1. Introduction
In the past years there has been an extensive investigation of the class of stochastic volatility models for the evaluation of options and complex derivatives. These models have proven to be extremely useful in generalizing the classic Black–Scholes economy and accounting for discrepancies between observation and predictions in the simple log-normal, constant-volatility model.
Several different specifications of stochastic volatility models have been suggested. A review of the first and seminal stochastic volatility models can be found in
Ball and Roma (
1994). Among these,
Wiggins (
1987) studies a case in which the volatility (more precisely, its logarithm) follows an Ornstein—Uhlenbeck process with mean-reversion, while Hull and White, in their fundamental paper
Hull and White (
1987), exploit a Taylor expansion technique to solve their stochastic volatility option pricing problem in their framework, “the dynamics of the Hull–White stochastic volatility model predicts that both expectation and most likely value of instantaneous volatility converge to zero”
Jaeckel (
2022).
In
Stein and Stein (
1991), Stein and Stein assume that the volatility is driven by an arithmetic Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process and develop the analytic density function of stock returns to evaluate option prices.
Schobel and Zhu (
1999)’s model extends the stochastic volatility model of Stein and Stein, by using Fourier inversion techniques to allow for correlation between instantaneous volatilities and the underlying stock returns. They also derive a closed-form pricing solution for European options. One interesting aspect is that the dynamics of Stein and Stein’s model, as well as that of Schoebl and Zhu, predict that volatility is most likely close to zero.
While all pre-1990 models, including
Scott (
1987) and
Chesney and Scott (
1989), necessitate wide use of numerical techniques since they have no closed-form solutions, Heston, in his fundamental paper (
Heston 1993), in 1993 provides a new approach for deriving a closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility. Although his model was not the first stochastic volatility model introduced in the option pricing literature and although it is now many years old, it has certainly assumed great importance within this field and is still used today as a benchmark for all stochastic volatility models. From our point of view, it is interesting to note that the dynamics of Heston’s model predict that volatility can vanish (i.e., reach zero) and remain at zero for a while or remain very low or very high for long periods of time.
In
Hagan et al. (
2002), the authors derived so-called SABR models, i.e., stochastic volatility models trying to capture the volatility smile in derivatives markets. In particular, in SABR models, the forward value meets specific properties to overcome contradictions between the model and the market, such as those that emerged in the study of market smiles and skews using local volatility models. They write “market smiles and skews are usually managed by using local volatility models á la Dupire. We discover that the dynamics of the market smile predicted by local volatility models are opposite of observed market behavior: when the price of the underlying decreases, local volatility models predict that the smile shifts to higher prices; when the price increases, these models predict that the smile shifts to lower prices”. Quoting
Jaeckel (
2022) again, “the dynamics of the Hagan model predict that the expectation of volatility is constant over time, that variance of instantaneous volatility grows without limit, and that the most likely value of instantaneous volatility converges to zero”.
Another interesting paper dealing with option pricing under stochastic volatility is
Carr and Sun (
2007), in which the authors develop a new approach for pricing European-style contingent claims written on the spot price of an underlying asset whose volatility is stochastic. In
He and Zhu (
2016), an analytical approximation formula for European option pricing under a stochastic volatility model with regime-switching is derived, while in
He and Chen (
2021), the authors derive a closed-form pricing formula for European options under a stochastic volatility model with a stochastic long-term mean. The problem of option hedging and implied volatilities in the presence of stochastic volatility is addressed in
Renault and Touzi (
1996).
In
Alghalith et al. (
2020), the authors relax the assumption of constant volatility of volatility and therefore allow the volatility of volatility to vary over time. In this context, they propose novel nonparametric estimators for stochastic volatility and the volatility of volatility.
In
Hoque et al. (
2020), an interesting and relevant issue of option pricing is addressed. Specifically, the predictive power of implied volatility smirk to forecast foreign exchange return is investigated. In
Le et al. (
2021), the intraday implied volatility for pricing currency options is studied.
As for the issues relating to the estimation and computation of volatility, the reader can see, e.g.,
Liu et al. (
2019),
Wiggins 1987,
Harvey (
1998),
Breidt et al. (
1998),
Poon and Granger (
2005),
Luo et al. (
2008),
He and Zhu (
2016),
Cuchiero et al. (
2020), and references therein. In addition, for recent review papers, one can refer, e.g., to
Taylor (
1994),
Shephard and Andersen (
2009),
Shephard (
2005),
Shin (
2018), and to references therein.
As mentioned, most stochastic volatility models in the literature allow (although they do not deal with this issue) volatility to take on arbitrarily small values (or even vanish), albeit for such a short time that arbitrage opportunities are not created. It is also well known (and intuitive) that allowing the volatility to vanish will create arbitrage opportunities. This would seem to be a good reason to avoid this case from a financial point of view.
In practice, it is hardly possible to discriminate statistically between volatility processes that become arbitrarily small and processes that vanish altogether for a sufficiently small amount of time, so it might be useful to examine the structure of a model that has a volatility component effectively vanishing, with a nontrivial local time. The market described in this way allows fleeting arbitrage opportunities, so that pricing contingent claims are, a priori, not obvious.
Our paper aims at studying the structure of an options market with vanishing stochastic volatility. Specifically, we seek a pricing formula for contingent claims written on an asset with a volatility that follows a stochastic Markov process that will eventually vanish over very short time periods with probability of one. We investigate the form of pricing measures in this situation, first in a simple binomial case, and then for a diffusion model, by constructing a weak approximation in discrete space and continuous time. We deduce our main result, for the continuous time case, through a passage to the limit.
Although many papers deal with stochastic volatility and its applications, the author is not aware of any papers addressing arbitrage issues and looking for pricing formulas for contingent claims in the case of vanishing stochastic volatility.
Let us note that in the recent past, the phenomenon of very low volatility has been observed in the financial markets and the economy. As an instance, we all remember how, in 2016 and 2017, financial markets were characterized by very low volatility, raising the question of whether volatility measures may adequately reflect risks in financial markets; however, this phenomenon is not limited to 2017: volatility has been subdued for the majority of the recovery since early 2009. See, e.g.,
Hausman (
2017),
Guagliano and Ramella (
2018).
With regard to literature on market arbitrage opportunities in this framework, in
Jarrow and Protter (
2005), the authors study hidden (i.e., almost not observable) arbitrage opportunities in markets where large traders affect the price process. The arbitrage opportunities are hidden because they occur on a small set of times (typically of Lebesgue measure zero).
It is important to point out that our model and that of
Jarrow and Protter (
2005) are different, in the sense that in the latter the price process is studied and the null local time directly affects this process, whereas in our case, we consider the stochastic volatility process, and the null local time directly affects the volatility process. The two processes obviously differ in their nature and, accordingly, the types of arbitrage are also different. Still, basically, the principle is the same: there is a very short time in which arbitrage opportunities may arise.
Another interesting paper on arbitrage occurrence is
Osterrieder and Rheinlander (
2006), in which the authors study “arbitrage opportunities in diverse markets (as introduced by
Fernholz (
1999)). By a change of measure technique they can generate a variety of diverse markets. The construction is based on an absolutely continuous but non-equivalent measure change which implies the existence of instantaneous arbitrage opportunities in diverse markets”.
The content of the paper is organized as follows. In
Section 2, we introduce our problem. Then, after a brief description of the notation in
Section 3,
Section 4 details the class of models under consideration. In
Section 5 we discuss the general case: first, we study discrete-time models that shed some light on the pricing of options under these circumstances. Then, we deduce our main result, for the continuous time case, through a passage to the limit. Finally, after a brief explicit discussion of a simple model in
Section 6, we devote
Section 7 to possible interpretations and practical implications of our models. We draw our conclusions in
Section 8.
2. The Problem
Consider a diffusion-type model for the evolution of the price of an asset:
Here,
and
are processes adapted to a filtration
, describing the information structure. Especially, assume that the volatility
itself follows a stochastic Markov process:
where
is a Brownian motion assumed, for simplicity, to be independent of
.
We will look at the problem of pricing for a contingent claim written on this asset.
For convenience, we will often work with the logarithm of the price process, rather than the price itself. Thus, we rewrite our model as
where
Y is the logarithm of the price of the asset (or a vector of assets, if
, and the volatility is itself a diffusion process. Again,
W and
B are independent standard Brownian motions. By Itô’s rule, if
,
, and, under an equivalent martingale measure,
In general, is an adapted process, and the drift term for Y will be . Under the martingale measure, the new drift will thus be and .
Remark 1. In the following, we will resort to continuous time jump processes. A continuous time jump process could be defined with equations similar to (3), where the Brownian driving noises are replaced by Poisson martingales, . With appropriate rescaling, these SDEs can be made to converge weakly to (3) (see, for example, Ethier and Kurtz (1986), Ikeda and Watanabe (1981)). We should point out that
is not in itself a
physical quantity, since it is
that has an actual interpretation, as infinitesimal variance rate. It is thus advisable, if a model is written for
instead of
, that it avoids
to change sign for definiteness, preventing it from turning negative. It is also well known (and intuitive) that allowing
to vanish will allow arbitrage opportunities to arise (see., e.g.,
Duffie (
1996)). This would seem a good reason to avoid this case from a financial point of view. However, most stochastic volatility models, as we said in the Introduction, will let
take arbitrarily small values or even vanish, albeit for such a
short time that no arbitrage opportunities actually arise (see, for instance, respectively,
Bjork (
2009) for a log-normal model, and
Heston (
1993) for a CIR-like model). Technically, this corresponds to the fact that the boundary
acts as a natural or a no-exit entrance boundary for the volatility process (see, e.g.,
Revuz and Yor (
1991)). In such a situation, no additional boundary condition can be imposed at
.
It is, however, possible to construct models that keep nonnegative by imposing an appropriate behavior at a boundary, for instance, through a reflecting boundary condition at . In this case, the process displays a local time measuring, in a sense, the time spent at the boundary, and even if the Lebesgue measure of the set of ts where the process stays on the boundary is zero, it accumulates to a finite value.
In practice, it is hardly possible to discriminate statistically between volatility processes that become arbitrarily small and processes that vanish altogether for a sufficiently small amount of time, so it might be useful to examine the structure of a model that has a volatility component that effectively vanishes, with a nontrivial local time. In such a situation, pricing contingent claims are, a priori, not obvious, since the market allows arbitrage opportunities to arise briefly. In this paper, we address this question and look for a pricing formula for contingent claims. The case of American options with stochastic volatility (but no arbitrage) has been discussed, e.g., in
Mastroeni (
1998).
4. The Model
Consider again (
1). Assume that
is a continuous process, adapted to
, and
is a diffusion process, driven by a Brownian motion
, which, for simplicity, we will take to be independent of
.
Such an assumption simplifies proofs, but is not essential, as far as general theorems go (see, e.g., Chapter 14 in
Bjork (
2009)). It does affect the ability to compute explicit formulas in simple models. We assume, without further comment, that there is a unique strong solution for any set of initial conditions. Additional technical assumptions, satisfied by standard models, will be made later. For simplicity, we will assume a zero riskless borrowing rate, i.e., all prices are already discounted.
For convenience, we will often work with the logarithm of the price process, rather than the price itself, .
The solution to (
1) is, in principle, adapted to the filtration
. Note that
, in itself, has no
physical meaning, since only
can be interpreted as infinitesimal variance and can be observed, at least in principle. In fact,
, so that if
with probability of one, it turns out that
, even though not Markovian, still carries all the relevant information included in
(in fact, for any
t,
will be measurable with respect to
, where
). On the other hand, a model where
is allowed to change sign, and such that
strictly, might have little practical significance. Thus, we will restrict ourselves to the case when
a.s. .
It is well known (see, e.g.,
Bjork (
2009)) that an
equivalent martingale measure will exist if Girsanov’s theorem can be applied to (
1) and allow for an equivalent measure under which the price process
S, discounted with the riskless rate, will be a martingale.
Taking into account
, we rewrite our model as
where, as said earlier,
is the logarithm of the price of the asset (or a vector of assets, if
, and the volatility is itself a diffusion process. Again,
and
are independent standard Brownian motions. By Itô’s rule,
, and, under an equivalent martingale measure,
. In general,
is an adapted process, and the drift term for
will be
. Under the martingale measure, the new drift will thus be
and
.
Girsanov’s theorem will apply if the local martingale
is a martingale. Here,
Here, is the market price of risk for the volatility, (i.e., a measure of the extra return, or risk premium, that investors demand to bear risk). Since this is not a traded asset, the choice for is essentially arbitrary, tied to the attitude towards the volatility risk of a given investor. This arbitrariness is tied to the incompleteness of the market and the non-uniqueness of any martingale measure. For simplicity, we will make a choice, e.g., , but our arguments do not essentially depend on any particular choice.
Remark 2. Note that, as well known in the literature, in our model the financial market is not complete and, thus, even if an equivalent martingale measure does exist, it will not generally be unique. In fact, roughly speaking, we can change the stochastic volatility measure without changing the fact that the stock is a martingale; thus, we will have payoffs that have different values under different measures, i.e., the market is incomplete. We will not address this question and assume that a market price of risk
for the volatility has been established. See Bjork (2009) for details.
The martingale condition is equivalent to
. A sufficient condition for this is, for instance,
(see, e.g.,
Karatzas and Shreve (
1991)).
A simple computation will show that models where
is allowed to vanish with probability of one may fail to satisfy Girsanov’s condition. This is equivalent to violating the
no free lunch condition and
almost equivalent to violating the no-arbitrage condition (see, e.g.,
Duffie (
1996)). This could be a reasonable motivation for considering only models that do not exhibit this behavior at all.
However, this restriction does not seem completely natural. For instance, it is very hard to check empirically, compared to a model with arbitrarily small volatility, such as log-normal or CIR-like models. Moreover, it seems worthwhile to examine how a market where the Girsanov theorem does not apply will actually behave.
In the following we will look at the pricing of European options for models where the volatility processes stay nonnegative, but are allowed to vanish.
Precisely, we will consider the case of a regular diffusion with reflection at 0. Much more general boundary conditions, constraining the volatility to the nonnegative axis but allowing for very different behaviors at zero, could be handled along the same lines.
Remark 3. Asian options (where the payoff depends on ) present no further features, since they can be treated by simply adjoining an extra equation of the form . Though the resulting price process is degenerate, Girsanov’s theorem still applies (see Albeverio et al. (1992)). Similarly, a wide class of exotic options falls within the realms of the following discussions. Assuming reflecting boundary conditions at , it is easy to see that Girsanov’s theorem will generally fail; hence, our model allows for arbitrage. Although this is very intuitive, we should note that the set is very thin: for regular diffusion models, though uncountable, it will have Lebesgue measure zero. On the other hand, arbitrage is only possible at time . The following discussion suggests that standard arguments can be extended to allow for fair pricing of a contingent claim, even in this case.
In order to achieve this, our argument will start from discrete-time and/or discrete-space approximating models. One could say that these models are, in some sense, more realistic descriptions of the market and that diffusion models are only convenient limits motivated by the enormous speed and volume of modern trading. If so, pricing for a diffusion model can be obtained by taking appropriate limits. In other words, since the lack of a paradigm for pricing under the present circumstances prevents direct pricing in a continuous-time, continuous-space model, we take the limit pricing from a discrete model as the definition of a fair price.
6. A Simple Explicit Example
Consider the simplest reflecting volatility model, i.e., reflecting Brownian motion. In this case, the process
would have the same distribution as
. For a simple conditional log-normal price model
with
Brownian motion independent of
, according to our discussion, the pricing equation would be given by (keeping a zero riskless rate)
which can easily be solved as
In this case, our result states that the Hull and White formula (8) in
Hull and White (
1987) still applies even with reflecting volatility. Explicitly, the exponent is a random variable, with distribution, conditional on a path
, equal to
. Let us stress how the presence of a reflected stochastic volatility prevents the construction of an equivalent martingale measure, and offers the opportunity of arbitrage. Indeed, in Equation (
14),
is a constant, so there will be a positive risk premium even when local time is increasing, and, for a time of Lebesgue measure 0, there is no risk. This zero-measure is a consequence of the idealized continuous time model. However, as sketched in
Section 7, there is no arbitrage when conditioned on
, and this allows us to provide a
fair pricing equation as listed in
Section 5.
Denote by
the density of the distribution of
, and by
the log-normal density corresponding to
and
the normal density. It is clear that the following formula holds for the price of a European contingent claim with payoff
, written on this asset:
The Laplace transform of
is known (see, e.g.,
Kirillov and Gvishiani (
1982), or computed easily, by a Girsanov transform between Brownian motion and an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process) and equal to
7. Conditionally Non-Vanishing Volatilities
In this section, we address some issues related to the evolution of stochastic volatility in different situations, possible model interpretations, and practical implications. In these different situations, the correct model is not (
5) any longer: specifically, the volatility equation has to be modified appropriately. In particular, in this section we describe the corresponding occurrence of a breakdown in the availability of an equivalent martingale measure in the different situations.
We discussed in the previous sections how to handle options within a model where volatility is allowed to vanish in a way that allows arbitrage opportunities. Let
denote the first hitting time at zero for the volatility process. Generally, even though
almost surely, a reasonable model will give high probability to high values for this random variable. Specifically, since most trading occurs over a finite horizon, say
T, it is reasonable to wonder what practical implications a finite but very large
may have, since
will be small. We could thus consider our model, conditioned on the event that no actual arbitrage opportunities will arise within this finite horizon. This would take us back into familiar territory, but the conditioned model will have a significantly different form from its unconditioned
parent. Equivalently, we could work with the version of Girsanov’s theorem for non-equivalent measures (see
Lenglart (
1977)), since, in fact, the distribution of the process conditioned to
is absolutely continuous, albeit not equivalent, to the unconditioned distribution. The present argument could just as well be cast in the language used by
Lenglart (
1977).
Consider an option to be exercised at (no later than) time
T. We might want to consider its value depending on whether
or not. Again, for simplicity, let us fix
and assume that the second equation in (
5) allows
where
, while
.
Consider a stopping time (e.g., for some small ) and the process . Denote the distribution of by . Note that, on , . Applying Girsanov’s theorem to , we thus see that there exists (at least) a probability measure on such that, under , on , . A trader will have access to the present value of , but has no way of predicting when (and if) will actually touch zero. Until such an event arises, a trader might assume that the market does not allow for arbitrage at all. In fact, she/he would be working conditional on , where T is the time horizon under which she/he is trading. Most reasonable volatility models will indeed imply where is a small number. We could thus rewrite the model under and a pricing formula can be established on this -field using .
Note that
and, for sufficiently small
,
will be
almost the
right measure for the financial market.
However, working under this conditional measure, clearly, the correct model is not (
5) any longer; specifically, the volatility equation has to be modified appropriately.
To illustrate the situation quickly, consider the simple case of reflecting Brownian motion. For Brownian motion starting at
(see, e.g.,
Ito and McKean (
1974)),
For fixed
, probability is quickly going to one as
and
. A realistic model for the volatility will presumably have even lower values, since it might include features such as mean reversion towards a positive value. If we now condition on
, Brownian motion, starting at 0 and remaining positive for
, will be turned into a
Brownian meander (see
Durrett et al. (
1977),
Revuz and Yor (
1991), and
Pitman and Yor (
1996); see also
Ito and McKean (
1974)).
These considerations suggest the following description of the evolution of the stochastic volatility and the corresponding occurrence of a breakdown in the availability of an equivalent martingale measure:
The time axis is split into two sets, depending on whether is positive or vanishes.
The set
is a zero Lebesgue measure, uncountable, set with no isolated points. Levy’s local time
(see
Ito and McKean (
1974)) provides a time scale that serves as a
clock of the timespan over which arbitrage can occur. Note that the
, for an adapted process
, represents the arbitrage profit that can be realized by a trading strategy
, to take advantage of the difference between the riskless lending rate (which we are setting at zero) and the (certain, while
) return rate of the underlying asset.
The complement of
,
, is a union of open intervals. The distribution of the lengths of these intervals has been extensively studied (see
Jeanblanc et al. (
1996)).
Over each component of , performs an excursion. As known, a Brownian excursion process is a stochastic process that is closely related to a Brownian motion. In particular, a Brownian excursion process is a Brownian motion conditioned to be positive and to take the value 0 at time 1 (assuming it is normalized). Alternatively, it is a Brownian bridge process conditioned to be positive. More generally, we can think of the path of as a sequence of bridges over some random time intervals. Over these, equivalent martingale measures can be used for pricing, conditional on a non-vanishing volatility during the lifetime of the option.
Upon reaching a zero for the volatility (often an event of minimal probability for finite time horizons), the pricing measure
breaks down, in the sense that it is no longer equivalent to the physical measure. The fact is that it acts as if the second term in (
15) could be safely ignored since it is singular with respect to the corresponding measure. Of course, the relevance of this problem depends on
, i.e., it reduces to a subjective judgment call.
Using the reflecting volatility model allows for tractable formulas, at least in the simplest cases.
8. Conclusions
In this paper, we look at the problem of pricing for a contingent claim written on an asset with a volatility that follows a stochastic Markov process itself that will eventually vanish for very short periods with probability of one. Specifically, we look at the pricing of European options for models where the volatility processes stay nonnegative, but are allowed to vanish. Precisely, we consider the case of a regular diffusion with reflection at 0.
We investigate the form of pricing measures in this situation, first in a simple binomial case, and then for a diffusion model, by constructing a weak approximation in discrete space and continuous time.
In such a situation, pricing contingent claims are, a priori, not obvious, since the market allows arbitrage opportunities to arise briefly. Nevertheless, we can still produce a fair pricing equation.
Although many papers deal with stochastic volatility and its applications, the author is not aware of any papers addressing arbitrage issues and looking for pricing formulas for contingent claims in the case of vanishing stochastic volatility.
Let us note that, in the recent past, the phenomenon of very low volatility has actually been observed in the financial markets and the economy. As an instance, we all recall how, in 2016 and 2017, financial markets were characterized by very low volatility, raising the question of whether volatility measures adequately reflect risks in financial markets, but this phenomenon is not limited to 2017: volatility has been subdued for the majority of the recovery since early 2009.