Next Article in Journal
Dualism of the Health System for Sustainable Health System Financing in Benin: Collaboration or Competition?
Previous Article in Journal
Short-Term Forecasting of the JSE All-Share Index Using Gradient Boosting Machines
Previous Article in Special Issue
Effect of Human Capital Development on Household Income Growth in Burkina Faso: An Analysis Through a Decomposition Method
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Human Capital, Household Prosperity, and Social Inequalities in Sub-Saharan Africa

1
Faculty of Economics and Management, University of Yaoundé II, Yaoundé P.O. Box 1365, Cameroon
2
Department of Economics, African Centre of Excellence for Inequality Research (ACEIR), University of Nairobi, Nairobi P.O. Box 30197-00100, Kenya
3
African Centre for Shared Development Capacity Building (ACSDCB), Plot 21, Mokola Estate Extension, Barrack Road, Ibadan 200253, Nigeria
4
Kenya National Bureau of Statistics, Nairobi P.O. Box 30266-00100, Kenya
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2025, 13(8), 221; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13080221
Submission received: 24 May 2025 / Revised: 1 July 2025 / Accepted: 3 July 2025 / Published: 29 July 2025
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Human Capital Development in Africa)

Abstract

This article examines the relationship between human capital accumulation, household income, and shared prosperity using 2005–2018 household surveys in Cameroon, Ethiopia, Kenya, Nigeria, and Uganda. Human capital is found to be positively and significantly correlated with household wellbeing in all five nations. Health’s indirect benefits in Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya augment its direct benefits. Education has monotonic welfare benefits from primary to tertiary levels in all countries. Human capital and labour market participation are strongly associated with household wellbeing. The equalization of human capital endowments increases income for the 40% of the least well-off groups in three of the sample countries. All countries except Uganda record a decrease in human capital deprivation over the period studied. Redistribution is associated with a reduction in human capital deprivation, although less systematically than in the growth scenario. These results suggest that sizeable reductions in human capital deprivation are more likely to be accomplished by interventions that focus on boosting general human capital outcomes than those that redistribute the human capital formation inputs. In countries with declining human capital deprivation, the within-sector interventions seem to account for this success. Substantial heterogeneity in human capital poverty exists within and across countries and between rural and urban areas.

1. Introduction

1.1. Background

Addressing shortages of human capital stocks in Africa is instrumental in improving the standards of living in the region. The level and distribution of human capital endowments (general education, technical skills, health, and nutrition) are among the main determinants of inequality and poverty in Africa. The unequal distribution of human capital endowments at the individual and household levels is a source of disparities in access to current and future incomes, especially as mediated through labour markets.
According to Sen (1997) and Bebbington (1999), the individuals endowed with human capital are not only more skilled, productive, and efficient, but are also more capable of transforming capabilities into functioning. In analysing the relationship between human capital and welfare outcomes, it is important to determine whether a specific dimension of human capital fosters functioning or is a means to a specific end. For example, health can be an end in itself, if it reflects specific welfare dimensions, such as being well-nourished or being free from illness (Sen, 1998), but is a means to higher income or prosperity if it is an input into a production process (Grossman, 1972). However, from an ethical, individual perspective, average health levels should receive little weight in personal health assessments because an individual with poor health is deprived, irrespective of the general health prevailing in the population (Dotter & Klasen, 2020). This notwithstanding, the average perception of health in one’s neighbourhood may influence his/her self-perceived health status.
A framework for investigating the drivers, processes and welfare consequences of human capital dimensions is an important tool in generating evidence on what works to improve household prosperity in Africa and elsewhere. For instance, understanding the drivers of individual and household-level human capital endowments, and how the endowments can be translated into poverty and inequality reductions via labour market participation, is key to advancing the United Nations’ sustainable development goals. High initial inequality is detrimental to future economic growth and to poverty reduction efforts (Christiansen et al., 2002). The negative consequences of inequality occur through several channels, such as people’s engagement in rent-seeking activities and non-peaceful agitation for equal human rights. These are endemic behaviours in sub-Saharan countries due to the excessive marginalization of some communities, especially those in slums, and in rural and semi-arid areas.

1.2. Research Issues

The multidimensional nature of human capital and its different effects on welfare and shared prosperity have inspired policy advocates to place the question of human capital accumulation at the centre of the development process. From a long-run economic perspective, human capabilities (education, technical skills, nutrition and health) are key ingredients in consolidating social and technological processes that sustain shared growth (Lucas, 1988; Romer, 1990; Hanushek, 2013). Thus, substantial investments in human capital are required to transform and industrialize African economies. At the individual and household levels, it is important to understand the processes of human capital formation and to gauge its effects on economic prosperity. However, potential endogeneity, sample selectivity bias, and unobserved heterogeneity present major challenges in a proper assessment of the welfare effects of human capital formation. To that end, it is important to understand the mechanisms through which individual, household, and community characteristics affect human capital accumulation. Understanding drivers of human capital and its role in lifting households out of poverty and in empowering them to build prosperous livelihoods is the first contribution of this research endeavour, using the control function modelling and neighbourhood identification strategies, which can address endogeneity (for both continuous and dummy variables), sample selectivity, and unobserved heterogeneity biases simultaneously.
Evidence on how poverty changes over time and how the changes are linked to individual-level capabilities is vital for the design of anti-poverty interventions. Unfortunately, this sort of evidence is rare in African countries. Thus, explaining changes in household welfare in a way that accounts for effects due to inter-temporal differences across households in endowments and effects due to inter-temporal differences in returns to endowments is an indispensable intermediate step to understanding household prosperity and how it is shared.
Low levels of investments in education, nutrition, and health hinder inclusive growth by preventing vulnerable social groups from participating in its process (Appleton & Teal, 1998). Evidence on household shares in collective prosperity is a necessary task in devising public strategies to address social inequalities. The literature on equity and equal opportunities suggests that human capital plays a significant role in accounting for household prosperity (Roemer, 2002; Lefranc et al., 2008; Baye & Epo, 2015). An appraisal of the impacts of investments in human capital (education, skill, nutrition and health) on wellbeing through factual and counterfactual distributions analysis is an important policy simulation exercise. Designing factual and counterfactual human capital equalizing policy schemes and assessing their impacts on shared prosperity and on reduction in poverty and inequality is the second contribution of this paper.
The overarching idea that ties together the aforesaid two contributions is that the accumulation of human capabilities improves the level and distribution of wellbeing at both the household and community levels (Moser, 1998, 2006). Human capital constitutes one of the main inputs into the equalization of economic opportunities across social groups and across genders; especially overtime. Thus, generating evidence on how human capital endowments affect the shifting or movements of individuals or social groups in and out of some well-defined economic categories is key to designing workable social safety nets. In this regard, it is important to understand the extent to which deprivations in human capital sources of wellbeing are attributable to effects due to inter-sector mobility, those due to location-based improvements, and effects arising from location-based redistribution. Thus, understanding drivers of social mobility in Africa, and how this mobility is linked to human capabilities and functioning, is important in animating public policy debates on social inequalities. We make this third contribution by demonstrating the power of regression-based decomposition analysis of the level and distribution of household wellbeing. This type of analysis can be used to obtain multiple dimensions or a combination of dimensions in money metric units derived from drivers of a wellbeing/income-generating function.

1.3. Research Question and Objectives

This paper endeavours to answer the following question: What are the drivers and consequences of human capital formation on household income, shared prosperity, poverty, and social inequalities? The related specific objectives are to (1) determine the drivers of human capital and measure its effects on household wellbeing and growth accounting; (2) assess the impact of human capital sources of wellbeing on shared prosperity; (3) examine the role human capital plays in poverty and inequality reductions; and (4) explore changes in human capital (measured as income sources) deprivations over time and decompose the changes into those related to location-based growth, location-based redistribution, and mobility components.

1.4. Literature Review and Knowledge Gaps

In a presidential address to the American Economic Association, T. W. Schultz (1961) argued for the need to improve human capital, defined as the education, skills, health, and nutrition of individual household members. These dimensions of human capital increase prospects of labour market participation and household prosperity, which are reflected in gains in income, human wellbeing, and shared prosperity, as well as in reductions in inequality and poverty. According to Thirlwall (1999), human capital development takes several forms, such as spending on health and education facilities, formally organized education, adult education, in-service and institutional training, and retraining. Investments related to child nutrition and healthcare are also part and parcel of early human capital accumulation. In this context, impediments to greater productivity and household prosperity, such as illiteracy, poor health, malnutrition, unreceptiveness to new ideas, lack of initiative, and immobility, can be overcome by human capital investments.
An important component of theoretical literature in this field highlights a strong interactive effect between human capital and poverty reduction. There is consistent evidence that human capital formation reduces the unequal distribution of income, improves productivity, and promotes employment readiness (Fisher, 1946; T. W. Schultz, 1961, 1962; Becker, 1975; T. P. Schultz, 1993; Roemer, 1998; World Bank, 2005; Santos, 2009; Teixeira, 2014). A review of the literature indicates that the role of human capital in reducing poverty (Becker, 1995) cannot be well understood without decomposing human capital into its various dimensions and learning about the effects of individual dimensions on household income.
Human capital endowments enable people to contribute to and benefit from the growth process (Punam, 2014; Cumming et al., 2019). Moreover, the ‘Commission on Growth and Development [CGD] (2008)’ acknowledges that human capital investments through education and health promote the equality of opportunity, including in wages and employment. Components of human capital—education, nutrition, and health—are expected to have a positive effect on the creation of equal opportunity for all citizens (Mincer, 1991; Riddell & Song, 2011; Larionova & Varlamova, 2015).
Human capital theory suggests that education and health are the key determinants of current and future wellbeing (Becker, 1964; Grossman, 1972). These factors raise prospects of employment and employability, as well as people’s receptiveness to innovative ideas. Indeed, since the seminal works of Becker (see Becker, 1964; Becker & Tomes, 1976), recent advances in human capital formation frameworks have confirmed the role of human capital in the process of achieving household prosperity (Cunha et al., 2006; Cunha & Heckman, 2008; Heckman, 2007). Concerning the relationship between poverty traps and human capital accumulation, Ceroni (2001) finds that persistent inequalities in human capital follow from the observation that the poor require relatively higher financial returns to invest in human capital, because basic necessities such as food and shelter take the lion’s share of their incomes. This indicates that human capital accumulation has a non-negligible public good feature that requires government support.
A report by the World Bank (2015b) suggests that low levels of health and education, poor access to clean water, and sanitation are among the deprivations that cause low levels of income and wellbeing. Thus, improvements in the education, skills, health, and nutrition of household members, especially those who participate in the labour market, can considerably increase their productivity and earnings, as well as their receptiveness to advanced ideas and new technologies. In this way, the quality of labour can be enhanced by education, by improved health and nutrition for children and adults, by the migration of workers to places with better job opportunities, and by fertility reduction.
Studies analysing inter-temporal decomposition of poverty into growth and redistribution parts have identified the growth components as the one largely accounting for changes in the level of poverty when compared to the income redistribution component (Kakwani, 2000; Bigsten et al., 2003). Similarly, studies undertaking the sectoral decomposition of poverty changes typically attribute the bulk of the effects to the within-sector/group component. However, researchers are slow in extending these approaches to the decomposition of deprivations in regression-based sources of wellbeing, which turns out to attribute money metric units to otherwise non-monetary dimensions or a combination of dimensions of wellbeing. Up until now, nonmonetary dimensions of welfare have typically been captured in scalar form, making the determination of the attendant thresholds, a less transparent process. Thus, to better understand the processes of human capital formation, there is a need to explore the decomposition of changes in the deprivation of human capital regression-based sources of wellbeing along the mobility, sector-based growth and sector-based redistribution components.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The methodology is outlined in Section 2, followed by a detailed description and interpretation of the empirical results in Section 3, and Section 4 concludes the paper.

2. Methodology

2.1. Modelling, Estimation and Computation Methods

This paper adopts a battery of approaches embedded in a framework in which results from preceding analyses are typically used as inputs in subsequent analyses.

2.2. The Wellbeing-Generating Function

Denoting the household economic wellbeing function with Y, contingent on a set of vectors of exogenous and endogenous variables, an income-generating function specified in Equation (1) can be envisaged. The key variables determining Y may include human capital—education, skills, nutrition, labour market employment, and health—and household, community, and regional characteristics, which serve as controls. In the setup shown in Equation (1) (Heckman, 2004), human capital endowments are the endogenous covariates of policy interest.
L n Y = a 0 + k = 1 K a k Z k + η 1 E 1 + j = 2 J η j E j + ε 1
where L n Y , E1, and E , respectively, are the log of household income, a labour market indicator and human capital endowments (education, skills, nutrition, health, and/or mobility). The vector, Z , comprises K exogenous variables; a is a vector of K parameters of the exogenous explanatory variables; η is a vector of parameters of the potential endogenous explanatory variables; a 0 is the constant term; and ε 1 is the error term that captures both random terms and unobservable variables that are typically correlated with the endogenous regressors.
Since the parameter set η shows the effects of human capital endowments on household prosperity, with important policy implications, care is needed to estimate it. In particular, since household economic wellbeing and human capital endowments are jointly observed, endogeneity is a potential problem that should be addressed, if present. An appropriate estimation strategy to use in this case is the instrumental variables (IV) method. In this vein, the reduced form of the jth human capital, Equation (2) can take the form:
E j = b 0 j + k = 1 K b k Z k j + k = K + 1 K b k Z k j + ε 2 j
where K is an expanded vector of exogenous variables encompassing K covariates that belong in the economic welfare function and a vector of K K instrumental variables that affect the human capital endowment (E) but have no direct effect on household economic wellbeing L n Y , except through the jth human capital endowment. The vector b k is a set of K parameters of exogenous explanatory variables in the reduced form of the human capital endowments equation to be estimated, and ε 2 is the error term that captures both the random effects and other relevant but unobservable characteristics that influence human capital endowments.
In addition, the heterogeneity of responses due to the non-linear interaction of human capital endowments with unobservable variables could bias the estimated effects. The heterogeneity in household preferences, sometimes originating from inherited traits, could affect human capital endowments, whose effect on household economic wellbeing is captured by the interaction of the human capital endowments with their respective residuals derived from the reduced form estimates. We appeal to control functions to address these two potential issues (Heckman, 1976; Wooldridge, 2002, 2015).
Another potential endogenous variable is the labour market indicator, E1, which in our present endeavour is formal sector employment, modelled as a probit in Equation (3).
P E 1 = 1 z = Φ z δ
where P, E1, and z are probability, formal sector employment, and a vector of exogenous variables (including those in Equation (1) and instrumental variables). Φ (.) is the standard normal cumulative function and δ is the vector of parameters to be estimated. Following Wooldridge (2015, pp. 427–428), Equation (3) can be considered a probit reduced form of that equation. To purge the potential endogeneity of formal employment resulting from its correlation with the error term of the structural equation (Equation (1)), we estimate the probit model, compute the inverse Mills ratio, thus generating the generalized residual, r ^ .1
To address potential endogeneity and unobserved heterogeneity biases, Equation (1) can be augmented by including reduced form residuals (both linear and non-linear) and the interaction of the linear reduced form residuals with their corresponding endogenous counterparts, as shown in Equation (4):
L n Y = α 0 + k = 1 K α k Z k + j = 1 J η j E j + j = 2 J α j ε ^ 2 j + j = 2 J λ j ε ^ 2 j E j + φ r ^ + u
where ε ^ 2 j (j = 1, 2, …, J) are residuals of the endogenous regressors resulting from the reduced form model (Equation (2)). The residuals ε ^ 2 j serve as the controls for unobservable variables that correlate with E j , thus permitting these endogenous inputs to be treated as if they were exogenous covariates during estimation. The term, ε ^ 2 j E j is the interaction of the residuals with the actual values of each of the potential endogenous explanatory variables. The disturbance term, u is the random error and α ,   η ,   λ   and   φ are vectors of parameters to be estimated. Equation (4) is expected to produce parameter estimates that are unbiased and consistent (see Wooldridge, 2015). In the setup in Equation (4), testing the hypothesis of the exogeneity of human capital is equivalent to testing whether the coefficients on the reduced form residuals are jointly statistically insignificant.

2.3. The Identification Strategy

To instrument for health and formal sector work, we used the non-self-cluster mean of the health variable and the non-self-cluster proportion of formal sector employment, exploiting cluster-level information in the household surveys. These neighbourhood-based instruments are relevant bearing in mind the sociological constructs of emulation and imitation emerging from social interactions (Becker, 1975) norms that are practised widely in the countries under study. The expectation is that the higher the extent of wellness-reporting in a given neighbourhood, the more likely the excluded household head will report wellness, and vice versa. Similarly, if a higher proportion of formal sector workers is observed in a neighbourhood, the more likely is the excluded worker in the same cluster to be observed in formal sector work, especially if formal sector workers appear to be faring well.
The assignment of non-self-cluster means correlates with the endogenous variables but is not directly correlated with household spending, except through the wellness and sector of the activity of the key breadwinner or through other neighbourhood average characteristics that correlate with the non-self-cluster-based instruments. Because of the tendency for emulation within a cluster, assigning to a household belonging to the cluster a neighbourhood-level measure of an endogenous variable is equivalent to asserting that the assigned variable affects the household’s decisions, behaviours or status, but not the vice versa. This context reflects the exogeneity of the instruments.
Analysts familiar with the literature are likely to agree that the non-self-cluster mean/proportion may mitigate the endogeneity concerns, but some are likely to argue that such instruments may be associated with the excluded household’s wellbeing through unobserved channels. If, for example, formal sector workers are living in wealthier clusters, with both greater wellness and job availability, this context could equally affect their labour market decisions and wellbeing opportunities. Yet, the fundamental point here is that these are indirect channels, which we capture with the interaction term in our theoretical regression model stated in Equation (4).

