Next Article in Journal
The Consequences of Corruption on Inflation in Developing Countries: Evidence from Panel Cointegration and Causality Tests
Next Article in Special Issue
Estimating the Effects of Human Capital Constraints on Innovation in the Caribbean
Previous Article in Journal
An Inverse Problem Study: Credit Risk Ratings as a Determinant of Corporate Governance and Capital Structure in Emerging Markets: Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies
Previous Article in Special Issue
A Firm-Level Investigation of Innovation in the Caribbean: A Comparison of Manufacturing and Service Firms
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Do Technological Innovations Affect Unemployment? Some Empirical Evidence from European Countries

by
Kristina Matuzeviciute
1,*,
Mindaugas Butkus
1 and
Akvile Karaliute
2
1
Department of Economics, Šiauliai University, Šiauliai LT-77156, Lithuania
2
Department of Economics, Vytautas Magnus University, Kaunas LT-44246, Lithuania
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2017, 5(4), 48; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5040048
Submission received: 16 October 2017 / Revised: 25 November 2017 / Accepted: 28 November 2017 / Published: 7 December 2017
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Innovation and Economic Development)

Abstract

:
This paper analyses theoretical and empirical scientific literature about the impact of technological innovations on unemployment, considering the former as a key driver of long-term productivity and economic growth. Using panel data from 25 European countries for the period of 2000–2012, we aim to examine whether technological innovations affect unemployment. We used triadic patent families per million inhabitants as our main proxy for technological innovations, as well as other unemployment controls, in our model, which were estimated using System Generalized Method of Moments (SGMM). Finding no significant relationship between technological innovations and unemployment in our base estimation, we re-estimated it testing the impact with a time lag as well as using alternative proxies for technological innovations. Overall, the research estimations do not suggest that technological innovations have an effect on unemployment.
JEL Classification:
O33; E24; O52

1. Introduction

For more than two centuries, since the very beginning of the Industrial Revolution, the global economy has been moving rapidly forward due to new technologies. Each new technological wave has a positive effect on economic growth, productivity and opportunities for new business types. The researchers in many ways define the impact of innovation on labor market parameters: employment, unemployment, labor demand, wages and etc. One approach (Say 2009; Schumpeter 2017) suggests that technological progress leads to process and product innovation, which, in turn, leads to job creation. According to others (Wood 2004; Feldmann 2013), technological change can increase unemployment. Liso and Leoncini (2011) state that technological advancement provides opportunities for higher wages for skilled workers due to increased demand, while others (Piva et al. 2006) note that technological change negatively influences skilled and unskilled workers. As Alonso-Borrego and Collado (2002) noticed, technological innovation is one of the main sources for the creation and destruction of jobs.
Technological innovation is understood as a systematic, on-going, non-reflexive and managed process (Garud et al. 1997) is one of the key driving forces influencing long-term productivity and economic growth. As a result, the innovation process and the impact of the actions necessary to identify technological change are of interest to companies, governments and academics. It should be noted that innovation is sometimes viewed as a phenomenon that can also have negative effects associated with unemployment.
During the past three decades, much attention was paid to skill-biased technological change that firstly was empirically explored by Berman et al. (1994) who proved the existence of strong correlations between industry skill upgrading and increased investment in both computer technology and R&D in the U.S. manufacturing sector. Caselli and Coleman (2006) argue that developed countries use skilled labor more efficiently than developing countries that is caused by technology adoption because developed countries are skilled-labor-abundant and they choose technologies suitable for skilled labor while developing countries are low skilled-labor-abundant and they use technologies appropriate to unskilled labor. Acemoglu and Autor (2011) state that skill-based technological change reduces the demand for routine jobs that can be computerized.
Taking into account various effects revealed in scientific literature that innovations have on labor market as well as little empirical research at macro level on how innovations affect unemployment, in this paper we aim to examine nexus between technological innovation and unemployment in European countries. Technological innovation and its impact on labor market is a topic of great interest because it reveals the tendencies and the problems labor market encounters due to technological change. This paper, analyzing this topic, has four main novelties vis-à-vis previous literature in the area. First, this paper uses a unique dataset, which merges 25 European countries. Second, this paper investigates macro level research what is rare in the scientific literature of this topic. Third, triadic patent families to population as a measure of technological innovation is very new. Fourth, this paper investigates the impact of both triadic patent families to population (as a measure for innovation outputs) and R&D expenditures (as a measure for innovation inputs) on unemployment (two different measures—two different comparable results).
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: related literature concerning the nexus between technological innovation and unemployment is reviewed in Section 2. Section 3 presents model and data with descriptive statistics as well as estimation technique. The empirical findings are presented in Section 4 and Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Literature Review

2.1. The Nexus between Technological Innovation and Unemployment

Schumpeter introduced the concept of innovation in the 20th century, describing it as an industrial mutation describing it as an industrial mutation which is constantly changing the economic structure from within, destroying the old one while creating a new one. This is called as the process of creative destruction (Schumpeter 2008). According to J. A. Schumpeter, technological breakthrough will not be regarded as innovation if it does not generate economic or net profit growth. Hence, innovation can be understood as the basis of competition and the key driver of economic development.
According to Barnhizer (2016), it is not people but the convergence of technological innovations that more and more influences the nature of work, economy, social inequality and the existence of a middle class. The fact that developed economies, such as Western European countries and the United States, face the technological convergence is in line with Schumpeter’s idea of creative destruction but with a warning about the destructive destruction of economic and institutional forms. Power and technology are pushing the society in this direction.
The importance of innovation is increasing and it is relevant to understand a different role of various types of innovation. All innovations, throughout history, have been categorized in many ways. The variety of approaches for categorizing innovations considers many different aspects and it helps to measure and allow comparing innovations. Four types of innovations—product, process, marketing and organizational—are defined in The Oslo Manual1 (OECD 2005). This paper concerns the impact of technological innovation on unemployment, hence, only product and process innovations are the interest of this paper, because, as Ramanauskienė (2010) and Hoover (2012) mentioned, there are two types of technological innovation:
  • Product. It is linked to the revolution of new breakthroughs: the use of new materials and components, the acquisition of new products, such as telegraph, railways, cars, radio, etc. This leads to a qualitative improvement of life and opens up new opportunities in various areas. Technological progress makes it possible to produce more with lower costs.
  • Process. It means new production organization methods (new technologies). An example of process innovations is H. Ford’s idea of producing replaceable parts, assembling production lines, what allowed to produce cheap cars.
As Flichy (2007) states, the separation of process and product innovation is often artificial. However, it should be noted that the latter classification is mostly used in scientific research assessing the impact of technological innovations on labor market parameters.
There is a contradiction between researchers about the impact of product and process innovation on employment. According to Vivarelli (2014), Harrison et al. (2008), researchers distinguish two key aspects—product innovation provides new products on the market, which stimulates a new demand—this leads to a positive relationship between technological change and employment (Van Reenen 1997; Bogliacino and Vivarelli 2012; Vivarelli 2014; Marcolin et al. 2016) and process innovation leads to a negative effect on the labor force due to the replacement of labor with new machines, equipment and an increase in productivity and efficiency of firms (Van Reenen 1997; Peters 2004; Pianta 2004; Vivarelli 2014). In general, since the technological changes make it possible to produce in lower costs, a direct effect of innovation is technological unemployment. This idea contradicts Schumpeter’s statement that technological progress leads to process and product innovation, which naturally leads to job creation (Ziemnowicz 2013). According to Marxist philosophy, it is inconceivable that newly-engineered labor-saving machines could create a sufficient number of jobs (Wood 2004).
An overview of research by Feldmann (2013) notes that most of them prove that technological change can increase unemployment in certain circumstances and in some cases even in the long run and this confirms the 19th century Malthus’ statement that a rising demand for a product due to reduced prices is unlikely to be sufficient as demand for redundant workers is decreasing. Profit growth cannot be sufficient unless the companies firstly invest in capital-intensive technologies. Finally, lower wages may be a reason that companies will not be encouraged to hire more employees due to a reduced demand for products. As a result of all these factors, innovation leads to technological unemployment (Malthus 2008; Vivarelli 2014), which leads to the fact that some workers lose their jobs, as a direct consequence of labor-saving innovation. Autor (2015) states that there is no long-run increase in unemployment caused by technological progress but changes in technology affect the types of jobs available. Some people (according to their occupation’s probability of computerization) are at a high, medium or low risk (Frey and Osborne 2017). Brynjolfsson and McAfee (2011) also acknowledge ideas about the deep changes that computerization is bringing but, as the authors note, these changes can become more valuable because people who had the wrong skills now can find more valuable skills and be more desirable for employers.
Despite this concern, the economic theory points out the existence of indirect effects that can counterbalance the reduction in employment (Bogliacino and Vivarelli 2012; Vivarelli 2015). The proponents of classical economic theory have raised the theory, the one that K. Marx later referred to as the theory of compensation: technological changes can lead to various market compensation mechanisms: new machines, lower prices, new investments and lower wages (Vivarelli 2014). These compensation mechanisms can offset the initial influence of labor-saving innovation in process innovation (Meschi et al. 2016).
Taking into account all provisions, the results from theoretical studies do not provide clear-cut answer about the impact of technological innovation on unemployment. There is a confrontation between two views: one states that labor-saving innovations create technological unemployment, the other view argues about questionable compensation mechanisms, resulting from prices and new demand, that absorb unemployment (Piva and Vivarelli 2005). Therefore, empirical analyses, that reveal and prove the results received in different ways with different methods, different measurement instruments, are needed that can take into account the overall impact of technological innovation on unemployment.

2.2. Empirical Research on the Quantitative Assessment of Technological Innovations’ Impact on Labor Market Parameters

In most research, R&D expenditures are a measure of innovation inputs and patents are a measure of outputs (Fai and von Tunzelmann 2001; Bonanno 2016; Vivarelli 2014, 2015). Although Kromann et al. (2011) argue that the best variable reflecting technological changes in the economy is R&D expenditures, the patents, as Kortum (1997) suggests, is the main technological variable reflecting the important aspects of the technological process and, presumably, “correlating with the immeasurable dimensions of technological change.” However, according to Feldmann (2013), Dernis and Kahn (2004), the following limitations on the calculation of patents under their registration at the national patent office can be pointed out: first, the registration of patents in one office varies greatly according to their technical and economic significance; secondly, it is difficult to compare them internationally, since they are affected by local preferences and geographic location. For these reasons, the number of triadic patent families per one million inhabitants (independent/exogenous variable) which avoids these limitations is used in the research as the main output indicator of technological innovation. Triadic patents are patents registered in three patent systems: the European Patent Organization, the US Patent and Trademark Office and the Japanese Patent Office. This indicator is recommended to be used in all macro-level studies aimed to assess technological progress. In addition, this indicator falls into the European Union (EU) aggregate innovation index as one of the indicators of the intellectual property factor group—another argument justifying the significance of this indicator.
It should be noted that this variable also has disadvantages: (i) triadic patents do not differ between product and process innovation; (ii) SMEs rely less on patenting than large companies and that produces bias, since the average size of firms varies from country to country; (iii) some industries rely more on patents than others, which reflects a further bias, as the structure of industries varies between countries; (iv) the significance of triadic patent families varies among families; (v) application for the patent and its registration abroad costs money, so patents of a lower value are usually only completed in the country of the inventor, despite the fact that the European Patent Organization, the US Patent and Trademark Office and the Japanese Patent Office propose to take into account the potentially higher value of patents when they are registered with all three organizations (Feldmann 2013).
There are relatively very few research on the impact of technological innovations on labor market parameters at macro level. According to Vivarelli (2014), the macroeconomic studies of innovation impact on employment are limited to the period 1980–1990 and microeconomic studies began later and now are more frequent. As this research considers macro level effect, only previous empirical research at macro level are presented in Table 1 and research on technological innovation impact on labor market parameters at sectoral and micro level are presented in Appendix A.
Macro level research explore the impact of technological innovations on the economy as a whole. However, analyzed research (see Table 1) provides an unambiguous answer about the impact of technological innovation on labor market parameters. Feldmann (2013) in his research showed that technological progress increases unemployment in the short term but, for example, Marcolin et al. (2016) proved that technological innovation has a positive effect on employment.
As noticed in the theoretical analysis, the empirical analysis usually also distinguishes the impact of product and process innovations on labor market parameters. Authors (e.g., Blanchflower and Burgess 1998; Greenan and Guellec 2000; Greenhalgh et al. 2001; Hall et al. 2008; Harrison et al. 2008; etc.) find a positive relationship between product innovation and employment. The employment effects of process innovations are less clear in empirical research. The results of studies are not significant (e.g., Hall et al. 2008; Harrison et al. 2008; etc.), the impact of process innovation on employment is negative (e.g., Dachs and Peters 2014; Falk 2015; Kwon et al. 2015; etc.) or positive (e.g., Casavola et al. 1996; Smolny 1998; Greenhalgh et al. 2001; Lachenmaier and Rottmann 2011; etc.).
The limitation of micro level studies is that these studies do not take into account impact on competing firms of the same industry and the impact on other industries (Feldmann 2013). Sectoral level studies estimate the net employment effect in particular industries but they do not take into account the cross-sectoral indirect (compensative) effects of technological change (Bogliacino and Vivarelli 2012). The majority of the sectoral level studies explore the innovation impact on employment and these studies are more popular in relation to skills than micro level studies. The main findings of the sectoral level studies are that process innovation is labor saving and product innovation is employment friendly (e.g., Mehta and Mohanty 1993; Huo and Feng 2010; etc.) and that technological innovation increases the relative demand for skilled workers (e.g., Machin and Van Reenen 1998; Morrison Paul and Siegel 2001).
Hence, with no clear both theoretical and empirical predictions, the impact of technological innovation on unemployment is a question of this research. The interest can be explained by few arguments: first, there are only few macro level research of technological innovation impact on labor market parameters; second, there are only few research about the impact on unemployment; third, there is no clear answer about technological innovation impact on unemployment.
Reviewing research concerning particularly the issues of unemployment, we distinguished variables that influence unemployment and that we have to control in our model while examining technological innovation impact on unemployment (see below):
  • Foreign direct investment. According to Blomström et al. (1997) and Lipsey et al. (2010), net incoming investment is likely to reduce unemployment, while net outflow may have different effects. In addition, as Feldmann (2013) suggests that foreign direct investment is likely to be a source of international technological prevalence.
  • Tax wedge on labor cost. It is a variable expressed as the sum of taxes on salary, income or consumption. The tax wedge is an additional burden (cost) for companies. From a theoretical point of view, work-related taxes reduce employment, as they increase the employer’s wage costs and reduce employee wages, after deducting taxes (Boeri and Van Ours 2008). According to Nickell (1997), the impact of this variable on unemployment depends on who carries the tax burden. If taxes are paid by employees lowering wages after tax, then the demand for labor should not be affected—the real impact of all this should then depend on what is going on with the labor supply. If employees increase demand at the current wage level, compensating lower wages after taxes, the correlation may even be negative, i.e., higher taxes relate to lower unemployment. If taxes cannot be diverted to salaries due to the bargaining power of the union, the lowest wage level or the compressed wage structure, then demand for labor is likely to be negatively influenced and unemployment will increase (Baccaro and Rei 2007).
  • GDP (gross domestic product) per capita. Empirical studies (e.g., Meidani and Zabihi 2011; Malley and Molana 2007) reveal the relationship between unemployment and GDP—the unemployment rate is most often negatively related (i.e., GDP is increasing, unemployment is decreasing) with GDP per capita, however, in some research a positive correlation exists between these variables.
  • Public unemployment spending. Research by Bertola et al. (2007) and Nickell et al. (2005) showed that unemployment benefits increase unemployment. This is also confirmed by the theory of labor economics, according to which, unemployment benefits reduce the intensity of job search and willingness to accept job offers.
  • Consumer price index (CPI) is the main indicator of inflation. Traditional explanation of inflation impact on unemployment is usually based on Phillips curve: an approach developed by Phillips (1958) and Samuelson and Solow (1960). Recent research (Henzel and Wollmershäuser 2008; Kim and Ahn 2008; Zhang and Clovis 2010; Basarac et al. 2011; Malikane and Mokoka 2014) confirmed the validity of Phillips curve approach that increasing inflation decreases unemployment.
  • Trade union density. This is the percentage of employees belonging to trade unions. According to Baccaro and Rei (2007), this indicator can affect unemployment in two ways: first, higher average wages; second, through the compressed salary structure. In the first case, if the union affects labor costs over their market-clearing price, employees who want to work for prevailing wages do not find job. In the second case, the salaries of workers with lower productivity are likely to be determined by the prevailing trends in the labor market. Moreover, according to Soskice (1990), when collective bargaining is coordinated, the unions intend to internalize the spill-over effects associated with their wage policies. Therefore, it can be noted that the relation between the density of unions and coordination of negotiations should be negative. Research by Blanchard and Wolfers (2000) and Baccaro and Rei (2007) showed that higher union density is associated with higher unemployment.
  • Wage bargaining coordination. This variable is related to lower unemployment, as coordinated bargaining tends to internalize the spillover effects of wage bargaining and leads to lower real wage establishment than in uncoordinated bargaining (Tarantelli 1986; Soskice 1990; Flanagan 1999). According to Saint-Paul (2004), a positive relationship between bargaining coordination and unemployment may also be if one party decides that coordination may potentially increase the monopoly power of the unions. According to Calmfors and Driffill (1988), countries can be divided into two groups: the first, where salaries are centrally established, such as Belgium and the Nordic countries; the second, where salary establishment system is highly decentralized, for example the UK. It has been shown that in countries where the salary establishment system is highly centralized or highly decentralized there is lower inflation and higher employment, in the case of decentralized or centralized systems, there is low inflation and high employment. Nickell et al. (2005) and Feldmann (2011) showed that the high degree of coordination of wage-setting is associated with relatively low unemployment.
  • Collective bargaining coverage. Collective agreements are negotiating processes between the employee and the employer, defining employment relationships that are particularly relevant to salaries, working hours and work standards. However, in some cases this may also mean labor market regulation (Cazes et al. 2012). Collective bargaining coverage is an indicator reflecting the impact of collective bargaining on employment (OECD 2005); this is “the proportion of employees covered by collective bargaining” (Estep 2016). According to Feldmann (2013), the power of trade unions would be stronger if employers voluntarily or for some legal or administrative reasons apply agreed terms of contracts and for those employees who are not the members of trade union. Therefore, a high rate of collective bargaining coverage is likely to influence the increase of unemployment.
As this overview of theoretical and empirical research indicates, the results can differ according to country’s economic, technological and labor market development. Therefore, this indicates the need of empirical research on the impact of technological innovation on unemployment.

3. Model, Data and Estimation Method of the Research

This research encompasses 25 European countries: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey and the United Kingdom. Lack of data for all necessary variables for the research reduced the number of European countries included in the analysis. Data covers the period of 2000–2012 on yearly basis, thus this enables us to capture just short-term effect of technological innovation on unemployment.
Empirical research is based on dynamic panel data regression model and two-step generalized method of moments (GMM) to estimate it. The most generalized dynamic panel data model takes the form:
Yi,t = δYi,t−1 + α + βiXi,t + ciCi,t + μi + φt + eit,
where: Y—dependent (endogenous) variable; Y(−1)—lagged dependent variable; i and t stand for cross-sectional unite (country) and time (year), respectively; α—constant; X—core independent variable of the research (theoretically assumed as exogenous but this assumption is hard to hold); C—vector of control variables; μ—time-fixed unobserved cross-sectional heterogeneity; φ—time effects that are constant for all cross-sectional observations; δ, β, c—parameters that show impact of right-hand side variables on dependent variable and need to be estimated; e—error that is normally distributed with constant variation and zero serial correlation.
GMM is used for estimating the model because it enables us to deal with potential endogeneity problem of right-hand side variables. Following the GMM methodology, first—we will differentiate the equation, second—for estimation as instruments will use lagged observations of the first difference of the independent variables. GMM method is presented and discussed in detail by Arellano and Bond (1991). Alonso-Borrego and Arellano (1999) and Blundell and Bond (1998), regarding weak instrumental variables and suggestions by Arellano and Bover (1995), suggest overcoming that problem by using additional moment conditions for an equation expressed in levels are also employed in the analysis. Combination of equation in differences with equation in levels is called system GMM (SGMM). As Bond et al. (2001) and Hauk and Wacziarg (2009) stressed, for estimating more consistent and efficient parameters the SGMM should be used for panel data regressions.
Properties of GMM estimators for panel data, which have become very popular in the empirical literature, are not well known when the number of cross-sectionals is small. Soto (2009) as well as Hayakawa (2007) analyzed the properties of various GMM and other estimators applying Monte Carlo simulations. They found that SGMM estimator is less biased than the first differencing or the level estimators. To take into account the concern of Blundell and Bond (1998) about the downward-biased tendency of standard errors estimated by the SGMM approach for small finite samples we used finite-sample corrections to the asymptotic covariance matrix of the parameters suggested by Windmeijer (2005), which are nowadays almost universally used.
To investigate the overall validity of the SGMM estimation, based on Arellano and Bond (1991) and Blundell and Bond (1998), two tests must be carried out: (1) the Sargan test, which tests the validity of the instruments; and (2) the AR(2) test, which tests the presence of second-order serial correlation. The SGMM estimation results are valid only after passing the above two tests.
Table 2 presents variables used in the empirical research as well as their measurement and the expected impact on dependent variable.
Trade union density, coordination of wage-setting and collective bargaining coverage variables are some of the most commonly used proxies for wage bargaining systems (wbs) and they will be used as alternatives while estimating the model for robustness check:
unemi,t = δ·unemi,t−1 + α + β·tpfi,t + c1·fdi_inwi,t + c2·fdi_outi,t + c3·taxi,t + c4·gdpi,t + c5·bnfi,t + c6·cpii,t + c7·wbsi,t + μi + φt + ei,t,
where: unem—unemployment level; unem(−1)—lagged unemployment level variable; tpf—triadic patent families per million inhabitants; fdi_inw—inward FDI stocks (% of GDP); fdi_out—outward FDI stocks (% of GDP); tax—tax wedge on labor cost; gdp—GDP per capita; bnf—public unemployment spending; cpi—consumer price index; wbs will be alternatively proxied by using: tud—trade union density, wbc—coordination of wage-setting, cbc—collective bargaining coverage.
The descriptive statistics of the variables are shown in Table 3.
The descriptive statistics of the variables expressed in percentage changes are shown in Table 4.

4. Estimation Results

Estimations (I)–(III) in Table 5 present three main estimations of Equation (2). They differ in terms of which variable is used to proxy wage bargaining system. All three estimations passed AR(2) and Sargan tests and thus instruments are valid and results are not affected by second-order serial correlation.
All estimations, except one, do not suggest that technological innovations (approximated by Triadic patent families (tfp) have an effect on unemployment. The third estimation shows negative correlation, i.e., higher innovation activity is associated with lower unemployment rate, what is not in line with our general hypothesis. Almost all control variables included in the model are statistically significant: inward FDI negatively and outward FDI positively associated with unemployment rate, economic growth as well as higher price index, as a subsequence of economic growth, negatively correlate with unemployment rate, more generous public spending on unemployment seems to have negative outcome—it increases unemployment due to lowering alternative costs of work. Higher tax wedge on labor cost decreases unemployment but this is suggested just by estimation [I]. Trade union density unlike with wage bargaining coordination or collective bargaining coverage seems to have no effect on unemployment. In most of the cases, except for GDP and CPI, estimated magnitude of control variables’ impact on unemployment rate does not differ much from estimation to estimation.
Having no clear empirical evidence of relationship between technological innovation and unemployment, following Feldmann (2013), who is arguing that this relationship could occur with a time lag, we augmented our general Equation (2) to examine this potential delay of effect in time that was not captured by our previous estimations (see Estimations (IV)–(VI) in Table 5).
Nonetheless, we were testing impact consistently with a delay up to three years, just in one case this impact was captured (see Estimation (V)) and did not change after adding more lags. Like in previous case, this impact is negative and does not have verification in other estimations.
Next step of our research is related to changing a core independent variable that was used to proxy technological innovations. Doing so we are performing robustness check of findings regarding our core independent variable. As it was mentioned in the literature review, two alternative approaches are usually employed while searching for variables to proxy technological innovations—the first one to measure output was already adopted, the second one concentrates on input. For a measuring input for technological innovations, we used variable R&D intensity (expenditures on R&D to GDP ratio). According to Vivarelli (2015), R&D intensity is associated with product innovations and creation of new jobs and thus negatively correlates with unemployment but many research listed in Table 1 and Appendix A find strong empirical link between R&D intensity, innovations and productivity growth, revealing that R&D being a foundation of technological progress at macro, sectoral or micro level could make impact on unemployment.
Estimation results of Equation (2) with R&D intensity variable instead of Triadic patent families are presented in Table 6. All other variables in Equation (2) remain the same.
All new estimations (VII)–(XII) in Table 6 passed AR(2) and Sargan tests and thus instruments are valid and results are not affected by second-order serial correlation. We do not find strong empirical evidence of an R&D intensity effect on unemployment because in the case of just one estimation (X) relationship is significant and positive (with a two year lag).

5. Conclusions

Is the technological innovation a major driver of the increasing unemployment in European countries? This issue is argued frequently in the debates but the important issue has not been so well-analyzed empirically at macro level. As theoretical analysis shows there are relatively few research on the impact at macroeconomic level and it provides proof that technological innovation influences changes of unemployment.
Our regression results indicate that technological innovations have no effect on unemployment what shows that the macro-analysis is inconclusive. This can be explained by the measurement limitations that total unemployment rate might be a rather broad variable to capture effects of technological innovations. Possible future studies should distinguish unemployment by types for more detailed analysis of the effect on structural or long-term unemployment also including other control variables such as employment protection legislation index, unemployment benefit ratio, workers’ average hourly salary, public debt, minimum wage adjusted for inflation and etc.
The other explanation is that country specific macroeconomic conditions and regulations are important for the situation in labor market what affects the investment decisions of firms. On the labor supply side, preferences for leisure, institutional restrictions including working time and household composition are significant thus this was not the object of the current research. Therefore, it is difficult to estimate the impact of technological innovation at the time the innovation is introduced when the lagging compensation effects are unknown. Future research can include investigating the long-run effects of innovations in order to analyze major shifts in economy.

Author Contributions

All authors contributed equally to this work.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Research on technological innovation impact on labor market outcomes.
Table A1. Research on technological innovation impact on labor market outcomes.
Level of AnalysisAuthor(s), YearMeasurement Instrument(s) for Technological Innovation(s) as Exogenous Variable(s)Labor Market Outcome(s) as Endogenous Variable(s)PositiveNegativeNon-Significant/Unclear
Sectoral levelMehta and Mohanty (1993)Technology elasticity (adoption)Labor demand X
Berman et al. (1994)Investment in computers, expenditures on R&DSkilled labor force demandX
Bogliacino and Vivarelli (2011); Bogliacino and Vivarelli (2012)R&D expenditureLabor demandX
Goux and Maurin (2000)New technologies usageLabor demand X
Gera et al. (2001)The stock of R&D, the stock of patentsSkilled labor force demandX
Morrison Paul and Siegel (2001)Investment in technology, R&D investmentLabor demand X
Evangelista and Savona (2002)Innovation intensityEmployment X
Piva et al. (2006)ICT technologiesSkilled and unskilled labor force demand X
Pieroni and Pompei (2008)Patent per capitaGross job turnover rateX
Bogliacino and Pianta (2010)R&D expenditure, expenditure for innovation-related machineryEmploymentX
Huo and Feng (2010)The index of process and product innovation intensityEmploymentX
Micro levelCasavola et al. (1996)R&D expenditure, patents, software licensesEmploymentX
Doms et al. (1997)Automation technologiesWages, occupational mix, workforce educationX
Dunne et al. (1997)R&D stock, technology adoptionEmployment, labor share changeX
Van Reenen (1997)PatentsEmploymentX
Blanchflower and Burgess (1998)Introduction of new technologyEmploymentX
Klette and Førre (1998)2R&D investmentsJob creation X
Smolny (1998)Product and process innovations3EmploymentX
Boone (2000)Product and process innovationsUnemployment X
Gatti (2000)Product-oriented and knowledge-based R&DUnemploymentX
Greenan and Guellec (2000)4Product and process innovationEmploymentX
Aguirregabiria and Alonso-Borrego (2001)Investment on R&D, purchases of technological capitalEmployment by occupationsX
Falk and Seim (2001)Investment in ITHigh-skilled employmentX
Greenan et al. (2001)R&D expenditure, IT adoption and intensity of usageWages, skill composition, employmentX
Luque (2005)Technological intensitySkill mix changesX
Piva et al. (2005)R&D expenditureEmployment (blue-collars, white-collars) X
Greenhalgh et al. (2001); Lachenmaier and Rottmann (2007); Yang and Lin (2008); Lachenmaier and Rottmann (2011)R&D, patentsEmploymentX
Hall et al. (2008); Harrison et al. (2008); Dachs and Peters (2014); Falk (2015)Product and process innovationsEmploymentX
Baccini and Cioni (2010)Introduction of ICTDemand for skilled workers X
Coad and Rao (2011)R&D expenditure, patents applicationsTotal number of jobsX
Meschi et al. (2011)R&D expenditure, technological transfer from abroad, foreign ownershipDemand for skilled laborX
Evangelista and Vezzani (2012)Product and process innovationsEmploymentX
Bogliacino et al. (2012); Ciriaci et al. (2016)R&D expenditureEmploymentX
Kwon et al. (2015)Product5 and process6 innovationsEmploymentX
Meschi et al. (2016)R&D expenditure; the obtained availability of a foreign patent or other appropriable devices developed abroad; investment in foreign machinery and equipment per workerEmployment (blue-collars, white-collars)X
Investment in domestically produced machinery and equipment per workerEmployment (blue-collars, white-collars) X
Haile et al. (2017)The share of foreign ownershipSkilled and unskilled labor force demandX (for skilled workers) X (for unskilled workers)

References

  1. Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor. 2011. Skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for employment and earnings. Handbook of Labor Economics 4: 1043–71. [Google Scholar]
  2. Aguirregabiria, Victor, and César Alonso-Borrego. 2001. Occupational structure, technological innovation and reorganization of production. Labor Economics 8: 43–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Alonso-Borrego, César, and Manuel Arellano. 1999. Symmetrically Normalized Instrumental Variable Estimation Using Panel Data. Journal of Business & Economic Statatistics 17: 36–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Alonso-Borrego, César, and Dolores Collado. 2002. Innovation and Job Creation and Destruction. Recherches économiques de Louvain 68: 148–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Arellano, Manuel, and Olympia Bover. 1995. Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-components Models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Autor, David H. 2015. Why Are There Still So Many Jobs? The History and Future of Workplace Automation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29: 3–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Baccaro, Lucio, and Diego Rei. 2007. Institutional Determinants of Unemployment in OECD Countries: Does the Deregulatory View Hold Water? International Organization 61: 527–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Baccini, Alberto, and Martina Cioni. 2010. Is technological change really skill-biased? Evidence from the introduction of ICT on the Italian textile industry (1980–2000). New Technology Work and Employment 25: 80–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Barnhizer, David. 2016. The Future of Work: Apps, Artificial Intelligence, Automation and Androids. Cleveland-Marshall Legal Studies Paper 289. Available online: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2716327 (accessed on 2 October 2017). [CrossRef]
  11. Basarac, Martina, Blanka Skrabic, and Petar Soric. 2011. The Hybrid Phillips curve: empirical evidence from transition economies. Finance a Uver 61: 367–83. [Google Scholar]
  12. Berman, Eli, John Bound, and Zvi Griliches. 1994. Changes in the Demand for Skilled Labor within U.S. Manufacturing: Evidence from the Annual Survey of Manufactures. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109: 367–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bertola, Giuseppe, Francine D. Blau, and Lawrence M. Kahn. 2007. Labor market institutions and demographic employment patterns. Journal of Population Economics 20: 833–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Blanchard, Olivier, and Justin Wolfers. 2000. The Role of Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment: The Aggregate Evidence. The Economic Journal 110: 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Blanchflower, David G., and Simon M. Burgess. 1998. New Technology and Jobs: Comparative Evidence from a Two Country Study. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 5: 109–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Blomström, Magnus, Gunnar Fors, and Robert E. Lipsey. 1997. Foreign Direct Investment and Employment: Home Country Experience in the United States and Sweden. Economic Journal 107: 1787–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel-data models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Boeri, Tito, and Jan Van Ours. 2008. The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets, 2nd ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press, ISBN 978-0-691-15893-8. [Google Scholar]
  19. Bogliacino, Francesco, and Mario Pianta. 2010. Innovation and employment: A Reinvestigation using Revised Pavitt classes. Research Policy 39: 799–809. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Bogliacino, Francesco, Mariacristina Piva, and Marco Vivarelli. 2012. R&D and employment: An application of the LSDVC estimator using European microdata. Economics Letters 116: 56–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bogliacino, Francesco, and Marco Vivarelli. 2011. Innovation and employment: Some evidence from European sectors. No. dises1178. Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore, Dipartimenti e Istituti di Scienze Economiche (DISCE). [Google Scholar]
  22. Bogliacino, Francesco, and Marco Vivarelli. 2012. The job creation effect of R&D expenditures. Australian Economic Papers 51: 96–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Bonanno, Graziella. 2016. ICT and R&D as inputs or efficiency determinants? Analysing Italian manufacturing firms (2007–2009). Eurasian Business Review 6: 383–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Bond, Stephen, Clive Bowsher, and Frank Windmeijer. 2001. Criterion-based Inference for GMM in Autoregressive Panel Data Models. Economic Letters 73: 379–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Boone, Jan. 2000. Technological Progress, Downsizing and Unemployment. The Economic Journal 110: 581–600. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Andrew McAfee. 2011. Race against the Machine: How the Digital Revolution Is Accelerating Innovation, Driving Productivity and Irreversibly Transforming Employment and the Economy. Lexington: Digital Frontier Press, ISBN 978-0-9847251-0-6. [Google Scholar]
  27. Calmfors, Lars, and John Driffill. 1988. Bargaining structure, corporatism and macroeconomic performance. Economic Policy 3: 13–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Casavola, Paola, Andréa Gavosto, and Paolo Sestito. 1996. Technical Progress and Wage Dispersion in Italy: Evidence from Firms’ Data. AnnalesD’Économieet de Statistique 41/42: 387–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Caselli, Francesco, and Wilbur John Coleman II. 2006. The World Technology Frontier. American Economic Review 96: 499–522. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Cazes, Sandrine, Sameer Khatiwada, and Miguel Malo. 2012. Employment Protection and Collective Bargaining: Beyond the Deregulation Agenda. ILO Working Paper 133. Geneva: International Labour Organization. [Google Scholar]
  31. Ciriaci, Daria, Pietro Moncada-Paternò-Castello, and Peter Voigt. 2016. Innovation and job creation: A sustainable relation? Eurasian Business Review 6: 189–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Coad, Alex, and Rekha Rao. 2011. The firm-level employment effects of innovations in high-tech US manufacturing industries. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 21: 255–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Dachs, Bernhard, and Bettina Peters. 2014. Innovation, employment growth and foreign ownership of firms: A European perspective. Research Policy 43: 214–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Dernis, Hélène, and Mosahid Khan. 2004. Triadic Patent Families Methodology. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2004/02. Paris, France: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar]
  35. Doms, Mark, Timothy Dunne, and Kenneth R. Troske. 1997. Workers, Wages and Technology. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 253–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Dunne, Timothy, John Haltiwanger, and Kenneth R. Troske. 1997. Technology and jobs: Secular changes and cyclical dynamics. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 46: 107–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Evangelista, Rinaldo, Paolo Guerrieri, and Valentina Meliciani. 2014. The economic impact of digital technologies in Europe. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 23: 802–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Evangelista, Rinaldo, and Maria Savona. 2002. The Impact of Innovation on Employment in Services: Evidence from Italy. International Review of Applied Economics 16: 309–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Evangelista, Rinaldo, and Antonio Vezzani. 2012. The impact of technological and organizational innovations on employment in European firms. Industrial and Corporate Change 21: 871–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Estep. 2016. 2007–2013 m. žmogiškųjų išteklių plėtros veiksmų programos priemonės „Socialinio dialogo skatinimas” poveikio, efektyvumo ir sukurtų rezultatų vertinimas. Available online: http://www.esinvesticijos.lt/lt/dokumentai/2007-2013-m-zmogiskuju-istekliu-pletros-veiksmu-programos-priemones-socialinio-dialogo-skatinimas-poveikio-efektyvumo-ir-sukurtu-rezultatu-vertinimo-santrauka (accessed on 2 October 2017).
  41. Fai, Felicia, and Nicholas von Tunzelmann. 2001. Industry-specific competencies and converging technological systems: Evidence from patents. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 12: 141–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Falk, Martin. 2015. Employment Effects of Technological and Organizational Innovations: Evidence Based on Linked Firm-level Data for Austria. Journal of Economics and Statistics 235: 268–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Falk, Martin, and Katja Seim. 2001. The Impact of Information Technology on High-skilled Labor in Services: Evidence from Firm Level Panel Data. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 10: 289–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Feldmann, Horst. 2011. Central Bank Independence, Wage Bargaining and Labor Market Performance: New Evidence. Southern Economic Journal 77: 692–725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Feldmann, Horst. 2013. Technological Unemployment in Industrial Countries. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 23: 1099–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Flanagan, Robert J. 1999. Macroeconomic Performance and Collective Bargaining: An International Perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37: 1150–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Flichy, Patrice. 2007. Understanding Technological Innovation: A Socio-Technical Approach. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, ISBN 978-1-84720-39-5. [Google Scholar]
  48. Frey, Carl Benedikt, and Michael A. Osborne. 2017. The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerisation? Technological Forecasting & Social Change 114: 254–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Garud, Raghu, Praveen Rattan Nayyar, and Zur Baruch Shapira. 1997. Technological Innovation: Oversights and Foresights. New York: Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-55299-0. [Google Scholar]
  50. Gatti, Donatella. 2000. Unemployment and Innovation Patterns: The Critical Role of Coordination. Industrial and Corporate Change 9: 521–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Gera, Surendra, Wulong Gu, and Zhengxi Lin. 2001. Technology and the demand for skills in Canada: An industry-level analysis. Canadian Journal of Economics 34: 132–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Goux, Dominique, and Eric Maurin. 2000. The Decline in Demand for Unskilled Labor: An Empirical Analysis Method and its Application to France. The Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 596–607. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Greenan, Nathalie, and Dominique Guellec. 2000. Technological Innovation and Employment Reallocation. Labour 14: 547–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Greenan, Nathalie, Jacques Mairesse, and Agnes Topiol-Bensaid. 2001. Information Technology and Research and Development Impacts on Productivity and Skills: Looking for Correlations on French Firm Level Data. NBER Working Paper 8075. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  55. Greenhalgh, Christine, Mark Longland, and Derek Bosworth. 2001. Technological Activity and Employment in a Panel of UK Firms. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 48: 260–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Haile, Getinet, Ilina Srour, and Marco Vivarelli. 2017. Imported technology and manufacturing employment in Ethiopia. Eurasian Business Review 7: 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Hall, Bronwyn H., Francesca Lotti, and Jacques Mairesse. 2008. Employment, innovation and productivity: Evidence from Italian microdata. Industrial and Corporate Change 17: 813–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Harrison, Rupert, Jordi Jaumandreu, Jacques Mairesse, and Bettina Peters. 2008. Does Innovation Stimulate Employment? A Firm-Level Analysis Using Comparable Micro Data on Four European Countries. NBER Working Paper 14216. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  59. Hauk, William R., and Romain Wacziarg. 2009. A Monte Carlo study of growth regressions. Journal of Economic Growth 14: 103–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Hayakawa, Kazuhiko. 2007. Small sample bias properties of the system GMM estimator in dynamic panel data models. Economics Letters 95: 32–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Henzel, Steffen, and Timo Wollmershäuser. 2008. The new keynesian Phillips curve and the role of expectations: Evidence from the CESifo world economic survey. Economic Modelling 25: 811–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Hoover, Kevin D. 2012. Applied Intermediate Macroeconomics. New York: Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-76388-2. [Google Scholar]
  63. Huo, Jingjing, and Hui Feng. 2010. The Political Economy of Technological Innovation and Employment. Comparative Political Studies 43: 329–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Kim, Bae-Geun, and Byung Kwun Ahn. 2008. An assessment of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve in the Korean economy. Economic Analysis 14: 85–131. [Google Scholar]
  65. Klette, Tor Jakob, and Svein Erik Førre. 1998. Innovation and Job Creation in a Small Open Economy—Evidence from Norwegian Manufacturing Plants 1982–92. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 5: 247–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Kortum, Samuel S. 1997. Research, Patenting and Technological Change. Econometrica 65: 1389–419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Kromann, Lene, Jan Rose Skaksen, and Anders Sørensen. 2011. Automation, Labor Productivity and Employment—A cross Country Comparison. CEBR Working Paper 3-2015. Copenhagen, Denmark: Copenhagen Business School. [Google Scholar]
  68. Kwon, Sang Jib, Eunil Park, Jay Y. Ohm, and Kyeongsik Yoo. 2015. Innovation activities and the creation of new employment: An empirical assessment of South Korea’s manufacturing industry. Social Science Information 54: 354–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Lachenmaier, Stefan, and Horst Rottmann. 2007. Effects of Innovation on Employment: A Dynamic Panel Analysis. International Journal of Industrial Organization 29: 210–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Lachenmaier, Stefan, and Horst Rottmann. 2011. Effects of innovation on employment: A dynamic panel analysis. International Journal of Industrial Organization 29: 210–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Lipsey, Robert E., Fredrik Sjöholm, and Jing Sun. 2010. Foreign Ownership and Employment Growth in Indonesian Manufacturing. NBER Working Paper 15936. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  72. Liso, Nicola, and Riccardo Leoncini. 2011. Internationalization, Technological Change and the Theory of the Firm. New York: Routledge, ISBN 978-1-203-84641-4. [Google Scholar]
  73. Luque, Adela. 2005. Skill Mix and Technology in Spain: Evidence from Firm-Level Data. Banco de España. Working Paper 0513. Madrid: Banco de España & Working Papers Homepage. [Google Scholar]
  74. Machin, Stephen, and John Van Reenen. 1998. Technology and Changes in Skill Structure: Evidence from Seven OECD Countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113: 1215–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Malikane, Christopher, and Tshepo Mokoka. 2014. The new keynesian Phillips curve: Endogeneity and misspecification. Applied Economics 46: 3082–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Malley, Jim, and Hassan Molana. 2007. The Relationship between Output and Unemployment with Efficiency Wages. German Economic Review 8: 561–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Malthus, Thomas Robert. 2008. Principles of Political Economy. Edited by J. Pullen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  78. Marcolin, Luca, Sébastien Miroudot, and Mariagrazia Squicciarini. 2016. Routine Jobs, Employment and Technological Innovation in Global Value Chains. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers No. 01. Paris: OECD iLibrary. [Google Scholar]
  79. Mehta, R., and S. K. Mohanty. 1993. Demand for Labour in Manufacturing Sector: A Decomposition Analysis for Developing Countries. Indian Journal of Industrial Relations 29: 171–90. [Google Scholar]
  80. Meidani, Ali A. Naji, and Maryam Zabihi. 2011. The Dynamic Effect of Unemployment Rate on Per Capita Real GDP in Iran. International Journal of Economics and Finance 3: 170–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Meschi, Elena Meschi, Erol Taymaz, and Marco Vivarelli. 2011. Trade, technology and skills: Evidence from Turkish microdata. Labour Economics 18: S60–S70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Meschi, Elena Meschi, Erol Taymaz, and Marco Vivarelli. 2016. Globalization, Technological Change and Labor Demand: A Firm. Level Analysis for Turkey. Review of World Economics 152: 655–80. [Google Scholar]
  83. Morrison Paul, Catherine J., and Donald S. Siegel. 2001. The Impacts of Technology, Trade and Outsourcing on Employment and Labor Composition. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 103: 241–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Nickell, Stephen. 1997. Unemployment and labor market rigidities. Europe vs. North America. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11: 55–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Nickell, Stephen Nickell, Luca Nunziata, and Wolfgang Ochel. 2005. Unemployment in the OECD since the 1960s. What Do We Know? Economic Journal 115: 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. OECD. 2005. Oslo Manual: Guidelines for Collecting and Interpreting Innovation Data, 3rd ed. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Peters, Bettina. 2004. Employment Effects of Different Innovation Activities: Microeconometric Evidence. ZEW—Centre for European Economic Research Discussion Paper 04-073. Mannheim: Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW). [Google Scholar]
  88. Phillips, A. W. 1958. The relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom 1861–1957. Economica 25: 283–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Pianta, Mario. 2004. The impact of innovation on jobs, skills and wages. Economia e Lavoro 1: 7–26. [Google Scholar]
  90. Pieroni, Luca, and Fabrizio Pompei. 2008. Evaluating Innovation and Labour Market relationships: The Case of Italy. Cambridge Journal of Economics 2: 325–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Pini, Paolo. 1995. Economic Growth, Technological Change and Employment: Empirical Evidence for a Cumulative Growth Model with External Causation for Nine OECD Countries: 1960–1990. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 6: 185–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Piva, Mariacristina, Enrico Santarelli, and Marco Vivarelli. 2005. The skill bias effect of technological and organisational change: Evidence and policy implications. Research Policy 34: 141–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Piva, Mariacristina, Enrico Santarelli, and Marco Vivarelli. 2006. Technological and Organizational Changes as Determinants of the Skill Bias: Evidence from the Italian Machinery Industry. Managerial and Decision Economics 27: 63–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Piva, Mariacristina, and Marco Vivarelli. 2005. Innovation and Employment: Evidence from Italian Microdata. Journal of Economics 86: 65–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Ramanauskienė, J. 2010. Inovacijų ir Projektų Vadyba. Akademija: ASU leidyboscentras, ISBN 978-9955-896-88-3. [Google Scholar]
  96. Saint-Paul, Gilles. 2004. Why Are European Countries Diverging in Their Unemployment Experience? Journal of Economic Perspectives 18: 49–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Samuelson, Paul A., and Robert M. Solow. 1960. Analytical aspects of anti-inflation policy. American Economic Review 50: 177–94. [Google Scholar]
  98. Say, Jean Baptiste. 2009. A Treatise on Political Economy or the Production, Distribution and Consumption of Wealth. New York: BiblioBazaar, vol. 2, ISBN 9781110312887. [Google Scholar]
  99. Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 2008. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 3rd ed. New York: HarperCollins, ISBN 0-87855-698-2. [Google Scholar]
  100. Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 2017. The Theory of Economic Development. New York: Routledge, ISBN 978-0-06-156161-0. [Google Scholar]
  101. Simonetti, Roberto, Karl Taylor, and Marco Vivarelli. 2000. Modelling the employment impact of innovation. In The Employment Impact of Innovation: Evidence and Policy. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  102. Smolny, Wernerr. 1998. Innovations, Prices and Employment: A Theoretical Model and an Empirical application for West German Manufacturing Firms. The Journal of Industrial Economics 46: 359–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  103. Soskice, David. 1990. Wage Determination: The Changing Role of Institutions in Advanced Industrialized Countries. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 6: 36–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Soto, Marcelo. 2009. System GMM Estimation with a Small Sample. UFAE and IAE Working Papers 780.09. Barcelona, Spain: Centre d’Estudis Olímpics. [Google Scholar]
  105. Tancioni, Massimiliano, and Roberto Simonetti. 2002. A macroeconometric model for the analysis of the impact of technological change and trade on employment. Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 13: 185–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  106. Tarantelli, E. 1986. Economiapoliticadellavoro e Dellerelazioniindustrialicomparate. Turin: Utet, ISBN 9788802040141. [Google Scholar]
  107. Van Reenen, John. 1997. Employment and technological innovation: Evidence from UK manufacturing firms. Journal of Labor Economics 15: 255–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Vivarelli, Marco. 1995. The Economics of Technology and Employment: Theory and Empirical Evidence. Aldershot: Elgar. [Google Scholar]
  109. Vivarelli, Marco. 2014. Innovation, employment and skills in advanced and developing countries: A survey of economic literature. Journal of Economic Issues 48: 123–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  110. Vivarelli, Marco. 2015. Innovation and Employment. Bonn: IZA World of Labor 154, Institute of Labor Economics. [Google Scholar]
  111. Windmeijer, Frank. 2005. A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics 126: 25–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Wood, John Cunningham. 2004. Karl Marx’s Economics: Critical Assessments. London and New York: Routledge, vol. IV, ISBN 0-415-06510-0. [Google Scholar]
  113. Yang, Chih-Hai, and Chun-Hung A. Lin. 2008. Developing Employment Effects of Innovations: Microeconometric Evidence from Taiwan. Developing Economies 46: 109–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Zhang, Chengsi, and Joel Clovis. 2010. The new keynesian Phillips curve of rational expectations: A serial correlation extension. Journal of Applied Economics 13: 159–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Ziemnowicz, Christopher. 2013. Joseph A. Schumpeter and Innovation. In Encyclopedia of Creativity, Invention, Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Edited by Elias G. Carayannis. New York: Springer, vol. 1, pp. 1171–1176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1
The Oslo Manual is the foremost international source of guidelines for the collection and use of data on innovation activities in industry (OECD 2005).
2
The authors study manufacturing sector both at the firm and industry level.
3
The database for the empirical application consists of the data-set from the business survey and the investment survey of the IFO institut, München. Innovations are defined as novelties or essential improvements of the product or the production technique (Smolny 1998).
4
This research describes the dynamics of employment both at a firm and sector level.
5
Five items, e.g., “Product innovation conducted in my company has a positive impact on achieving industrial standards.”
6
Five items, e.g., “Process innovation enhances product quality.”
Table 1. Research on technological innovation impact on labor market outcomes.
Table 1. Research on technological innovation impact on labor market outcomes.
Level of AnalysisAuthor(s), YearMeasurement of Technological Innovation(s)Labor Market Outcome(s)Impact
PositiveNegativeNon-Significant/Unclear
Macro levelPini (1995)R&D expenditure, patentsEmploymentX
Vivarelli (1995)R&D linked to product and process innovationsEmployment X
Simonetti et al. (2000)R&D linked to product and process innovationsEmployment X
Tancioni and Simonetti (2002)R&D linked to product and process innovationsEmployment X
Feldmann (2013)Triadic patent families to populationUnemploymentX
Evangelista et al. (2014)ICTEmploymentX
Marcolin et al. (2016)ICT-intensity, patentsEmploymentX
Table 2. Research variables, their measurement and expected effect on dependent variable.
Table 2. Research variables, their measurement and expected effect on dependent variable.
Variables (Acronym)MeasurementExpected Correlation with Dependent Variable
Dependent variableUnemployment (unem)Total (% of total labor force)-
Core independent variablesTriadic patent families (tfp)Per million inhabitants+ive
Expenditure on R&D (exp_RD)% of GDP+ive
Control variablesInward foreign direct investment (fdi_inv)Inward FDI stocks (% of GDP)−ive
Outward foreign direct investment (fdi_out)Outward FDI stocks (% of GDP)−ive/+ive
Tax wedge on labor cost (tax)% of total labor costs−ive/+ive
Gross domestic product (gdp)GDP per capita−ive
Public unemployment spending (bnf)% of GDP+ive
Consumer price index, CPI (cpi)2010 = 100−ive/+ive
Trade union density (tud)Decimal fraction of wage and salary earners that are trade union members+ive
Coordination of wage-setting/wage bargaining coordination (wbc)Coordination of wage-setting:
1—Fragmented wage bargaining, confined largely to individual firms or plants
2—Mixed industry and firm-level bargaining, weak government coordination through MW setting or wage indexation
3—Negotiation guidelines based on centralized bargaining
4—Wage norms based on centralized bargaining by peak associations with or without government involvement
5—Maximum or minimum wage rates/increases based on centralized bargaining
−ive
Collective bargaining coverage (cbc)Decimal fraction of all wage and salary earners in employment with the right to bargaining+ive
Table 3. Descriptive statistics.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics.
VariableObservationsMeanSt. Dev.MinMax
unem5449.046.031.1037.30
tpf41322.7443.230.01302.20
exp_RD5111.470.930.177.00
fdi_inw45257.2793.937.401822.60
fdi_out44442.2654.510.20476.80
tax51236.578.5911.9051.40
gdp54332,321.0027,543.001609.30178,710.00
bnf3620.940.780.003.55
cpi52892.9614.2819.28146.07
tud47533.0921.325.6592.46
wbc4622.711.251.005.00
cbc39861.4727.625.39100.00
Table 4. Summary statistics of variables expressed in percentage changes.
Table 4. Summary statistics of variables expressed in percentage changes.
VariableObservationsMeanSt. Dev.MinMax
unem5102.6620.38−37.50148.28
tpf37117.95148.81−92.302000.00
exp_RD4712.8710.15−30.02109.41
fdi_inw4168.1548.39−49.66922.21
fdi_out40917.52142.92−65.822843.20
tax477−0.383.87−36.0219.04
gdp5096.1311.86−27.5545.26
bnf3237.9644.22−48.87408.36
cpi4953.014.37−4.4754.40
tud410−2.685.78−60.4032.85
wbc4310.8218.47−80.00200.00
cbc323−1.337.38−58.6833.33
Table 5. Estimation results of general model.
Table 5. Estimation results of general model.
Regressors(I)(II)(III)(IV)(V)(VI)
unem(−1)−0.0095
(−0.0406)
0.0847
(0.3298)
−0.0704
(−0.3480)
−0.1545
(−0.6435)
0.1734
(0.7458)
0.3548
(1.3380)
const24.4595 ***
(4.8719)
26.8262 ***
(2.7712)
14.7437 ***
(3.2841)
0.1742
(1.5100)
0.1773 *
(1.8990)
0.0269
(0.2130)
tfp0.0391
(1.0875)
0.0078
(0.1604)
−0.1195 **
(−2.4237)
0.0361
(0.6613)
−0.0357 **
(−2.311)
−0.0231
(−0.6074)
tpf(−1) 0.0030
(0.0856)
−0.0764 ***
(−3.5290)
−0.0357
(−0.5888)
tpf(−2) −0.0286
(−0.7250)
−0.0374
(−1.3770)
0.0067
(0.1288)
tpf(−3) 0.0428
(1.3240)
0.0051
(0.1833)
0.0018
(0.0539)
fdi_inw−0.2942 ***
(−3.2246)
−0.2990 ***
(−3.0501)
−0.2038 ***
(−3.5170)
−0.1003
(−0.1620)
0.1698
(1.5590)
0.0345
(0.0403)
fdi_out0.1504 ***
(3.3707)
0.0687 **
(1.9869)
0.0999 ***
(2.5975)
−0.1083
(−0.9702)
0.1410
(0.9312)
0.2181
(0.7136)
tax−0.6345 ***
(−3.3390)
−0.4974 *
(−1.8868)
0.0706
(0.3527)
6.5548
(1.0690)
−1.8506
(−0.9022)
−0.6114
(0.1007)
gdp−1.0080 ***
(−4.2362)
−0.4820 **
(−2.0937)
−0.3110 *
(−1.7043)
−3.2039
(−0.9656)
−1.3872 *
(−1.9100)
0.2880
(0.0916)
bnf0.4349 ***
(6.6521)
0.4445***
(3.6069)
0.4406***
(5.5457)
−0.6074
(−0.5691)
0.2254 ***
(2.9010)
0.4117 ***
(3.6490)
cpi−2.2878 ***
(−4.9252)
−4.0226 ***
(−2.7645)
−1.9268 ***
(−2.7832)
13.2747
(0.7829)
2.0432
(1.3840)
−2.4810 ***
(−2.8130)
tud0.0174
(0.6512)
3.0757
(1.4880)
wbc −0.1581 ***
(−3.1691)
−0.1717 *
(−1.9460)
cbc −0.1975 ***
(−2.7413)
0.0729
(0.2288)
Error AR(2) test1.3784
(0.1681) a
1.6085
(0.0991)
0.6466
(0.5179)
0.6827
(0.4948)
1.4879
(0.1368)
−0.0314
(0.9750)
Sargan over-identification test1.4246
(0.8039) a
1.1994
(0.7732)
4.3351
(0.5781)
4.3030
(0.5530)
3.6705
(0.4967)
5.0628
(0.3703)
Number of countries2524 b25252425
Number of observations285275242207200175
Note: all variables are logged. All estimations are 2-step SGMM including equations in levels. z-scores are presented in parentheses of estimates. *, **, *** indicates significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent level, respectively. All estimates include time dummies. a p-value presented in parentheses of AR(2) and Sargan tests. b Estimation does not include Iceland because of lack of the data on wbc variable.
Table 6. Estimation results with alternative core independent variable.
Table 6. Estimation results with alternative core independent variable.
Regressors(VII)(VIII)(IX)(X)(XI)(XII)
unem(−1)−0.2123
(−0.6412)
0.7606 *
(1.7780)
0.6411 ***
(3.0880)
−0.1757
(−0.5246)
0.5311
(0.7977)
0.5247 ***
(2.6680)
const0.2896 **
(2.0240)
0.0666
(0.7427)
0.0854
(1.126)
0.1653
(1.2710)
−0.0616
(−0.1569)
0.0149
(0.1555)
exp_RD0.3133 *
(1.9600)
−1.1571
(−1.3370)
−0.3196
(−0.6251)
0.1885
(1.0220)
−0.6198 *
(−1.8760)
0.3389
(0.6967)
exp_RD(−1) 0.4551
(1.1250)
−1.0037 *
(−1.8040)
0.0558
(0.0708)
exp_RD(−2) 0.5023 ***
(3.0900)
−0.6924
(−1.4860)
−0.1335
(−0.2484)
exp_RD(−3) 0.0548
(0.1388)
1.5332
(1.5790)
0.2581
(0.3593)
fdi_inw0.5442
(1.4250)
−0.5225 *
(−1.9150)
0.0546
(0.4407)
−0.2386 ***
(−3.0160)
−0.4066 **
(−2.0640)
−0.1588
(−0.7381)
fdi_out−0.2486 *
(−1.6930)
0.1941
(−1.9150)
0.1008
(0.9132)
0.2273 ***
(2.5770)
0.2220
(0.7156)
0.24852
(1.4210)
tax−1.3716
(−0.5100)
4.2048
(1.0700)
−3.0450
(−1.4180)
2.0796
(0.9722)
0.8196
(0.1513)
−1.8100
(−0.9853)
gdp0.9767
(1.2110)
−0.4772
(−0.3803)
0.2848
(0.4436)
−1.5139
(−1.3900)
−1.0445
(−0.6012)
−0.0673
(−0.0881)
bnf0.6823 ***
(2.6180)
0.1350
(0.6900)
0.3427 ***
(4.0830)
−0.0213
(−0.1123)
−0.0765
(−0.6264)
0.3441 ***
(3.4580)
cpi−11.2546
(−1.3940)
4.0532
(0.9258)
−0.1826
(−0.1082)
6.3396
(1.3950)
4.9574 **
(2.0150)
−0.9789
(−0.5745)
tud3.4459 ***
(2.9180)
3.9298 ***
(2.7010)
wbc −0.0373
(−0.4092)
−0.4244 ***
(−3.1180)
cbc 0.1894
(0.3055)
0.5252 *
(1.9060)
Error AR(2) test1.3018
(0.1930)
0.1461
(0.8838)
0.1745
(0.8615)
0.3290
(0.7348)
0.6101
(0.5418)
−1.4187
(0.1560)
Sargan over-identification test4.3321
(1.0000)
9.7972
(1.0000)
6.0488
(1.0000)
2.5043
(1.0000)
1.4737
(1.0000)
8.0036
(1.0000)
Number of countries252425252425
Observations281270235227218191
Note: see notes below Table 5.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Matuzeviciute, K.; Butkus, M.; Karaliute, A. Do Technological Innovations Affect Unemployment? Some Empirical Evidence from European Countries. Economies 2017, 5, 48. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5040048

AMA Style

Matuzeviciute K, Butkus M, Karaliute A. Do Technological Innovations Affect Unemployment? Some Empirical Evidence from European Countries. Economies. 2017; 5(4):48. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5040048

Chicago/Turabian Style

Matuzeviciute, Kristina, Mindaugas Butkus, and Akvile Karaliute. 2017. "Do Technological Innovations Affect Unemployment? Some Empirical Evidence from European Countries" Economies 5, no. 4: 48. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5040048

APA Style

Matuzeviciute, K., Butkus, M., & Karaliute, A. (2017). Do Technological Innovations Affect Unemployment? Some Empirical Evidence from European Countries. Economies, 5(4), 48. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5040048

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop