1. Introduction
Governments attending the Paris Climate Conference in December 2015 [
1] declared their commitment to keeping world temperature levels at no more than two degrees higher than pre-industrial levels. The presumption is that it is feasible to achieve this target through environmental policies, which may take the form of market interventions through taxes and subsidies, regulations, or information and persuasion. One question for society is: ‘How effective will these policies be?’ A second question is: ‘Will there be public support for any of these policies?’ Education may play a role in developing experts who will design and evaluate policies. It may also play a role in developing public understanding [
2]. According to [
3], the public understanding of climate change in the US is riddled with misconceptions, which influence individual behaviour and attitudes towards government interventions to promote environmental sustainability. One place where we might expect to observe an educational effect is in undergraduate economics. Economists play prominent roles in the design of government policies and an economics education might be expected to dispel misconceptions about the efficacy of policy instruments. However, education faces substantial challenges in changing attitudes, not least in the context of societal response to environmental problems [
4].
Studies of curriculums and textbooks in economics show that a sustainability perspective can be hard to integrate within mainstream economics, not least at an undergraduate level. At the same time, introductory economics deals with concepts that are highly relevant from a sustainability perspective. These references are concentrated in microeconomics, such as market interventions to deal with negative externalities (e.g., government regulation on pollution) (cf. [
5,
6]). Existing evidence tells us rather little about the effect of economic teaching on the understanding of, and attitudes towards, environmental issues [
7]. We know very little about the effects of basic knowledge in economics on sustainability attitudes, even though it is common in many countries to take introductory courses in economics, or take economics as a minor, while majoring in another discipline.
We investigated the role of current undergraduate teaching in economics on students’ support for alternative instruments in environmental policy. We examined the change in knowledge and support for policies amongst undergraduate economists. Across our whole sample, we found a small increase in support for, and belief in, the efficacy of market-based interventions, relative to non-market based interventions. However, we did not find an association between the knowledge of relevant economic policies and the support for their use.
The paper is organised as follows. First, we review existing research, which informed the framing of the research questions. We then describe the collection of data through two surveys of undergraduate students, before presenting our results. The paper concludes with a discussion of possible interpretations of our results and the implications these may have for teaching, policy, and future research.
4. Results
4.1. Changes in Policy Attitudes among Students in Economics after One Semester
Aggregate results are summarised in
Table 5. These show a small increase in economics students’ acceptance of market-based instruments and a small decrease in acceptance of non-market-based instruments. The increase in the acceptance of market-based policies was largely driven by greater support for the use of subsidies. Survey responses from other students studying law or politics did not show a significant change regarding market-based institutions. Law students do, however, become less accepting of the other instruments.
4.2. Changes in Knowledge among Students in Economics after One Semester
First, we observed no difference between the students enrolled in economics modules and the students enrolled in law and politics modules, in terms of the average performance on the economics multiple choice questions in the first survey. There did not appear to be any self-selection effect on the knowledge of economics. However, the students enrolled on the economics modules improved their performance on the two questions that were included in both surveys. The proportion of students in economics modules giving the correct answer increased from 34% to 51% on question 1 (on supply, demand, and the efficiency of markets), and from 32% to 45% on question 2 (on government policy to address market failure in the context of environmental problems). There was no change between the two surveys in the performance of students enrolled on the law and politics modules. These comparisons suggest (i) that the improvement in the performance of the economics students was not the result of repeated testing with the same questions and (ii) that the questions did capture elements of the economic reasoning which the economics teaching was intending to develop.
For the third question about “externalities”, where the question is exchanged between the first and second step, we found that there are no substantial differences between economists (18%) and the other students (22%) in the first survey. In the second survey, the differences are larger, as 66% of the economics students chose the correct answer, while only 41% of the other students chose the correct answer. This question is not included in the further analyses.
The aggregate analysis suggests that students enrolled in economics modules improved their understanding of economics, became more convinced about the efficacy of market-based policies, and became more positive towards those policies. We then compared the policy attitudes of those students in the economics modules who answered the economics knowledge questions correctly, and those who did not. We found no significant difference. This result might be generated by confounding differences at an individual level, so we now turn to individual level multivariate analysis.
4.3. Cross-Sectional Analysis of Knowledge and Preferences at Wave 2
We conducted cross-sectional regression analyses to examine associations between knowledge and policy preference after one semester of economics. The results are presented in
Table 6. The knowledge variable in
Table 6 is the aggregate of scores for the three multiple choice questions included in the second survey. We found no relationship between the end of semester knowledge and attitudes towards market-based instruments, but students who scored more highly on the knowledge questions, were less likely to support non-market instruments.
Table 6 suggests two powerful influences upon attitudes towards environmental policy instruments. Students with a strong commitment to environmental sustainability and students who had more trust in political institutions, were much more likely to support either market-based or non-market intervention.
4.4. Longitudinal Difference-in-Difference Analysis of Relationships between Knowledge and Attitudes
Finally, we examined the relationships between a change in attitude to environmental policies and a change in knowledge.
Table 7 shows that we found no relationship between a change in knowledge and a change in attitudes. In fact, we found that students with a strong prior commitment to environmental sustainability strengthen their support for government intervention either through the market, or through other means. The final analysis, which examines whether there actually is a causal effect between knowledge and policy preference, is a difference in difference model. This model takes the longitudinal aspect of the study into account and therefore, could be claimed to better capture the causality between knowledge and policy preferences. The results are presented in
Table 7. From these analyses, we do not find any relationship between the knowledge and acceptance of different environmental policy measures.
5. Discussion
We found that undergraduate students who enrolled in a module in introductory microeconomics improved their economic reasoning in ways that might be expected to influence their attitudes towards policies. Moreover, we did find that, on average, these students became slightly more supportive of market-based government environmental policies and slightly less supportive of non-market policies. However, our individual level analysis found no relationship between a change in attitude and a change in knowledge. This could be because our measures of economic reasoning were not sufficiently powerful to detect a change. However, aggregate students’ performance on our main two questions increased from a success rate of 34%, to a success rate of 51% on one question, and from a success rate of 32%, to a success rate of 45% on another question. These changes indicate some substantive shifts in understanding which might be expected to influence attitudes. Moreover, our results are rather robust to alternative analyses, using different dependent variables (acceptance/perceived efficiency of different tools) and different operational definitions of our main independent variable (knowledge indices, question by question).
One possible explanation for the change in aggregate attitudes to policy instruments is that there is a ‘socialisation effect’ in economics teaching, which encourages a sense that market-based interventions are more normal than non-market interventions. One element in this may be a form of socialisation identified by [
42], as ‘following the ancestral leader’. Harring’s study [
33] showed how undergraduates converge towards acceptance of the views of their professor. However, there may also be a deeper level process at work. Undergraduates are inducted into the discipline of economics with the mantra that the subject offers a ‘positive’ depiction of the world that is free from any value judgements [
43]. Market solutions provide the focus for teaching (marginalising other forms of policy) and these solutions are also idealised as offering the best hope for the efficient maximisation of human welfare. Assumptions and values underpinning this focus and idealisation are largely hidden from view.
One possible explanation for the absence of a relationship at an individual level between attitudes and knowledge, is that attitudes are framed by powerful values that are resistant to change. Our data suggest that the attitudes to environmental policies examined in this study are very strongly framed by environmental values in a manner anticipated by value-belief-norm theory [
21] and the theory of planned behaviour [
44]. This interpretation presents a challenge to the traditional assumption of mainstream economics, that positive and normative judgements belong to separate domains.
Alternatively, it could be that the introductory undergraduate economics curriculum gives lecturers and students little space to explore the implications for policy of the principles that students are being encouraged to accept. It may, of course, be argued that economics major undergraduates will spend subsequent years engaging with the implications of economic analysis, for policies in different spheres. However, this leaves two questions to be answered, that have received little attention in previous research. First, to what extent does the treatment of relationships between theory and policy in first year economics build assumptions and beliefs about the subject which may prove problematic in subsequent study? [
45] and, what happens to those students who only study economics for one semester?
We now consider some possible implications of these interpretations for the ‘public understanding of economics’, and the development of attitudes and reasoning amongst future experts in economics. Economic analysis strongly features in policy debate over public response to environmental problems. Public understanding of economics matters because (i) it constrains what policies are likely to achieve and (ii) the popularity of policies amongst voters affects policy makers’ choices. A large proportion of undergraduates enrolled in first year economics modules do not proceed to an economics major. Therefore, it is pertinent to ask what influence this experience has upon the development of their attitudes towards economic policies, as well as the development of their economic understanding. Normalisation of the belief that governments can guide markets towards more efficient solutions through ‘environmental’ taxes and subsidies, would increase the scope for governments to intervene in this way. Of course, we cannot presume that governments would necessarily use this scope to act wisely. Therefore, the belief that this would be ‘a good thing’ largely depends on attitudes towards the balance between individual and collective responses to environmental issues and, therefore, belief in ‘the tragedy of the commons’.
Our results raise an important question for the training of economists, who may exert substantial influence over the shape of future policy. We do find evidence that a single semester of teaching substantially improved undergraduates’ understanding of some basic economic ideas. This is encouraging for teaching. However, we detected no relationship between changing understanding and changing attitudes to policy. This is troublesome for a profession that claims that its policy advice is derived solely from its rational analysis. There is a possibility that new economists are trained to believe that their own judgements are ‘objective’, when in fact they have been forged through normalisation, as they are inducted into the discipline.
Our research, therefore prompts some suggestions for future research. There is a need for better evidence on the relative effect of increasing economics understanding and social normalisation on the development of attitudes towards environmental policies. There is also a need for research into the effect of changing teaching strategies and changing the quantity of economics teaching on the development of attitudes towards, and beliefs about, environmental issues. In an era when the role of expert knowledge in policy formation seems to be diminishing, there is an imperative for disciplines to re-examine the ways in which they are shaping collective futures.