2.4. Procedure for Accounting for Growth in Household Wellbeing

This section shows how to use the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition procedure to account for income growth in household wellbeing and then compare the relative contributions of human capital endowments to those associated with other individual, household, and community characteristics. In our setup, we consider estimated coefficients obtained from the structural model (Equation (4)) and from descriptive statistics of the different variables used in this equation to compute the contribution of endowments and returns to endowments between two periods, (t) and (t + n). After removing any arbitrariness in selecting the base year by using the Shapley value approach, which is equivalent to averaging the quantities at the two potential reference points, we can write down the following model:
L n Y ¯ t + n L n Y ¯ t = m = 1 M 0.5 X ¯ t + n , m X ¯ t , m ( β ^ t + n , m + β ^ t , m ) + m = 1 M 0.5 X ¯ t , m + X ¯ t + n , m ( β ^ t + n , m β ^ t , m )
where Xm (m = 1, 2, …, M) represents each of the variables captured in Equation (4)—both observed and predicted. The left-hand side captures growth in household wellbeing, as proxied by income, between period t and t + n. The first right-hand-side term of Equation (5) simply shows the part of the growth in household wellbeing between t and t + n that can be explained by endowments in the different characteristics. The second term is the part of growth in household wellbeing between period t and t + n that can be explained by differentials in returns to the endowments. Note that various refinements of the standard Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition (Oaxaca, 1973; Blinder, 1973) can also be used to account for the growth in household wellbeing, asset endowment, or anthropometric indicators. In a context where sample selection is accounted for, the Neuman and Oaxaca (2004) method is relevant.

2.5. Assessing Welfare Impacts of Human Capital Endowments

To characterize the impact of human capital on shared prosperity, poverty, and inequality, we first simulate factual and counterfactual distributions of household welfare. To compute the factual and counterfactual distributions, we appeal to Bourguignon et al. (2007) and Baye and Epo (2015). The underlying idea here is to obtain two welfare distributions where the factual distribution equals the initial household wellbeing distribution and the counterfactual distribution is derived from the factual distribution when differences in human capital endowments are eliminated, say by assigning the mean value or the cluster mean value to all households. To get the counterfactual benchmarks, we first obtain the factual distribution by expressing the estimated counterpart-form of Equation (4) as shown in Equation (6).
L n Y ^ = α ^ 0 + k = 1 K α ^ k X k + j = 1 J η ^ j E j + j = 2 J α ^ j ε ^ 2 j + j = 2 J λ ^ j ε ^ 2 j E j + φ ^ r ^
It is worth stressing that Equation (6) represents the estimated factual distribution of household income or wellbeing. From Equations (4) and (6), the factual or observed household welfare distribution in log form is obtainable as L n Y = L n Y ^ + u ^ , so that taking the antilog, we have Y = E x p L n Y ^ + u ^ , which is expressed in full as in Equation (7).
Y = E x p [ α ^ 0 + k = 1 K α ^ k Z k + j = 1 J η ^ j E j + j = 2 J α ^ j ε ^ 2 j + j = 2 J λ ^ j ε ^ 2 j E j + φ ^ r ^ + u ^ ]
where u ^ is the predicted error term from the estimation of Equation (4). From the factual distribution, we can derive the counterfactual distribution to study the impact of human capital interventions on a wide range of household welfare outcomes, such as the poverty–growth–redistribution relationships, sectorial decomposition, and shared prosperity. The counterfactual value function is as stated in Equation (8).
If the household heads are allocated the mean value (or their cluster mean value) of the human capital endowments ( E - j ) , while allowing exogenous circumstance-related variables to enter the function as observed, we have the distribution of wellbeing Y E - , defined as:
Y E - = E x p [ α ^ 0 + k = 1 K α ^ k Z k + j = 1 J η ^ j E - j + j = 2 J α ^ j ε ^ 2 j + j = 2 J λ ^ j ε ^ 2 j E - j + φ ^ r ^ + u ^ ]
Equation (8) is a counterfactual distribution in which human capital endowments are equalized at mean or cluster mean values. It is called counterfactual because it is not observed in real life; human capital endowments are not equalized across households, but public policy interventions may generate effects that mimic such a scenario.

2.6. Analysing the Impact of Human Capital on Shared Prosperity

To gauge the effect of human capital on shared prosperity, we use the factual (Equation (7)) and counterfactual (Equation (8)) distributions of wellbeing. Precisely, we compare shared prosperity using these two settings. To undertake this analysis, we adopt the World Bank (2013) definition of shared prosperity, which is the difference in average wellbeing at the bottom 40% of the distribution of a wellbeing metric between two periods. In this context, we consider the growth in average expenditure of the bottom 40 per cent in the factual and counterfactual distributions, and the impact of human capital is elicited by comparing the two scenarios.
For both distributions, the weighted average wellbeing per adult equivalent at the bottom 40 per cent is defined as:
Y ¯ B 40 = h = 1 z y h P Y = y h P Y z
where B40 is the poorest 40 per cent of the population, or the 40 per cent least well-off households, and Y - B 40 is the weighted average wellbeing per adult equivalent of the least well-off households. P Y = y h is the probability density function of nonnegative values of wellbeing of households, y h in vector Y represents the wellbeing of household h, and P Y z = 0.4 represents an ordering of Y until the 40th percentile.
Following the World Bank (2015a), we measure shared prosperity by growth in average expenditure at the bottom 40 per cent of the wellbeing distribution between two periods. Given Y - t + n , B 40 and Y - t , B 40 , the mean wellbeing per adult equivalent at the bottom 40 per cent at the two time periods (years) t and t + n, then shared prosperity is given as:
θ B 40 = Y ¯ t + n , B 40 Y ¯ t , B 40 n 1
where θ B 40 is the World Bank’s shared prosperity index (SPI). When observations are recorded over years, the shared prosperity index presents the annualized growth in average expenditure at the bottom 40 per cent of the welfare distribution. The corresponding annualized growth rate in population mean welfare is defined as:
θ = Y ¯ t + n Y ¯ t n 1
where Y - t and Y - t + n are the population mean welfare in time t and t + n, respectively; θ , the annualized growth in population mean welfare, represents average prosperity; and the shared prosperity premium is given by SPP = θ B 40 θ . Notice that the realization of a positive SPP is harder than that of a positive SPI because, in growing their incomes, the poorest groups compete with everyone else in the economy. In contrast, negative quantities of SPI and SPP occur comparatively easily because the poor face large relative human capital deprivations that work against their prosperity.
As indicated earlier, to measure the impact of human capital on shared prosperity, we compute the difference in shared prosperity or shared prosperity premium between the factual and counterfactual distributions. To verify the robustness of our approach, other social welfare functions, such as Sen’s (1976) social welfare function (SWF) or Atkinson’s SWF, can be used to assess the impact of a human capital intervention on household economic outcomes. Furthering our analysis, we also compute the Palma ratio, which focuses on the income disparities between those at the bottom and top of the wellbeing distribution, to supplement our shared prosperity analysis. This ratio is defined as the wellbeing share of the richest 10% divided by the share of the poorest 40 per cent. However, the downside of the Palma ratio is that it may satisfy the Pigou–Dalton transfer principle only weakly, if at all.
The factual–counterfactual analysis can also serve a broader policy purpose by eliciting the impact of human capital endowments on poverty, inequality, the components of growth–redistribution decomposition, and the sectoral intertemporal decomposition of measured poverty.

2.7. Derivation of Regressed Income Sources and Deprivation Lines

Without a loss of generality, we can express Equation (7) as Equation (12), in which case, the total welfare for the i th household is the income sum from all estimated welfare sources, M, plus the predicted error term, which is given as:
y i = exp α ^ 0 + m = 1 M β ^ m X i , m + u ^ i
where yi, is the income of household i from source m, m = 1, 2, …, M; α ^ 0 is the estimated constant term; m = 1 M β ^ m X i , m is the sum of income from M-estimated sources of household wellbeing; and u ^ i is the residual. Equation (13) gives the expression for generating the value for the estimated welfare source, m, for each household.
exp ( β ^ m X i , m ) = y i exp α ^ 0 + j m M 1 β ^ j X i , j + u ^ i
Notice that expression (13) is not a share or ratio equation but a compact mathematical way of separating out the income associated with source m from the incomes derived from all other sources, M − 1. Operationalizing Equation (13) for each regressed income source, we can sum utilities (revenues) from different income sources to obtain the total welfare for each household in money-metric units. After predicting the different regressed sources of welfare, growth–redistribution decomposition and the sectoral decomposition of changes in deprivation in each of the different sources between the two time periods are performed. Official monetary poverty lines and non-parametric regressions of each regressed welfare/income source on total expenditure per adult equivalent are used to obtain the relevant welfare cut-off line of each regression-based source of wellbeing.
Particularly, we performed non-parametric regressions with data from each of the five countries using the DAD 4.1 software. A non-parametric regression does not impose a functional form between the human capital income source and total expenditures per adult equivalent (PAE). Instead, it allows for some flexibility in the estimation of the relationship between the two variables following a weighting scheme based on the human capital income source of those households with total expenditures PAE in the neighbourhood of the predetermined monetary poverty line. This technique assigns a weighting scheme that attributes smaller weights as the absolute gaps between household total expenditures PAE and the predetermined poverty line increase. The results obtained by this process are less affected by outliers in the data and therefore unlikely to suffer from specification bias attributable to wrong functional forms.2 In each case, we project the value of the monetary poverty line from the total expenditures PAE axis to the non-parametric line, and then read the corresponding value on the human capital income source axis as the cut-off point, below which a household is considered as suffering from human capital deprivation.

2.8. Analysing Growth–Redistribution Decomposition of Changes in Human Capital Deprivation

To investigate the impact of human capital on the poverty-redistribution relationship, we make use of the well-known growth–redistribution decomposition framework attributed to Datt and Ravallion (1992) and Kakwani (2000). Particularly, we adopt the general framework for exact decomposition that can admit more than two factors using a Shapley value-based approach (Shorrocks, 1999). This method is considered a rationalization of the averaging procedure to eliminate the residual term that remains in the standard growth–redistribution decomposition (Datt & Ravallion, 1992). Given a welfare threshold, change in wellbeing between the initial period (t) and the final period (t + n) can be expressed as a contribution of growth, φ G S h , and that of redistribution, φ R S h , in the decomposition of changes in any measure of deprivation or poverty that is additively decomposable.
In the present endeavour, the welfare sub-indicators are the M regressed income sources, extracted from our estimated income-generating functions (Equations (12) and (13)). The relevant predicted income or welfare sources could be limited to regressed sources of human capital endowments, in which changes in their deprivation between two time periods are decomposed into growth and redistribution components.
Adopting the P α class of deprivation measures (Foster et al., 1984), the aggregate change in the deprivation of the regressed income source, m, can be expressed as:
Δ P α m = P α m μ t + n m , L t + n m P α m μ t m , L t m = ν α m G , R
Δ P α m is expressed as a function of the growth (G) and redistribution (R) components. The Shapley growth component Δ P α m takes the form:
ϕ G S h , m 2 , v = 1 2 ν α m G , R ν α m R + ν α m G = 0.5 P α m μ t + n m , L t + n m P α m μ t m , L t + n m + P α m μ t + n m , L t m P α m μ t m , L t m
The Shapley redistribution component Δ P α m can be expressed as:
φ R S h , m 2 , v = 1 2 ν α m G , R ν α m G + ν α m R = 0.5 P α m μ t + n m , L t + n m P α m μ t + n m , L t m + P α m μ t m , L t + n m P α m μ t m , L t m
Equations (15) and (16) express the decomposition of wellbeing changes of regressed income source, m, into growth and redistribution components, respectively. The change in deprivation can now be expressed as the sum of the growth and redistribution components with:
Δ P α m = φ α G S h , m 2 , ν + φ α R S h , m 2 , ν

2.9. Addressing Sectoral Decomposition of Changes in Human Capital Deprivation

The generation of regressed income sources as indicated in Equation (13) is inspired by the regression income source framework suggested by Morduch and Sicular (2002) and Wan (2004). To explore the extent to which changes in human capital deprivation are due to mobility, location-based growth and location-based redistribution effects, we implement the sectoral decomposition of changes in deprivation. Subgroup consistency constitutes one of the most desirable properties of a good measure of deprivation once the welfare cut-off is established (Foster & Shorrocks, 1991; Balisacan, 1995). This implies that, all else being equal, the overall level of deprivation would fall whenever deprivation decreases within some subgroups of the population and is unchanged outside of those groups. In terms of the principle of additive decomposability, overall deprivation is the weighted average of subgroup deprivation levels. These weights are the respective population shares of the different subgroups.
We compute the within-location and between-location components in accounting for observed changes in deprivation. To attain this task, we exploit the sectoral decomposition approach (Ravallion & Huppi, 1991) of changes in deprivation between two dates, t and t + n, and the Shapley value decomposition framework (Shorrocks, 1999). To undertake the decomposition, let f s m and P s m represent the population share and deprivation level of a particular regressed source, m, that reflects the level of deprivation for sector/location s ∈ S. Hinging on the property of subgroup decomposability of the Pα class of deprivation measures, let aggregate levels of deprivation of regressed source m be expressed as P α , t m = s S f s , t m P α s , t m . Change in the level of aggregate deprivation between period t and t + n yields:
Δ P α m = P α , t + n m P α , t m = s S [ f s , t + n m P α s , t + n m f s , t m P α s , t m ]
Extending the analysis, we can account for the overall change in deprivation ( Δ P α m ) in terms of changes in deprivation within given sectors or groups Δ P α s m = P α s , t + n m P α s , t m , s S , and the population shifts between sectors/groups, Δ f s = f s , t + n m f s , t m , s S .
To obtain an exact decomposition, we adopt the Shapley value-based decomposition framework. We then express the exact within-sector effects ϕ α W S h , m and between-sector effects ϕ α B S h , m of aggregate deprivation changes of source, m, as:
ϕ α W S h , m =   0.5 s S [ f s , t m + f s , t + n m ] Δ P α s m
ϕ α B S h , m =   0.5 s S [ P α s , t m + P α s , t + n m ] Δ f s m
The overall change in deprivation, as expressed in Equation (18), can now be rewritten in terms of exactly two components: within-location changes in deprivation and between-location population shift effects:
Δ P α m =   ϕ α W S h , m +   ϕ α B S h , m = W i t h i n - l o c a t i o n   e f f e c t s   +   B e t w e e n - l o c a t i o n   p o p u l a t i o n   s h i f t s   e f f e c t
The within-sector effects can be further decomposed into within-location growth and within-location redistribution effects, where the groups are urban, semi-urban, and rural locations.

3. Empirical Results and Discussions

It is worth noting that the statistical procedures outlined in the methodological section above are designed to identify impacts of policies or interventions on the level or distribution of the household wellbeing. However, due to the cross-sectional nature of the data we use, our estimation results are best interpreted as associations, rather than as impacts or causal effects, except in simulation scenarios where we appeal to a ceteris paribus assumption.

3.1. Determinants of Household Wellbeing

We report only results for estimations using the control function for the five countries studied, as the results from the OLS, 2SLS (residual inclusion method), and the reduced form estimates can be viewed in the Appendix A and Appendix B. The control function generalized residual version accounts for the potential endogeneity of health and labour market inputs into the wellbeing-generating function. The coefficients on the predicted residual for health, the interaction of health with its predicted residual, and the generalized residual for formal sector labour market participation are statistically different from zero. This statistical significance of the coefficients on the control function variables is the validation of our choice to prefer the control function estimates.
Table 1, Columns 1 to 5, shows that human health capital is positively and significantly related to household economic wellbeing in all five countries. These results indicate that a unit (percentage) increase in the health index (wellness) produces a 0.32 to 2.65 log-point increase in household economic wellbeing, with Uganda (Table 1, Column 5) registering the highest value and Ethiopia the lowest (Table 1, Column 2). The indirect effect of health, as captured by the interaction of health with its reduced-form residual, shows that the reduced-form unobservable variables significantly complement health in explaining household economic wellbeing in Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya (Table 1, Columns 1 to 3). This is a technical point worth elaboration.
The coefficient on health is the direct effect of health on household wellbeing. As can be readily checked from the regression results, the coefficient on the interaction between health and its predicted residual (interaction term) is the indirect effect of health on household economic wellbeing. The indirect effects of health on wellbeing depend on the estimated coefficients of the interaction of wellness and its residual captured at the mean value of the residual. Table 1, in the case of Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya, shows the indirect effects of health on household wellbeing to be positive and statistically significant. This is evidence of important complementarities between health and unobserved correlates of health in advancing household prosperity. In Uganda, the unobservable variables are substituting for health (reducing the direct effect) in explaining household economic wellbeing (Table 1, Column 5). In Nigeria, the substitution effect is statistically insignificant. Thus, in four of the five countries, there is evidence of important unobserved heterogeneities. These unobserved heterogeneities may originate from inherited genetic endowments from parents or geographical-based circumstances that are generally beyond individual or household control but are affecting the effect of health on wellbeing.
Table 1, Columns 1 to 5, suggests that, compared with no education, the positive and significant effects of levels of education on household welfare increase monotonically from a primary to a tertiary level of education. Comparing these effects by level of education reveals that Kenya registered the highest effect for a primary level of education (0.15 log-points), Ethiopia for secondary education (0.29 log-points), and Uganda for tertiary education (0.6 log-points). Thus, the promotion of human capital (education and health) would increase household wellbeing through two key mechanisms—namely, improved employment opportunities (Mincer, 1962) and the enhancement of the decision-making abilities of individuals (Becker, 1964; Grossman, 1972; T. Schultz, 1975).
Formal sector engagement is contingent on participation in the labour market and obtaining a job. In four of the five countries, Kenya, Ethiopia, Nigeria, and Cameroon, formal sector work is associated with 0.08 to 0.63 log-points of positive and significant effects on household welfare (Table 1, Columns 1 to 4). On the contrary, formal sector work tends to dampen household wellbeing in Uganda (by 0.59 log-points). This negative effect of formal sector work in Uganda is attributable to the possibility that there is a relatively high phenomenon of job mismatch, which is characterized as underemployment.
Age portrays a significant U-shaped relationship with household wellbeing in all five countries. The age range above which any additional year improves household welfare is between 35 and 45 years (Table 1, Columns 1 to 5). Deviating from the general beliefs about gender bias, female household heads have 0.07 to 0.09 log-points higher household income relative to their male counterparts in Cameroon and Ethiopia (Table 1, Columns 1 and 2). However, this finding is not evidence that the mean incomes of female heads in Cameroon and Ethiopia are higher than the average incomes of their male counterparts. Instead, the estimates show that female household headship in the two countries is correlated with factors that have higher income returns relative to factors that matter for male headship. For example, females with tertiary education or entrepreneurial talent might have higher chances of heading households in certain contexts.
Meanwhile, the incomes of female household heads in Kenya and Nigeria are 0.07 log-points less than those of their male counterparts. Land ownership, measured at the cluster level (Table 1), is negatively associated with household economic wellbeing in all countries studied. This finding likely reflects the difficulties that households in rural communities face in converting land into consumable or marketable produce. However, land in Africa is highly valued and much sought after, but arguably for non-income reasons (Berry, 1993). The prevalence of farmer–grassier conflicts may also be at the root of the estimated negative returns of land ownership.
Household heads residing in rural areas are 0.23 to 0.43 log-points less on an income scale compared to their urban counterparts, with Kenya registering the highest estimate (Table 1, Columns 1 to 5). As opposed to the general belief that there is a wellbeing premium in marriage, our results show that couples register welfare deficits in all five countries. In terms of regions, the main takeaway from Table 1 is that dwellers in localities that do not host the political or economic capital, as well as in regions that are arid or likely to suffer from droughts, registered household economic wellbeing deficits ranging from 0.04 log-points to 0.73 log-points in the five countries. Over time, households incurred wellbeing gains in the order of 0.34 to 1.93 log-points, with Nigeria recording the highest values.
Table 1 also reports the estimated coefficients of the generalized residuals for formal sector engagement in the five countries. A negative effect of the generalized residual suggests that a formal sector worker selected into the estimation sample enjoys a smaller amount of economic wellbeing than a formal sector worker drawn randomly from the general population. Meanwhile, a positive effect suggests that a formal sector worker selected into the estimation sample spends more than a formal sector worker drawn randomly from the general population. Specifically, in the case of Cameroon, because the sample mean of the generalized residual is 0.039 (see Table A1 in the Appendix A), formal sector workers captured in the estimation sample are about 6.1% (0.039 × (−157)) less endowed in wellbeing compared to their counterparts randomly drawn from the general population. In the case of Nigeria, the sample mean of the generalized residual is −0.041 (see Table A1 in the Appendix A), which suggests that formal sector workers in the estimation sample are about 2.3% ((−0.041) × (−57.2)) more endowed in economic wellbeing relative to their counterparts randomly drawn from the general population. Lastly, it is worth noting that the estimated coefficients on dummy covariates can be adjusted as in Halvorsen and Palmquist (1980, p. 474).

3.2. Explaining Household Wellbeing Growth: The Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder Decomposition Estimates

To gauge household wellbeing growth for each of the five countries in the study, we use the household wellbeing function and the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition framework to analyse the contributions of the different household income sources in explaining wellbeing growth (Table 2). Descriptive statistics of variables used to carry out the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions and the control function-generalized residual estimates by year used to implement the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions are available in the Appendix B.
Cameroon (2007–2014), Ethiopia (2013–2018), and Uganda (2005–2015) reported growth in household wellbeing of 0.04, 0.52, and 0.01 log-points, respectively (Table 2, Columns 3, 6, and 15). On the contrary, Kenya (2005–2015) and Nigeria (2010–2015) recorded deficits in household wellbeing growth of 0.27 and 0.91 log-points, respectively (Table 2, Columns 9 and 12).
To assess the net effects of the different household wellbeing sources, we considered the sum of access and returns to endowments components for the different sources of the wellbeing function (Table 2, Columns 3, 6, 9, 12, and 15). In all five countries, we observe the important role that human capital (health, education, and labour mobility) plays in enhancing growth in household welfare or in attenuating the effects of adverse factors. Additionally, we observe the relatively important role of returns to endowments in general, and particularly the returns associated with human capital in driving the welfare gaps in the five countries (See Table 2, Columns 3, 6, 9, 12, and 15).
We observe that human health capital is key in accounting for growth or deficits in household wellbeing. While in Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Nigeria (Table 2, Columns 3, 6 and 12), health largely explains growth in household wellbeing, in Kenya and Uganda, it largely accounts for the shortfalls in growth (Table 2, Columns 6 and 15). Education has a net positive effect on household wellbeing growth in all the countries in the study, except in Cameroon, where it has a negative net contribution to growth. In terms of formal sector employment, Table 2 shows that the net effect of formal sector employment on household welfare growth is positive in four of the five countries. In Kenya, the net effect of formal sector employment on welfare growth is negative, perhaps due to a large share of unregistered but profitable firms in the informal sector. Farmland ownership is household growth-ameliorating in Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya (Table 2, Columns 3, 6 and 9), but household income growth-reducing in Nigeria and Uganda (Table 2, Columns 12 and 15).
Table 2 also shows that female household heads contribute positively towards expanding household welfare in Ethiopia and Nigeria (Table 2, Columns 6 and 12). Meanwhile, female headship is household income growth-eroding in Cameroon, Kenya and Uganda (Table 2, Columns 3, 9 and 15).
Although largely driven by returns to endowments, the location dummy in Table 2 suggests the following: (a) households residing in rural areas in Cameroon positively accounted for growth in household wellbeing, unlike the regional dummies—excluding the political and economic capitals (Table 2, Column 3); (b) rural households and regional dummies in Ethiopia, except for the Amhara, Oromia, Benishangul Gumuz, and SNNP provinces, negatively accounted for observed growth in household wellbeing (Table 2, Column 6); (c) rural Kenyan households, as well as those residing in the Eastern and Nyanza provinces, appear to contribute negatively to household wellbeing growth, unlike their urban counterparts and the other provinces (Table 2, Column 9); (d) residing in rural areas and the South East regions of Nigeria positively contributed to household welfare improvements relative to their urban colleagues and the other regions (Table 2, Column 12); and (e) whereas rural areas accounted negatively for growth in household welfare, regional dummies accounted positively to growth in household wellbeing (Table 2, Column 12).

3.3. Shared Prosperity Analysis

Table 3 and Table 4 report the results of shared prosperity, whilst Table 5 displays the Palma ratios. Table 3 suggests that over the period under review for each country (Cameroon 2007 and 2014; Ethiopia 2013 and 2018; Kenya 2005 and 2015; Nigeria 2010 and 2015; and Uganda 2005 and 2015), the average expenditure of households at the 40th percentile of the wellbeing distribution increases when human capital inequality is eliminated in the counterfactual distribution, except in Cameroon in 2007 (Table 3, Column 3) and Uganda in 2015 (Table 3, Column, 6). In addition, the relative gains reported across locations (overall, urban and rural) are higher in rural areas than in urban areas and in all locations. This points to the observation that the bottom 40% of the population registered far greater improvements in wellbeing in rural areas than in urban areas.
Table 4 enables the assessment of shared prosperity and its nature in all five countries. Column 1 shows that in the factual distribution, shared prosperity is depicted overall and by location, except for urban Cameroon. In addition, Uganda (2005–2015) and Ethiopia (2013–2018) reveal high rates of growth in household wellbeing of the bottom 40 per cent of the wellbeing distribution. Except for Cameroon, urban areas in other countries experienced higher rates of shared prosperity than their rural counterparts in the factual distribution.
Considering the counterfactual distribution (Table 4, Column 2), we observe that the bottom 40th percentile registered positive growth overall and for both rural and urban areas in the five countries. The higher values for urban areas imply that putting in place interventions that level human capital differences would lead to shared prosperity improvements, more so in urban than in rural locations. Additionally, equalizing human capital is shared prosperity-enhancing in Cameroon, Kenya (excluding urban Kenya), and Nigeria overall and by location, as revealed by the growth rates of the bottom forty per cent in the counterfactual relative to the factual distribution (Table 4, Column 2 versus Column 1). While Ethiopia and Uganda registered shared prosperity in the counterfactual distributions, the shared prosperity rates were lower than in the corresponding factual distributions.
In terms of shared prosperity premium, Kenya stands out distinctly in registering shared prosperity premiums in both the factual and counterfactual distributions—overall and by location. In both factual and counterfactual distributions, Uganda registered shared prosperity premiums overall and in rural settings. In addition, Nigeria registered shared prosperity premiums in the counterfactual distribution overall and in rural areas. (Table 4, Column 2). Meanwhile, Cameroon and Ethiopia experienced shared prosperity deficits in both distributions over the periods under analysis. This is an indication that in these two countries, although the share of benefits from growth accruing to the population increased over the different periods under review, the 40% least well-off households gained proportionately less from the rising prosperity compared to their well-off counterparts.
To assess inequality between households at the bottom and top of the distributions, Table 5 presents the Palma ratios for the factual and counterfactual distributions. Results illustrate that in all five countries, in both distributions, inequality is worsening between the top 10% and the bottom 40% of the less well-off. Particularly, in Cameroon, Nigeria, and Uganda, equalizing human capital endowments is inequality-increasing in the counterfactual distribution between the richest 10th percentile and the bottom 40th percentile compared to the factual distribution (Table 5, Columns 2 versus 1). This outcome is probably due to lower returns to higher stocks of human capital endowments among the least well-off, engendered by equalization. On the contrary, the negative inequality impacts for Kenya and Ethiopia suggest that eliminating human capital disparities is Palma ratio-decreasing in the counterfactual distribution. This is a signal that by adopting interventions that level disparities in human capital in Ethiopia and Kenya, the shares of average household expenditure of the top 10th percentile of the population in terms of wellbeing divided by the bottom 40th percentile would decrease over time. Thus, allowing interventions that level the playing field in terms of human capital differences would have an inequality-reducing tendency between the tails of the distribution of wellbeing. The findings in Table 4 and Table 5 suggest that the growth and inequality effects of human capital equalization are context-specific.

3.4. The Role of Human Capital Endowments on Poverty and Inequality

Table 6 shows factual and counterfactual poverty indices, and Table 7 indicates the impact of human capital equalization on inequality in all five countries. We employ the Foster–Greer and Thorbecke indices for the incidence, depth/intensity, and severity of poverty. Table 6, Columns 3, 6, and 9, portrays the changes in the incidence, depth, and severity of poverty when we compare the counterfactual and the factual distributions. These results show that levelling human capital disparities reduces the incidence, depth, and severity of poverty in Cameroon, Ethiopia, Kenya, and Nigeria.
In Table 6, the poverty reduction gains were higher in rural than in urban areas in these four countries. Results also indicate that eliminating human capital differences, achievements in reducing the incidence and depth of poverty become more pronounced in Nigeria and Ethiopia (Table 6, Columns 3 and 6). Meanwhile, Nigeria and Kenya registered the greatest success in the alleviation of the severity of poverty—that is, in reducing the inequality among the poor (Table 6, Column 9). However, equalizing human capital disparities is poverty-exacerbating in all three measures in Uganda. This is some indication that the actual distribution of human capital is inequality-reducing in Uganda.
Regarding the dynamics of inequality measured by Gini in Table 7 above, we observe that equalizing human capital disparities as in the counterfactual distribution reduced inequality overall and by location in Ethiopia and Kenya (Table 7, Column 3). Considering the urban–rural dynamics in Ethiopia and Kenya, the differences between the counterfactual and factual distributions show that the inequality-reducing tendency due to human capital equalization is more of an urban than a rural phenomenon. On the contrary, levelling disparities in human capital is Gini inequality-increasing in Uganda, Nigeria, and Cameroon by large orders of magnitude (Table 7, Column 3). In addition, an increase in inequality became more acute in rural areas in Cameroon and Uganda and more severe in urban areas in Nigeria, unlike in their rural counterparts after equalization.

3.5. Components of Inter-Temporal Changes in Human Capital Deprivations

Estimates of Human Capital Deprivations

The monetary poverty and human capital income source cut-off points are shown in Table A3 and Table A4 in Appendix A. Table 8 shows results of the incidence (Table 8, Columns 2 and 6), depth (Table 8, Columns 3 and 7), and severity (Table 8, Columns 4 and 8) of human capital deprivations. The evolution of the population shares (Table 9, Columns 1 and 5) suggests that in Cameroon (2007–2014), Ethiopia (2013–2018), and Kenya (2005–2015), rural areas experienced declining population shares in contrast to urban areas. This may reflect rural–urban migration. Meanwhile, in Nigeria and Uganda, rural population shares increased, and urban population shares contracted—a possible reflection of reverse migration. These shares inform the weights used to compute changes in the incidence, depth, and severity of human capital poverty. The incidence of human capital deprivation declined in four of the five countries in the periods under study. Only in Kenya did the incidence of human capital poverty worsen.

3.6. Estimates of the Growth and Redistribution Effects of Changes in Human Capital Deprivations

Table 9 presents the growth and redistribution effects of intertemporal changes in human capital deprivation. In all five countries, we observe the important role of growth in attenuating the incidence, depth, and severity of human capital poverty (Table 9, Columns 1, 4 and 7). There is some indication that growth might be a credible channel to improve human capital endowments.
The largest effects of growth on the incidence of human capital deprivation were registered in Nigeria and Ethiopia and in Kenya and Nigeria for the depth and severity of human capital deprivation. In addition, the results suggest that to eradicate human capital deprivations in a substantive way in all five countries, there is a need for interventions that enhance human capital both in urban and rural areas.
The ability of the redistribution component to alleviate human capital deprivation is less systematic (Table 9, Columns 2, 5, and 9) than the case of the growth component. However, we observe higher benefits in mitigating human capital deprivations in situations where the redistribution components are negative. These results indicate that to significantly reduce human capital deprivation, interventions that improve investments in human capital are likely to be more inclusive than those that redistribute it in the process of bridging disparities in these endowments. However, in countries like Ethiopia and Uganda that register declining overall incidence, depth, and severity of human capital deprivation, we observe that the redistribution components declined overall and by location, especially in Ethiopia. For Uganda, the redistribution component was negative for the incidence of deprivation and only in urban areas for the depth and severity of human capital deprivation.
On the contrary, in countries with worsening overall incidence or depth and severity of human capital deprivation, like Kenya, Cameroon, and Nigeria, the positive redistribution components overwhelm the growth components. Meanwhile, in Cameroon, Kenya, and Nigeria, the effects of redistribution in rural areas were more effective than those in urban areas in affecting the incidence of human capital deprivation.

3.7. Estimates of Sectoral Decomposition of Changes in Human Capital Deprivation

Regarding the sectoral decomposition of changes in human capital deprivation by location, Table 10 shows estimates of the incidence (Columns 1 to 3), depth (Columns 4 to 6), and severity (Columns 7 to 9) of deprivation. In the different scenarios portraying a decline in human capital deprivation, we observe that the within-sector effects largely account for the decrease in countries achieving such improvements (Table 10, Columns 1, 4, and 7). The importance of a decline in human capital (HC) deprivation within rural areas significantly accounts for the reduction in the incidence of human capital deprivation in Cameroon, Ethiopia, Nigeria, and Uganda (Columns 1 and 3). On the contrary, in Kenya, the within-sector effects worsen the incidence of human capital deprivation, and the contribution of rural areas appears to be the main driving force (Columns 1 and 3).
Considering the between-sector effects, Table 10 (Columns 2, 5, and 8) depicts two distinct scenarios. In Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya, rural settings register negative values, suggesting a contribution to the alleviation of human capital (HC) deprivation. Meanwhile, urban localities posted positive values, although their effects were lower than those in rural areas. The revelation here is that the fall in the proportion of human capital deprived households in rural areas affects the overall deprivation rates and therefore deserves some policy attention. In Nigeria and Uganda, the overall between-sector effects are positive, but the negative within-sector effects overwhelm the positive effects to yield a favourable effect on the alleviation of human capital deprivation (Columns 1–3). In this setting, both urban and rural areas register net favourable effects in the deprivation-alleviation process (Column 3).
In terms of the depth and severity of HC deprivation, (1) Nigeria stands out prominently in that, both within- and between-sector effects exacerbate HC deprivation; (2) in the case of Ethiopia and Kenya, both within- and between-sector effects are HC poverty-reducing; and (3) meanwhile, in Cameroon and Uganda, the two effects show opposing signals on HC depth and severity rates.
Nonetheless, the outcome of the overall dynamics of deprivation at the national level and by location appears to hinge largely on the extent of the within-sector components for the incidence depth and severity of HC poverty, except in the case of the severity of HC poverty in Uganda.

4. Discussion

As a framework paper in distributive analysis, this work has made the following contributions to the related literature:
(i)
The power of the control function procedure in policy analysis has been shown to lie in simultaneously netting out endogeneity, sample selectivity, and unobserved heterogeneity biases from the evidence generated to support policy decisions and actions.
(ii)
While this method has been widely implemented in the literature (Heckman, 1976; Wooldridge, 2002, 2015), we are probably the first to use it to analyse the nexus between growth, shared prosperity, and inequality in Sub-Saharan Africa, thus showing how to strengthen the evidence needed to address slow growth while also reducing social inequalities in the region.
(iii)
The estimated welfare-generating function allows for factual and counterfactual analyses of the impacts of public policies on welfare outcomes of interest (Bourguignon et al., 2007), thus showing the difference that interventions can make in people’s wellbeing.
(iv)
Our empirical procedure facilitates the monetization of otherwise non-monetary dimensions of wellbeing, such as human capital or its components, e.g., health, education, nutrition, and labour market engagements.
(v)
As noted previously, up until now, nonmonetary dimensions of welfare have typically been captured in a scalar form, thus masking their optimal thresholds and constituent parts, particularly in poverty and inequality reduction analyses.

5. Conclusions

This study investigated the drivers and consequences of human capital on household income, income growth, poverty, inequality, and shared prosperity, as well as the decomposition of changes in human capital deprivation using household survey data from Cameroon, Ethiopia, Kenya, Nigeria, and Uganda collected in the period 2005–2018. To achieve these objectives, we deployed (a) control functions to estimate parameters of the income generating functions; (b) the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition to account for growth in household welfare; (c) factual and counterfactual distribution analyses to capture the impact of human capital endowments on poverty, inequality, and shared prosperity; and (d) deprivation indices and inter-temporal decomposition methods to configure changes in human capital deprivation into growth–redistribution and within–between location components.
The results showed that human capital positively and significantly correlates with household wellbeing in all five countries. The indirect effects of human health capital complement the direct effects in explaining household economic wellbeing in Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya. The welfare effects of education increase monotonically, from primary to tertiary levels, in all five countries. Compared with the informal sector, formal sector work correlates positively with household welfare in Cameroon, Ethiopia, Kenya, and Nigeria. Households residing in rural areas are on a lower wellbeing level than their urban counterparts in all countries.
Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Uganda registered appreciable growth in household wellbeing, unlike Kenya and Nigeria. Returns to endowments in Cameroon, access and returns to endowments in Ethiopia, and access to endowments in Uganda correlated favourably with improvements in household wellbeing. In Kenya and Nigeria, both access and returns to human capital endowments affect growth in household income. The results also showed the role of human capital (health, education, and labour) in enhancing household income or attenuating unfavourable effects on it. There is evidence that human health capital is key in accounting for growth in household income. While in Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Nigeria, health largely explains growth in household wellbeing, in Kenya and Uganda, it accounts for growth shortfalls. Education has a net positive effect on growth in household income, except in Cameroon, where it has a negative net contribution. The effect of formal sector employment on growth in household welfare is positive in four of the five countries—Kenya being the odd one.
The average expenditure of households at the bottom 40th percentile of the income distribution increases with human capital equalization, except in Cameroon in 2007 and Uganda in 2015. Households at the bottom 40th percentile of income distribution registered positive growth overall and by location in the five countries. The higher values for urban areas imply that putting in place interventions that level human capital differences would improve shared prosperity, more so in urban than in rural areas. Human capital equalization is shared-prosperity enhancing in Cameroon, rural Kenya, and generally in Nigeria. Kenya and Uganda stood out distinctly in registering large shared-prosperity premiums in both the factual and counterfactual distributions. Meanwhile, Nigeria registered shared-prosperity premiums only in the counterfactual distribution overall and in rural areas. Cameroon and Ethiopia experienced shared-prosperity deficits in both distributions over the study period. This is an indication that in these two countries, although the share of benefits from growth accruing to the population increased over time, the 40% least well-off households gained less from the rising prosperity.
An analysis of the incidence, depth, and severity of poverty by comparing these indices between the factual and counterfactual distributions reveals that they fell for all countries except Uganda. Considering the urban–rural patterns, the benefits associated with equalizing human capital disparities are higher in rural than urban areas in Cameroon, Ethiopia, Kenya, and Nigeria. The Gini indices declined in rural and urban settings when disparities in human capital were removed, but only in Ethiopia and Kenya. To eradicate human capital deprivation in a substantive way in the five countries, there is a need for interventions that expand human capital provision to cover both urban and rural areas. The ability of the redistribution component in alleviating human capital deprivation is non-negligible but less systematic than the growth component. These results indicate that to significantly reduce human capital deprivations, interventions that improve human capital outcomes are more likely to be inclusive than those that redistribute human capital inputs. However, in Kenya, Cameroon, and Nigeria, the positive redistribution components overwhelm the growth components; meanwhile, the effects of redistribution in rural areas are more effective than those in urban areas in stemming the incidence of human capital deprivation.
In countries experiencing reductions in human capital deprivation, we observed that the within-sector effects largely account for this success. In Cameroon, Ethiopia, and Kenya, rural settings seem to account for observed reductions in human capital deprivation. This is evidence that differential interventions may be needed for rural and urban areas. In Nigeria and Uganda, the negative within-sector effects overwhelm the positive between-sector effects in alleviating human capital deprivation. In this setting, both urban and rural areas register net reductions in human capital poverty. Nonetheless, the overall change in human capital deprivation at the national and local levels is largely driven by within-sector interventions.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, B.N.E., F.M.B. and G.M.; Methodology, B.N.E., F.M.B., G.M., O.A. and S.K.; Software, S.K.; Validation, B.N.E. and F.M.B.; Formal analysis, B.N.E., F.M.B., G.M., D.K.M., O.A. and S.K.; Investigation, B.N.E. and F.M.B.; Data curation, B.N.E., F.M.B., G.M. and S.K.; Writing—original draft, B.N.E., F.M.B., G.M., D.K.M., O.A. and S.K.; Writing—review & editing, B.N.E., F.M.B., G.M., D.K.M., O.A. and S.K.; Project administration, O.A.; Funding acquisition, G.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the African Economic Research Consortium (AERC), Nairobi. Grant No: RC20514.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable because we used secondary data sources.

Data Availability Statement

Data for Ethiopia, Kenya, Nigeria and Uganda was obtained from the Living Standards Measurement Study (LSMS), The World Bank’s Flagship Household Survey Program (https://www.worldbank.org/en/programs/lsms#) and for Cameroon from the National Institute of Statistics (http://ins-cameroun.cm). These data sets were accessed on 31 June 2021.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Descriptive statistics.
Table A1. Descriptive statistics.
CameroonEthiopiaKenyaNigeriaUganda
VariablesMeanSd.MeanSd.MeanSd.MeanSd.MeanSd.
Household expenditure per adult equivalent723,665737,53915,39118,11955307224121,822169,10022,904104,601
Health0.7320.3130.8070.3120.8230.3110.8620.2910.6840.429
Health times year dummy 0.3660.406
No education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.2210.4150.4720.4990.2380.4260.1160.3200.1570.364
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3280.4700.2700.4440.2490.4320.2090.4060.5130.500
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3570.4790.1200.3250.1560.3630.2090.4070.2250.417
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.0920.2890.1210.3260.1330.3400.1270.3330.0720.259
Age42.6815.5243.1715.4544.60315.92951.2414.9643.4515.639
Age squared2062153121031527224316322849163021321550
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.2780.4480.3050.4600.3240.4680.1500.3570.3030.460
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.4550.4980.5430.4980.6170.4860.6780.4670.7360.441
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.5580.4970.6810.4660.7120.4530.7990.4000.7240.447
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership0.3400.2400.3850.2670.4890.2550.5650.3170.5100.195
Formal (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.1670.3730.1780.3820.1430.3500.1630.3690.2440.429
Locality A0.0610.2390.0890.2850.1370.3440.1650.3710.3030.460
Locality B0.0750.2630.0550.2280.0950.2940.1530.3600.2300.421
Locality C0.0560.2300.1480.3550.1390.3460.1890.3920.2360.425
Locality D0.1190.3230.0410.1970.0590.2350.1590.3660.2300.421
Locality E0.0600.2370.0670.2490.0780.2680.1590.366
Locality F0.0810.2720.0520.2220.1780.3830.1750.380
Locality G0.1110.3140.0590.2360.1970.397
Locality H0.1010.3020.1500.3570.1150.319
Locality I0.0500.2180.1570.364
Locality J0.0900.2860.0750.263
Locality K 0.1070.309
Year dummy0.4910.5000.5630.4960.6220.485 0.3950.489
Health residual−0.0010.302−0.0100.288−0.0080.302−0.0010.279−0.0180.420
Health times year dummy residual 0.0000.190
Health times its residual0.0890.1410.0740.1500.0840.1400.0770.1150.1620.173
Health times year dummy times its residual 0.0350.083
Generalized residual for formal sector0.0390.049−0.0350.060−0.0570.057−0.0410.059−0.0600.077
Non-self-cluster average of health0.7320.0890.8070.0990.8230.1070.8010.1050.6810.130
Non-self-cluster average of health times year dummy 0.3660.405
Non-self-cluster average of formal employment0.1670.1360.1770.1660.1430.1470.1550.1640.2400.128
Non-self-cluster average for labour market participation0.9320.0850.7210.1590.8690.1650.8800.1030.8500.125
Factual distribution for household expenditure per capita787,107.8781,335.115,447.918,160.95531.17224.7121,431.6170,008.423,012.4104,929
Counterfactual distribution when human capital is equalized735,009.3720,076.218,955.821,115.96431.78006.7301,665.9540,281.166,134.7863,941.7
Being sick (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3410.4740.1350.3420.2750.4470.2020.4020.3800.485
Visited a hospital for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3490.4770.0740.2620.0550.2280.0770.2660.1670.373
Visited a health centre for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3320.4710.1140.3180.0240.1540.0120.1110.0830.276
Consulted by a health practitioner (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.1710.3770.2740.4460.2040.4030.1440.3510.3280.469
Source: Computed by authors. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = North West, F = West, G = South, and H = South West. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table A2. Multiple correspondence analysis results of the health composite index.
Table A2. Multiple correspondence analysis results of the health composite index.
CameroonEthiopiaKenya
VariablesScoresContributionsVariablesScoresContributionsVariablesScoresContributions
First AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond Axis
Being sick (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Being sick (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Being sick (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−1.845−0.6200.1000.009Yes−2.345−0.7340.1340.010Yes−2.020−0.0320.2020.000
Otherwise0.9710.3260.1900.018Otherwise0.3870.1210.0220.002Otherwise0.7340.0120.0730.000
Visited a hospital for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Visited a hospital for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Visited a hospital for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−0.5711.9030.0090.087Yes−2.834−5.6480.0900.272Yes−3.1335.0200.1050.184
Otherwise0.298−0.9930.0180.167Otherwise0.1980.3940.0060.019Otherwise0.191−0.3060.0060.011
Visited a health centre for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Visited a health centre for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Visited a health centre for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−0.6501.6800.0150.086Yes−2.6803.5950.1420.193Yes−3.402−9.2350.0600.009
Otherwise0.390−1.0070.0260.143Otherwise0.346−0.4640.0180.025Otherwise0.0980.2670.0020.305
Consulted by a health practitioner (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Consulted by a health practitioner (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Consulted by a health practitioner (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−2.934−1.0190.0500.005Yes−2.0730.2020.2010.001Yes−2.521−0.0420.2360.000
Otherwise0.6080.2110.2400.024Otherwise0.774−0.0760.0750.001Otherwise0.6290.0100.0590.000
Principal inertial for first dimension: 42.06%Principal inertial for first dimension: 47.46%Principal inertial for first dimension: 55.18%
Principal inertial for second dimension: 29.09%Principal inertial for second dimension: 27.37%Principal inertial for second dimension: 26.02%
Principal inertial for third dimension: 19.53%Principal inertial for third dimension: 18.22%Principal inertial for third dimension: 14.70%
Principal inertial for fourth dimension9.33%Principal inertial for fourth dimension: 6.94%Principal inertial for fourth dimension: 4.10%
Total inertia: 100%Total inertia: 100Total inertia: 100%
Number of observations: 20,982Number of observations: 12,032Number of observations: 34,931
NigeriaUganda
VariablesScoresContributionsVariablesScoresContributions
First AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond AxisFirst AxisSecond Axis
Being sick (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Being sick (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−2.364−0.2590.2100.000Yes−1.650−0.0680.1850.000
Otherwise0.5980.0660.0530.002Otherwise0.8470.0350.0950.000
Visited a hospital for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Visited a hospital for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−3.6802.1290.1990.004Yes−2.1352.8770.1340.028
Otherwise0.316−0.1830.0170.045Otherwise0.367−0.4940.0230.160
Visited a health centre for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Visited a health centre for treatment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−2.844−17.6230.0000.005Yes−2.011−5.4860.0640.027
Otherwise0.0330.2040.0170.448Otherwise0.1720.4690.0050.313
Consulted by a health practitioner (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)Consulted by a health practitioner (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)
Yes−2.7990.1320.2110.000Yes−1.867−0.0700.2070.000
Otherwise0.475−0.0220.0360.000Otherwise0.7890.0290.0880.000
Principal inertial for first dimension: 55.32%Principal inertial for first dimension: 64.17%
Principal inertial for second dimension: 25.53%Principal inertial for second dimension: 27.88%
Principal inertial for third dimension: 10.89%Principal inertial for third dimension: 5.96%
principal inertial for fourth dimension: 8.26%Principal inertial for fourth dimension: 1.99%
Total inertia: 100%Total inertia: 100%
Number of observations: 8839Number of observations: 6241
Source: computed by authors.
Table A3. Monetary poverty and human capital income source deprivation lines.
Table A3. Monetary poverty and human capital income source deprivation lines.
CountryMonetary Poverty LinesHuman Capital Deprivation Lines
Cameroon369,100441,500
Ethiopia75106010
Kenya12951556
Nigeria24,410293,500
Uganda45,24040,790
Source: computed by authors. Notes: Values for Cameroon are reported in FCFA. Ethiopia in Ethiopian birr; Kenya in Kenyan shilling; Nigeria in Naira; Uganda in Ugandan shilling.
Table A4. Weighted descriptive statistics of the human capital income source.
Table A4. Weighted descriptive statistics of the human capital income source.
ObservationsMeanStandard DeviationMinimumMaximum
Cameroon
Initial period–200710,679451,07650,305281,468601,633
Final period–201410,303380,69750,599217,734538,159
Pooled survey20,982411,81061,391217,734601,633
Ethiopia
Initial period–2013499364651921314414,002
Final period–2018677082612130479714,678
Pooled survey11,76374462226314414,678
Kenya
Initial period–200513,15813396534792507
Final period–201521,74616327825943085
Pooled survey34,90416217835763085
Nigeria
Initial period–20104763297,17222,962251,755354,676
Final period–2015403433,27023,0680.04494,795
Pooled survey8797171,528133,8000.044354,676
Uganda
Initial period–2005367840,644773510,01762,698
Final period–2015237145,4218896836667,892
Pooled survey604943,5398772836667,892
Source: Computed by authors. Notes: Values for Cameroon are reported in FCFA. Ethiopia in Ethiopian birr; Kenya in Kenyan shilling; Nigeria in Naira; Uganda in Ugandan shilling.

Appendix B

Table A5. OLS and 2SLS (residual inclusion method) wellbeing-generating function: Dependent variable is the log of total household expenditures per adult equivalent.
Table A5. OLS and 2SLS (residual inclusion method) wellbeing-generating function: Dependent variable is the log of total household expenditures per adult equivalent.
CameroonEthiopiaKenyaNigeriaUganda
VariablesOLS
Col. (1)
2SLS
Col. (2)
OLS
Col. (3)
2SLS
Col. (4)
OLS
Col. (5)
2SLS
Col. (6)
OLS
Col. (7)
2SLS
Col. (8)
OLS
Col. (9)
2SLS
Col. (10)
Health−0.093 ***0.152−0.085 ***0.296 *−0.0040.374 ***−0.084 **0.805 ***0.156 ***3.294 ***
(0.014)(0.156)(0.019)(0.154)(0.011)(0.083)(0.033)(0.260)(0.035)(0.552)
Health times year dummy −0.012−1.604 ***
(0.047)(0.294)
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.024 **−0.021 *0.090 ***0.089 ***0.163 ***0.157 ***0.115 ***0.110 ***0.114 ***0.093 **
(0.011)(0.011)(0.013)(0.013)(0.009)(0.009)(0.019)(0.019)(0.041)(0.041)
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.114 ***0.116 ***0.304 ***0.306 ***0.291 ***0.290 ***0.251 ***0.257 ***0.261 ***0.150 ***
(0.011)(0.012)(0.024)(0.024)(0.010)(0.010)(0.020)(0.021)(0.048)(0.052)
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.329 ***0.325 ***0.543 ***0.541 ***0.446 ***0.438 ***0.618 ***0.615 ***0.730 ***0.506 ***
(0.016)(0.016)(0.029)(0.029)(0.011)(0.011)(0.025)(0.025)(0.066)(0.077)
Age−0.011 ***−0.010 ***−0.025 ***−0.024 ***−0.012 ***−0.012 ***−0.021 ***−0.018 ***−0.052 ***−0.076 ***
(0.001)(0.002)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.001)(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.007)
Age squared0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.001 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.0180.032 **0.043 **0.079 ***−0.095 ***−0.070 ***−0.097 ***−0.084 **−0.085 **0.108 **
(0.011)(0.014)(0.019)(0.024)(0.010)(0.011)(0.037)(0.039)(0.041)(0.053)
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.255 ***−0.252 ***−0.300 ***−0.313 ***−0.432 ***−0.422 ***−0.214 ***−0.216 ***−0.419 ***−0.269 ***
(0.011)(0.011)(0.018)(0.018)(0.008)(0.009)(0.019)(0.019)(0.038)(0.046)
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.054 ***−0.059 ***−0.040 **−0.025−0.096 ***−0.098 ***−0.267 ***−0.242 ***−0.128 ***−0.323 ***
(0.011)(0.011)(0.020)(0.021)(0.011)(0.011)(0.035)(0.037)(0.047)(0.058)
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership−0.222 ***−0.230 ***−0.152 ***−0.129 ***−0.033 **−0.030 **−0.316 ***−0.315 ***−0.330 ***−0.311 ***
(0.020)(0.021)(0.028)(0.029)(0.014)(0.014)(0.029)(0.029)(0.068)(0.068)
Formal sector (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.367 ***0.368 ***0.0320.0320.177 ***0.176 ***0.0320.029−0.043−0.030
(0.012)(0.012)(0.022)(0.022)(0.010)(0.010)(0.020)(0.020)(0.035)(0.035)
Locality A−0.268 ***−0.242 ***−0.121 ***−0.092 ***−0.051 ***−0.074 ***−0.296 ***−0.279 ***−0.548 ***−0.729 ***
(0.020)(0.026)(0.033)(0.035)(0.014)(0.015)(0.025)(0.025)(0.039)(0.050)
Locality B−0.199 ***−0.203 ***−0.243 ***−0.229 ***−0.091 ***−0.106 ***−0.423 ***−0.400 ***−0.561 ***−0.688 ***
(0.022)(0.023)(0.028)(0.028)(0.012)(0.012)(0.026)(0.027)(0.043)(0.048)
Locality C−0.509 ***−0.501 ***−0.065 **−0.050 *−0.202 ***−0.223 ***−0.406 ***−0.376 ***−0.205 ***−0.668 ***
(0.015)(0.016)(0.027)(0.028)(0.011)(0.012)(0.024)(0.024)(0.039)(0.090)
Locality D−0.446 ***−0.435 ***−0.082 **−0.097 ***−0.142 ***−0.126 ***−0.126 ***−0.094 ***
(0.016)(0.018)(0.036)(0.037)(0.012)(0.012)(0.027)(0.030)
Locality E−0.402 ***−0.399 ***−0.217 ***−0.177 ***−0.121 ***−0.131 ***−0.163 ***−0.142 ***
(0.016)(0.017)(0.059)(0.061)(0.010)(0.010)(0.024)(0.025)
Locality F−0.166 ***−0.157 ***−0.363 ***−0.357 ***
(0.016)(0.017)(0.029)(0.029)
Locality G−0.103 ***−0.102 ***−0.277 ***−0.249 ***
(0.025)(0.025)(0.085)(0.086)
Locality H−0.104 ***−0.107 ***
(0.018)(0.018)
Year dummy0.276 ***0.309 ***0.880 ***0.805 ***0.887 ***0.856 ***0.526 ***1.919 ***0.685 ***0.455 ***
(0.009)(0.022)(0.012)(0.032)(0.008)(0.010)(0.043)(0.258)(0.029)(0.050)
Health residual −0.247 −0.386 ** −0.385 *** −0.911 ***−3.151 ***−3.151 ***
(0.157) (0.156) (0.084) (0.262)(0.553)(0.553)
Health times year dummy residual 1.634 ***
(0.298)
Constant13.531 ***13.302 ***9.498 ***9.145 ***8.164 ***7.862 ***12.178 ***11.264 ***10.389 ***8.784 ***
(0.039)(0.151)(0.064)(0.156)(0.037)(0.076)(0.097)(0.248)(0.158)(0.323)
R-squared/adjusted R-squared0.373/0.3720.373/0.3720.462/0.4610.462/0.4610.413/0.4120.413/0.4120.388/0.3870.391/0.3890.204/0.2020.208/0.206
F-Stat [df; p-val]622.37592.89530.53504.530.0000.000309.55281.08103.1199.20
Prob > F0.0000.0000.0000.0001438.41360.50.0000.00060406040
Number of observations20,98220,98211,76311,76334,81734,8178794879410.389 ***8.784 ***
Source: Computed by authors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = Northwest, F = West, G = South, and H = Southwest. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table A6. Reduced form parameter estimates of health and formal employment equations.
Table A6. Reduced form parameter estimates of health and formal employment equations.
CameroonEthiopiaKenyaNigeria Uganda
VariableReduced Form: Health
Col. (1)
Probit of Formal Employment
Col. (2)
Reduced Form: Health
Col. (3)
Probit of Formal Employment Col. (4)Reduced Form: Health
Col. (5)
Probit of Formal Employment Col. (6)Reduced Form: Health
Col. (7)
Reduced Form: Health * Year Dummy
Col. (8)
Probit of Formal Employment Col. (9)Reduced Form: Health
Col. (10)
Probit of Formal Employment
Col. (11)
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.012 **−0.429 ***−0.0020.366 ***0.014 ***0.109 ***−0.010−0.0090.370 ***0.0080.023
(0.006)(0.048)(0.006)(0.071)(0.004)(0.040)(0.008)(0.006)(0.075)(0.015)(0.082)
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.0050.216 ***−0.0140.642 ***0.0020.452 ***−0.020 **−0.0070.671 ***0.036 **0.239 **
(0.006)(0.046)(0.012)(0.085)(0.005)(0.049)(0.009)(0.006)(0.074)(0.017)(0.093)
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.0130.689 ***−0.0031.670 ***0.020 ***0.870 ***−0.019 *−0.012 *1.609 ***0.072 ***0.883 ***
(0.008)(0.054)(0.013)(0.093)(0.005)(0.045)(0.010)(0.007)(0.077)(0.024)(0.117)
Age−0.003 ***0.026 ***−0.004 ***0.045 ***0.001 *0.019 ***0.005 ***0.005 ***0.075 ***0.008 ***0.013
(0.001)(0.009)(0.001)(0.014)(0.001)(0.007)(0.001)(0.001)(0.018)(0.002)(0.011)
Age squared0.000−0.000 ***0.000−0.001 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.001 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 **
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)−0.056 ***−0.257 ***−0.096 ***−0.440 ***−0.059 ***−0.186 ***−0.056 ***−0.022 *−0.337 **−0.062 ***−0.134
(0.006)(0.045)(0.009)(0.076)(0.005)(0.044)(0.016)(0.011)(0.148)(0.015)(0.081)
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.012 **−0.143 ***0.033 ***−0.549 ***−0.019 ***−0.237 ***0.004−0.003−0.178 ***−0.045 ***−0.236 ***
(0.005)(0.040)(0.009)(0.074)(0.004)(0.035)(0.008)(0.006)(0.066)(0.014)(0.074)
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.019 ***0.101 **−0.040 ***−0.1120.008−0.0170.040 ***0.040 ***0.1760.060 ***0.097
(0.006)(0.042)(0.010)(0.078)(0.005)(0.053)(0.015)(0.011)(0.117)(0.017)(0.084)
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership0.021 **−0.309 ***−0.033 **0.152−0.007−0.018−0.0130.009−0.017−0.019−0.105
(0.011)(0.084)(0.015)(0.173)(0.006)(0.064)(0.014)(0.010)(0.106)(0.026)(0.156)
Locality A−0.100 ***−0.290 ***−0.040 **−0.1080.050 ***0.147 **0.0030.011−0.0120.037 **−0.163 *
(0.010)(0.079)(0.016)(0.099)(0.007)(0.062)(0.011)(0.008)(0.086)(0.015)(0.084)
Locality B0.010−0.092−0.019−0.1090.035 ***0.045−0.025 **−0.000−0.0480.026−0.261 ***
(0.011)(0.077)(0.014)(0.091)(0.006)(0.061)(0.012)(0.008)(0.092)(0.016)(0.082)
Locality C−0.025 ***−0.276 ***−0.022−0.401 ***0.043 ***0.106 **−0.020 *0.009−0.0850.121 ***−0.018
(0.008)(0.073)(0.013)(0.083)(0.005)(0.050)(0.011)(0.007)(0.086)(0.015)(0.087)
Locality D−0.040 ***−0.238 ***0.044 **−0.025−0.032 ***0.058−0.035 ***−0.005−0.086
(0.008)(0.070)(0.018)(0.124)(0.006)(0.056)(0.012)(0.008)(0.083)
Locality E0.002−0.066−0.076 ***−0.278 *0.027 ***0.173 ***0.0140.021 ***−0.223 **
(0.009)(0.064)(0.029)(0.142)(0.005)(0.046)(0.010)(0.007)(0.087)
Locality F−0.012−0.0900.001−0.420 ***
(0.009)(0.060)(0.014)(0.094)
Locality G0.0150.146 *−0.052−0.276 **
(0.013)(0.078)(0.041)(0.139)
Locality H0.022 **0.066
(0.009)(0.064)
Year dummy −0.125 ***−0.0390.202 ***−0.393 ***0.080 ***−0.200 ***−0.0030.542 ***0.3750.065 ***0.090
(0.005)(0.033)(0.005)(0.057)(0.004)(0.036)(0.045)(0.031)(0.393)(0.011)(0.057)
Non-self-cluster average of health0.305 ***−0.468 **0.392 ***−0.0430.389 ***0.1660.267 ***−0.050 *−0.4240.164 ***−0.543 **
(0.025)(0.186)(0.029)(0.315)(0.015)(0.149)(0.044)(0.030)(0.331)(0.039)(0.216)
Non-self-cluster average of health times year dummy 0.0210.422 ***−0.616
(0.056)(0.038)(0.486)
Non-self-cluster average of labour market participation0.056−0.061 **0.056
(0.037)(0.025)(0.037)
Non-self-cluster average of formal employment−0.051 ***1.503 ***0.0202.005 ***0.0011.833 *** 1.988 ***−0.088 **0.447 **
(0.018)(0.129)(0.027)(0.212)(0.012)(0.106) (0.174)(0.037)(0.221)
Constant0.714 ***−1.190 ***0.576 ***−1.815 ***0.472 ***−1.829 ***0.564 ***−0.016−3.046 ***0.441 ***−0.376
(0.028)(0.239)(0.040)(0.420)(0.022)(0.215)(0.055)(0.038)(0.501)(0.063)(0.318)
R-squared/adjusted R-squared/0.084/0.0830.1450.138/0.1360.3170.068/0.0670.1310.065/0.0630.851/0.8500.29650.071/0.0680.082
F-Stat [df; p-val]/Wald chi2(df)95.661192.4100.711248.0148.91214.434.042778.761052.3231.01250.43
Number of observations20,98220,98211,95111,95134,81734,81788048804880460406040
Source: Computed by authors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = North West, F = West, G = South, and H = South West. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table A7. IV (2SLS) estimates of the household wellbeing-generating function.
Table A7. IV (2SLS) estimates of the household wellbeing-generating function.
VariableCameroon
Col. (1)
Ethiopia
Col. (2)
Kenya
Col. (3)
Nigeria
Col. (4)
Uganda
Col. (5)
Health 0.374 **0.268 *0.234 ***0.787 ***3.191 ***
(0.164)(0.161)(0.084)(0.273)(0.790)
Health times year dummy −1.545 ***
(0.308)
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.0180.089 ***0.159 ***0.112 ***0.097
(0.011)(0.014)(0.009)(0.020)(0.062)
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.117 ***0.307 ***0.290 ***0.256 ***0.164 **
(0.012)(0.025)(0.010)(0.022)(0.076)
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.323 ***0.544 ***0.442 ***0.625 ***0.534 ***
(0.017)(0.029)(0.011)(0.024)(0.111)
Age−0.009 ***−0.024 ***−0.012 ***−0.016 ***−0.077 ***
(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.004)(0.011)
Age squared0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.001 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.045 ***0.076 ***−0.080 ***−0.087 **0.113
(0.015)(0.025)(0.011)(0.042)(0.080)
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.249 ***−0.313 ***−0.426 ***−0.220 ***−0.278 ***
(0.011)(0.019)(0.009)(0.020)(0.068)
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.063 ***−0.026−0.098 ***−0.247 ***−0.306 ***
(0.012)(0.021)(0.011)(0.039)(0.084)
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership−0.238 ***−0.132 ***−0.031 **−0.303 ***−0.323 ***
(0.021)(0.030)(0.014)(0.032)(0.102)
Formal (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.364 ***0.0250.172 ***0.001 **−0.083
(0.013)(0.022)(0.010)(0.001)(0.053)
Locality A−0.219 ***−0.095 ***−0.065 ***−0.275 ***−0.725 ***
(0.027)(0.036)(0.015)(0.027)(0.074)
Locality B−0.206 ***−0.232 ***−0.100 ***−0.397 ***−0.688 ***
(0.023)(0.029)(0.012)(0.029)(0.072)
Locality C−0.495 ***−0.052 *−0.215 ***−0.374 ***−0.666 ***
(0.016)(0.028)(0.012)(0.026)(0.133)
Locality D−0.426 ***−0.097 **−0.132 ***−0.093 ***
(0.018)(0.038)(0.012)(0.032)
Locality E−0.396 ***−0.182 ***−0.127 ***−0.145 ***
(0.017)(0.062)(0.010)(0.026)
Locality F−0.149 ***−0.359 ***
(0.017)(0.029)
Locality G−0.100 ***−0.253 ***
(0.026)(0.087)
Locality H−0.109 ***
(0.018)
Year dummy 0.338 ***0.810 ***0.867 ***1.860 ***0.464 ***
(0.023)(0.034)(0.010)(0.271)(0.072)
Constant13.096 ***9.172 ***7.975 ***11.240 ***8.894 ***
(0.158)(0.161)(0.077)(0.262)(0.455)
R-squared/adjusted R-squared/pseudo-R-squared/centred-R-squared0.3360.4460.4050.312−0.776
F-Stat [df; p-val]/Wald chi2(df)586.75514.271420.5275.8546.68
Under identification test (Anderson canon. corr. LM statistic): Chi-sq [df; p-value]150.70 [0.00]167.72 [0.00]627.1 [0.00]96.36 [0.00]26.78 [0.00]
Weak identification test (Cragg–Donald Wald F statistic):75.5484.31316.232.2213.38
Stock–Yogo weak ID test: 10% maximal IV size19.9319.9319.9313.4319.93
Sargan statistic (over-identification test of all instruments): Chi-sq [df; p-value]0.2620.170155.4 [0.00]46.84 [0.00]14.58 [0.00]
Endogeneity test of health: Chi-sq [df; p-value]8.636 [0.00]5.037 [0.024]8.187 [0.004]29.67 [0.00]33.09 [0.00]
Number of observations20,98211,95134,81788046040
Source: Computed by authors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = North West, F = West, G = South, and H = South West. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table A8. Descriptive statistics of variables used to effectuate the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions.
Table A8. Descriptive statistics of variables used to effectuate the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions.
CameroonEthiopiaKenyaNigeriaUganda
Variables2007
Col. (1)
2014
Col. (2)
2013
Col. (3)
2018
Col. (4)
2005
Col. (5)
2015
Col. (6)
2010
Col. (7)
2015
Col. (8)
2005
Col. (9)
2015
Col. (10)
Health 0.7940.6680.6930.8130.7770.8500.8630.8610.6490.737
Health times year dummy 0.0000.802
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3320.3250.2810.2630.2180.2670.2110.2060.5180.507
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.3490.3660.0990.1370.1390.1660.2110.2080.2220.228
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.0800.1050.0970.1400.1540.1210.1210.1340.0610.089
Age41.9143.4844.3142.3044.4944.6649.4353.4042.2545.28
Age squared1988213922102020222422542676305720222301
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.2670.2890.2960.3120.2980.3400.1510.1480.2890.324
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.4410.4700.6470.4600.6420.6010.6770.6790.7250.753
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.5670.5480.6810.6880.7280.7020.7940.8070.7240.725
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership 0.3630.3150.4330.3480.4950.4850.5670.5620.4870.546
Formal (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.1810.1520.1880.1710.1590.1340.1730.1510.2370.254
Locality A0.0510.0710.1170.1000.1120.0570.1600.1700.2260.237
Locality B0.0520.0610.1970.1110.0940.1660.1610.1440.2250.253
Locality C0.1300.1070.2010.1110.0390.2930.1810.1990.2300.231
Locality D0.0680.0940.0550.0900.1600.0880.1590.160
Locality E0.1300.0910.0230.0540.2480.1360.1790.169
Locality F0.1140.0880.2260.102
Locality G0.0470.0530.0250.073
Locality H0.1010.078
Health residual−0.0080.006−0.005−0.0130.005−0.0160.002−0.005−0.024−0.009
Health times year dummy residual 0.0810.072
Health times its residual0.0820.0970.1200.0390.1370.0520.008−0.0090.1730.145
Health times year dummy times its residual 0.0050.071
Generalized residual for formal sector employment0.0410.038−0.034−0.035−0.073−0.047−0.041−0.040−0.062−0.057
Constant1.0001.0001.0001.0001.0001.0001.0001.0001.0001.000
Total10,67910,3034993677013,07121,7464760403436692371
Source: Computed by authors. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = North West, F = West, G = South, and H = South West. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table A9. Control function-generalized residual estimates by year, used to implement the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions.
Table A9. Control function-generalized residual estimates by year, used to implement the Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decompositions.
CameroonEthiopiaKenyaNigeriaUganda
VariablesEstimates 2007 Col. (1)Estimates 2014 Col. (2)Estimates 2013 Col. (3)Estimates 2018 Col. (4)Estimates 2005 Col. (5)Estimates 2015 Col. (6)Estimates 2010 Col. (7)Estimates 2015 Col. (8)Estimates 2005 Col. (9)Estimates 2015 Col. (10)
Health0.0530.241−0.929 ***1.208 ***1.466 ***−0.203 **−4.581 ***0.1448.807 ***0.382
Health times year dummy
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.075 ***0.0130.101 ***0.068 ***0.065 ***0.167 ***−0.0610.059 **0.0020.147 **
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.230 ***0.062 ***0.273 ***0.306 ***0.107 ***0.369 ***0.0530.231 ***−0.202 **0.371 ***
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.606 ***0.182 ***0.508 ***0.554 ***0.145 ***0.708 ***0.379 ***0.549 ***−0.1040.874 ***
Age−0.020 ***−0.004−0.016 ***−0.033 ***0.002−0.028 ***0.077 ***−0.023 ***−0.106 ***−0.067 ***
Age squared0.001 ***0.001 *0.001 ***0.001 ***−0.0010.001 ***−0.001 ***0.001 ***0.001 ***0.001 ***
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.068 ***0.038 *−0.0450.146 ***−0.032−0.055 ***−0.712 ***0.0550.609 ***−0.187 **
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.339 ***−0.117 ***−0.238 ***−0.341 ***−0.489 ***−0.359 ***−0.232 ***−0.214 ***0.058−0.482 ***
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.061 ***−0.087 ***−0.037−0.037−0.118 ***−0.060 ***0.652 ***−0.319 ***−0.688 ***−0.096
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership (=1)−0.439 ***−0.113 ***−0.241 ***−0.032−0.203 ***0.036 ***−0.258 ***−0.330 ***−0.087−0.462 ***
Formal (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.118 **0.858 ***0.0310.0860.092 *0.036 **0.0750.124−0.751 **−0.400
Locality A−0.056−0.285 ***−0.056−0.152 ***0.164 ***−0.376 ***0.037−0.390 ***−0.970 ***−0.648 ***
Locality B−0.117 ***−0.200 ***−0.228 ***−0.243 ***−0.234 ***−0.084 ***−0.340 ***−0.496 ***−0.919 ***−0.610 ***
Locality C−0.202 ***−0.636 ***−0.057−0.064 *−0.492 ***−0.226 ***−0.228 ***−0.412 ***−1.315 ***−0.366 ***
Locality D−0.164 ***−0.559 ***0.107 *−0.196 ***0.049 **−0.267 ***−0.314 ***−0.036
Locality E−0.117 ***−0.571 ***−0.336 ***−0.095−0.126 ***−0.182 ***0.378 ***−0.227 ***
Locality F−0.008−0.217 ***−0.337 ***−0.386 ***
Locality G−0.016−0.195 ***−0.286 **−0.267 **
Locality H0.051 **−0.218 ***
Health residual−0.054−0.461 *0.830 ***−1.792 ***−1.556 ***0.0574.480 ***−5.485 ***−8.287 ***−0.275
Health times year dummy residual 16.647 ***5.294 ***
Health times its residual−0.234 ***0.279 ***0.163 *0.894 ***0.444 ***0.097−0.0761.602−0.684 ***−0.213
Health times year dummy times its residual 1.072−1.661
Generalized residual for formal sector employment0.675 **−2.682 ***−0.010−0.3020.1200.970 ***−0.508−0.3894.086 **2.009
Constant13.790 ***13.112 ***10.323 ***9.256 ***7.781 ***9.544 ***14.331 ***12.395 ***6.934 ***11.671 ***
R-squared/adjusted R-squared0.424/0.4230.315/0.3130.206/0.2030.240/0.2380.138/0.1360.368/0.3670.293/0.2900.367/0.3650.118/0.1140.239/0.233
F-Stat [df; p-val]356.83214.6861.53101.68109.86665.3893.62111.3628.7543.46
Total10,67910,3034993677013,07121,7464760403436692371
Source: Computed by authors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = North West, F = West, G = South, and H = South West. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table A10. Growth and redistribution decomposition analysis using the factual (initial) and counterfactual (final) distributions.
Table A10. Growth and redistribution decomposition analysis using the factual (initial) and counterfactual (final) distributions.
Cameroon
Growth P0
Col. (1)
Redistribution P0
Col. (2)
Change P0
Col. (3)
Growth P1
Col. (4)
Redistribution P1
Col. (5)
Change P1
Col. (6)
Growth P2
Col. (7)
Redistribution P2
Col. (8)
Change P2
Col. (9)
Urban−0.0110.008−0.003 ***−0.0030.001−0.002 ***−0.0020.001−0.001 ***
(0.013)(0.003)(0.004)(0.015)(0.001)(0.001)(0.015)(0.000)(0.000)
Rural−0.0430.012−0.031 ***−0.0220.012−0.010 ***−0.0130.008−0.004 ***
(0.007)(0.004)(0.005)(0.010)(0.001)(0.001)(0.011)(0.001)(0.001)
Overall−0.0260.006−0.020 ***−0.0110.005−0.006 ***−0.0060.003−0.003 ***
(0.003)(0.002)(0.003)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)
Ethiopia
Growth P0Redistribution P0Change P0Growth P1Redistribution P1Change P1Growth P2Redistribution P2Change P2
Urban−0.020−0.012−0.032 ***−0.006−0.003−0.009 ***−0.002−0.001−0.004 ***
(0.032)(0.003)(0.005)(0.033)(0.001)(0.001)(0.033)(0.000)(0.001)
Rural−0.128−0.010−0.135 ***−0.042−0.003−0.045 ***−0.018−0.001−0.019 ***
(0.016)(0.004)(0.009)(0.014)(0.001)(0.002)(0.014)(0.000)(0.001)
Overall−0.091−0.023−0.112 ***−0.029−0.007−0.036 ***−0.013−0.003−0.016 ***
(0.009)(0.002)(0.007)(0.006)(0.001)(0.002)(0.005)(0.000)(0.001)
Kenya
Growth P0Redistribution P0Change P0Growth P1Redistribution P1Change P1Growth P2Redistribution P2Change P2
Urban−0.024−0.019−0.044 ***−0.009−0.008−0.018 ***−0.005−0.004−0.010 ***
(0.014)(0.002)(0.003)(0.015)(0.001)(0.001)(0.016)(0.001)(0.001)
Rural−0.083−0.004−0.087 ***−0.0420.000−0.042 ***−0.0260.001−0.025 ***
(0.006)(0.002)(0.003)(0.007)(0.001)(0.001)(0.008)(0.001)(0.001)
Overall−0.057−0.018−0.075 ***−0.028−0.007−0.035 ***−0.017−0.004−0.021 ***
(0.003)(0.001)(0.002)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)
Nigeria
Growth P0Redistribution P0Change P0Growth P1Redistribution P1Change P1Growth P2Redistribution P2Change P2
Urban−0.2210.142−0.073 ***−0.0920.068−0.023 ***−0.0500.0390.010 ***
(0.047)(0.032)(0.010)(0.036)(0.004)(0.003)(0.036)(0.003)(0.001)
Rural−0.3600.108−0.237 ***−0.1790.089−0.085 ***−0.1120.066−0.042 ***
(0.036)(0.014)(0.010)(0.027)(0.003)(0.003)(0.027)(0.002)(0.002)
Overall−0.3050.116−0.176 ***−0.1450.078−0.063 ***−0.0870.055−0.030 ***
(0.032)(0.021)(0.009)(0.011)(0.003)(0.003)(0.010)(0.002)(0.001)
Uganda
Growth P0Redistribution P0Change P0Growth P1Redistribution P1Change P1Growth P2Redistribution P2Change P2
Urban−0.1230.1780.054 ***−0.0690.0930.024 ***−0.0470.0610.014 ***
(0.054)(0.034)(0.014)(0.041)(0.012)(0.004)(0.041)(0.009)(0.003)
Rural−0.2310.2680.036 ***−0.1410.1630.021 ***−0.0990.1160.015 ***
(0.027)(0.023)(0.010)(0.015)(0.007)(0.004)(0.015)(0.006)(0.003)
Overall−0.1990.2400.040 ***−0.1180.1400.022 ***−0.0820.0970.015 ***
(0.023)(0.024)(0.008)(0.009)(0.007)(0.003)(0.008)(0.006)(0.002)
Source: Computed by authors. Notes: Values in parentheses are standard errors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%.

Variables for Regression Analysis

Household surveys generally contain relevant variables for estimating income-generating functions using rigorous econometric regression frameworks. In particular, four sets of variables can be distilled from a typical household or living standards survey:
  • Outcome Variable (HEW): Household Economic Wellbeing
    -
    Total household expenditure per adult equivalent.
  • Potentially Endogenous Variables (C): Human Capital
    -
    Health capital.
    -
    Formal employment (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise).
The variable health is constructed using the multiple correspondence analysis approach. The methods used to construct these variables are indicated in Appendix A (Table A2).
  • Exogenous variables (Zk, k = 1, 2, …, K):
    -
    Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise).
    -
    Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise).
    -
    Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise).
    -
    Age of household head.
    -
    Age squared.
    -
    Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise).
    -
    Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise).
    -
    Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise).
    -
    Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership.
    -
    Year dummy.
    -
    Regional/provincial or zonal dummies.
  • Instruments for Endogenous Variables:
    -
    Non-self-cluster mean of health dummy or index.
    -
    Non-self-cluster proportion of formal employment.
    -
    Non-self-cluster proportion of labour market participation.

Notes

1
Equation (3) results from an indicator function E 1 = 1 [ z δ + ε 3 > 0 ] . Considering this indicator function and the structural Equation (1), the resulting control function rests on a number of distributional assumptions: 1. the pair ( ε 1 ,   ε 3 ) is independent of the vector of parameters z, which turns out to be stronger than the usual zero correlation assertion in the 2SLS estimator; 2. ε 1 is linearly related to ε 3 ; and 3. ε 3 ~ N o r m a l 0 ,   1 . In this setup, Equation (3) is a probit reduced form. Since the distribution of formal sector employment, E 1 , is completely characterized, the control function approach relies on the conditional expectation E L n Y z , E 1 = z 1 δ 1 + η 1 E 1 + E ε 1 z , E 1 >, and E ε 1 z , E 1 = φ E 1 λ z δ 1 E 1 λ z δ = φ r , where z 1 is the vector of exogeneous variables in Equation (1) and λ . = ϕ . / Φ . is the inverse Mills ratio (IMR), r the generalized error, with zero mean (see, Wooldridge, 2015; Gourieroux et al., 1987), and φ is its parameter. In tandem with the Heckman two-step approach (see, Wooldridge, 2002, we (i) estimate the reduced form probit in Equation (3); (ii) predict the probit index; (iii) compute the inverse Mills ratio; (iv) thus generating the generalized residual ( r ^ ) ; and (v) incorporate it into the estimating structural equation as in Equation (4).
2
For a detailed discussion of non-parametric regression approaches, see Härdle (1990).

References

  1. Appleton, S., & Teal, F. (1998). Human capital and economic development. Background paper for the African development report 1998. Available online: http://www.afdb.org (accessed on 1 March 2022).
  2. Araar, A., & Duclos, J. Y. (2009). Distributive Analysis Stata Package (DASP) 2.1 software. University of Laval, CIRPEE and the Poverty Economic and Policy Research Network. [Google Scholar]
  3. Balisacan, A. M. (1995). Anatomy of poverty during adjustment: The case of the Philippines. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 44(10), 33–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Barriga-Cabanillas, O. (2014). PROSPERITY: Stata module to compute shared prosperity convergence index (Statistical Software Components S457847). Boston College Department of Economics. [Google Scholar]
  5. Baye, M. F., & Epo, B. N. (2015). Impact of human capital endowments on inequality of outcomes in Cameroon. Review of Income and Wealth, 61(1), 93–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bebbington, A. (1999). Capitals and capabilities: A framework for analysing peasant viability, rural livelihoods and poverty. World Development, 27, 2021–2044. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital. Columbia University Press. [Google Scholar]
  8. Becker, G. S. (1975). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education (pp. 13–44). NBER. Available online: http://www.nber.org/books/beck75-1 (accessed on 30 June 2022).
  9. Becker, G. S. (1995). Human capital and poverty reduction (Human Resource Development and Operations Working paper No. HRO 52). World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  10. Becker, G. S., & Tomes, N. (1976). Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy, 84, S143–S162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Berry, S. (1993). No condition is permanent: The social dynamics of agrarian change in Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press. [Google Scholar]
  12. Bigsten, A., Kebede, B., Shimeles, A., & Taddesse, M. (2003). Growth and poverty reduction in Ethiopia: Evidence from household panel surveys. World Development, 31(1), 87–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Blinder, A. S. (1973). Wage discrimination: Reduced form and structural estimates. Journal of Human Resources, 8, 436–455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Bourguignon, F., Ferreira, F. H. G., & Menendez, M. (2007). Inequality of opportunity in Brazil. Review of Income and Wealth, 53, 585–618. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ceroni, C. B. (2001). Poverty traps and human capital accumulation. Economica, 68(270), 203–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Christiansen, L., Demery, L., & Paternostro, S. (2002). Growth distribution and poverty in Africa: Messages from the 1990s (Policy Research Working Paper Series No. 2810). World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  17. Commission on Growth and Development [CGD]. (2008). The growth report: Strategies for sustained growth and inclusive development. World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  18. Cumming, D. J., Johan, S., & Uzuegbunam, I. S. (2019). An anatomy of entrepreneurial pursuits in relation to poverty. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development. [Google Scholar]
  19. Cunha, F., & Heckman, J. (2008). Formulating, identifying and estimating the technology of cognitive and noncognitive skill formation. Journal of Human Resources, 43, 738–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Cunha, F., Heckman, J., Lochner, L., & Masterov, D. (2006). Interpreting the evidence on life cycle skill formation. In E. A. Hanushek, & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of education (Vol. 1). Elsevier. [Google Scholar]
  21. Datt, G., & Ravallion, M. (1992). Growth and redistribution components of changes in poverty measures: A decomposition with application to Brazil and India in the 1980s. Journal of Development Economics, 38, 275–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Dotter, C., & Klasen, S. (2020). An absolute multidimensional poverty measure in the functioning space (and relative measure in the resource space): An illustration using Indian data. In V. Beck, H. Hahn, & R. Lepenies (Eds.), Dimensions of poverty: Measurement, epistemic injustices, activism. Springer Nature. [Google Scholar]
  23. Fisher, A. G. B. (1946). Education and economic change. W. E. A. Press. [Google Scholar]
  24. Foster, J. E., Greer, J., & Thorbecke, E. (1984). A class of decomposable poverty measures. Econometrica, 52(3), 761–776. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Foster, J. E., & Shorrocks, A. F. (1991). Subgroup consistent poverty indices. Econometrica, 59, 687–709. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Gourieroux, C., Monfort, A., Renault, E., & Trognon, A. (1987). Generalised residuals. Journal of Econometrics, 34(1–2), 5–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Grossman, M. (1972). On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy, 80, 223–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Halvorsen, R., & Palmquist, R. (1980). The interpretation of dummy variables in semilogarithmic equations. American Economic Review, 70(3), 474–475. [Google Scholar]
  29. Hanushek, E. (2013). Economic growth in developing countries: The role of human capital. Journal of Economic Growth, 37, 204–221. [Google Scholar]
  30. Härdle, W. (1990). Applied non-parametric regression. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  31. Heckman, J. J. (1976). The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 5(4), 475–492. [Google Scholar]
  32. Heckman, J. J. (2004). Lessons from the technology of skill formation. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, 1038, 179–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Heckman, J. J. (2007). The economics, technology, and neuroscience of human capability formation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104, 13250–13255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Kakwani, N. (2000). On measuring growth and inequality components of poverty with application to Thailand. Journal of Quantitative Economics, 16, 67–80. [Google Scholar]
  35. Larionova, N. I., & Varlamova, J. A. (2015). Analysis of human capital level and inequality interaction. Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences, 6(1), S3. [Google Scholar]
  36. Lefranc, A., Pistolesi, N., & Trannoy, A. (2008). Inequality of opportunities vs. inequality of outcomes: Are western societies all alike? Review of Income and Wealth, 54, 513–546. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Mincer, J. (1962). On-the-job training: Costs, returns, and some implications. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), 50–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Mincer, J. (1991). Education and unemployment (NBER working paper. No. 3838). National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  40. Morduch, J., & Sicular, T. (2002). Rethinking inequality decomposition with evidence from rural China. Economic Journal, 112(476), 93–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Moser, C. O. N. (1998). Reassessing urban poverty reduction strategies: The asset vulnerability framework. World Development, 26, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Moser, C. O. N. (2006). Asset-based approaches to poverty reduction in a globalized context: An introduction to asset accumulation policy and summary of workshop findings (Working Paper 01). The Brookings Institution. [Google Scholar]
  43. Neuman, S., & Oaxaca, R. (2004). Wage decompositions with selectivity-corrected wage equations: A methodological note. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 2(1), 3–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Oaxaca, L. R. (1973). Male-female wage differentials in urban labour markets. International Economic Review, 14(3), 693–709. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Punam, P. (2014). Africa new economic landscape. The Brown Journal of World Affairs, 21(1), 163–179. [Google Scholar]
  46. Ravallion, M., & Huppi, M. (1991). Measuring changes in poverty: A methodological case study of Indonesia during an adjustment period. World Bank Economic Review, 5, 57–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Riddell, W. C., & Song, X. (2011). The impact of education on employment incidence and re-employment success: Evidence from the U.S. labour markets. Labour Economics, 18(4), 453–463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Roemer, J. E. (1998). Equality of opportunity. Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
  49. Roemer, J. E. (2002). Equality of opportunity: A progress report. Social Choice and Welfare, 19, 455–471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Romer, P. M. (1990). Human capital and growth: Theory and evidence. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 32, 251–286. [Google Scholar]
  51. Santos, M. E. (2009). Human capital and the quality of education in a poverty trap model. Oxford Poverty & Human Development Initiative (OPHI). [Google Scholar]
  52. Schultz, T. (1975). The value of the ability to veal with visequilibria. Journal of Economic Literature, 13(3), 827–846. [Google Scholar]
  53. Schultz, T. P. (Ed.). (1993). Investments in women’s human capital. University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  54. Schultz, T. W. (1961). Investment in human capital. American Economic Review, 51(1), 1–17. [Google Scholar]
  55. Schultz, T. W. (1962). Investment in human beings. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5). [Google Scholar]
  56. Sen, A. (1976). Poverty: An ordinal approach to measurement. Econometrica, 44, 219–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Sen, A. (1997). On economic inequality. Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  58. Sen, A. (1998). Mortality as an indicator of economic success and failure. The Economic Journal, 108, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Shorrocks, A. F. (1999). Decomposition procedures for distributional analysis: A unified framework based on shapley value. Department of Economics, University of Essex. [Google Scholar]
  60. Teixeira, P. N. (2014). Gary Becker’s early work on human capital: Collaborations and distinctiveness. IZA Journal of Labour Economics, 3, 12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Thirlwall, A. P. (1999). Growth and development (6th ed.). Macmillan Press Ltd. [Google Scholar]
  62. Wan, G. H. (2004). Accounting for income inequality in rural China: A regression-based approach. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(2), 348–363. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  64. Wooldridge, J. M. (2015). Control function methods in applied econometrics. Journal of Human Resources, 50(2), 420–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. World Bank. (2005). Introduction to poverty analysis. World Bank Institute. Available online: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/PGLP/Resources/PovertyManual.pdf (accessed on 30 June 2022).
  66. World Bank. (2013). Shifting gears to accelerate shared prosperity in Latin America and the Caribbean (Document of World Bank N°. 78507). World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  67. World Bank. (2015a). A measured approach to ending poverty and boosting shared prosperity: Concepts, data, and the twin goals (Policy Research Report). World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  68. World Bank. (2015b). Poverty forecasts, monitoring global development prospects. Demographic Trends and Economic Development. [Google Scholar]
Table 1. Wellbeing-generating function estimates using the control function method. The dependent variable is the log of total household expenditure per adult equivalent.
Table 1. Wellbeing-generating function estimates using the control function method. The dependent variable is the log of total household expenditure per adult equivalent.
VariablesCameroon
Col. (1)
Ethiopia
Col. (2)
Kenya
Col. (3)
Nigeria
Col. (4)
Uganda
Col. (5)
Health0.415 ***0.320 **0.334 ***0.814 ***2.653 ***
(0.161)(0.155)(0.086)(0.269)(0.591)
Health times year dummy −1.606 ***
(0.313)
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.0170.082 ***0.146 ***0.095 ***0.107 ***
(0.012)(0.015)(0.009)(0.021)(0.042)
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.089 ***0.293 ***0.282 ***0.231 ***0.209 ***
(0.012)(0.027)(0.010)(0.025)(0.056)
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.287 ***0.529 ***0.440 ***0.588 ***0.596 ***
(0.017)(0.031)(0.011)(0.030)(0.085)
Age−0.012 ***−0.024 ***−0.013 ***−0.020 ***−0.069 ***
(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.004)(0.008)
Age squared ×10−20.015 ***0.030 ***0.015 ***0.025 ***0.100 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Gender (female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.068 ***0.085 ***−0.066 ***−0.072 *0.057
(0.015)(0.025)(0.011)(0.040)(0.057)
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.234 ***−0.301 ***−0.430 ***−0.211 ***−0.318 ***
(0.011)(0.020)(0.009)(0.019)(0.050)
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.070 ***−0.024−0.094 ***−0.248 ***−0.269 ***
(0.011)(0.021)(0.011)(0.037)(0.061)
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership−0.187 ***−0.123 ***−0.028 **−0.302 ***−0.340 ***
(0.022)(0.030)(0.014)(0.030)(0.069)
Formal sector (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.627 ***0.085 *0.075 ***0.123 **−0.599 ***
(0.042)(0.047)(0.017)(0.057)(0.223)
Locality A−0.190 ***−0.090 **−0.068 ***−0.279 ***−0.732 ***
(0.027)(0.035)(0.015)(0.025)(0.050)
Locality B−0.199 ***−0.229 ***−0.104 ***−0.397 ***−0.711 ***
(0.023)(0.028)(0.012)(0.027)(0.049)
Locality C−0.467 ***−0.046−0.219 ***−0.373 ***−0.602 ***
(0.016)(0.028)(0.012)(0.025)(0.094)
Locality D−0.406 ***−0.095 **−0.137 ***−0.092 ***
(0.018)(0.037)(0.012)(0.030)
Locality E−0.380 ***−0.173 ***−0.136 ***−0.138 ***
(0.017)(0.061)(0.010)(0.025)
Locality F−0.135 ***−0.351 ***
(0.017)(0.029)
Locality G−0.110 ***−0.247 ***
(0.025)(0.086)
Locality H−0.112 ***
(0.018)
Year dummy0.341 ***0.817 ***0.847 ***1.931 ***0.500 ***
(0.023)(0.033)(0.011)(0.280)(0.053)
Health residual−0.569 ***−0.473 ***−0.420 ***−0.914 ***−2.386 ***
(0.165)(0.163)(0.092)(0.283)(0.601)
Health times year dummy residual 1.667 ***
(0.338)
Health times its residual0.151 ***0.143 *0.205 ***−0.020−0.361 *
(0.056)(0.080)(0.050)(0.139)(0.187)
Health times year dummy times its residual −0.106
(0.201)
Generalized residual for formal sector−1.570 ***−0.3690.825 ***−0.572 *3.104 ***
(0.242)(0.291)(0.110)(0.327)(1.200)
Constant12.922 ***9.085 ***7.969 ***11.260 ***9.515 ***
(0.160)(0.159)(0.082)(0.257)(0.400)
R-squared/adjusted R-squared0.374/0.3730.462/0.4610.414/0.4130.391/0.3900.209/0.208
F-Stat [df; p-val]544.77459.001230.5244.6188.89
Prob > F0.0000.0000.0000.0000.000
Number of observations20,98211,76334,81787946040
Source: Computed by authors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = Northwest, F = West, G = South, and H = Southwest. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region.
Table 2. Components of household wellbeing growth—access and returns to endowment effects: Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition.
Table 2. Components of household wellbeing growth—access and returns to endowment effects: Shapley–Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition.
CameroonEthiopiaKenyaNigeriaUganda
VariablesAE
Col. (1)
RE
Col. (2)
Total Col. (3)AE
Col. (4)
RE
Col. (5)
Total Col. (6)AE
Col. (7)
RE
Col. (8)
Total Col. (9)AE
Col. (10)
RE
Col. (11)
Total Col. (12)AE
Col. (13)
RE
Col. (14)
Total Col.
(15)
Health −0.0190.1370.1180.0171.6091.6260.046−1.358−1.3120.0044.0734.0770.404−5.839−5.435
Primary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.000−0.020−0.020−0.002−0.009−0.0110.0060.0250.0310.0000.0250.025−0.0010.0740.073
Secondary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.002−0.060−0.0580.0110.0040.0150.0060.0400.0460.0000.0370.0370.0010.1290.130
Tertiary education (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.010−0.039−0.0290.0230.0050.028−0.0140.0770.0630.0060.0220.0280.0110.0730.084
Age−0.0190.6830.6640.049−0.736−0.687−0.002−1.337−1.3390.107−5.142−5.035−0.2621.7071.445
Age squared0.0150.0000.015−0.0380.4230.3850.0030.4250.428−0.1524.0133.8610.251−1.297−1.046
Gender (Female = 1 and 0 = otherwise)0.001−0.008−0.0070.0010.0580.059−0.002−0.007−0.0090.0010.1150.1160.007−0.244−0.237
Rural area (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.0070.1010.0940.054−0.057−0.0030.0170.0810.0980.0000.0120.012−0.006−0.399−0.405
Married (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)0.001−0.014−0.0130.0000.0000.0000.0020.0410.0430.002−0.777−0.7750.0000.4290.429
Non-self-cluster average farmland ownership0.0130.1110.1240.0120.0820.0940.0010.1170.1180.001−0.041−0.040−0.016−0.194−0.210
Formal (1 = yes and 0 = otherwise)−0.0140.1230.109−0.0010.0100.009−0.002−0.008−0.010−0.0020.0080.006−0.0100.0860.076
Locality A−0.003−0.014−0.0170.002−0.010−0.0080.006−0.046−0.040−0.002−0.070−0.072−0.0090.0750.066
Locality B−0.001−0.005−0.0060.020−0.0020.018−0.0110.0200.0090.007−0.024−0.017−0.0210.0740.053
Locality C0.010−0.051−0.0410.005−0.0010.004−0.0910.044−0.047−0.006−0.035−0.041−0.0010.2190.218
Locality D−0.009−0.032−0.041−0.002−0.022−0.0240.008−0.039−0.0310.0000.0440.044
Locality E0.013−0.050−0.037−0.0070.0090.0020.017−0.0110.006−0.001−0.105−0.106
Locality F0.003−0.021−0.0180.045−0.0080.037
Locality G−0.001−0.009−0.010−0.0130.001−0.012
Locality H0.002−0.024−0.022
Health residual−0.0040.000−0.0040.0040.0240.0280.016−0.0090.0070.0040.0150.019−0.064−0.132−0.196
Health times year dummy residual −0.099−0.869
Health times its residual0.0000.0460.046−0.0430.0580.015−0.023−0.033−0.056−0.013−0.001−0.0140.0130.0750.088
Health times year dummy times its residual −0.019−0.104
Generalized residual for formal sector employment0.003−0.133−0.1300.0000.0100.010.014−0.051−0.0370.000−0.005−0.0050.0150.1240.139
Constant0.000−0.678−0.6780.000−1.067−1.0670.0001.7631.7630.000−1.936−1.9360.0004.7374.737
Total−0.0020.0420.0400.1380.3800.518−0.003−0.265−0.268−0.163−0.744−0.9070.311−0.3030.008
Source: Computed by authors. Notes: Values are reported in three decimal places. The values are reported in log-points. AE = Access to Endowments. RE = Returns to Endowments. For Cameroon, the localities are A = Adamaoua, B = East, C = Extreme North, D = North, E = North West, F = West, G = South, and H = South West. For Ethiopia: A = Tigray, B = Amhara, C = Oromia, D = Somali, E = Benishangul Gumuz, F = SNNP, G = Gambelia. For Kenya: A = North East province, B = Eastern province, C = Rift Valley province, D = Western province, E = Nyanza province. For Nigeria: A = North Central, B = North East, C = North West, D = South East, E = South West. For Uganda: A = Eastern region, B = Northern region, C = Western region. Considering countries that registered growth in household wellbeing, we note three scenarios. In Cameroon, observed growth in household wellbeing was driven by the returns to endowment components rather than access to endowments (Table 2, Columns 1 and 2). In Ethiopia, both access (Table 2, Column 4) and returns (Table 2, Column 5) to endowments explained registered growth rates. In Uganda, while access to endowment components (Table 2, Column 13) enhanced the growth in household welfare, the returns to endowment components (Table 2, Column 14) eroded the growth. In countries that register growth deficits in household wellbeing, both the access and returns to endowment components contributed to dwindling growth in household welfare in Kenya (Table 2, Columns 7 and 8) and Nigeria (Table 2, Columns 10 and 11).
Table 3. Impact of human capital equalization on mean wellbeing among the 40% of the least well-off households.
Table 3. Impact of human capital equalization on mean wellbeing among the 40% of the least well-off households.
Cameroon
20072014
LocationFactual
Col. (1)
Counterfactual
Col. (2)
Impact:Factual
Col. (4)
Counterfactual
Col. (5)
Impact:
Abs. [Rel.]
Col. (3)
Abs. [Rel.]
Col. (6)
Urban379,685.9370,940.2−8745.7
[−0.02]
358,274.9373,181.114,906.2
[0.04]
Rural194,339.9190,941.0−3398.9
[−0.02]
209,302.4228,485.319,182.9
[0.09]
Cameroon224,765.6221,562.2−3203.4
[−0.01]
252,823.2273,202.820,379.6
[0.08]
Ethiopia
20132018
LocationFactualCounterfactualImpact:FactualCounterfactualImpact:
Abs. [Rel.]Abs. [Rel.]
Urban4169.05232.81063.8
[0.26]
9586.711,885.12298.4
[0.24]
Rural2443.13450.41007.3
[0.41]
5300.17061.21761.1
[0.33]
Ethiopia2596.63649.91053.3
[0.41]
5952.57878.91926.4
[0.32]
Kenya
20052015
LocationFactualCounterfactualImpact:FactualCounterfactualImpact:
Abs. [Rel.]Abs. [Rel.]
Urban1307.11546.7239.6
[0.18]
3550.94178.1627.2
[0.18]
Rural877.51038.1160.6
[0.18]
2178.52659.2480.7
[0.22]
Kenya938.61113.0174.4
[0.19]
2404.12927.9523.8
[0.22]
Nigeria
20102015
LocationFactualCounterfactualImpact:FactualCounterfactualImpact:
Abs. [Rel.]Abs. [Rel.]
Urban46,155.954,174.78018.8
[0.17]
77,318.9236,015.5158,696.6
[2.05]
Rural26,706.733,189.96483.2
[0.24]
43,517.6145,297.3101,779.7
[2.34]
Nigeria31,308.738,692.67383.9
[0.24]
50,737.3167,429.2116,691.9
[2.30]
Uganda
20052015
LocationFactualCounterfactualImpact:FactualCounterfactualImpact:
Abs. [Rel.]Abs. [Rel.]
Urban2798.72494.7−304
[−0.11]
7076.75275.1−1801.6
[−0.25]
Rural1721.31804.783.4
[0.05]
3676.12813.6−862.5
[−0.23]
Uganda1909.81932.622.8
[0.01]
4135.43137.8−997.6
[−0.24]
Source: Computed by authors using the software component by Barriga-Cabanillas (2014). Notes: Values for Cameroon are reported in FCFA; Ethiopia in Ethiopian birr; Kenya in Kenyan shilling; Nigeria in Naira; Uganda in Ugandan shilling. Relative values in brackets.
Table 4. Impact of equalizing human capital on shared prosperity among 40% of the least well-off.
Table 4. Impact of equalizing human capital on shared prosperity among 40% of the least well-off.
LocationFactual
Col. (1)
Counterfactual
Col. (2)
Impact: Abs. [Rel.]
Col. (3)
Cameroon (2007–2014)
Urban−0.83
(1.36)
0.09
(2.40)
0.92
[1.11]
Rural1.07
(4.70)
2.60
(5.90)
1.53
[1.43]
Overall1.69
(3.56)
3.04
(4.67)
1.35
[0.80]
Ethiopia (2013–2018)
Urban18.1
(21.6)
17.8
(20.5)
−0.3
[0.02]
Rural16.7
(19.8)
15.4
(18.1)
−1.3
[0.08]
Overall18.0
(21.7)
16.6
(19.8)
−1.4
[0.08]
Kenya (2005–2015)
Urban10.5
(6.98)
10.4
(6.42)
−0.10
[0.01]
Rural9.52
(7.41)
9.86
(7.36)
0.34
[0.04]
Overall9.86
(7.81)
10.2
(7.49)
0.34
[0.04]
Nigeria (2010–2015)
Urban10.9
(12.8)
34.2
(35.2)
23.3
[2.14]
Rural10.3
(11.3)
34.4
(32.8)
24.1
[2.34]
Overall10.1
(11.9)
34.0
(33.8)
23.9
[2.37]
Uganda (2005–2015)
Urban152.8
(76.3)
111.5
(135.8)
−41.3
[0.27]
Rural113.6
(44.6)
55.9
(16.4)
−57.7
[0.51]
Overall116.5
(56.6)
62.4
(51.5)
−54.1
[0.46]
Source: Computed by authors using software component by Barriga-Cabanillas (2014). Notes: Relative values in square brackets [ ]. Overall annualized growth in parentheses ( ).
Table 5. Inequality impacts of equalizing human capital endowments: Palma ratios.
Table 5. Inequality impacts of equalizing human capital endowments: Palma ratios.
VariableFactual
Col. (1)
Counterfactual
Col. (2)
Impact: Abs [Rel.]
Col. (3)
Cameroon (2007–2014)
Urban1.881.960.08 [0.04]
Rural1.821.970.15 [0.08]
Cameroon2.032.100.07 [0.03]
Ethiopia (2013–2015)
Urban2.362.16−0.20 [0.08]
Rural2.462.31−0.15 [0.06]
Ethiopia3.092.67−0.42 [0.14]
Kenya (2005–2015)
Urban2.342.15−0.19 [0.08]
Rural1.951.93−0.02 [0.01]
Kenya2.532.34−0.19 [0.08]
Nigeria (2010–2015)
Urban2.395.012.62 [1.10]
Rural2.364.722.36 [1.00]
Nigeria2.645.112.47 [0.94]
Uganda (2005–2015)
Urban17.870.652.8 [2.97]
Rural7.1627.320.1 [2.81]
Uganda12.745.032.3 [2.54]
Source: Computed by authors.
Table 6. Effect of human capital equalization on household income poverty.
Table 6. Effect of human capital equalization on household income poverty.
Cameroon
Factual P0
Col. (1)
Counterfactual P0
Col. (2)
Change P0
Col. (3)
Factual P1
Col. (4)
Counterfactual P1
Col. (5)
Change P1
Col. (6)
Factual P2
Col. (7)
Counterfactual P2
Col. (8)
Change P2
Col. (9)
Urban0.168 ***0.165 ***−0.003 ***0.049 ***0.047 ***−0.002 ***0.021 ***0.020 ***−0.001 ***
(0.007)(0.007)(0.004)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.000)
Rural0.508 ***0.477 ***−0.031 ***0.180 ***0.170 ***−0.010 ***0.084 ***0.080 ***−0.004 ***
(0.011)(0.012)(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)(0.001)(0.003)(0.003)(0.001)
Overall0.375 ***0.355 ***−0.020 ***0.129 ***0.122 ***−0.006 ***0.059 ***0.056 ***−0.003 ***
(0.010)(0.009)(0.003)(0.004)(0.004)(0.001)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)
Ethiopia
Factual P0Counterfactual P0Change P0Factual P1Counterfactual P1Change P1Factual P2Counterfactual P2Change P2
Urban0.065 ***0.033 ***−0.032 ***0.017 ***0.008 ***−0.009 ***0.007 ***0.003 ***−0.004 ***
(0.008)(0.005)(0.005)(0.002)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Rural0.251 ***0.116 ***−0.135 ***0.074 ***0.029 ***−0.045 ***0.031 ***0.012 ***−0.019 ***
(0.015)(0.010)(0.009)(0.005)(0.003)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.001)
Overall0.210 ***0.098 ***−0.112 ***0.061 ***0.025 ***−0.036 ***0.025 ***0.009 ***−0.016 ***
(0.012)(0.007)(0.007)(0.004)(0.002)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.001)
Kenya
Factual P0Counterfactual P0Change P0Factual P1Counterfactual P1Change P1Factual P2Counterfactual P2Change P2
Urban0.191 ***0.147 ***−0.044 ***0.070 ***0.052 ***−0.018 ***0.036 ***0.026 ***−0.010 ***
(0.011)(0.010)(0.003)(0.005)(0.004)(0.001)(0.003)(0.002)(0.001)
Rural0.425 ***0.337 ***−0.087 ***0.172 ***0.130 ***−0.042 ***0.093 ***0.068 ***−0.025 ***
(0.009)(0.009)(0.003)(0.005)(0.004)(0.001)(0.003)(0.003)(0.001)
Overall0.361 ***0.285 ***−0.075 ***0.144 ***0.109 ***−0.035 ***0.077 ***0.056 ***−0.021 ***
(0.007)(0.007)(0.002)(0.004)(0.003)(0.001)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)
Nigeria
Factual P0Counterfactual P0Change P0Factual P1Counterfactual P1Change P1Factual P2Counterfactual P2Change P2
Urban0.182 ***0.109 ***−0.073 ***0.054 ***0.031 ***−0.023 ***0.023 ***0.013 ***0.010 ***
(0.020)(0.013)(0.010)(0.007)(0.005)(0.003)(0.004)(0.003)(0.001)
Rural0.466 ***0.228 ***−0.237 ***0.170 ***0.085 ***−0.085 ***0.085 ***0.043 ***−0.042 ***
(0.015)(0.009)(0.010)(0.007)(0.005)(0.003)(0.004)(0.003)(0.002)
Overall0.361 ***0.184 ***−0.176 ***0.128 ***0.065 ***−0.063 ***0.062 ***0.032 ***−0.030 ***
(0.017)(0.010)(0.009)(0.007)(0.004)(0.003)(0.004)(0.002)(0.001)
Uganda
Factual P0Counterfactual P0Change P0Factual P1Counterfactual P1Change P1Factual P2Counterfactual P2Change P2
Urban0.127 ***0.182 ***0.054 ***0.056 ***0.080 ***0.024 ***0.035 ***0.049 ***0.014 ***
(0.023)(0.020)(0.014)(0.012)(0.012)(0.004)(0.009)(0.009)(0.003)
Rural0.240 ***0.276 ***0.036 ***0.107 ***0.128 ***0.021 ***0.063 ***0.079 ***0.015 ***
(0.017)(0.013)(0.010)(0.009)(0.008)(0.004)(0.006)(0.005)(0.003)
Overall0.214 ***0.254 ***0.040 ***0.095 ***0.117 ***0.022 ***0.057 ***0.072 ***0.015 ***
(0.015)(0.010)(0.008)(0.008)(0.007)(0.003)(0.005)(0.005)(0.002)
Source: Computed by authors using the DASP software (version 2.1). Notes: Values in parentheses are standard errors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%. P0: poverty incidence; P1: poverty depth; P2: poverty severity. Poverty lines of the counterfactual distribution are calculated using a non-parametric approach to correspond to the official factual distribution poverty lines reported by the National Institute of Statistics for each country.
Table 7. Impact of human capital equalization on Gini income inequality.
Table 7. Impact of human capital equalization on Gini income inequality.
Cameroon
Factual
Col. (1)
Counterfactual
Col. (2)
Change
Col. (3)
Urban0.382 ***0.390 ***0.008 ***
(0.005)(0.005)(0.001)
Rural0.377 ***0.392 ***0.015 ***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.001)
Overall0.413 ***0.419 ***0.006 ***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.001)
Ethiopia
FactualCounterfactualChange
Urban0.430 ***0.416 ***−0.014 ***
(0.012)(0.012)(0.001)
Rural0.418 ***0.412 ***−0.006 ***
(0.010)(0.010)(0.001)
Overall0.451 ***0.432 ***−0.019 ***
(0.008)(0.008)(0.001)
Kenya
FactualCounterfactualChange
Urban0.434 ***0.411 ***−0.023 ***
(0.011)(0.009)(0.002)
Rural0.382 ***0.379 ***−0.003 ***
(0.004)(0.004)(0.001)
Overall0.439 ***0.420 ***−0.019 ***
(0.006)(0.005)(0.001)
Nigeria
Factual CounterfactualChange
Urban0.417 ***0.533 ***0.116 ***
(0.011)(0.011)(0.007)
Rural0.413 ***0.522 ***0.109 ***
(0.010)(0.008)(0.003)
Overall0.439 ***0.538 ***0.099 ***
(0.009)(0.007)(0.004)
Uganda
FactualCounterfactualChange
Urban0.652 ***0.802 ***0.150 ***
(0.018)(0.019)(0.018)
Rural0.539 ***0.754 ***0.214 ***
(0.011)(0.007)(0.011)
Overall0.618 ***0.781 ***0.162 ***
(0.013)(0.009)(0.012)
Source: Computed by authors using the DASP software by Araar and Duclos (2009). Notes: Values in parentheses are standard errors. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%.
Table 8. Human capital deprivations by location.
Table 8. Human capital deprivations by location.
Cameroon
20072014
Population share
Col. (1)
Incidence of deprivation
Col. (2)
Depth of deprivation
Col. (3)
Severity of deprivation
Col. (4)
Population share
Col. (5)
Incidence of deprivation
Col. (6)
Depth of deprivation
Col. (7)
Severity of deprivation
Col. (8)
Urban0.353 ***0.108 ***0.008 ***0.0005 ***0.423 ***0.137 ***0.012 ***0.002 ***
(0.017)(0.007)(0.001)(0.0001)(0.006)(0.005)(0.001)(0.0001)
Rural0.647 ***0.376 ***0.029 ***0.004 ***0.577 ***0.316 ***0.032 ***0.004 ***
(0.017)(0.014)(0.002)(0.0001)(0.006)(0.008)(0.001)(0.0001)
Overall 0.484 ***0.037 ***0.004 *** 0.452 ***0.044 ***0.006 ***
(0.011)(0.001)(0.0001) (0.009)(0.001)(0.0001)
Ethiopia
20132018
Population shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivationPopulation shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivation
Urban0.185 ***0.082 ***0.011 ***0.002 ***0.264 ***0.102 ***0.008 ***0.001 ***
(0.018)(0.009)(0.001)(0.0002)(0.025)(0.011)(0.001)(0.0001)
Rural0.815 ***0.509 ***0.051 ***0.007 ***0.736 ***0.421 ***0.032 ***0.003 ***
(0.019)(0.017)(0.002)(0.001)(0.025)(0.022)(0.002)(0.0003)
Overall 0.591 ***0.062 ***0.009 *** 0.523 ***0.040 ***0.004 ***
(0.013)(0.002)(0.001) (0.018)(0.002)(0.0003)
Kenya
20052015
Population shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivationPopulation shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivation
Urban0.235 ***0.145 ***0.043 ***0.013 ***0.304 ***0.168 ***0.021 ***0.003 ***
(0.013)(0.009)(0.002)(0.001)(0.011)(0.008)(0.001)(0.0002)
Rural0.765 ***0.539 ***0.171 ***0.056 ***0.696 ***0.555 ***0.078 ***0.014 ***
(0.013)(0.011)(0.004)(0.001)(0.011)(0.010)(0.001)(0.001)
Overall 0.684 ***0.214 ***0.069 *** 0.722 ***0.097 ***0.017 ***
(0.009)(0.003)(0.001) (0.007)(0.001)(0.001)
Nigeria
20102015
Population shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivationPopulation shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivation
Urban0.366 ***0.171 ***0.008 ***0.001 ***0.357 ***0.134 ***0.056 ***0.029 ***
(0.024)(0.015)(0.001)(0.0001)(0.023)(0.013)(0.006)(0.003)
Rural0.634 ***0.473 ***0.020 ***0.001 ***0.643 ***0.414 ***0.198 ***0.112 ***
(0.024)(0.020)(0.001)(0.0001)(0.023)(0.019)(0.011)(0.008)
Overall 0.644 ***0.028 ***0.002 *** 0.549 ***0.254 ***0.141 ***
(0.012)(0.001)(0.0001) (0.015)(0.010)(0.007)
Uganda
20052015
Population shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivationPopulation shareIncidence of deprivationDepth of deprivationSeverity of deprivation
Urban0.240 ***0.078 ***0.011 ***0.003 ***0.231 ***0.068 ***0.009 ***0.002 ***
(0.023)(0.009)(0.001)(0.001)(0.023)(0.009)(0.001)(0.001)
Rural0.760 ***0.382 ***0.053 ***0.013 ***0.769 ***0.363 ***0.053 ***0.014 ***
(0.023)(0.018)(0.003)(0.001)(0.023)(0.021(0.003)(0.001)
Overall 0.459 ***0.064 ***0.016 *** 0.431 ***0.063 ***0.016 ***
(0.017)(0.003)(0.001) (0.019)(0.003)(0.001)
Source: Computed using DAD 4.6 software. Notes: Figures in parentheses represent standard errors. Results are reported in three decimal places. These are absolute contributions. *** 1%, ** 5%, and * 10%.
Table 9. Growth and redistribution decomposition of changes in human capital deprivation.
Table 9. Growth and redistribution decomposition of changes in human capital deprivation.
CameroonGrowth
Component
Col. (1)
Redistribution
Component
Col. (2)
Δ P 0
Col. (3)
Growth
Component
Col. (4)
Redistribution
Component
Col. (5)
Δ P 1
Col. (6)
Growth
Component
Col. (7)
Redistribution
Component
Col. (8)
Δ P 2
Col. (9)
Urban−0.013−0.020−0.033−0.0020.0130.011−0.00030.0030.0033
(0.004)(0.004)(0.018)(0.002)(0.002)(0.002)(0.0004)(0.0004)(0.001)
Rural−0.0170.0330.016−0.0020.0080.006−0.00020.0010.0012
(0.001)(0.001)(0.015)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.0002)
Overall−0.029−0.003−0.032−0.0040.0110.007−0.0010.0030.002
(0.002)(0.002)(0.014)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.002)(0.002)(0.0004)
EthiopiaGrowth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 0 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 1 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 2
Urban−0.0780.028−0.050−0.012−0.007−0.019−0.002−0.002−0.004
(0.006)(0.006)(0.028)(0.005)(0.005)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Rural0.063−0.119−0.0560.012−0.041−0.0290.002−0.010−0.008
(0.013)(0.013)(0.030)(0.007)(0.007)(0.005)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Overall−0.0810.015−0.066−0.013−0.009−0.022−0.002−0.003−0.005
(0.005)(0.005)(0.013)(0.005)(0.005)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
KenyaGrowth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 0 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 1 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 2
Urban−0.016−0.051−0.067−0.1240.009−0.115−0.0500.005−0.045
(0.022)(0.022)(0.024)(0.009)(0.009)(0.006)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)
Rural−0.0010.0940.093−0.066−0.045−0.111−0.029−0.024−0.053
(0.001)(0.001)(0.012)(0.007)(0.007)(0.004)(0.003)(0.003)(0.001)
Overall−0.0010.0380.0395−0.096−0.019−0.115−0.042−0.010−0.052
(0.003)(0.003)(0.011)(0.006)(0.006)(0.003)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)
NigeriaGrowth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 0 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 1 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 2
Urban−0.2720.180−0.092−0.0620.1990.137−0.0430.1230.080
(0.013)(0.013)(0.035)(0.002)(0.002)(0.002)(0.001)(0.001)(0.008)
Rural−0.3750.275−0.100−0.0340.3110.277−0.0150.1900.175
(0.019)(0.019)(0.021)(0.004)(0.004)(0.013)(0.003)(0.003)(0.010)
Overall−0.3520.257−0.095−0.0520.2790.227−0.0320.1730.141
(0.007)(0.007)(0.020)(0.002)(0.002)(0.010)(0.001)(0.001)(0.007)
UgandaGrowth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 0 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 1 Growth
Component
Redistribution
Component
Δ P 2
Urban−0.0530.024−0.029−0.004−0.0015−0.006−0.001−0.002−0.003
(0.009)(0.009)(0.040)(0.004)(0.004)(0.007)(0.001)(0.001)(0.002)
Rural−0.008−0.022−0.030−0.00110.0003−0.0008−0.00030.00100.0007
(0.001)(0.001)(0.031)(0.004)(0.004)(0.003)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Overall−0.016−0.013−0.029−0.0020.0002−0.0022−0.00050.0004−0.0001
(0.002)(0.002)(0.025)(0.003)(0.003)(0.004)(0.0009)(0.0009)(0.0001)
Source: Computed using DAD 4.6. Notes: Figures in parentheses represent standard errors. Results are reported in three decimal places.
Table 10. Intra- and inter-sectoral components of changes in human capital deprivation.
Table 10. Intra- and inter-sectoral components of changes in human capital deprivation.
CameroonIntra-Sectoral Effects Col. (1)Inter-Sectoral Effects Col. (2)Impact on Δ P 0
Col. (3)
Intra-Sectoral Effects Col. (4)Inter-Sectoral Effects Col. (5)Impact on Δ P 1
Col. (6)
Intra-Sectoral Effects Col. (7)Inter-Sectoral Effects Col. (8)Impact on Δ P 2
Col. (9)
Urban0.0060.0220.0280.0020.0020.0040.0010.0000.001
(0.008) (0.001) (0.0001)
Rural−0.020−0.040−0.0600.007−0.0040.0030.002−0.0010.001
(0.016) (0.002) (0.0004)
Overall−0.014−0.018−0.0320.009−0.0020.0070.003−0.0010.002
(0.014) (0.001) (0.0004)
EthiopiaIntra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 0 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 1 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 2
Urban−0.0130.0330.020−0.0060.003−0.003−0.0020.001−0.001
(0.015) (0.001) (0.0003)
Rural−0.041−0.047−0.088−0.015−0.004−0.019−0.003−0.001−0.004
(0.028) (0.001) (0.001)
Overall−0.053−0.015−0.068−0.021−0.001−0.022−0.0050.000−0.005
(0.022) (0.003) (0.001)
KenyaIntra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 0 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 1 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 2
Urban−0.0180.0410.023−0.0310.009−0.022−0.0120.002−0.010
(0.012) (0.003) (0.001)
Rural0.068−0.0520.016−0.081−0.012−0.093−0.039−0.003−0.042
(0.016) (0.004) (0.001)
Overall0.050−0.0110.039−0.112−0.003−0.115−0.051−0.001−0.052
(0.011) (0.003) (0.001)
NigeriaIntra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 0 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 1 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 2
Urban−0.033−0.004−0.0370.049−0.0010.0480.028−0.00040.028
(0.020) (0.006) (0.003)
Rural−0.0650.006−0.0580.1760.0020.1770.1110.0000.111
(0.028) (0.011) (0.001)
Overall−0.0980.003−0.0950.2250.0010.2260.1390.00040.139
(0.020) (0.010) (0.007)
UgandaIntra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 0 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 1 Intra-Sectoral EffectsInter-Sectoral EffectsImpact on Δ P 2
Urban−0.007−0.003−0.010−0.001−0.0003−0.001−0.0007−0.0001−0.0008
(0.013) (0.001) (0.0007)
Rural−0.0230.004−0.019−0.00060.0006−0.0000.00060.00020.0007
(0.028) (0.004) (0.0007)
Overall−0.0300.002−0.029−0.0020.0003−0.002−0.00050.00040.0001
(0.025) (0.004) (0.0001)
Source: Computed using DAD 4.6. Notes: Figures in parentheses represent standard errors. Results are reported in three decimal places.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Epo, B.N.; Baye, F.M.; Mwabu, G.; Manda, D.K.; Ajakaiye, O.; Kipruto, S. Human Capital, Household Prosperity, and Social Inequalities in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economies 2025, 13, 221. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13080221

AMA Style

Epo BN, Baye FM, Mwabu G, Manda DK, Ajakaiye O, Kipruto S. Human Capital, Household Prosperity, and Social Inequalities in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economies. 2025; 13(8):221. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13080221

Chicago/Turabian Style

Epo, Boniface Ngah, Francis Menjo Baye, Germano Mwabu, Damiano K. Manda, Olu Ajakaiye, and Samuel Kipruto. 2025. "Human Capital, Household Prosperity, and Social Inequalities in Sub-Saharan Africa" Economies 13, no. 8: 221. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13080221

APA Style

Epo, B. N., Baye, F. M., Mwabu, G., Manda, D. K., Ajakaiye, O., & Kipruto, S. (2025). Human Capital, Household Prosperity, and Social Inequalities in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economies, 13(8), 221. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13080221

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop