4.3. Analysis of the Spatial Spillover Effect of Tax Greenness on Carbon Emissions
According to
Table 7, green taxation is positively correlated with local environmental pollution (Main), reflecting the “green paradox” phenomenon in China’s current green taxation system. Under the pressure of economic growth and the official evaluation system—for example, the GDP growth rate remains a key performance indicator—local governments may encourage or rely on industries with high pollution and high energy consumption to sustain high economic growth, thereby offsetting the carbon emission reduction effect of green taxation. However, in neighboring regions (Wx), green taxation is negatively correlated with per capita carbon emissions, suggesting that green taxation may generate positive spillover effects at the interregional level, potentially promoting the relocation of polluting enterprises or facilitating technology diffusion.
Within provinces, there exists an insignificant yet significantly negative U-shaped relationship between revenue decentralization (fdsr) and carbon emissions. This suggests that in the initial stage, the expansion of local fiscal revenue autonomy may slightly reduce carbon emissions by allocating funds toward environmental investments. However, once the degree of decentralization surpasses a certain inflection point, it tends to exacerbate carbon emissions. This strongly supports China’s “local competition” model. Under the economic growth-centered evaluation system, when local governments gain greater control over fiscal revenues, their focus tends to shift toward “hard” infrastructure and heavy chemical projects that can rapidly boost GDP, rather than “soft” environmental governance, which involves long cycles and delayed outcomes. As fiscal autonomy increases, local governments are more inclined to use financial resources for high-intensity investment competition and may even attract enterprises by lowering environmental access thresholds, resulting in increased carbon emissions. For surrounding regions, the fiscal revenue decentralization of a given province exhibits a significant “inverted U-shaped” effect. When the level of local fiscal decentralization increases, it initially imposes a strong negative spillover effect—manifested as increased carbon emissions—on neighboring provinces. However, beyond a certain threshold, this negative impact diminishes. This pattern reveals both the “pollution haven” effect and the “race to the bottom” mechanism. When a province gains more fiscal autonomy and actively attracts investment, its lax environmental policy may attract polluting firms from neighboring regions with stricter environmental standards, thereby increasing carbon emissions in surrounding areas in the short run.
Fiscal expenditure decentralization (fdse) exhibits a significant positive U-shaped relationship within the region. The initial effect is not pronounced, but once the inflection point is surpassed, higher levels of expenditure decentralization correspond to increased local carbon emissions. This follows a logic similar to that of revenue decentralization, but with greater emphasis on expenditure structure. Chinese local governments demonstrate a strong preference for “productive expenditure,” prioritizing spending on economic construction, energy, and transportation over public services and environmental protection. This tendency intensifies with the expansion of spending autonomy, as funds are increasingly directed toward projects that generate short-term economic growth. Consequently, environmental expenditures are crowded out, resulting in higher carbon emissions. This pattern of expenditure structure is closely associated with China’s development stage and was more prevalent during the period of rapid industrialization and urbanization. The effect on surrounding areas is again “U-shaped,” but the main term is negative (insignificant). This suggests that when a province increases expenditure decentralization, it may initially produce weak positive spillovers on the carbon emissions of neighboring regions—through cross-regional infrastructure investment or green technology R&D. However, significant negative spillovers tend to emerge in later stages, and these negative effects may dominate. By heavily investing in industrial park construction and offering subsidies, local governments may create “policy depressions” that attract high-quality enterprises and resources from surrounding areas. This compels neighboring regions to adopt more aggressive development strategies that increase carbon emissions in order to sustain economic growth, ultimately leading to a cycle of vicious competition.
Fiscal autonomy (fdsz) exhibits a clear inverted U-shaped relationship. It indicates that as a province’s fiscal autonomy increases, carbon emissions initially worsen and subsequently improve. This reflects the evolution of China’s development stage and governance capacity. In the early stage—before the inflection point—local governments expanded their financial resources but held outdated development concepts, leading to a prioritization of economic growth at the expense of environmental protection and, consequently, rising carbon emissions. However, once the economic level reaches a certain threshold, increasing pressure from central environmental assessments and growing public awareness of environmental protection prompt financially capable local governments to invest more in environmental governance. They also begin promoting industrial transformation and upgrading, thereby reducing carbon emissions. This represents a typical developmental trajectory shifting from “pollution first” to “governance later.” It also exhibits an inverted U-shaped impact on surrounding areas, but the initial term is positive, indicating that the enhancement of provincial fiscal autonomy generates a strong negative spillover on the carbon emissions of neighboring regions in the early stage. This mechanism is similar to that of fdsr. When a province’s financial capacity improves, it may attract industries and investment from surrounding areas through more favorable policies during the initial phase. This disrupts the development trajectory of neighboring regions and may compel them to rely on resource extraction or polluting industries, thereby increasing carbon emissions. However, once the province surpasses the inflection point and begins industrial upgrading and stricter enforcement of environmental regulations, it may gradually transfer some low-end industries to surrounding areas in a gradient manner.
The spatial rho coefficient is negative and statistically significant (−0.150, −0.146, −0.134**). This negative spatial autocorrelation suggests the presence of “alternative competition” or a “differentiation strategy” in the environmental performance among neighboring provinces.
The results in
Table 7 are based on maximum likelihood estimation using neighboring spatial weight matrices. To further verify the robustness of the model estimation results, we conducted spatial Durbin model estimations with alternative spatial weight matrices. The results, presented in
Table 8, are consistent with those derived from
Table 7, confirming the robustness and credibility of the regression results.
According to the results in
Table 9, the results across the three models are highly consistent, revealing a clear yet paradoxical pattern: the direct effect is significantly positive (approximately 0.4), which further confirms the previously observed “paradox.” Indirect effect: it is significantly negative (approximately −0.45), representing a critically important finding. This indicates that an increase in green taxation within a region exerts a significant inhibitory effect on carbon emissions in neighboring regions—referred to as a negative spillover effect. This phenomenon may arise because stringent local pollution controls prompt firms to adopt higher environmental standards, with technological or policy innovations spilling over into neighboring areas, thereby reducing cross-regional carbon emissions. Total effect (Total): negative but statistically insignificant. After the direct effect (emission increase) and indirect effect (emission reduction) offset each other, the overall impact of green taxation on emissions across the entire region becomes statistically insignificant. This suggests that while the net effect is not clearly discernible from a global average perspective, green taxation significantly alters the spatial distribution of emissions. The primary impact of green taxation lies in its spatial spillover effect, rather than in directly reducing local emissions.
The moderating effect of the interaction between the level of economic development and fiscal decentralization is introduced to explain how the emission reduction effect of fiscal decentralization varies with the level of economic development. As shown in
Table 10, the coefficients of the three interaction terms on the local effect are significantly negative, indicating that economic development weakens the positive impact of fiscal decentralization on regional carbon emissions. In terms of the spatial spillover effect, the coefficients of the three interaction terms are all significantly positive, suggesting that economic development also mitigates the effect of fiscal decentralization in increasing carbon emissions in neighboring areas.
This result reflects the challenge of carbon emission reduction under China’s unbalanced regional development. Specifically, developed regions (such as Beijing, Shanghai, Jiangsu, and Zhejiang, which have higher per capital GDP) have crossed the inflection point of the Environmental Kuznets Curve and place greater emphasis on green and low-carbon development. In the process of development, these regions may transfer carbon emission pressures to surrounding less developed areas through mechanisms such as industrial relocation and investment competition. Meanwhile, to achieve political performance goals such as “sustained growth” and “stable employment,” economically underdeveloped regions are more inclined to relax environmental regulations to attract the transfer of high-carbon industries from neighboring developed regions, thereby falling into the trap of “pollution haven.” This dynamic leads to a spatial pattern in which carbon emissions decrease in developed regions while increasing in surrounding less developed areas, which is highly consistent with the negative spatial rho.
According to the results in
Table 11, decomposing the spatial effects of the three dimensions of fiscal decentralization and economic growth on carbon emissions, the results of the direct effects of fiscal revenue decentralization and fiscal expenditure decentralization are consistent with the regression results of the spatial Durbin model. Regarding spatial spillover effects, a higher level of economic development in neighboring provinces strengthens the promoting effect of fiscal revenue decentralization and fiscal expenditure decentralization on local carbon emissions within the region. Under the dimension of fiscal autonomy, the interaction term between fiscal decentralization and per capita PGDP is not significant, indicating that the level of economic development in neighboring provinces does not moderate the relationship between fiscal autonomy and carbon emissions in the region.
The results in
Table 12 address the central research question of this paper: whether China’s current institutional framework of fiscal decentralization enhances or weakens the impact of green taxation on carbon emissions. The direct effect of the Green Government Tax Revenue Index (ggti) is significantly positive across all three models. This indicates that under China’s current fiscal and taxation system, although green taxation serves as an important policy tool, it does not effectively reduce regional carbon emissions and is instead positively correlated with them. This suggests that local governments primarily perceive green taxation as a source of fiscal revenue rather than as a regulatory mechanism for curbing carbon emissions.
With regard to the moderating effect of fiscal decentralization, we examine both the statistical significance and the direction of the interaction terms between fiscal decentralization and green taxation. The findings reveal that fiscal expenditure decentralization (fdse) has the weakest moderating effect, whereas fiscal revenue decentralization (fdsr) and fiscal autonomy (fdsz) exhibit significant moderating effects. This implies that local governments are more responsive to the sources of fiscal revenue than to how it is allocated, which aligns with fiscal incentive theory. The overall effect of fiscal autonomy is negative, suggesting that increased local fiscal self-sufficiency can, to some extent, enhance the emission-reduction effectiveness of green taxation.
Table 13 presents the spatial effect decomposition of
Table 12, accurately distinguishing the influence of interaction terms into direct, indirect, and total effects. The results confirm the interaction effect between fiscal decentralization and green taxation. Moreover, the spatial phenomenon in which local and surrounding area effects offset or even contradict each other contributes to the uncertainty and divergence in the overall effect.
The decomposition results of the interaction term for fiscal revenue decentralization reveal that green taxation, under the influence of fiscal revenue decentralization, increases carbon emissions overall. This is primarily due to intensified tax competition among local governments under fiscal revenue decentralization, whereby the strict enforcement of green taxes locally may drive high-carbon-emission enterprises to neighboring regions.
The interaction term for fiscal expenditure decentralization exhibits a contradictory pattern: the local effect is negative, indicating that local governments can reduce local carbon emissions by allocating green tax revenues to specific environmental purposes and emission control initiatives. However, this may simultaneously increase emissions in surrounding areas, effectively shifting the carbon emission problem across space.
The spatial effect decomposition of the interaction term for fiscal autonomy indicates that when local governments possess sufficient financial resources and greater fiscal self-sufficiency, their fiscal interests become more aligned with long-term carbon reduction goals.
According to the spatial effect decomposition results in
Table 13, the signs and significance of the total effect of green taxation vary under the three dimensions of fiscal decentralization. This suggests that the role of green taxation in influencing carbon emissions does not depend solely on the tax itself, but on the specific fiscal decentralization framework within which it is implemented. This highlights the importance of integrating green taxation with complementary policy instruments and focusing on policy synergy.