The Price of Poverty: Inequality and the Strategic Use of Clientelism in Divided Democracies
Abstract
1. Introduction
2. A Probabilistic Voting Model with Vote-Buying
2.1. Voters
2.1.1. Elite Voters
2.1.2. Non-Elite Voters
2.1.3. Comparative Analysis: Elite and Non-Elite Voters
2.2. Political Parties
2.2.1. Elite Political Party
2.2.2. Non-Elite Political Party
2.3. The Characterization Result
3. Empirical Evidence
3.1. Data and Results
3.2. Results
4. Final Notes
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
1 | We denote as the transpose of the column vector . |
2 | It is straightforward to verify that the function is a bijection; hence, its inverse function exists and is well-defined. |
3 | Due to the dynamic process involved in Equation (1), more periods are better. However, more periods result in a few countries because of the availability of the GINI or democracy data. Therefore, we selected counties with high HDI (>0.7) and present the last year with complete information concerning GINI and the democracy index. |
References
- Abers, R. (1998). From clientelism to cooperation: Local government, participatory policy, and civic organizing in Porto Alegre, Brazil. Politics & Society, 26(4), 511–537. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alamdari, K. (2005). The power structure of the Islamic Republic of Iran: Transition from populism to clientelism and militarization of the government. Third World Quarterly, 26(8), 1285–1302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alvaredo, F., & Gasparini, L. (2015). Recent trends in inequality and poverty in developing countries. In Handbook of income distribution (Vol. 2, pp. 697–805). Elsevier. [Google Scholar]
- Amat, F., & Beramendi, P. (2016). Economic and political inequality: The role of political mobilization. In CAGE online working paper series, 277. Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy (CAGE), University of Warwick. [Google Scholar]
- Anderson, C. J., & Tverdova, Y. V. (2005). Corruption, political allegiances, and attitudes toward government in contemporary democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 49(1), 91–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arias, E. D. (2006). Trouble en route: Drug trafficking and clientelism in Rio de Janeiro shantytowns. Qualitative Sociology, 29(4), 427–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aspinall, E., & Hicken, A. (2020). Guns for hire and enduring machines: Clientelism beyond parties in Indonesia and the Philippines. Democratization, 27(1), 137–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Auyero, J. (1999). “From the client’s point(s) of view”: How poor people perceive and evaluate political clientelism. Theory and Society, 28(2), 297–334. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Auyero, J. (2000). The logic of clientelism in Argentina: An ethnographic account. Latin American Research Review, 35(3), 55–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bacchus, E. B., & Boulding, C. (2022). Corruption perceptions: Confidence in elections and evaluations of clientelism. Governance, 35, 609–632. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Best, H. (2010). Associated rivals: Antagonism and cooperation in the German political elite. In Democratic elitism: New theoretical and comparative perspectives. Brill. [Google Scholar]
- Best, H., & Hoffmann-Lange, U. (2018). Introduction: Challenged elites—Elites as challengers. Towards a unified theory of representative elites. Historical Social Research, 43(4), 7–32. [Google Scholar]
- Birch, S. (1997). Nomenklatura democratization: Electoral clientelism in post-soviet Ukraine. Democratization, 4(4), 40–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Campati, A. (2022). Elite and liberal democracy: A new equilibrium? Topoi: An International Review of Philosophy, 41(1), 15–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Chanie, P. (2007). Clientelism and ethiopia’s post-1991 decentralisation. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 45(3), 355–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clark, J. (2004). Social movement theory and patron-clientelism: Islamic social institutions and the middle class in Egypt, Jordan, and Yemen. Comparative Political Studies, 37(8), 941–968. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Converse, P. (2006). The nature of belief systems in mass publics (1964). Critical Review, 18(1–3), 1–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Daby, M. (2021). The gender gap in political clientelism: Problem-solving networks and the division of political work in Argentina. Comparative Political Studies, 54(2), 215–244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eaton, K. (2006). The downside of decentralization: Armed clientelism in Colombia. Security Studies, 15(4), 533–562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenstadt, S. N., & Roniger, L. (1980). Patron-client relations as a model of structuring social exchange. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 22(1), 42–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenstadt, S. N., & Roniger, L. (1981). Clientelism in communist systems: A comparative perspective. Studies in Comparative Communism, 14(2/3), 233–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenstadt, S. N., & Roniger, L. (1984). Patrons, clients and friends: Interpersonal relations and the structure of trust in society. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Ekiert, G. (1991). Democratization processes in east central Europe: A theoretical reconsideration. British Journal of Political Science, 21(3), 285–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fergusson, L., Molina, C. A., & Robinson, J. A. (2022). The weak state trap. Economica, 89(354), 293–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fox, J. (1994). The difficult transition from clientelism to citizenship: Lessons from Mexico. World Politics, 46(2), 151–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fox, J. (1996). How does civil society thicken? the political construction of social capital in rural Mexico. World Development, 24(6), 1089–1103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Friedman, S., Laurison, D., & Miles, A. (2015). Breaking the ‘class’ ceiling? Social mobility into Britain’s elite occupations. The Sociological Review, 63(2), 259–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gallego, A. (2015). Unequal political participation worldwide. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Gherghina, S., & Nemčok, M. (2021). Political parties, state resources and electoral clientelism. Acta Politica, 56(4), 591–599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gibson, E. (1996). Class and conservative parties. Johns Hopkins University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Graziano, L. (1976). A conceptual framework for the study of clientelistic behavior. European Journal of Political Research, 4(2), 149–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graziano, P. (2019, December 11). Report the middle class and the social cohesion. Council of Europe 1363rd Meeting, Strasbourg, France. [Google Scholar]
- Guerrero-Sierra, H., Duque, P., & Nio, C. (2024). Analysis of worldwide research on clientelism: Origins, evolution, and trends. Social Science Information, 63(3). [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hafner-Burton, E., Hughes, D., & Victor, D. (2013). The cognitive revolution and the political psychology of elite decision making. Perspectives on Politics, 11(2), 368–386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hallin, D. C., & Papathanassopoulos, S. (2002). Political clientelism and the media: Southern Europe and Latin America in comparative perspective. Media Culture & Society, 24(2), 175–195. [Google Scholar]
- Hicken, A. (2011). Clientelism. Annual Review of Political Science, 14(1), 289–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hicken, A. (2007). How do rules and institutions encourage vote buying? In F. C. Schaffer (Ed.), Elections for sale: The causes and consequences of vote buying (pp. 68–89). Lynne Rienner Publishers. [Google Scholar]
- Hicken, A., Aspinall, E., Weiss, M. L., & Muhtadi, B. (2022). Buying brokers: Electoral handouts beyond clientelism in a weak-party state. World Politics, 74(1), 77–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Higley, J. (2010). Elite theory and elites. In K. T. Leicht, & J. C. Jenkins (Eds.), Handbook of politics. Handbooks of sociology and social research. Springer. [Google Scholar]
- Hilgers, T. (2011). Clientelism and conceptual stretching: Differentiating among concepts and among analytical levels. Theory and Society, 40(5), 567–588. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Holcombe, R. G. (2021). Elite influence on general political preferences. Journal of Government and Economics, 3, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huijsmans, T., Rijken, A. J., & Gaidyte, T. (2022). The income gap in voting: Moderating effects of income inequality and clientelism. Political Behavior, 44, 1203–1223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Huntington, S. P. (1991). Democracy’s third wave. Journal of Democracy, 2(2), 12–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huntington, S. P. (1997). After twenty years: The future of the third wave. Journal of Democracy, 8(4), 3–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Husermann, S., & Schwander, H. (2012). Varieties of dualization? Labor market segmentation and insider-outsider divides across regimes. In P. Emmenegger, S. Husermann, B. Palier, & M. Seeleib-Kaiser (Eds.), The age of dualization. The changing face of inequality in deindustrializing societies (pp. 27–51). Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Inglehart, R. (1997). The silent revolution: Changing values and political styles among western publics. Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Jaime-Castillo, A. M. (2009). Economic inequality and electoral participation: A cross-country evaluation. SSRN Electronic Journal. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jensen, C., & Jespersen, B. B. (2017). To have or not to have: Effects of economic inequality on turnout in European democracies. Electoral Studies, 45, 24–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Joseph, R. (1997). Democratization in Africa after 1989: Comparative and theoretical perspectives. Comparative Politics, 29(3), 363–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Keefer, P. (2007). Clientelism, credibility, and the policy choices of young democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 804–821. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Keefer, P., & Vlaicu, R. (2008). Democracy, credibility, and clientelism. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 24(2), 371–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. I. (Eds.). (2007). Patrons, clients and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Land, C. H. (1983). Political clientelism in political studies: Retrospect and prospects. International Political Science Review/Revue Internationale de Science Politique, 4(4), 435–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Laurison, D. (2016). Social class and political engagement in the United States. Sociology Compass, 10(8), e12390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, J. (2002). Primay causes of Asian democratization: Dispelling conventional myths. Asian Survey, 42(6), 821–837. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Legg, K. (1972). Interpersonal relationships and comparative politics: Political clientelism in industrial society. Politics, 7(1), 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levitsky, S. (2007). From populism to clientelism? The transformation of labor-based party linkages in Latin America. In H. Kitschelt, & S. I. Wilkinson (Eds.), Patrons, clients and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition (pp. 206–226). Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Lindberg, S. I. (2003). “It”s our time to “chop”’: Do elections in Africa feed neo-patrimonialism rather than counter-act it? Democratization, 10(2), 121–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Z., Qian, T., & Zhang, Q. (2021). Power signaling and intergovernmental transfers: Evidence from the distribution of center-to-province earmarked transfers in China. Social Science Quarterly, 102, 683–705. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lo Bue, M., Sen, K., & Lindberg, S. (2021). Clientelism, public goods provision, and governance. SSRN Electronic Journal. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lust, E. (2009). Democratization by elections? Competitive clientelism in the Middle East. Journal of Democracy, 20(3), 122–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mainwaring, S., & Viola, E. J. (1985). Transitions to democracy: Brazil and Argentina in the 1980s. Journal of International Affairs, 38(2), 193–219. [Google Scholar]
- Manzetti, L., & Wilson, C. J. (2007). Why do corrupt governments maintain public support? Comparative Political Studies, 40(8), 949–970. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Matsubayashi, T., & Sakaiya, S. (2021). Income inequality and income bias in voter turnout. European Journal of Political Economy, 66, 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mavrogordatos, G. T. (1997). From traditional clientelism to machine politics: The impact of PASOK populism in Greece. South European Society & Politics, 2(3), 1–26. [Google Scholar]
- Meisel, J. (1958). The myth of the ruling class. University of Michigan Press. [Google Scholar]
- Mosca, G. (1939). The ruling class. McGraw-Hill. [Google Scholar]
- Okada, A., Sakakibara, K., & Suga, K. (1996). The dynamic transformation of political systems through social contract: A game theoretic approach. Social Choice Welfare, 14, 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pani, M. (2011). Hold your nose and vote: Corruption and public decisions in a representative democracy. Public Choice, 148(1/2), 163–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Papadopoulos, Y. (1997). Transformations of party clientelism in southern Europe in a phase of democratic consolidation. Swiss Political Science Review, 3(4), 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pareto, V. (1991). The rise and fall of elites. An application of theoretical sociology. Routledge. [Google Scholar]
- Pellicer, M., Wegner, E., Bayer, M., & Tischmeyer, C. (2022). Clientelism from the Client’s perspective: A meta-analysis of ethnographic literature. Perspectives on Politics, 20(3), 931–947. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Penfold-Becerra, M. (2007). Clientelism and social funds: Evidence from Chávez’s Misiones. Latin American Politics & Society, 49(4), 63–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policy. MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Poggi, G. (1983). Clientelism. Political Studies, 31(4), 662–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ravanilla, N., Haim, D., & Hicken, A. (2021). Brokers, social networks, reciprocity, and clientelism. American Journal of Political Science, 66(4), 795–812. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Remmer, K. L. (1992). The process of democratization in Latin America. Studies in Comparative International Development, 27(4), 3–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Robinson, J., & Verdier, T. (2003). The political economy of clientelism. Typescript. University of California, Berkeley. [Google Scholar]
- Roudakova, N. (2008). Media–political clientelism: Lessons from anthropology. Media, Culture & Society, 121(1), 41–59. [Google Scholar]
- Schwander, H. (2019). Labor market insecurity among the middle class: A cross-pressured group. Political Science Research and Methods, 8(2), 369–374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scott, J. C. (1972). Patron-client politics and political change in Southeast Asia. The American Political Science Review, 66(1), 91–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shchukin, V., & Arbatli, C. E. (2022). Clientelism and development: Vote-buying meets patronage. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 34(1), 3–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scervini, F., & Segatti, P. (2012). Education, inequality and electoral participation. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility, 30(4), 403–413. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schmidt, S. W., Scott, J. C., Lande, C., & Guasti, L. (Eds.). (1979). Friends, followers, and factions: A reader in political clientelism. University of California Press. [Google Scholar]
- Solt, F. (2008). Economic inequality and democratic political engagement. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 48–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Solt, F. (2010). Does economic inequality depress electoral participation? Testing the Schattschneider hypothesis. Political Behavior, 32(2), 285–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stokes, S. (2007). Is vote-buying undemocratic? In F. C. Schaffer (Ed.), Elections for sale: The causes and consequences of vote buying (pp. 117–143). Lynne Rienner Publishers. [Google Scholar]
- Stokes, S. (2021). Clientelism and development: Is there a poverty trap? WIDER working paper 91. United Nations University. [Google Scholar]
- Stokes, S., Dunning, T., Nazareno, M., & Brusco, V. (2013). Brokers, voters, and clientelism. The puzzle of distributive politics. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Stokes, S. C. (2005). Perverse accountability: A formal model of machine politics with evidence from Argentina. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 315–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Strom, K. (1989). Inter-party competition in advanced democracies. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 1(3), 277–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Szwarcberg, M. (2013). The microfoundations of political clientelism: Lessons from the Argentine case. Latin American Research Review, 48(2), 32–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thachil, T. (2014a). Elite parties, poor voters: How social services win votes in India. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Thachil, T. (2014b). How services win votes. In Elite parties, poor voters: How social services win votes in India (pp. 142–182). Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Thompson, M. R. (2010). Populism and the revival of reform: Competing political narratives in the Philippines. Contemporary Southeast Asia, 32(1), 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van De Walle, N. (2007). Meet the new boss, same as the old boss? The evolution of political clientelism in Africa. In Patrons, clients and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition (pp. 50–67). Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Vicente, P. C., & Wantchekon, L. (2009). Clientelism and vote buying: Lessons from field experiments in African elections. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 25(2), 292–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vilchez, V. C., Paucar-Caceres, A., & Werner, K. (2021). A systemic framework to evaluate political clientelism and citizens’ subjectivation processes. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 38, 6–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wantchekon, L. (2003). Clientelism and voting behavior: Evidence from a field experiment in Benin. World Politics, 55(3), 399–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Weitz-Shapiro, R. (2012). What wins votes: Why some politicians opt out of clientelism. American Journal of Political Science, 56(3), 568–583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Williams, G., & Filippakou, O. (2010). Higher education and UK elite formation in the twentieth century. Higher Education, 59(1), 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wood, T. (2018). The clientelism trap in Solomon Islands and Papua New Guinea, and its impact on aid policy. Asia & the Pacific Policy Studies, 5, 481–494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Wren, A., & McElwain, K. M. (2011). Voters and parties. The Oxford Handbook of Political Science. [Google Scholar]
- Yıldırım, K., & Kitschelt, H. (2020). Analytical perspectives on varieties of clientelism. Democratization, 27(1), 20–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuda, T. K. (2021). The complementary roles between clientelism and familism in social policy development. Social Policy & Administration, 55(7), 1370–1392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Dimension | Elite Voters | Non-Elite Voters |
---|---|---|
Average ideal public expenditure | Low () | High () |
Partisan cohesion (f) | High () | Low () |
Collective action capacity | Strong (coordination, organization) | Weak (atomization, low integration) |
Dependence on state provision | Low (self-sufficiency via private provision) | High (state-dependent for public goods) |
Access to power | High (control of institutions/resources) | Low (structurally excluded) |
Dominant partisan bias | Toward party A (elite) | Toward party B (non-elite) |
Year | Mean | Std. Dev. | Freq. |
---|---|---|---|
2013 | 0.343 | 0.250 | 26 |
2014 | 0.333 | 0.243 | 26 |
2015 | 0.327 | 0.243 | 26 |
2016 | 0.331 | 0.244 | 26 |
2017 | 0.334 | 0.241 | 26 |
2018 | 0.337 | 0.236 | 26 |
2019 | 0.314 | 0.228 | 26 |
Average | 0.331 | 0.237 | |
Total | 182 |
Country/Year | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Armenia | 0.69 | 0.68 | 0.68 | 0.67 | 0.70 | 0.70 | 0.67 |
Belarus | 0.11 | 0.11 | 0.11 | 0.10 | 0.11 | 0.10 | 0.11 |
Belgium | 0.04 | 0.04 | 0.04 | 0.03 | 0.03 | 0.03 | 0.03 |
Bolivia | 0.20 | 0.24 | 0.23 | 0.22 | 0.21 | 0.22 | 0.21 |
Brazil | 0.33 | 0.32 | 0.33 | 0.34 | 0.36 | 0.38 | 0.37 |
China | 0.26 | 0.26 | 0.25 | 0.24 | 0.25 | 0.24 | 0.24 |
Colombia | 0.69 | 0.67 | 0.66 | 0.70 | 0.68 | 0.66 | 0.66 |
Cyprus | 0.29 | 0.28 | 0.28 | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.27 |
Dominican Republic | 0.64 | 0.63 | 0.62 | 0.61 | 0.60 | 0.60 | 0.58 |
Ecuador | 0.51 | 0.51 | 0.51 | 0.51 | 0.50 | 0.49 | 0.48 |
Estonia | 0.10 | 0.10 | 0.10 | 0.09 | 0.09 | 0.09 | 0.08 |
Finland | 0.06 | 0.06 | 0.06 | 0.06 | 0.05 | 0.05 | 0.05 |
Greece | 0.40 | 0.39 | 0.39 | 0.38 | 0.36 | 0.35 | 0.34 |
Hungary | 0.23 | 0.24 | 0.24 | 0.24 | 0.24 | 0.25 | 0.25 |
Iran | 0.34 | 0.32 | 0.31 | 0.32 | 0.33 | 0.33 | 0.33 |
Luxembourg | 0.05 | 0.05 | 0.05 | 0.04 | 0.04 | 0.04 | 0.04 |
Malta | 0.22 | 0.22 | 0.22 | 0.21 | 0.21 | 0.20 | 0.20 |
Norway | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.02 |
Panama | 0.57 | 0.55 | 0.54 | 0.53 | 0.52 | 0.52 | 0.50 |
Peru | 0.45 | 0.44 | 0.44 | 0.43 | 0.43 | 0.42 | 0.41 |
Romania | 0.31 | 0.31 | 0.31 | 0.30 | 0.30 | 0.30 | 0.29 |
Russia | 0.55 | 0.54 | 0.54 | 0.53 | 0.53 | 0.52 | 0.52 |
Slovakia | 0.13 | 0.11 | 0.11 | 0.10 | 0.10 | 0.09 | 0.09 |
Slovenia | 0.16 | 0.15 | 0.15 | 0.15 | 0.15 | 0.14 | 0.14 |
Turkey | 0.61 | 0.59 | 0.58 | 0.57 | 0.56 | 0.56 | 0.55 |
Ukraine | 0.66 | 0.64 | 0.63 | 0.62 | 0.62 | 0.61 | 0.60 |
USA | 0.06 | 0.06 | 0.06 | 0.06 | 0.07 | 0.08 | 0.08 |
Country | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | HDI 2019 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Armenia | 30.6 | 31.5 | 32.4 | 32.5 | 33.6 | 34.2 | 29.9 | 0.776 |
Belarus | 26.6 | 27.2 | 26.3 | 25.6 | 25.4 | 25.2 | 27.2 | 0.808 |
Belgium | 27.7 | 28.1 | 27.7 | 27.5 | 27.4 | 27.4 | 27.4 | 0.931 |
Bolivia | 47.6 | 47.2 | 45.6 | 44.6 | 44.1 | 43.4 | 39.0 | 0.703 |
Brazil | 52.7 | 52.9 | 53.3 | 53.5 | 53.9 | 53.0 | 53.4 | 0.766 |
China | 42.1 | 42.0 | 42.0 | 42.0 | 42.2 | 42.2 | 38.5 | 0.761 |
Colombia | 53.6 | 52.6 | 51.6 | 50.8 | 50.4 | 51.3 | 51.3 | 0.767 |
Cyprus | 32.2 | 32.2 | 32.1 | 32.0 | 32.2 | 31.7 | 30.1 | 0.896 |
Dominican Republic | 47.7 | 44.3 | 45.2 | 45.7 | 44.2 | 43.0 | 41.9 | 0.771 |
Ecuador | 46.9 | 45.6 | 45.1 | 44.0 | 43.2 | 42.5 | 42.4 | 0.759 |
Estonia | 31.1 | 30.2 | 30.0 | 29.5 | 29.1 | 29.5 | 30.0 | 0.892 |
Finland | 27.2 | 26.8 | 26.4 | 26.3 | 25.8 | 25.6 | 25.6 | 0.938 |
Greece | 36.1 | 36.3 | 35.7 | 35.4 | 34.3 | 33.1 | 32.4 | 0.888 |
Hungary | 29.2 | 30.4 | 30.3 | 30.2 | 29.6 | 30.0 | 30.0 | 0.850 |
Iran | 40.8 | 39.5 | 38.4 | 37.6 | 36.2 | 36.5 | 37.4 | 0.783 |
Luxembourg | 34.4 | 32.9 | 32.2 | 31.4 | 31.4 | 30.9 | 30.4 | 0.927 |
Malta | 28.8 | 29.7 | 29.2 | 28.9 | 28.7 | 28.0 | 28.0 | 0.895 |
Norway | 26.4 | 26.8 | 27.5 | 28.9 | 27.8 | 27.3 | 27.0 | 0.961 |
Panama | 51.5 | 50.2 | 49.9 | 49.6 | 48.4 | 47.1 | 47.3 | 0.815 |
Peru | 43.9 | 43.1 | 43.4 | 43.8 | 43.2 | 42.4 | 41.5 | 0.777 |
Romania | 34.5 | 35.5 | 35.6 | 34.8 | 34.4 | 34.3 | 34.8 | 0.828 |
Russia | 40.9 | 39.9 | 39.6 | 39.2 | 38.6 | 38.0 | 38.5 | 0.824 |
Slovenia | 31.7 | 30.6 | 30.4 | 30.0 | 30.3 | 30.0 | 30.2 | 0.917 |
Turkey | 40.2 | 40.2 | 39.5 | 39.0 | 39.5 | 39.3 | 39.7 | 0.820 |
Ukraine | 24.6 | 24.2 | 25.5 | 25.1 | 26.1 | 26.6 | 28.6 | 0.785 |
USA | 40.3 | 41.0 | 41.5 | 41.2 | 41.1 | 41.4 | 41.5 | 0.930 |
Country | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Armenia | 48.79 | 47.46 | 46.48 | 45.91 | 45.62 | 43.08 | 44.19 |
Belarus | 59.60 | 59.91 | 60.31 | 60.61 | 60.79 | 61.46 | 61.67 |
Belgium | 49.04 | 48.95 | 48.79 | 48.95 | 50.02 | 50.97 | 51.47 |
Bolivia | 67.61 | 69.35 | 69.09 | 68.05 | 66.13 | 69.27 | 57.98 |
Brazil | 58.00 | 58.00 | 56.99 | 54.87 | 54.37 | 54.55 | 55.14 |
China | 67.34 | 67.21 | 67.07 | 66.92 | 66.65 | 66.43 | 66.01 |
Colombia | 62.78 | 63.22 | 63.71 | 63.70 | 62.78 | 62.16 | 60.76 |
Cyprus | 53.25 | 53.49 | 53.00 | 53.33 | 54.82 | 57.18 | 58.51 |
Dominican Republic | 54.91 | 55.33 | 57.29 | 57.90 | 58.73 | 60.03 | 61.04 |
Ecuador | 60.34 | 60.44 | 63.28 | 64.56 | 65.53 | 64.31 | 63.66 |
Estonia | 56.04 | 56.82 | 56.38 | 58.62 | 59.69 | 60.37 | 62.80 |
Finland | 54.30 | 53.84 | 53.41 | 53.44 | 53.79 | 55.06 | 55.44 |
Greece | 37.74 | 38.10 | 39.00 | 38.97 | 40.89 | 41.88 | 42.97 |
Hungary | 46.87 | 49.53 | 51.03 | 52.85 | 53.83 | 54.65 | 55.15 |
Iran | 37.44 | 38.93 | 36.73 | 37.22 | 38.39 | 36.60 | 39.00 |
Luxembourg | 55.92 | 56.66 | 55.92 | 55.21 | 56.06 | 56.53 | 57.26 |
Malta | 50.81 | 51.21 | 52.74 | 54.07 | 55.58 | 57.89 | 59.27 |
Norway | 62.78 | 62.60 | 62.19 | 61.50 | 61.08 | 61.68 | 61.82 |
Panama | 61.49 | 60.94 | 60.91 | 60.89 | 60.90 | 61.50 | 62.42 |
Peru | 75.08 | 74.59 | 73.42 | 73.96 | 74.16 | 74.49 | 74.75 |
Romania | 50.66 | 51.14 | 50.83 | 50.55 | 52.23 | 52.68 | 52.98 |
Russia | 59.17 | 59.40 | 59.14 | 59.28 | 59.49 | 59.81 | 59.41 |
Slovenia | 58.15 | 56.71 | 55.91 | 56.21 | 55.91 | 55.74 | 56.08 |
Turkey | 45.90 | 45.00 | 45.09 | 46.34 | 47.05 | 47.37 | 45.68 |
Ukraine | 52.24 | 51.07 | 51.15 | 51.04 | 50.96 | 51.36 | 51.71 |
USA | 57.70 | 58.12 | 58.46 | 58.85 | 59.24 | 59.65 | 59.92 |
Model 0 b/se | Model 1 b/se | Model 2 b/se | Model 3 b/se | Model 4 b/se | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Log GINI | 0.4618 (0.3204) | 1.1613 ** (0.3855) | 3.9879 ** (1.3154) | 1.3169 * (0.6552) | 2.5238 *** (0.7510) |
Log Employment Rate | 0.9941 * (0.3997) | −0.0854 (0.4651) | 2.6431 *** (0.6791) | 0.7649 (1.2303) | |
Lagged Clientelism t-1 | 0.2002 (0.1921) | 0.2445 (0.2391) | 0.6471 *** (0.1444) | 0.5483 *** (0.1577) | |
Lagged Gini | −3.0145 ** (1.0680) | −1.0800 (0.8603) | |||
Lagged Employment Rate | 2.7063 (1.4475) | ||||
Time Dummies | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N*T | 182 | 130 | 130 | 130 | 130 |
N (i) | 26 | 26 | 26 | 26 | 26 |
Hausman | 10.8215 | ||||
p-Value Hausman | 0.0045 | ||||
Log-Likelihood | 125.6670 | ||||
Wald | 14.2875 | 17.1189 | 19.3009 | 50.7586 | 63.7108 |
Sargan Test | 19.3009 | 26.6270 | 30.0460 | 38.7186 | |
p-Value Sargan | 0.1275 | 0.0900 | 0.0860 | 0.1732 | |
Chi2 | 12.9345 | 14.0158 | 16.6270 | 28.8861 | 28.9696 |
p-Value Chi2 | 0.0048 | 0.0059 | 0.0009 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Cendales, A.; Guerrero-Sierra, H.; Mora, J.J. The Price of Poverty: Inequality and the Strategic Use of Clientelism in Divided Democracies. Economies 2025, 13, 205. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13070205
Cendales A, Guerrero-Sierra H, Mora JJ. The Price of Poverty: Inequality and the Strategic Use of Clientelism in Divided Democracies. Economies. 2025; 13(7):205. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13070205
Chicago/Turabian StyleCendales, Andrés, Hugo Guerrero-Sierra, and Jhon James Mora. 2025. "The Price of Poverty: Inequality and the Strategic Use of Clientelism in Divided Democracies" Economies 13, no. 7: 205. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13070205
APA StyleCendales, A., Guerrero-Sierra, H., & Mora, J. J. (2025). The Price of Poverty: Inequality and the Strategic Use of Clientelism in Divided Democracies. Economies, 13(7), 205. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13070205