Next Article in Journal
Product Market Competition, Corporate Investment, and Firm Value: Scrutinizing the Role of Economic Policy Uncertainty
Next Article in Special Issue
Wage Inequality’s Decreasing Effect on Enterprise Operating Revenues
Previous Article in Journal
Human Capital, Networks and Segmentation in the Market for Academic Economists
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Impact of Recent Economic Crises on Income Inequality and the Risk of Poverty in Greece

1
Department of Public Administration, Panteion University of Social and Political Sciences, 17671 Athens, Greece
2
Research Institute for Tourism, 10564 Athens, Greece
3
Department of Sociology, University of the Aegean, 81100 Mytilene, Greece
4
Department of Economics, University of Athens, 10559 Athens, Greece
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2023, 11(6), 166; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060166
Submission received: 25 April 2023 / Revised: 26 May 2023 / Accepted: 5 June 2023 / Published: 13 June 2023

Abstract

:
We consider the impact of the two recent economic crises, one that resulted from the great recession of 2007–2009 and one following the COVID-19 pandemic, on income inequality and the risk of poverty in Greece. To this end, we also investigate the key macroeconomic variables affecting the Greek income distribution. We find that alternative measures of inequality and relative poverty have deteriorated during the years of crises, implying that the country’s response to economic shocks has been particularly harmful for its more disadvantaged citizens. Regarding the variables affecting the income distribution, we show that income inequality and the risk of poverty increase with growth, implying that the benefits of growth, and burdens of recession, are distributed unequally among members of the Greek society. Moreover, inequality appears to increase with unemployment and decrease with the share of wages and salaries in total income. This finding highlights the importance of labour market regulations and workers’ welfare for attaining equality. Finally, we provide evidence that, during pre-election periods, income inequality is reduced, meaning that the political budget cycles, which are characteristic of the Greek economy, generate gains in terms of equality, but these gains are short-lived and mainly benefit the middle bracket of the income distribution.

1. Introduction

Economic crises do not affect all members of a given society equally but embody redistributive mechanisms: those that have a limited capacity to respond are more vulnerable and, therefore, suffer greater losses. From this idea has sprung a long line of empirical works investigating the effects of economic crises on income distribution and the risk of poverty. Their conclusion, albeit not unanimous, is that income inequality, poverty, and the risk of social exclusion tend to increase during periods of crisis (Melidis and Tzagkarakis 2022; Bodea et al. 2021). This result mainly materializes through the negative impact on income distribution of the austerity measures undertaken to confront economic slowdowns (De Beer 2012).
Since the great recession fueled by the financial crisis of 2007–2009, Greece has become a synonym for economic crisis and the Greek economy has been in a recession for over half of the last fifteen years. This less-than-ideal situation has been the result of two major crises that took place in the country. The first one followed the great recession and took place between 2011 and 2016. It is known in the literature as the great economic slump. During those years, Greece faced the devastating consequences of its macroeconomic and structural imbalances: unprecedentedly high unemployment rates (in 2013 the unemployment rate amounted to 27.5% of the labour force) combined with generally negative economic growth rates (in 2011 the growth rate of the real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) was −10.1%). Throughout the entirety of the great economic slump, it was only in 2014 that the real GDP growth rate turned marginally positive (0.5%)1.
This crisis was followed by a three-year period (2017–2019) of significant de-escalation of unemployment (from 21.5% to 17.3%) and, at the same time, the GDP growth rate started to increase from an annual rate of 1.1% to 1.8%. Then, in 2020 and 2021, the Greek economy was hit by its second recent crisis, this time due to the COVID-19 pandemic. In 2020, economic growth was down by an astonishing 9.0%, while in 2021 the GDP growth rate was up to 8.3%, signaling a significant recovery of the economy boosted largely by the support measures undertaken both at a national and at a European level.
The main objective of this paper is to investigate the redistributive effects of these two almost consecutive crises of 2011–2016 and 2020–2021 and to measure their impact on the income distribution and the risk of poverty. To this end, we also investigate the main macroeconomic variables that affect the distribution of personal income and the risk of poverty in Greece.
When considering the issue of income distribution, what matters is personal income distribution, which refers to the way income is distributed among members of society regardless of its origin. The most widely used index is the “Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income”. Its value ranges from 0% (absolute equality) to 100% (absolute inequality). Another common criterion is the “income quintile share ratio S80/S20”, which measures the ratio of the disposable income of the richest 20% of a given population to that of the poorest 20%. Notice that the S80/S20 is affected by the extreme values of the income distribution, whereas the Gini coefficient is not affected by extreme values and, thus, arguably reflects inequalities in a more satisfactory manner.
When we consider the effect of crises on poverty, we investigate the effect of crises on relative poverty and, more specifically, on the “at-risk-of-poverty rate”2. This index, being defined as the share of people with an equivalized disposable income below the at-risk-of-poverty threshold, set at 60% of the national median equivalized disposable income after social transfers, is a measure of low incomes in comparison to that of other residents in the country. As a result, this indicator operates as another measure of income inequality.
The phenomena of income inequality and poverty in Greece have been the subject of extensive empirical analysis (See mainly Melidis and Tzagkarakis 2022; Kaplanoglou 2022; Kotsios 2022; Andriopoulou et al. 2018, 2019; Giannitsis and Zografakis 2018; Kaplanoglou and Rapanos 2018; Matsaganis and Leventi 2014; Mitrakos 2014; Koutsampelas and Tsakloglou 2013; Mitrakos and Tsakloglou 2012; Tsakloglou and Mitrakos 2006; Tsakloglou and Panopoulou 1998; Tsakloglou 1993, 1990). This paper is, to our knowledge, the first attempt to examine how the aforementioned issues have been affected by the recent economic crises. As such, it also adds to the extensive literature on crises and inequality, surveyed in Dabla-Norri et al. (2015), in a substantial and policy-relevant way and, we believe, our results could serve as guidelines for a more socially desirable response to future economic setbacks.
Our paper also contributes to the ongoing discussion around the key macroeconomic factors that could potentially influence income distribution and the risk of poverty3. More specifically, we investigate the effect of the unemployment rate, the real GDP growth rate, and the share of labour income (in its narrow sense, that is, wages and salaries) in the GDP. We go on to summarize the main findings on the relationship of these three variables with income inequality, as reported in a number of relevant empirical articles.
Firstly, the extent of unemployment and income inequality have been found to be positively correlated, meaning that higher unemployment rates tend to be associated with greater inequality (e.g., Petrakos et al. 2022). Secondly, there is an opaque link between income distribution and economic growth dependent on a number of factors, such as market conditions and the extent of the state’s redistributive role. The critical factor is the effectiveness of redistributive measures, mainly social transfers, used by the state (Vavoura and Vavouras 2022). In the case of the EU member states, income inequality has been found to be positively correlated with economic growth in the cases of the economically developed member states and negatively correlated in the cases of the developing ones (Jianu et al. 2021).
Finally, a third factor considered is the share of wages and salaries in total income. Intuition suggests that as the share of wages and salaries in total income increases, income distribution should improve. However, this relationship also depends on the form and the progressiveness of the tax system in place, as well as on the effectiveness of the social welfare system. Hence, the correlation between labour income shares, imperfectly measured by the share of wages and salaries (Krueger 1999) and income inequality, is not clear (Erauskin 2020). Greece is particularly interesting in terms of its labour income because it presents the lowest share of wages and salaries in the total GDP compared to all EU member states during the period 1995–2021, for which data are available.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 introduces the methodology, Section 3 presents the results, which are discussed in Section 4, and Section 5 concludes.

2. Methodology

In our analysis, we study the longitudinal evolution of personal income distribution and risk of poverty in the case of Greece during the period 1995–2021. We focus on 1995–2021 because it is for those years only that reliable data on income distribution and poverty exist. The data are derived from the Statistics on Income and Living Conditions of Households (SILC), which are based on the Eurostat methodology (EU-SILC). Before 1995 there are no official data available regarding the distribution of income in Greece, neither from the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT), nor from any other public body, with the exception of individual estimates of researchers on the subject.
A simple overview of the evolution of the Gini coefficient in Greece and the European Union (EU) during the years 1995–2021 is presented in Figure 1. We observe, first, that income inequality in Greece is consistently above the EU average throughout the 1995–2021 period and, second, that during the years of the two crises (2011–2016 and 2020–2021) the Greek income distribution shows signs of deterioration. The current paper aims to establish that the second observation holds: that crises have indeed increased income inequality and the risk of poverty in the case of Greece.
It is important to mention that the pattern presented in Figure 1 is anything but universal. Focusing only on the EU, in the aftermath of the global crisis of 2007–2009, we observe that between 2006 and 2009 the Gini coefficient of 12 member states increased, in 12 it decreased, and in 1 it remained unchanged, while for 2 there are no data available. Regarding the 2020–2021 COVID-19 pandemic, we observe that between 2019 and 2021 the income distribution, as measured by the value of the Gini coefficient, worsened in 9 EU member states, improved in 14, and in 3 it remained unchanged, while for 1 there are no data available. We argue that the effects of crises on income inequality vary with the policy mix that governments use to deal with them. In the case of the EU, the majority of the member states witnessed a betterment of their income distribution as a result of the two major recent crises4. To this rule, Greece, at first sight, appears to be an exception.
At this point, it is useful to explain why we have chosen to measure inequality via the Gini coefficient of disposable income, as opposed to the Gini coefficient of market income. In addition to data availability, since data for the Gini coefficient of market income is only available for the years 2006–20195, there is an additional methodological issue. By definition, disposable income is market income, that is, income from work and capital, after the deduction of direct taxes and payment of social security contributions. A comparison of market income and disposable income could be useful to evaluate the distributive role of the state. However, we argue that, when referring to income distribution and risk of poverty, what matters is the actual distribution of disposable income and not the income before the exercise of any redistributive role by the state. For this reason, the great bulk of the relevant empirical work relies on disposable income. Of course, the Gini coefficient of market income is always higher (depicting higher inequality) than the corresponding coefficient of disposable income, as the available data reveal. In the case of Greece for the period 2006–2019, for which data are available for market income, we can see this in Figure A4 of Appendix C.
To assess the robustness of our observations from Figure 1, we check our second measure of income inequality, which is the income quintile share ratio index S80/S20, and our measure of relative poverty, that is, the at-risk-of-poverty rate. A pattern similar to the pattern in Figure 1 is revealed: throughout the period under consideration, the values of the income quintile share ratio index S80/S20, presented in Figure 2, and the at-risk-of-poverty rate, shown in Figure 3, are systematically higher in Greece compared to the EU average. This implies that disparities between poor and rich incomes, as well as the percentages of the at-risk-of-poverty and social exclusion categories, have been consistently more severe in the Greek economy. More importantly, in the crises years under consideration (2011–2016 and 2020–2021), both indicators appear to deteriorate (see Figure 2 and Figure 3). We proceed to formally test whether this second pattern can be verified. This takes us to the formal statement of our research hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1.
During the years of the two recent crises, income inequality and poverty have increased in Greece.
To test this, we also investigate the most important macroeconomic variables that affect the intertemporal distribution of income in the country.
Our approach is an empirical one and it is based on the formulation and estimation of linear econometric models related to its subjects, which combine quantitative and dichotomous or dummy variables as independent variables. We construct three empirical models, each with one of the following three dependent variables:
(1) The Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income (GINI), as defined and measured by the Eurostat Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) and the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT).
(2) The income quintile share ratio index S80/S20 (QSR), as defined and measured by the Eurostat Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) and the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT).
(3) The at-risk-of-poverty rate (ROPR), as defined and measured by the Eurostat Statistics on Income and Living Condition (SILC) and the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT).
Based on the overview of the relevant theory and the purposes of our empirical analysis, we specify the following explanatory variables in the above three linear models. First, we use as explanatory variables the one-year lagged dependent variables to account for the fact that income inequality and poverty can have an autocorrelated AR(1) component and, hence, may be determined by past levels6.
(4) The one-year lagged Gini coefficient (GINI-1) since the value of the current Gini coefficient can be influenced by its value in the previous year.
(5) The S80/S20 index with one year lag (QSR-1) since the value of the current S80/S20 coefficient may be affected by its value in the previous year.
(6) The at-risk-of-poverty rate with one year lag (ROPR-1) since the value of the current ROPR also has the potential to be shaped by its past value.
The second group of explanatory variables is related to the share of labour income, or rather dependent labour income, in total income. We include:
(7) The share of wages and salaries in GDP (WGDP), as measured by ELSTAT and the Eurostat methodology. This variable is particularly interesting in the case of Greece because the country is characterised by the lowest share of wages and salaries in the total GDP compared to all EU member states, during the period 1995–2021 for which data are available. Only three EU member states, and only for a short, specific time period, presented a lower share of wages and salaries in the GDP. Namely, Bulgaria during the period 1995–1997, Romania during the period 2009–2012, and Ireland during the period 2015–20217.
Our third group of explanatory variables is chosen so as to better capture the macroeconomic impact of an economic crisis. After the global financial crisis of 2007–2009, which developed into what is widely known as the great recession of 2007–2009, Greece entered a prolonged period of economic and fiscal crisis. Exit from this crisis became possible only in 2017. During that period, extensive literature (see, for example, Petrakos et al. 2022) has documented the following. Between 2008 and 2013 the unemployment rate jumped from 7.8% to an unprecedented 27.5% and, from there, it started to decrease gradually. Furthermore, during the years between 2008 and 2016, the country’s total real GDP shrunk from €247.8 billion to €182 billion, a decrease corresponding to more than a quarter of its real value (26.6%). The most critical years of the 2008–2016 period were the years 2011–2016, which were characterised by unemployment rates higher than 20% and were, at the same time, associated with negative economic growth rates. Hence, we include in our models:
(8) The total real GDP in chainlinked volumes (2010) in millions of euros (RGDP) as measured by ELSTAT and the Eurostat methodology.
(9) The overall (total) annual unemployment rate (UNR) as measured by ELSTAT and the Eurostat methodology.
To address our research hypothesis on the impact of economic crises we are forced to include:
(10) A dummy variable for economic crises (GESCOV), which takes the value 1 during the years of crises in Greece (2011–2016 and 2020–2021) and 0 otherwise.
Finally, our last explanatory variable represents the impact of political factors. In particular, it captures the opportunistic behavior of governments during pre-election periods in order to win the upcoming general elections. This is the well-known phenomenon of “political electoral cycles” or “political budget cycles”. The central hypothesis of this phenomenon is that incumbent politicians, faced with a “myopic” electorate with a decaying memory of past events (Bonfiglioli and Gancia 2013) or taking advantage of informational asymmetries that exist between them and rational constituents (Rogoff and Sibert 1988), choose to maximize their voting function instead of their social welfare function (Nordhaus 1975). Consequently, governments may pursue opportunistic expansionary fiscal policies before elections to appear competent and offer voters an illusion of economic prosperity (Petrakos et al. 2021b). This behavior may affect the distribution of income in the short run due to the economic benefits provided to the electorate to soften their impressions about the current governance of the country. The limited empirical research that exists on this issue concludes that income inequality actually improves during pre-election periods (Sever and Yucel 2021). To allow for the well-documented presence of political budget cycles (e.g., Petrakos et al. 2021b) in the Greek economy, we include:
(11) A dummy variable for elections (ELE), which takes the value 1 during the years of parliamentary elections in Greece during the period 1995–2021 and 0 otherwise.
Having specified our dependent and explanatory variables, we proceed to the specification of our empirical models. Let y m i denote, for m = 1, 2, 3, respectively, the annual values of indices GINI, QSR, and ROPR, considered as dependent variables in the ith year, i = 1, 2, …, 27. Let x j i , j = 1, 2, …, 6, denote the values of Xj corresponding to the 6 quantitative explanatory variables GINI-1, QSR-1, ROPR-1, WGDP, RGDP, and UNR, respectively. Let, in addition, z k i , k = 1, 2 denote, respectively, the values of the two dummy variables GESCOV and ELE.
We assume that the mean value of the dependent variable of each sample can be expressed as a linear combination of the quantitative variables and the dummy variables in the following way:
E y m i = β 0 + j = 1 6 β j x j i + k = 1 2 γ k z k i
We derive the following three models, which were tested against the usual assumptions of the OLS models:
  • Model 1 (m = 1): dependent variable GINI.
  • Model 2 (m = 2): dependent variable QSR.
  • Model 3 (m = 3): dependent variable ROPR.
In order to access and compare the predictive accuracy of the three models, we use the Mean Absolute Percentage Error (MAPE) for m = 1, 2, 3:
M A P E ( m ) = 1 n i = 1 n | y m i y ^ m i | | y m i | × 100 %

3. Results

This section contains the results of our analysis. We present our results for Model 1, with GINI as the dependent variable, Model 2, with QSR as the dependent variable, and Model 3, with ROPR as the dependent variable.

3.1. Model 1 (m = 1): Dependent Variable GINI

In Model 1, the statistically significant independent variables are GINI-1, WGDP, RGDP, and the dummies GESCOV and ELE. The coefficient estimates and the significance tests are presented in Table 1 and the analysis of variance in Table A1 of Appendix A. Model 1 shows a coefficient of determination R2 = 71.12 (R2adj = 63.9). The Model 1 residuals are symmetrically distributed around zero with a standard deviation of 0.6281 and the largest one, corresponding to the eighth observation, is valued at 1.548. Nevertheless, there are not studentized residuals with Bonferroni p < 0.05 to be considered as outliers.
From the Durbin–Watson test, the D-W Statistic is 2.27 with p-value at 0.966, larger than any significance level, concluding no autocorrelation at lag 1 in the model. Applying the studentized Breusch–Pagan test, we end up with BP statistics at 3.6664 on 5 df with p-value = 0.5984 and, hence, we cannot reject homoscedasticity of the model residuals. Finally, the Shapiro–Wilk test for normality with W statistic at 0.96019 and p-value = 0.3953 fails to reject the normality of the residuals. The above-mentioned test of the assumptions and relative conclusions is also illustrated in the diagnostics plots in Figure A1 of Appendix B. Searching for multicollinearity, the values of the VIF in Table 1, being less than three, indicate that there is no multicollinearity effect among the predictors.
In Model 1, the coefficient corresponding to WGDP has a negative sign, which indicates that increases in WGDP, i.e., increases in the share of wages and salaries in GDP, are associated with decreases in the value of the GINI, implying a decrease in income inequality. In contrast, the GESCOV dummy variable comes in with a positive sign, which suggests that crises years are associated with increases in income inequality. At the same time, the dummy variable ELE has a negative coefficient, which suggests that during parliamentary election years, income inequality is reduced in the short term. This result is related to the phenomenon of political budget cycles. Furthermore, since RGDP enters with a positive sign, Model 1 confirms the hypothesis that income inequality is positively related to economic growth in the cases of developed countries. Finally, in the context of the present model, the unemployment rate (UNR) is not a statistically significant explanatory variable.

3.2. Model 2 (m = 2): Dependent Variable QSR

In Model 2, the statistically significant independent variables are QSR-1, WGDP, RGDP, and the dummy variable GESCOV. The coefficient estimates and significance tests of the model are presented in Table 2 and the analysis of variance in Table A2 of Appendix A. Model 2 shows a coefficient of determination R2 = 75.79 (R2adj = 71.17). The Model 2 residuals are positively skewed, with a standard deviation of 0.21 and the largest one, corresponding to the eighth observation, is valued at 2.17. Nevertheless, there are not studentized residuals with Bonferroni p < 0.05 to be considered as outliers.
From the Durbin–Watson test, the D-W Statistic is 2.11 with p-value at 0.572, larger than any significance level, concluding no autocorrelation at lag 1 in the model. Applying the studentized Breusch–Pagan test, we end up with BP statistics at 1.005 on 4 df with p-value = 0.909. Thus, we cannot reject the homoscedasticity of the model residuals. Finally, the Shapiro–Wilk test for normality, with W statistic at 0.8617 and p-value = 0.0024, rejects the normality of the residuals. The above-mentioned test of the assumptions and relative conclusions is also illustrated in the diagnostics plots in Figure A2 of Appendix B. Searching for multicollinearity, the values of the VIF in Table 2, being less than two, indicate that there is no multicollinearity effect among the predictors.
In Model 2, as in Model 1, the variable WGDP has a negative coefficient, which implies that increases in the share of wages and salaries in GDP are associated with decreases in income inequality, as measured by QSR. Furthermore, as in Model 1, the GESCOV dummy variable has a positive sign, which suggests that crises years are associated with increases in income inequality. As in Model 1, RGDP has a positive sign, meaning that income inequality is positively related to economic growth. In Model 2, the dummy variable ELE is not statistically significant, which suggests that the economic policy followed during the pre-election periods in the country, while limiting the overall inequality of income distribution as measured by the Gini coefficient, does not seem to affect the quintile share ratio index S80/S20 in a statistically significant way. That is, the ratio of the disposable income of the richest 20% of the population to that of the poorest 20% is not significantly affected. As in Model 1, the unemployment rate (UNR) is not a statistically significant explanatory variable.

3.3. Model 3 (m = 3): Dependent Variable ROPR

In Model 3, the statistically significant independent variables are WGDP, RGDP, UNR, and the dummy variable GESCOV. The coefficient estimates and significance tests of the model are presented in Table 3 and the analysis of variance in Table A3 of Appendix A. Model 3 shows a coefficient of determination R2 = 79.46 (R2adj = 75.55). Model 3 residuals are symmetrically distributed around zero with a standard deviation of 0.65 and the largest one, corresponding to the eighth observation, is valued at 3.13. Nevertheless, there are not studentized residuals with Bonferroni p < 0.05 to be considered as outliers.
From the Durbin–Watson test, the D-W Statistic is 1.44 with p-value at 0.02, concluding positive autocorrelation at lag 1 estimated at 0.15. Applying the studentized Breusch–Pagan test, we end up with BP statistics at 2.2322 on 4 df with p-value = 0.6931, meaning that we cannot reject the homoscedasticity of the model residuals. Finally, the Shapiro–Wilk test for normality, with W statistic at 0.949 and p-value = 0.22, fails to reject the normality of the residuals. The above-mentioned test of the assumptions and relative conclusions is also illustrated in the diagnostics plots in Figure A3 of Appendix B. Searching for multicollinearity, the values of the VIF in Table 3, being less than three, indicate that there is no multicollinearity effect among the predictors.
In order to cope with the autocorrelation detected with the D-W test, we introduce ROPR lag 1 (ROPR-1) and RORP lag 2 (ROPR-2) variables as predictors but get no significant improvement, since the lag variables are not significant, and autocorrelation remains at the same level.
In Model 3, as in Models 1 and 2, the variable WGDP has a negative coefficient, which implies that increases in the share of wages and salaries in GDP are associated with decreases in the at-risk-of-poverty rates. Crucially, as in Models 1 and 2, the GESCOV dummy variable has a positive coefficient, which suggests that crises years are associated with increases in the risk of poverty. As in Models 1 and 2, RGDP comes in with a positive sign, which confirms the hypothesis that the risk of poverty is positively related to economic growth in the cases of developed countries. Moreover, in Model 3 the unemployment rate (UNR) is a statistically significant explanatory variable, and its coefficient has a positive sign, which implies that increases in unemployment are associated with increases in the risk of poverty. Reducing unemployment can, therefore, be regarded as a significant means for reducing the at-risk-of-poverty rate. In Model 3, the dummy variable ELE is not statistically significant, which suggests that the economic policy followed during the pre-election periods in the country, while limiting the overall inequality of income distribution, does not seem to affect the risk of poverty in a statistically significant way.

3.4. Predictive Accuracy

In order to assess and compare the predictive accuracy of the three models, we use the Mean Absolute Percentage Error (MAPE(m)) with m = 1, 2, 3 for Models 1, 2, and 3, respectively. The results are: M A P E 1 = 1.72 ,   M A P E 2 = 2.86 ,   M A P E 3 = 2.83 . Therefore, we conclude that Model 1 has better predictive accuracy when compared to the other two models.

3.5. Correlation between Inequality and Risk of Poverty

There is a significant positive correlation among all three dependent variables in the proposed regression models of the previous sections. The correlations were measured with the Pearson coefficient and are illustrated in Figure 4.
By further investigating the correlation between income inequality as it is measured by the Gini coefficient and the risk of poverty in the case of Greece, we can conclude that:
  • Small values of the Gini coefficient GINI (low income inequality) are related to small values of the at-risk-of-poverty rate ROPR (low risk of poverty rate).
  • As illustrated in Figure 5, the lower values of income inequality (GINI) and risk of poverty (ROPR) are tied together in a close, linear relationship. However, in the higher value area for both variables, the relationship is somehow loose.
We can conclude that, in order to control the risk of poverty (ROPR), income inequality (GINI) has to be reduced.

4. Discussion

The aim of this paper is twofold. Firstly, we uncover the most important determinants of income inequality in Greece for the years 1995–2021. Secondly, we determine whether the economic crises that affected the Greek economy during 2011–2016, as a result of the global financial crisis, and during 2020–2021, as a result of the COVID-19 pandemic, improved or deteriorated income inequality and relative poverty in the country. Table 4 summarizes the results from our three empirical models presented in the previous section.
The first take-home point from our empirical analysis is that income inequality is autocorrelated. Regardless of the measure we use, income inequality depends heavily on past values like GINI-1 or QSR-1, and it appears that its adjustment process is slow: the one-year lagged inequality measure has a significant positive effect on the current measure, meaning that a history of inequality creates further inequality. This result is supported by a number of different studies for different times and places. In fact, the persistence of high and, in many countries, rising income inequality over recent decades has become a growing concern at a global level (OECD 2008; Dabla-Norris et al. 2015).
The second factor of interest is the positive correlation between growth (RGDP) and inequality and poverty measures. This idea is not new in the literature, and it is actually common in the case of developed economies (Jianu et al. 2021). For Greece in particular, the relationship between income distribution and economic growth has been found to depend heavily on the effectiveness of the redistributive measures, mainly social transfers, used by the state (Vavoura and Vavouras 2022). We should not, however, dismiss the fact that the redistributive role of social transfers in Greece is limited to pensions, since all other forms of social transfers have been found to exert insignificant effects on income distribution (Papatheodorou and Petmesidou 2006). Consequently, the positive coefficient of the RGDP variable can be viewed as evidence of the limited redistributive role that Greek governments have played overtime, resulting in an unequal sharing of the benefits of economic growth (or an unequal sharing of the burdens of economic recession) among the members of Greek society.
This last point, regarding the role of the state, takes us to our next determinant of income inequality that appears to be instrumental in the case of Greece. We refer to the effect of the election (ELE) dummy, which is negatively correlated with inequality when we measure it via the Gini coefficient, but its effect becomes insignificant when we measure it via the quintile share ratio index S80/S20 or the at-risk-of-poverty rate. This result can be interpreted as follows. We know that the Greek economy is characterised by severe political budget cycles and that these cycles materialize mainly through an increase in government expenditure and, more specifically, via pre-election transfer payments (Petrakos et al. 2021a). These transfers decrease average income inequality, at least in the short term, but do not go as far as to affect extreme inequality (i.e., the share of the top and bottom 20%) and poverty. In other words, the pre-election transfers are mainly targeted towards the “average” voter in terms of personal income, possibly because it is precisely this type of citizen whose voting intentions are more volatile and, hence, more susceptible to opportunistic behavior on the side of the incumbent government. This idea, that governments distribute funding so as to influence the vote of swing voters, is, in fact, one that has been occasionally observed in European countries, for example, by Dahlberg and Johansson (2002) in Sweden and by Case (2001) in Albania.
Another important aspect of income inequality and poverty is their close ties to the labour market conditions. To begin with, a vast collection of literature documents the influence of unemployment on inequality and poverty (e.g., Mocan 1999; Cysne 2009; Zandi et al. 2022). In our study, unemployment has a significant positive correlation with the risk of poverty, although we do not find evidence that it significantly affects either of our other inequality measures. In any case, this result could help guide policy makers to increase their focus on unemployment when battling poverty and inequality. For Greece in particular, where the unemployment rate has not fallen below 15% during the period 2011–2021 according to Eurostat, we argue that any regulations aimed at the improvement of income distribution are destined to fail unless they tackle the catastrophic economic and social consequences of prolonged unemployment.
However, the mechanism through which the labour market affects income inequality and poverty is not limited to unemployment. There is a second core factor: the labour income share. In our model, we follow the standard approach of measuring the labour income share via the share of wages and salaries in GDP (WGDP)8. This measure is known to have problems (Krueger 1999), mainly because it mismeasures the labour share of self-employment which, in Greece, is the highest among EU members9. Nonetheless, its strong negative correlation with all three measures of relative inequality and poverty (see Table 4), emphasizes the importance of workers’ welfare and labour income protection as forces towards income equalization.
Related to the topic of income inequality, we should point out that there is a rapidly growing literature, following the works by Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014), Piketty and Zucman (2014), and Dao et al. (2017), on labour income share, documenting its worldwide decline. However, EU countries on aggregate have been found to follow no such trend. Cette et al. (2020) and Gutiérrez and Piton (2020) document the stability of the labour income share in Europe, with certain countries, Greece being one of them, witnessing an increase10. We argue that this trend has mitigated the effects of economic crises, which we are about to discuss, on Greek income distribution.
Finally, our most interesting result and our most notable contribution to the literature is summed up by the positive correlation between the crises (GESCOV) dummy and all three of our measures of inequality (GINI, QSR) and poverty (ROPR). This finding verifies our research hypothesis: the two recent economic crises were associated with a sharp increase in income inequality and relative poverty in Greece. The austerity measures adopted by EU institutions and the Greek government as a reaction to the country’s debt crisis, fueled by the global financial crisis, as well as the policies that followed in response to the COVID-19 pandemic, operated as redistributive mechanisms, essentially “taking from the poor and giving to the rich”. The redistributive role of the crises is stronger in the case of the lowest of incomes, given that the effect of the crises dummy is found to be higher in the at-risk-of-poverty rate. In other words, the crises in Greece have hit the economically weakest the hardest. Our results are in line with Nolan et al. (2019) who investigated the impact of the great recession of 2007–2009 and reported that Greece constitutes “the most dramatic case” of crisis-induced increased inequality.
To conclude, our study serves as a reminder that the central pilar of the Greek government’s economic and social policy, especially during periods of crisis, should be to dampen their redistributive effects by increasing the role of the benefit and tax system in cushioning a declining aggregate income and in protecting households against income losses. However, to date, the policy mix adopted in order to deal with economic slowdowns does not appear to have contributed effectively to this direction.
Lastly, it should not go without mentioning that policy recommendations involving the Greek benefit and tax system can hardly be viewed as complete without mentioning the need to improve its effectiveness, to control hidden economy activity, and to restrict corruption (Manolas et al. 2013). Unless tax evasion, mainly among the incomes from entrepreneurial activities, is reduced, taxes and social security contributions will have but a weak impact on the reduction of inequality (Papatheodorou 1998).

5. Conclusions

The main objective of our analysis was to investigate whether the distribution of income and the risk of poverty in Greece in the post-1995 period were affected by the economic crises of the 2010s onward. We found that both income inequality and poverty worsened as a result of the crises and that this result is robust to different measures of inequality and poverty, namely the Gini coefficient, the quintile share ratio index S80/S20, and the at-risk-of poverty rate. All of these measures exhibit a significantly positive correlation with the economic crises’ dichotomous variable, implying that the country’s response to economic shocks was particularly harmful for the economically disadvantaged members of the Greek society. We argue that this matter of extreme importance has received limited attention both from Greek economists and in public debate, and we hope that our study could help to shed light on the issue.
A second purpose of our work was to examine the most important macroeconomic variables affecting the distribution of income in Greece. Our findings can be summed up as follows. Firstly, increases in the share of wages and salaries in the GDP are associated with reductions in income inequality and the risk of poverty. Secondly, reductions of unemployment rates are associated with reductions of the risk of poverty. These two results suggest that labour market conditions are crucial for income inequality and that shielding workers’ welfare is bound to increase equality, at least in the case of Greece. Thirdly, income inequality is positively related to economic growth. This result suggests that the benefits of growth and the burdens of recession are not distributed equally among the members of the Greek society. Finally, during pre-election periods, income inequality, as measured by the Gini coefficient, is reduced but extreme inequality, as measured by the quintile share ratio index S80/S20 and the at-risk-of poverty rate, is unaffected. This result implies that the political budget cycles that are characteristic of the Greek economy create gains in terms of equality, but these gains are short-lived and mainly benefit the middle bracket of the income distribution.
We conclude that the recent economic crises did not affect the Greek society in a balanced way, but rather had a strongly redistributive character. This does not, however, appear to have been the case for the majority of the rest of the EU member states. Consequently, we argue that there is a lesson to be learned for Greek policy makers who, in the future, should try to dampen these redistributive effects.
Future research, should such data become available, could consider how the effects of crises have varied for different regions of Greece and how they have depended on specific geographical and economic characteristics, possibly also taking into consideration tourism seasonality, as in Tsiotas et al. (2020), in order to propose useful regional policies.
Moreover, following works like Zeqiraj et al. (2022), Khan et al. (2014), and Kaasa (2003), principal component analysis could be applied to construct indicators of health and education, population and environmental conditions, sectoral growth and balance of payment factors, private investment, and public and social expenditures. Researching the link between such indicators and the income distribution could provide a spherical view of the evolution of income inequality in Greece and serve as the basis for the design of appropriate poverty combating policies.
Finally, from a cross-country study similar to Petrakos et al. (2023) of the four EU member states that were hit hardest by the global crisis of 2007–2009, namely Portugal, Italy, Greece, and Spain, it could be possible to draw interesting inferences regarding the impact of different austerity measures on the income distribution and to propose fewer equality-distorting alternatives for the future.

Author Contributions

Conceptualisation, I.V. and K.R.; methodology, G.P.; validation, G.P. and K.R.; formal analysis, G.P.; data curation, I.V.; writing—original draft preparation, C.V.; writing—review and editing, C.V. and I.V. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available datasets were analysed in this study. Data have been provided by Eurostat (ILC_DI12), EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) and the Hellenic Statistical Authority (ELSTAT).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

This appendix contains the ANOVA tables for the regression models.
Table A1. Analysis of variance of Model 1: dependent variable GINI.
Table A1. Analysis of variance of Model 1: dependent variable GINI.
SourceDFAdj. SSAdj. MSF-Valuep-Value
Regression519.4363.88719.850.000
GINI-113.3663.36588.530.008
WGDP13.4893.48898.840.008
RGDP11.8811.88104.770.041
GESCOV = 114.1744.174110.580.004
ELE = 112.0142.01425.110.035
Error207.8910.3945
Total2527.327
Table A2. Analysis of variance of Model 2: dependent variable QSR.
Table A2. Analysis of variance of Model 2: dependent variable QSR.
SourceDFAdj. SSAdj. MSF-Valuep-Value
Regression42.95280.7382016.430.000
QSR-110.91740.9174320.420.000
WGDP10.54540.5454412.140.002
RGDP10.25170.251745.600.028
GESCOV = 111.11441.1143924.810.000
Error210.94340.04492
Total253.8962
Table A3. Analysis of variance of Model 3: dependent variable ROPR.
Table A3. Analysis of variance of Model 3: dependent variable ROPR.
SourceDFAdj. SSAdj. MSF-Valuep-Value
Regression434.5558.638720.310.000
WGDP127.95527.954765.730.000
RGDP17.0387.037916.550.001
UNR15.4915.491312.910.002
GESCOV = 116.4006.399515.050.001
Error218.9320.4253
Total2543.487

Appendix B

This appendix contains the diagnostics plots for the regression models.
Figure A1. Diagnostic plots of Model 1: dependent variable GINI.
Figure A1. Diagnostic plots of Model 1: dependent variable GINI.
Economies 11 00166 g0a1aEconomies 11 00166 g0a1bEconomies 11 00166 g0a1c
Figure A2. Diagnostic plots of Model 2: dependent variable QSR.
Figure A2. Diagnostic plots of Model 2: dependent variable QSR.
Economies 11 00166 g0a2aEconomies 11 00166 g0a2bEconomies 11 00166 g0a2c
Figure A3. Diagnostic plots of Model 3: dependent variable ROPR.
Figure A3. Diagnostic plots of Model 3: dependent variable ROPR.
Economies 11 00166 g0a3aEconomies 11 00166 g0a3bEconomies 11 00166 g0a3c

Appendix C

This appendix contains the evolution of the Gini coefficient for market income and disposable income in Greece, for the years where data for both indices are available.
Figure A4. The evolution of the Gini coefficient for market income and disposable income in Greece during the period 2006–2019. Data sources: Gini coefficient for market income: OECD; Gini coefficient for disposable income: Eurostat; Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income: EU-SILC survey (ilc-di12).
Figure A4. The evolution of the Gini coefficient for market income and disposable income in Greece during the period 2006–2019. Data sources: Gini coefficient for market income: OECD; Gini coefficient for disposable income: Eurostat; Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income: EU-SILC survey (ilc-di12).
Economies 11 00166 g0a4

Notes

1
All data refer to Eurostat estimates.
2
See Eurostat (ILC_LI02), At-risk-of-poverty rate—EU-SILC and ECHP surveys. Online data code: TESPM010.
3
Microeconomic determinants of poverty and income inequality have also been found to be of major importance, particulartly for the design of appropriate policies (see for example Naschold (2009)). However, in the case of Greece no such data are available for the years under consideration.
4
Eurostat (ILC_DI12), EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income—EU-SILC survey. Online data code: TESSI190.
5
Eurostat and ELSTAT provide estimates of the Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income before social transfers (pensions included in social transfers) since 2003 (ilc-di12b) as well as estimates of the Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income before social transfers (pensions excluded from social transfers) since 2003 (ilc-di12c). They do not provide estimates of the Gini coefficient based on market income. Only OECD, provides estimates of the Gini coefficient based on market income (before taxes and transfers) but only for the period 2006–2019.
6
We have also tested lagged variables of higher order and found no significant effect. Additionally, we run time series analysis for the y variables and also tried the Detrend model for which we have experienced violation of the basic assumptions. Given that our aim was to identify and quantify the relation of income inequality with certain predictors, we proceed and present the selected OLS models (with lag1 variable where appropriate).
7
Eurostat, GDP and main components (output, expenditure and income). Online data code: NAMA_10_GDP.
8
This is the narrow concept of labour income. The broad one is “compensation of employees” and it also includes employers’ social contributions.
9
OECD (2023), Self-employment rate (indicator). doi: 10.1787/fb58715e-en.
10
Eurostat, GDP and main components (output, expenditure and income), nama_10_gdp.

References

  1. Andriopoulou, Eirini, Alexandros Karakitsios, and Panos Tsakloglou. 2018. Inequality and Poverty in Greece: Changes in Times of Crisis. Cham: Springer International Publishing. [Google Scholar]
  2. Andriopoulou, Eirini, Eleni Kanavitsa, and Panos Tsakloglou. 2019. Decomposing poverty in hard times: Greece 2007–2016. Revue d’ Économie du Développement 27: 125–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bodea, Cristina, Christian Houle, and Hyunwoo Kim. 2021. Do financial crises increase income inequality? World Development 147: 105635. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bonfiglioli, Alessandra, and Gino Gancia. 2013. Uncertainty, electoral incentives and political myopia. The Economic Journal 123: 373–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Case, Anne. 2001. Election goals and income redistribution: Recent evidence from Albania. European Economic Review 45: 405–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Cette, Gilbert, Lorraine Koehl, and Thomas Philippon. 2020. Labor share. Economics Letters 188: 108979. [Google Scholar]
  7. Cysne, Rubens Penha. 2009. On the positive correlation between income inequality and unemployment. Review of Economics and Statistics 91: 218–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Dabla-Norris, Era, Kalpana Kochhar, Nujin Suphaphiphat, Frantisek Ricka, and Evridiki Tsounta. 2015. Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality: A Global Perspective. Bretton Woods: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
  9. Dahlberg, Matz, and Eva Johansson. 2002. On the vote-purchasing behavior of incumbent governments. American Political Science Review 96: 27–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Dao, Mai Chi, Mitali Das, Zsoka Koczan, and Weicheng Lian. 2017. Why Is Labor Receiving a Smaller Share of Global Income? Theory and Empirical Evidence. Bretton Woods: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
  11. De Beer, Paul. 2012. Earnings and income inequality in the EU during the crisis. International Labour Review 151: 313–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Erauskin, Iñaki. 2020. The labour share and income inequality: Some empirical evidence from the period 1990–2015. Applied Economic Analysis 28: 173–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Giannitsis, Tassos, and Stavros Zografakis. 2018. Crisis Management in Greece. No. 50-2018. Bruxelles: IMK at the Hans-Böckler-Stiftung Foundation, Macroeconomic Policy Institute. [Google Scholar]
  14. Gutiérrez, Germán, and Sophie Piton. 2020. Revisiting the global decline of the (non-housing) labor share. American Economic Review: Insights 2: 321–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Jianu, Ionut, Marin Dinu, Dragos Huru, and Alexandru Bodislav. 2021. Examining the relationship between income inequality and growth from the perspective of EU member States’ stage of development. Sustainability 13: 5204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Kaasa, Anneli. 2003. Factors Influencing Income Inequality in Transition Economies. University of Tartu Economics and Business Administration Working Paper Series, 18; Tartu: Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, University of Tartu. [Google Scholar]
  17. Kaplanoglou, Georgia. 2022. Consumption inequality and poverty in Greece: Evidence and lessons from a decade-long crisis. Economic Analysis and Policy 75: 244–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Kaplanoglou, Georgia, and Vassilis T. Rapanos. 2018. Evolutions in consumption inequality and poverty in Greece: The impact of the crisis and austerity policies. Review of Income and Wealth 64: 105–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Karabarbounis, Loukas, and Brent Neiman. 2014. The global decline of the labor share. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129: 61–103. [Google Scholar]
  20. Khan, Muhammad Azhar, Muhammad Zahir Khan, Khalid Zaman, and Ayisha Khan. 2014. Poverty–growth–inequality triangle by principal component analysis: With an empirical illustration using Pakistan’s data. International Journal of Rural Management 10: 69–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Kotsios, Panagiotis. 2022. Income inequality measurement through tax data: The case of Greece. Bulletin of Applied Economics 9: 175–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Koutsampelas, Christos, and Panos Tsakloglou. 2013. The distribution of full income in Greece. International Journal of Social Economics 40: 311–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Krueger, Alan B. 1999. Measuring labour’s share. American Economic Review 89: 45–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Manolas, George, George Sfakianakis, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2013. Tackling the debt crisis in Greece: The role of the underground economy. Social Cohesion and Development 8: 25–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Matsaganis, Manos, and Chrysa Leventi. 2014. Poverty and inequality during the Great Recession in Greece. Political Studies Review 12: 209–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Melidis, Michail, and Stylianos I. Tzagkarakis. 2022. The evolution of social vulnerability in Greece during the economic crisis (2008–2017). European Societies 24: 229–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Mitrakos, Theodore. 2014. Inequality, Poverty and Social Welfare in Greece: Distributional Effects and Austerity. Working Papers, No. 174. Athens: Bank of Greece. [Google Scholar]
  28. Mitrakos, Theodore, and Panos Tsakloglou. 2012. Inequality and poverty in Greece: Myths, realities and crisis. In Reforming Greece: Sisyphean Task or Herculean Challenge? Edited by Othon Anastasakis and Dorian Singh. SEESOX Book Series on Current Affairs; Oxford: St Antony’s College, pp. 90–99. [Google Scholar]
  29. Mocan, H. Naci. 1999. Structural unemployment, cyclical unemployment, and income inequality. Review of Economics and Statistics 81: 122–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Naschold, Felix. 2009. Microeconomic determinants of income inequality in rural Pakistan. The Journal of Development Studies 45: 746–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Nolan, Brian, Matteo G. Richiardi, and Luis Valenzuela. 2019. The drivers of income inequality in rich countries. Journal of Economic Surveys 33: 1285–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Nordhaus, William D. 1975. The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies 42: 169–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2008. Growing Unequal? Income Distribution and Poverty in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar]
  34. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2023. Self-Employment Rate (Indicator). Available online: https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/employment/self-employment-rate/indicator/english_fb58715e-en (accessed on 6 June 2023).
  35. Papatheodorou, Christos. 1998. Inequality in Greece: An Analysis by Income Source. LSE STICERD Research Paper 39. London: London School of Economics and Political Science. [Google Scholar]
  36. Papatheodorou, Christos, and Maria Petmesidou. 2006. Poverty profiles and trends. How do southern European countries compare with each other? In Poverty and Social Deprivation in the Mediterranean: Trends, Policies & Welfare Prospects in the New Millennium. Edited by Maria Petmesidou and Christos Papatheodorou. London: Zed Books. [Google Scholar]
  37. Petrakos, George, Konstantinos Rontos, Chara Vavoura, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2021a. The mechanism of political budget cycles in Greece. 2021. In Advances in Longitudinal Data Methods in Applied Economic Research: 2020 International Conference on Applied Economics (ICOAE). Cham: Springer International Publishing. [Google Scholar]
  38. Petrakos, George, Konstantinos Rontos, Chara Vavoura, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2022. Quantifying the Effects of recent Economic and Fiscal Crises on Income Inequality in Greece. Paper presented at 2022 International Conference on Applied Economics (ICOAE), Madrid, Spain, July 7–9. [Google Scholar]
  39. Petrakos, George, Konstantinos Rontos, Chara Vavoura, Luca Salvati, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2021b. Political budget cycles and the effects of the excessive deficit procedure: The case of Greece. Regional Statistics 11: 32–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Petrakos, George, Konstantinos Rontos, Chara Vavoura, Luca Salvati, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2023. Income inequality in the over-indebted Eurozone countries and the role of the Excessive Deficit Procedure. Open Economies Review, forthcoming. [Google Scholar]
  41. Piketty, Thomas, and Gabriel Zucman. 2014. Capital is back: Wealth-income ratios in rich countries 1700–2010. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129: 1255–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Rogoff, Kenneth, and Anne Sibert. 1988. Elections and macro-economic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies 55: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Sever, Can, and Emekcan Yucel. 2021. Electoral Cycles in Inequality. Working Papers 2021/01. Istanbul: Bogazici University, Department of Economics. [Google Scholar]
  44. Tsakloglou, Panos. 1990. Aspects of poverty in Greece. Review of Income and Wealth 36: 381–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Tsakloglou, Panos. 1993. Aspects of inequality in Greece: Measurement, decomposition and inter-temporal change. Journal of Development Economics 40: 53–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Tsakloglou, Panos, and Giota Panopoulou. 1998. Who are the poor in Greece? Analysing poverty under alternative concepts of resources and equivalence scales. Journal of European Social Policy 8: 213–36. [Google Scholar]
  47. Tsakloglou, Panos, and Theodore Mitrakos. 2006. Inequality and poverty in Greece in the last quarter of the twentieth century. In Social Policy in Greece. Edited by Maria Petmesidou and Elias Mossialos. Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 126–43. [Google Scholar]
  48. Tsiotas, Dimitrios, Thomas Krabokoukis, and Serafeim Polyzos. 2020. Detecting interregional patterns in tourism seasonality of Greece: A principal components analysis approach. Regional Science Inquiry 12: 91–112. [Google Scholar]
  49. Vavoura, Chara, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2022. Income inequality and poverty in Greece during the recent economic, fiscal and COVID-19 crises. Social Cohesion and Development 17: 5–21. [Google Scholar]
  50. Zandi, GholamReza, Raja Rehan, Qazi Muhammad Adnan Hye, Sadaf Mubeen, and Shujaat Abbas. 2022. Do Corruption, Inflation and Unemployment Influence the Income Inequality of Developing Asian Countries? International Journal of Applied Economics, Finance and Accounting 14: 118–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Zeqiraj, Veton, Kazi Sohag, and Shawkat Hammoudeh. 2022. Financial inclusion in developing countries: Do quality institutions matter? Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 81: 101677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The evolution of the value of the Gini coefficient in Greece and the European Union during the period 1995–2021. Data sources: (1) Eurostat, EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income-EU-SILC survey. (2) ELSTAT, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC). Note: GINI-GR = the value of the Gini coefficient in Greece. GINI-EU = the average value of the Gini coefficient in the European Union.
Figure 1. The evolution of the value of the Gini coefficient in Greece and the European Union during the period 1995–2021. Data sources: (1) Eurostat, EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), Gini coefficient of equivalized disposable income-EU-SILC survey. (2) ELSTAT, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC). Note: GINI-GR = the value of the Gini coefficient in Greece. GINI-EU = the average value of the Gini coefficient in the European Union.
Economies 11 00166 g001
Figure 2. The evolution of the value of the income quintile share ratio S80/S20 index in Greece and the European Union during the period 1995–2021. Data sources: (1) Eurostat, EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), inequality of income distribution S80/S20 income quintile ratio, EU-SILC survey. (2) ELSTAT, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC). Note: QSR-GR = the value of the income quintile share ratio S80/S20 index in Greece. GINI-EU = the average value of the income quintile share ratio S80/S20 index in the European Union.
Figure 2. The evolution of the value of the income quintile share ratio S80/S20 index in Greece and the European Union during the period 1995–2021. Data sources: (1) Eurostat, EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), inequality of income distribution S80/S20 income quintile ratio, EU-SILC survey. (2) ELSTAT, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC). Note: QSR-GR = the value of the income quintile share ratio S80/S20 index in Greece. GINI-EU = the average value of the income quintile share ratio S80/S20 index in the European Union.
Economies 11 00166 g002
Figure 3. The evolution of the value of the at-risk-of-poverty rate in Greece and the European Union during the period 1995–2021. Data sources: (1) Eurostat, EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), at-risk-of-poverty rate by poverty thresholds, EU-SILC survey. (2) ELSTAT, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC). Note: ROPR-GR = the value of at-risk-of-poverty rate in Greece. ROPR-EU = the average value of at-risk-of- poverty rate in the European Union.
Figure 3. The evolution of the value of the at-risk-of-poverty rate in Greece and the European Union during the period 1995–2021. Data sources: (1) Eurostat, EU Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC), at-risk-of-poverty rate by poverty thresholds, EU-SILC survey. (2) ELSTAT, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (SILC). Note: ROPR-GR = the value of at-risk-of-poverty rate in Greece. ROPR-EU = the average value of at-risk-of- poverty rate in the European Union.
Economies 11 00166 g003
Figure 4. Correlations among dependent variables: Gini coefficient (GINI), quintile share ratio index S80/S20 (QSRR), and at-risk-of-poverty rate (ROPR).
Figure 4. Correlations among dependent variables: Gini coefficient (GINI), quintile share ratio index S80/S20 (QSRR), and at-risk-of-poverty rate (ROPR).
Economies 11 00166 g004
Figure 5. Gini coefficient (GINI) and at-risk-of-poverty rate (ROPR) xy plot.
Figure 5. Gini coefficient (GINI) and at-risk-of-poverty rate (ROPR) xy plot.
Economies 11 00166 g005
Table 1. Estimates of the coefficients of Model 1: dependent variable GINI.
Table 1. Estimates of the coefficients of Model 1: dependent variable GINI.
TermCoef.SE Coef.t-Valuep-ValueVIF
β 0 23.037.363.130.005
GINI-10.4810.1652.920.0081.90
WGDP−0.3220.108−2.970.0082.82
RGDP0.0000140.0000062.180.0411.59
GESCOV = 11.2120.3733.250.0041.95
ELE = 1−0.6160.273−2.260.0351.04
Table 2. Estimates of the coefficients of Model 2: dependent variable QSR.
Table 2. Estimates of the coefficients of Model 2: dependent variable QSR.
TermCoef.SE Coef.t-Valuep-ValueVIF
β 0 4.461.163.860.001
QSR-10.5280.1174.520.0001.18
WGDP−0.10570.0303−3.480.0021.95
RGDP0.0000050.0000022.370.0281.52
GESCOV = 10.6340.1274.980.0002.00
Table 3. Estimates of the coefficients of Model 3: dependent variable ROPR.
Table 3. Estimates of the coefficients of Model 3: dependent variable ROPR.
TermCoef.SE Coef.t-Valuep-ValueVIF
β 0 32.151.9016.930.000
WGDP−0.73390.0905−8.110.0002.04
RGDP0.0000270.0000074.070.0011.86
UNR0.12680.03533.590.0022.93
GESCOV = 11.7690.4563.880.0012.71
Table 4. Summary of results.
Table 4. Summary of results.
TermGINIQSRROPR
GINI-10.481--
QSR-1-0.528-
WGDP−0.322−0.1057−0.7339
RGDP0.0000140.0000050.000027
UNR--0.1268
GESCOV = 11.2120.6341.769
ELE = 1−0.616--
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Petrakos, G.; Rontos, K.; Vavoura, C.; Vavouras, I. The Impact of Recent Economic Crises on Income Inequality and the Risk of Poverty in Greece. Economies 2023, 11, 166. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060166

AMA Style

Petrakos G, Rontos K, Vavoura C, Vavouras I. The Impact of Recent Economic Crises on Income Inequality and the Risk of Poverty in Greece. Economies. 2023; 11(6):166. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060166

Chicago/Turabian Style

Petrakos, George, Konstantinos Rontos, Chara Vavoura, and Ioannis Vavouras. 2023. "The Impact of Recent Economic Crises on Income Inequality and the Risk of Poverty in Greece" Economies 11, no. 6: 166. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060166

APA Style

Petrakos, G., Rontos, K., Vavoura, C., & Vavouras, I. (2023). The Impact of Recent Economic Crises on Income Inequality and the Risk of Poverty in Greece. Economies, 11(6), 166. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060166

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop