is . Lemma 5 tells us how to compute the price at time t. Let ; thus, and Suppose that , where , with a constant interest rate r and that the survival process admits a constant intensity γ such thatwhere is Dirac delta function at aparticular value
of default time τ. Then, At , and, at , . If , then Therefore, for a bond of face-value of at maturity date T, default decreases the present value of the bond by a factor . Hence, is a reasonable pricing formula. In addition, note that, in this simple case, the price formula we presented here matches the price formula derived with classical methods in the usual case (see the following references for comparison Duffie and Singleton (2012, p. 102); Bingham and Kiesel (2013, p. 396); Martellini et al. (2003, p. 448)). Example 2 (Credit Default Swap)
. A credit default swap () is a contract in which the holder of a defaultable asset buys an insurance against default. The elements of a are: the maturity time T, the fee rate function and the recovery function . The buyer of default protection pays a fee at a rate K up to default time τ or to maturity time T and receives the amount at default from the seller of the protection. The price of the at time t is given by the difference in price between the value of the protective leg and premium leg:where the protection price isand the premium price is Suppose K and R are constants and default admits a constant intensity γ such thatat aparticular value
of default time τ. Then, the legs prices areand Therefore, . At , 6. Absence of Arbitrage on Unusual Spaces
The no-arbitrage arguments culminated in the fundamental theorem of asset pricing: under the
usual conditions, for a real valued semimartingale X, there exists a probability measure
equivalent to
under which X is a σ-martingale
if and only if X does not permit a free lunch with vanishing risk. Given that
and
, then X is said to satisfy no free lunch with vanishing risk (NFLVR) if
where
is the closure of C in the norm topology of
Delbaen and Schachermayer (
2006).
is known as the equivalent local martingale measure (ELMM). However, in some models of financial markets, ELMM may fail to exist. An alternative was developed, an equivalent local martingale deflator (ELMD), which is a strictly positive local martingale that transforms the semimartingale X to a local martingale. It was shown that the existence of a strictly positive local martingale deflator is equivalent to the no arbitrage condition of the first kind (NA1). An
measurable random variable ζ is called an arbitrage of the first kind if
,
and for any initial wealth
if there exists an admissible ϕ such that
Kardaras (
2012). NA1 is a weaker condition than NFLVR. While extending NFLVR and NA1 and the equivalence relations ELMM and ELMD, respectively, to
unusual stochastic basis is possible and is of importance, it is definitely out of scope here. However, here we will present an argument to show the viability of financial markets and markets with defaults on
unusual probability spaces.
Again, consider a market on
un usual probability space
. Introduce the filtration
and its completion under
,
. In addition, let
be a real valued optional semimartingale that is at least of RLL paths and
is
.
is RCLL semimartingale and the stochastic basis
satisfies the usual conditions. Suppose
satisfied the conditions NFLVR with
admissible portfolio and
exits a.s.; then, there is ELMM
such that
is a local martingale, i.e., let
; then,
. Knowing that
is a local martingale under
where
is admissible, then how do we recover Y? and what is the portfolio ϕ in
? Knowing that
, we are going to employ optional projection of the space
on
to answer these questions. We begin by showing that
where “·” is the stochastic integral with respect to RCLL semimartingale
and a predictable integrand and “∘” is the stochastic integral with respect to RLL optional semimartingales Y with an optional integrand. Again, we are going to identify
with
for brevity.
Theorem 3. Let be a -local martingale. Then, a.s. .
Proof. Let
be a sequence of stopping times in
where
is a martingale for all k and
. Note that
and
. Then,
. In addition,
and
since
for all s. Moreover, if
is evolving in the interval
, then
is evolving in the interval
. Hence,
Alternatively, one can use approximation methods of stochastic integrals by sums to arrive to the same result. Thus, in the limit of a partition
of
where T is some time horizon and for any
,
where we have chosen the intervals,
, for which
. Then,
Note that the stochastic integral “·” is defined in the usual sense with respect to
and is valid under any refinement of the interval
. This allows using the intervals
where, in the limit, the integral is defined. Consider a partition of
. Then, the projection of the integral
on
is
By properties of conditional expectations and knowing that for any
,
and
is
-measurable, we get
by localization and integrability, pass the limit through the expectation,
by
Therefore, for any . Note that, in the limit, .
Lemma 9. is a local optional martingale under .
Proof. By the result of the above theorem, for any , . ☐
By the same method, we have established NFLVR in the unusual conditions, it is possible to see that if NA1 is satisfied for on then it is satisfied for Y on . Therefore, one can rest assured that if NFLVR or NA1 are satisfied for RCLL semimartingales on then they must be satisfied for their optional version by optional projection on . Hence, optional markets are free of arbitrage. The same is true for optional defaultable markets as they are a special case of optional markets, where defaultable assets and cash-flows are optional semimartingales.
In practice, it may be of interest to know how to transform a defaultable process, Y, to a local optional martingale with a strictly positive local optional martingale deflator, Z. Here, we will demonstrate, with a simple example, a method to derive Z;
Example 3. Consider as in Equation (1). However, suppose that X and x are continuous local martingales and that (see Remark 5). We are going to find a strictly positive local optional martingale deflator Z for Y. Given that and knowing that the sum of local optional martingales is a local optional martingale and that the products of Z with continuous local martingales X and are local optional martingales, then it suffices to consider finding Z such that is a local optional martingale. To do so, we choose and find the appropriate conditions that θ must satisfy so that is a local martingale. We do this as follows: With and , one can easily see that the process is a local optional martingale. Remark 5. Implicit in the definition is the fact that X and x are the default-free evolution of the components of the asset Y over its life and H is the default process. This allows us to suppose that H and are orthogonal. In reality, X and x can’t be observed in isolation of H. In defaultable markets, we observe the process . The above calculation of local martingale deflator assumes knowledge of x, X and H, and that they are related in a particular way. This is done to prove that local optional martingale deflators can be constructed for defaultable asset Y.