Next Article in Journal
Multistep Forecast Averaging with Stochastic and Deterministic Trends
Previous Article in Journal
When It Counts—Econometric Identification of the Basic Factor Model Based on GLT Structures
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Liquidity and Business Cycles—With Occasional Disruptions

by
Willi Semmler
1,2,†,
Gabriel R. Padró Rosario
1,*,† and
Levent Koçkesen
3,†
1
Department of Economics, The New School for Social Research, New York, NY 10003, USA
2
Department of Economics, Bielefeld University, 33615 Bielefeld, Germany
3
Department of Economics, Nazarbayev University, Astana 010000, Kazakhstan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
Econometrics 2023, 11(4), 27; https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics11040027
Submission received: 7 July 2023 / Revised: 4 November 2023 / Accepted: 4 December 2023 / Published: 12 December 2023

Abstract

:
Some financial disruptions that started in California, U.S., in March 2023, resulting in the closure of several medium-size U.S. banks, shed new light on the role of liquidity in business cycle dynamics. In the normal path of the business cycle, liquidity and output mutually interact. Small shocks generally lead to mean reversion through market forces, as a low degree of liquidity dissipation does not significantly disrupt the economic dynamics. However, larger shocks and greater liquidity dissipation arising from runs on financial institutions and contagion effects can trigger tipping points, financial disruptions, and economic downturns. The latter poses severe challenges for Central Banks, which during normal times, usually maintain a hands-off approach with soft regulation and monitoring, allowing the market to operate. However, in severe times of liquidity dissipation, they must swiftly restore liquidity flows and rebuild trust in stability to avoid further disruptions and meltdowns. In this paper, we present a nonlinear model of the liquidity–macro interaction and econometrically explore those types of dynamic features with data from the U.S. economy. Guided by a theoretical model, we use nonlinear econometric methods of a Smooth Transition Regression type to study those features, which provide and suggest further regulation and monitoring guidelines and institutional enforcement of rules.

1. Introduction

Resilience of the product, labor, and financial markets are typically considered as robust buffers against disruptive shocks to the macroeconomy. Recently, Brunnermeier (2021) has referred to the concept of resilience to explain the stability of the macroeconomy during normal times. There are, however, also factors such as resiliency destroyers that can undermine resilience and can lead to disruptive dynamics. In Semmler et al. (2023), the theory of resilience is evaluated from the perspective of complex system dynamics across various time scales. Various model versions examine the concept of resilience as local resilience (corridor stability) and global resilience (global stability). The analysis reveals the existence of endogenous economic resilience, sudden resilience breakers, loss of resilience, disruptive contractions, or persistent cycles. However, achieving resilience involves extensive monetary, financial, and fiscal policies.
Previous studies on complex features and shock responses suggest that small shocks typically have temporary effects, while larger shocks can give rise to various phenomena, including significant disruptions. These disruptions can be mitigated through policy interventions, which aim to stabilize the system but do not necessarily restore steady-state growth. Instead, they may result in the emergence of further cycles. This behavior is often captured using the concept of Hopf bifurcation, which describes a locally unstable dynamic that can exhibit globally cyclical dynamics under the influence of policies. In this paper, we take a step further by outlining different variants of a dynamic model. Using U.S. time-series data, we estimate the dynamics of the financial–real interaction, specifically focusing on the liquidity dynamics within the financial sector.
We estimate econometrically the model through a Smooth Transition Regression ( STR ) method. The econometrically estimated dynamic model shows the existence of such complex system dynamics, which can be vulnerable to loss of resilience and contractions. In this empirical paper, we explore some features first addressed by Semmler and Koçkesen (2017). In our empirics, we first need to transform our analytically studied continuous-time form into an estimable discrete-time form employing the discrete-time Smooth Transition Regression ( STR ) methodology. Our estimation procedure is applied to the U.S. time-series data for a certain time period. Hereby, we can show the existence of cyclical solution paths, if supported by sufficient policies, and demonstrate that the empirics of financial–real forces can indeed exhibit multiple features and even robustness of large shocks when policy interventions are effective.
Technically, the essential nonlinearities and regime changes can generate a locally stable or unstable equilibrium responding to small shocks. Additionally, it can exhibit global resilience, characterized by persistent (limit) cycles as predicted by the Hopf bifurcation type dynamics, which assumes unstable dynamics close to the equilibrium but stabilizing forces activated further out. The econometrically estimated model reveals the existence of local non-resilience and global resilience. For the locally unstable but globally bounded fluctuations—global resilience—we can detect asymmetric responses to shocks. Furthermore, certain dynamics within the system can lead to disruption and traps, as we highlight in our analysis.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we will sketch some nonlinear model variants of the liquidity–macro link to explain the above scenarios. Section 3 presents simulations featuring some of the above-mentioned complex outcomes for small and large shocks. In Section 4, we estimate econometrically the model through the Smooth Transition Regression ( STR ) method for U.S. time-series data. Section 5 provides some conclusions. In Appendix A, some technical details are presented.

2. Sketch of Nonlinear Model Variants and Simulations

We start with a sketch of the basic dynamic model augmented by two perturbation terms that are decisive for the dynamics. The basic part of our model is consistent with a monetary growth model with an explicit LM schedule. We will provide a sketch of the dynamic models and conduct a series of simulations to demonstrate the possible dynamics of the model. Using a Lyapunov function, we can assess whether the dynamic system tends to stay near its equilibrium point or drift away from it.1

2.1. Analytical Model Variants

The basis of our presentation here is a model that is grounded in an IS - LM version for a growing real economy that links output to liquidity and credit flows. It assumes that financial flows to economic agents (to households and firms) are related to the balance sheets of the economic agents. We assume that when the agents’ balance sheets deteriorate (improve), creditworthiness and credit flows deteriorate (improve). Based on the literature cited above, credit conditions, specifically creditworthiness, and consequently the spending behavior of economic agents, are influenced by both liquidity on the financial side and the dynamics of output and real income on the real side.
We use the broad definition of liquidity as a measure of liquidity: cash, deposits, credit and credit lines from banks, and short-term treasury bonds. We usually observe that at high levels of economic expansion, liquidity rises, default risk falls, and asset prices and creditworthiness rise. The reverse may be assumed to happen during a low level of economic activity. As liquidity shrinks, default risk rises, asset prices fall, and creditworthiness and credit provisions fall. Concerning spending, we may thus assume that spending accelerates (decelerates) when output and liquidity rise above (fall below) some threshold level. The main features of a dynamic model of liquidity, credit, and output in a growing economy can cause regime changes triggered by state-dependent reactions. These reactions can be expressed in a deterministic form as follows.
We presume that economic agents respond to both financial variables (balance sheet variables) and real variables. In the generic form, the financial variables are λ = L / K and real variables are ρ = Y / K , with L denoting liquidity, a balance sheet variable, Y, output (or real income), a real variable, and K the capital stock, while λ ^ ( λ , ρ ) and ρ ^ ( λ , ρ ) represent the growth rates of both ratios, respectively. When we undertake the empirical estimate with data on firms, we interpret real income, Y, as a firms’ income and ρ as a firms’ income relative to capital stock. Thus, ρ denotes the rate of return on real capital.
A model of the type as shown in Equation (1) can be derived from an aggregate model, assuming that the firms’ income is linear in aggregate income.
λ ˙ = λ ( α β ρ ) ρ ˙ = ρ ( γ + δ λ )
In simple terms, model (1) establishes a connection between variations in income and liquidity, linking them with fluctuations in liquidity and income. The term β ρ denotes the liquidity that is used for growth and new transactions and is thus used in the second equation as the term + δ λ for households and firms. Parameter γ represents the natural dissipation of capital value, for example due to depreciation. On the other hand, in the absence of a new injection of liquidity, the income growth rate is firmly negative, thus pushing the income toward zero if no new liquidity is provided. There is a cross-dual interdependence since the growth rate of each variable depends on the other state variable. Note that, due to this last property of model (1), the positive quadrant λ > 0 , ρ > 0 is invariant, which means that if we start with positive liquidity and income, they will remain positive forever.
Our actual model can be thought of as being composed of two parts. First, a basic part of the model that exhibits no thresholds and regime changes can be expressed linearly as system (1). Our basic dynamic equations can then be defined as follows, and are easily shown to be constant along trajectories of the model of Equation (1) where no other terms appear so far.2 Usually, when such a model is solved, one can observe trajectories that oscillate around a common center point with the same cycle length. The cyclical relationship it exhibits is similar to a predator–prey system. We can then introduce some perturbation terms and call this the basis for system (I).3
λ ^ = α β ρ ϵ 1 λ ρ ^ = γ + δ λ ϵ 2 ρ
Here, the coefficients α , β , ε 1 , γ , δ , and ε 2 are positive. In model (2), α represents the natural liquidity growth, for example, through the central bank’s growth rate of liquidity (money) supply. The terms ε 1 λ and ε 2 ρ prevent the liquidity and income from growing without bounds. The additional terms will then create some reversions to the steady state.
The model of Equation (2) is a nonlinear system of differential equations of Lotka–Volterra type, which originated in the 1920s in the mathematical studies of interacting species, with ϵ 1 and ϵ 2 as perturbation terms. However, this system of Equation (2) has three equilibria ( λ * = 0 ρ * = 0 ) , ( λ * = α ϵ 1 , ρ * = 0 ) , and λ * > 0 , γ * > 0 . The first two are saddle points, and the last one is an attraction point. Except for those that start on one of the axes, all of the trajectories converge to the unique attracting point λ * > 0 , γ * > 0 . The dynamics of the model of Equation (2) will be simulated below by choosing economically realistic parameters. For a more detailed discussion of the subsequent subsections, including the perturbation term, corridor stability cycles, and a limit cycle outside an asymptotically stable region, please refer to Semmler et al. (2023).

2.2. System I

Regarding the system described in Equation (2), it is important to consider the potential dynamics influenced by an additional perturbation term referred to as h ( λ , ρ ) . This term represents a weak perturbation that can be activated with varying degrees of strength. The function h ( λ , ρ ) represents the idea that, during business contractions, there is a reduced willingness among lenders, such as depositors or banks, to deposit cash or a tendency to decrease deposits. Additionally, banks may lower credit lines offered to firms and households, all of which are contingent upon the condition of the banks, firms, or households. In addition, if agents anticipate insolvencies or bankruptcies, withdrawing liquidity becomes eminent as a means to safeguard financial assets for worse times. However, the dissipation of liquidity will entail a decline in liquidity flow to households and firms, leading to lower capital outlay and investment, possibly setting in motion complicated dynamics.4
Formally, concerning the function h ( λ , ρ ) , we assume that if the rate of return for firms falls below a certain rate of return, ϕ ( ρ < ϕ ) with ϕ < ρ * , and/or if simultaneously liquidity drops below a certain ratio, μ ( λ < μ ) with μ < λ * , there will be a strong dissipation of liquidity. This, in turn, will have a corresponding impact on the capital outlay and investment of firms and the spending of households. Consequently, we replace model Equation (2) with the following system of differential equations.
λ ^ = α β ρ ϵ 1 λ h ( λ , ρ ) ρ ^ = γ + δ λ ϵ 2 ρ
The term h ( λ , ρ ) in Equation (3) serves as a control term in our dynamic system. It captures the response of banks and firms when the liquidity ratio falls below the threshold μ and when the rate of return drops below the threshold ϕ .5 Hereby, the impact on contractions becomes stronger. We shall assume that h ( λ , ρ ) in Equation (3) is a smooth function satisfying the following conditions:
( i ) 0 h ( λ , ρ ) ( λ 0 , ρ 0 ) ( ii ) 0 = h ( λ , ρ ) ( ρ ϕ , λ μ )
For our simulation, we chose the following:
h ( λ , ρ ) = v [ max ( ϕ ρ , 0 ) max ( μ λ , 0 ) ] 1 / 2
In addition, we make the assumption that μ < λ * and ϕ < ρ * . Subsequently, we label the nonlinear differential Equation (3) as system (I). Equation (3) can also be employed to explain system (II) described below, although in system (II) the effect of h ( λ , ρ ) remains large. The coefficient v refers to the reaction coefficient or perturbation term that, given different values, helps understand any type of convergence.
The proposition that system (I), represented by model of Equation (2), remains stable in the vicinity of the equilibrium holds true even when h ( λ , ρ ) is activated. This is because the Jacobian matrix at λ * , ρ * yields the same local dynamic outcomes for Equation (3) as it does for Equation (2). Whereas the term h ( λ , ρ ) pushes the trajectories toward the axes, as soon as λ and ρ decline below μ and ϕ , the terms ϵ 1 and ϵ 2 generate attracting forces, keeping the trajectories in a compact set. So for a small h ( λ , ρ ) and small shocks, we may still have convergence toward the steady state λ * , ρ * , as in Equation (2).

2.3. System II

Therefore, system (I) exhibits two distinct scenarios. In the case of a small reaction coefficient, v, the trajectories still converge towards the equilibrium for small shocks. However, this convergence does not hold when v becomes larger. In the context of system (I), we can assume that v is active but remains sufficiently small. In contrast, we designate system (II) as the case when v is significantly larger and is triggered by larger shocks. An effective approach to demonstrate the potential scenarios is through a simulation study, as depicted in the upcoming simulations in Section 3.
In summary, system (II) represents a scenario where the value of v is sufficiently large.6 To construct our simulation, we also choose h ( λ , ρ ) = v [ max ( ϕ ρ , 0 ) max ( μ λ , 0 ) ] 1 / 2 , but this time with high values of v. Similarly, we use this nonlinear differential Equation (3) to represent system (II). Below, we present the results for unstable dynamics, with v = 2 , allowing the reaction parameter v to become even larger. The immediate effect is that there will be strong disruptions since the trajectories approach zero, and all values go down to zero.

2.4. System III

However, there remains a possibility of certain attractive forces even in the case of large shocks. This occurs in the presence of a limit cycle, which can be observed when v = 1 , as illustrated below. A similar occurrence is observed when v = 0.6 . In this case, one cycle is repelling and the other is attracting. The system could be stable for trajectories starting close to the equilibrium. Only a stronger shock, i.e., initial conditions far enough from the equilibrium, will generate persistent fluctuations and limit cycles. Thus, the system could exhibit corridor stability, then some regions of instability, but then again, for large shocks, some global stability, i.e., global resilience.
Regardless, certain parameter values of v lead to the presence of a single limit cycle that exhibits both inward and outward attraction. This existence can be demonstrated using the Hopf bifurcation theory, which refers to the transition from a stable equilibrium (where it remains unchanged over time) to a situation where it exhibits periodic or oscillatory behavior. This type of persistent cycle will be studied below in Dynamics III and also empirically in Section 4.
For stronger shocks, i.e., for farther departure from the equilibrium values of λ and ρ , system (III) may locally become unstable. However, it remains globally bounded as it converges towards a limit cycle, even in the case of large shocks. Thus, for initial conditions farthest away from the equilibrium, the limit cycle is approached from the outside.

3. Numerical Simulations

Next, we will simulate the above three types of dynamics. In general, the subsequent simulation study uses the following parameters: α = 0.1 , γ = 0.07 , ϵ 1 = 0.045 , β = 0.6 , δ = 0.7 , ϵ 2 = 0.078 , ϕ = 0.15 , and μ = 0.10 . The economically relevant equilibrium is λ * = 0.12 , ρ * = 0.18 .

3.1. Dynamics I

Figure 1 depicts the trajectories of the system with either Equation (2) or Equation (3), the latter with small h ( λ , ρ ) effects, where it shows the trajectories. However, they are oscillating, asymptotically approaching the equilibrium λ * > 0 , ρ * > 0 . Locally stable, small shocks in the neighborhood of the steady states, or a sufficient liquidity provision policy, giving rise to small h ( λ , ρ ) disturbances only, will create local convergence. Economically, this is the case of self-stabilizing economic dynamics through liquidity buffers or liquidity policy, low h ( λ , ρ ) in economic terms. This is also called corridor stability (Dimand 2005; Leijonhufvud 1973). In this scenario, the large h ( λ , ρ ) is not operating locally and is not causing any notable destabilization.

3.2. Dynamics II

When large shocks occur along with significant effects from h ( λ , ρ ) and a large value of v, it increases the risk of insolvency, as seen in Figure 2. This often has occurred in terms of bank failures on the asset and/or liability side of banks if ( 1 ) there is no Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation ( FDIC ) insurance for deposits, ( 2 ) banks did long-term lending, but short term borrowing, and ( 3 ) the value of capital assets (T-bonds), on the Banks asset side, was rapidly dropping due to interest rate rise. There were fast contagion effects among the depositors (and depositors of other banks). There were insufficient liquidity policies provided by the Federal Reserve ( FED ) , and the Silicon Valley Bank ( SVB ) could not provide fast enough liquidity from the FED using long-term assets as collateral.
In fact, in Dynamics II, if the diverging forces become strong enough to trigger significant disruptions, such as bank runs and contagion effects, it can lead to a situation where these forces cannot be adequately controlled through liquidity policy. Consequently, large effects from h ( λ , ρ ) will occur, causing the trajectories of λ and ρ to approach zero. This scenario entails an increased risk of insolvency, leading to actual insolvency, and with little liquidity policy coming to the rescue.

3.3. Dynamics III

However, if sufficient self-stabilizing forces and liquidity policies, such as FED lending against collaterals or extended deposit guarantees, are coming in, the disruptive and repelling h ( λ , ρ ) force is weakening after large shocks; the responses can weaken the h ( λ , ρ ) effects and the destabilizing forces, generating forces, leading to smaller fluctuations and limit cycles. Therefore, stability can mean stabilization toward stable cyclical fluctuations.
In the case of Dynamics III, self-stabilization and policies can prevent large shocks from moving the trajectory of λ , and ρ does not go to the boundary to zero, as occurred in Dynamics II. However, now those stabilizing forces can come to the rescue, as displayed in Figure 3. Contagion is prevented (through liquidity provision and guarantee of deposits) and central bank short-term borrowing is maintained; this way, firms can keep cash flows going, and the ρ does not go to zero.
In the next section, we will undertake a nonlinear econometric time series study to evaluate if such cycles, as in Dynamics III, can occur when we look at U.S. time-series data.

4. Estimation of Cycles Using Smooth Transition Regression Methodology

One of the major nonlinear time series methods to estimate nonlinear models, outlined in the previous section, is the regime change model. This encompasses the Markov Regime Switching model, which involves random switches between regimes, and the Threshold methodology, where pre-fixed thresholds dictate the occurrence of regime switches. There is also the Smooth Transition Regression ( STR ) methodology, which allows for smooth regime changes. For our empirical estimations using certain time periods of U.S. time-series data on liquidity and output or income (capital income) dynamics, we will use the STR methodology. In our empirical study, we thus focus on the implications of the endogenous banking liquidity dynamics resulting from the balance sheet dynamics of banks and study the endogenous liquidity of the corporate sector as the major driver of output and income.

4.1. Direct and Indirect Methods

In a more general context for such a regime-switching estimations method, there is also a direct method , which consists of discretizing the model, as given in Section 2, which could lead to directly estimating its parameters. For a survey and comparison of the numerical accuracy of different discretization methods, see Kloeden and Platen (1992); for the local linearization procedure, see Ozaki and Ozaki (1989) and Ozaki (1985).
The second method, referred to as the indirect method in this context, is less model-dependent and instead focuses on approximating the continuous-time model using discrete-time state-dependent dynamics. In this approach, the lag structure is determined based on the data. Therefore, the direct method tests the model via parameters. In contrast, the indirect method could be considered a test of the presence of nonlinearities in the liquidity–output interaction without imposing restrictions directly implied by the model.
A model with a state-dependent reactions is, for example, the following van der Pol equation.
x ¨ α ( 1 x 2 ) x ˙ + β x = ϵ
The term ϵ represents a white noise shock, while α and β are constants. The second-order differential equations in x can be estimated through direct procedures by employing, for example, the Euler Procedure ; see Ozaki and Ozaki (1989). The van der Pol equation helps us describe the oscillatory behavior of the system ranging from simple harmonic motion to more complex, nonlinear oscillations depending on the value of the damping parameter α .
Discrete-time threshold autoregressive models along those lines have become popular since they offer a rich array of dynamic behavior, including regime changes, asymmetries, and state-dependent reactions. Hansen (2011), Tong (1990), Potter (1994), Mittnik (1994), De Gooijer and Kumar (1992), Pesaran and Potter (1992), and Sayers (1994) provide an extensive review of the literature on this framework.
A generalization of this framework, called the Smooth Transition Regression ( STR ) model, is elaborated by Granger and Teräsvirta (1993), Luukkonen et al. (1988a, 1988b), Teräsvirta (1994), and Teräsvirta et al. (2010). The STR model is based on the idea that, unlike threshold autoregressive models, in both types of empirically oriented multiple equilibria models, the transitions between regimes, as steady-state rest points, may occur smoothly.
A single discrete time equation of the STR model type can be written as follows.
y t = β X t + ( θ x t ) F ( z t ) + ϵ x t = ( 1 , y t 1 , , y t p ; x 1 t , , x k t )
Here, z t is any variable postulated to govern the transition between regimes and F is some bounded and continuous function. One widely used form of the STR model is the Logistic   STR   ( LSTR ) model characterized by a logistic function F, i.e.,
F ( z t c ) = [ 1 + e x p ( γ ( z t c ) ) ] 1 , γ > 0
with F ( ) = 0 ,   F ( + ) = 1 ,   F ( 0 ) = 1 / 2 . Another form is called the Exponential   STR   ( ESTR ) model, where function F is exponential, i.e.,
F ( z t c ) = 1 e x p [ γ ( z t c ) 2 ] , γ > 0
with F ( ± ) = 0 , F ( + ) = 1 , F ( 0 ) = 1 / 2 .
Granger and Teräsvirta (1993), Teräsvirta (1994), and Eitrheim and Teräsvirta (1996) present a full-fledged testing, specification, estimation, and evaluation procedure for STR models and show that the STR family contains threshold autoregressive and exponential autoregressive models as special cases. Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992), Granger and Teräsvirta (1993), and Teräsvirta (1994) applied this procedure to various economic series.

4.2. STR Methodology and Data

The empirical methodology of STR involves several steps. The first step entails specifying a linear model that serves as the null hypothesis against which the linearity is tested. A test with power against both LSTR and ESTR involves testing H 0 : ϕ 1 = ϕ 2 = ϕ 3 = 0 in the following auxiliary regression:
y t = β x t + ϕ 1 x t z t d + ϕ 2 x t z t d 2 + ϕ 3 x t z t d 3 + η t
The above regression can also be used to determine the transition variable z t by conducting the test for different variables. If linearity is rejected for several choices of z t , the one with the smallest probability value is preferred as the transition variable. Given that the linearity hypothesis is rejected in favor of an STR type of nonlinearity, one determines whether an LSTR or ESTR model is more appropriate by using the following sequence of nested hypotheses:
H 03 : ϕ 3 = 0 H 02 : ϕ 2 = 0 | ϕ 3 = 0 H 01 : ϕ 2 = 0 | ϕ 3 = ϕ 2 = 0
If the test of H 02 has the smallest probability value, one chooses the ESTR and otherwise chooses the LSTR family. Estimation of a specified STR model can then be undertaken by nonlinear least squares. For the following analysis, we employ the same data on the firms described above. The liquidity and the rate of return series have one unit root, as indicated by the augmented Dickey–Fuller tests. The data have been detrended and rendered stationary using the Hodrick–Prescott (HP) filter (with smoothness parameter 1600).7
The analysis covers the time period 1960.1–1988.4, utilizing quarterly data from the U.S. economy. The liquidity variable is defined as the ratio of liquid assets of the non-financial corporate business sector, obtained from the Flow of Funds Accounts (1994), to the capital stock for the same sector as estimated by Fair (1992).8 The resulting series was seasonally adjusted before the analysis was conducted. As the income variable, we take the rate of return on capital, calculated as the flow of profits for the non-financial corporate business sector from the Flow of Funds Accounts, divided by the capital stock. Although the data were available for 1952.1–1991.4, the test and estimation period has been chosen as 1960.1–1988.4 for two reasons. First, before 1960.1 , the series contains outliers that have been argued to favor the hypothesis of nonlinearities. Second, the period between 1988.4 and 1991.4 will later be used for out-of-sample forecasts. In both periods, liquidity provision is not operating under the central bank Taylor rule of monetary policy.
The main reason for choosing that time span is that, during that time period, the Taylor monetary policy rule was not yet being followed, and direct liquidity, for example, aiming at the growth rate of the money supply, was the ruling monetary policy variable. Our model is mainly concerned with the dynamics of the quantity of endogenous liquidity (and output or income), and the model does not much reference the role of the external interest rate. Even though since the beginning of 1990 the Taylor rule has become important, we believe that model dynamics with respect to endogenous liquidity could still be relevant because much of the liquidity is provided endogenously. In our data set, we are also bypassing banking liquidity, driven by the asset and liability side of banks’ balance sheets. We work directly with the endogenous liquidity available for the corporate sector.

5. The Linear Model

We use the following linear model as the reference model:
λ t = a 1 + B 1 ( L ) λ t + C 1 ( L ) ρ t + ϵ 1 t ρ t = a 2 + B 2 ( L ) λ t + C 2 ( L ) ρ t + ϵ 2 t
where B 1 ( L ) and C 1 ( L ) are polynomials in lag operator L of degree 6, whereas B 2 ( L ) and C 2 ( L ) are of degree 8.9 Using the above-mentioned data set, the estimated linear equation for liquidity is10
λ t = 3 × 10 5 ( 3 × 10 4 ) + 0.96 ( 0.10 ) λ t 1 0.15 ( 0.13 ) λ t 2 0.13 ( 0.12 ) λ t 3 + 0.53 ( 0.12 ) λ t 4 0.53 ( 0.13 ) λ t 5 + 0.18 ( 0.10 ) λ t 6 + 0.02 ( 0.04 ) ρ t 1 0.06 ( 0.05 ) ρ t 2 0.001 ( 0.05 ) ρ t 3 0.06 ( 0.05 ) ρ t 4 0.04 ( 0.05 ) ρ t 5 + 0.01 ( 0.04 ) ρ t 6
R 2 = 0.81 S E = 0.003 L M ( 7 ) = 1.64 ( 0.13 ) A R C H ( 1 ) = 3.66 ( 0.06 ) L J B = 0.93 ( 0.63 ) R E S E T ( 2 ) = 1.73 ( 0.18 )
For the rate of return equation, we obtained
ρ = 1 × 10 4 ( 7 × 10 4 ) + 0.81 ( 0.24 ) λ t 1 0.30 ( 0.32 ) λ t 2 + 0.13 ( 0.32 ) λ t 3 0.56 ( 0.29 ) λ t 4 0.06 ( 0.30 ) λ t 5 + 0.27 ( 0.32 ) λ t 6 0.30 ( 0.32 ) λ t 7 + 0.60 ( 0.23 ) λ t 8 + 0.72 ( 0.10 ) ρ t 1 0.12 ( 0.12 ) ρ t 2 + 0.12 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 3 0.05 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 4 0.001 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 5 + 0.06 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 6 + 0.04 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 7 0.27 ( 0.09 ) ρ t 8
R 2 = 0.73 S E = 0.008 L M ( 8 ) = 1.32 ( 0.26 ) A R C H ( 1 ) = 0.44 ( 0.50 ) L J B = 2.36 ( 0.31 ) R E S E T ( 2 ) = 0.64 ( 0.53 )
The standard diagnostic tests do not indicate any miss-specification for any of the equations. When simulated as a system, the linear model generates, as one would expect, convergent cycles and loses its forecasting ability soon after the iterations are started.

5.1. Linearity Tests and Model Specification

We postulate the following nonlinear equations as our alternatives to the linear ones above:
λ t = α 1 + Φ 1 ( L ) λ t + Θ 1 ( L ) ρ t + ( β 1 + Ψ 1 ( L ) λ t + Ω 1 ( L ) ρ t ) F 1 ( z i ( t d 1 ) ; γ 1 , c 1 ) + u 1 t
ρ t = α 2 + Φ 2 ( L ) λ t + Θ 2 ( L ) ρ t + ( β 2 + Ψ 2 ( L ) λ t + Ω 2 ( L ) ρ t ) F 2 ( z i ( t d 2 ) ; γ 2 , c 2 ) + u 2 t
which would result in either a logistic smooth transition regression ( LSTR ) model characterized by a logistic function F,
F ( z i ( t d j ) c j ) = [ 1 + e x p ( γ j ( z i ( t d j ) c j ) ) ] 1 , γ j > 0 ; i = 1 , 2 ; j = 1 , 2
or an exponential smooth transition regression ( ESTR ) model where function F is given by
F ( z i ( t d j ) c j ) = 1 e x p [ γ j ( z i ( t d j ) c j ) 2 , γ j > 0 ; i = 1 , 2 ; j = 1 , 2
The auxiliary equation to test for linearity is the same for both function forms of F. We run the tests for each equation and various lags of both variables as potential transition variables. Table 1 gives the results for the cases where the overall linearity tests have probability values ( p ) smaller than 0.10 . The probability value for H 03 is p 3 , for H 02 it is p 2 , and for H 01 it is p 1 .
The linearity hypothesis is rejected at a 6% significance level for the liquidity equation when the transition variable is ρ t 6 . It is rejected for several transition variables in the case of the rate of return equation, the most significant one arising when λ t 7 is the transition variable. In addition, for both equations, LSTR -type models are suggested. Hence, we have the following general specifications:
λ t = α 1 + Φ 1 ( L ) λ t + Θ 1 ( L ) ρ t + ( β 1 + Ψ 1 ( L ) λ t + Ω 1 ( L ) ρ t ) F 1 ( ρ t 6 ; γ 1 , c 1 ) + u 1 t
ρ t = α 2 + Φ 2 ( L ) λ t + Θ 2 ( L ) ρ t + ( β 2 + Ψ 2 ( L ) λ t + Ω 2 ( L ) ρ t ) F 2 ( λ t 7 ; γ 2 , c 2 ) + u 2 t
where F 1 and F 2 are both logistic functions.

5.2. Estimation and Diagnostics

The STR models can be estimated using nonlinear least squares. Certain lags of both variables, which proved to be insignificant, were excluded to arrive at more parsimonious specifications. The estimated LSTR equation for liquidity is
λ t = 0.0008 ( 0.0004 ) + 0.75 ( 0.06 ) λ t 1 + 0.55 ( 0.09 ) λ t 4 0.36 ( 0.08 ) λ t 5 0.22 ( 0.05 ) ρ t 5 + 0.18 ( 0.05 ) ρ t 6 + 0.56 ( 0.14 ) λ t 3 0.18 ( 0.07 ) ρ t 4 + 0.36 ( 0.12 ) ρ t 5 0.39 ( 0.10 ) ρ t 6 × 1 + exp 2.85 ( 1.42 ) × 72.59 ρ t 6 0.005 ( 0.003 ) 1
R 2 = 0.85 S E = 0.0029 L M ( 7 ) = 1.81 ( 0.09 ) A R C H ( 1 ) = 0.06 ( 0.81 ) L J B = 1.45 ( 0.48 )
The LSTR model for liquidity performs better than its linear counterpart regarding static in-sample forecasting. The standard diagnostics do not indicate any miss-specification. The test for remaining nonlinearity indicates that the estimated model captures the nonlinearity well.
The transition parameter is 207.21 , which indicates a fast transition between what can be regarded as two regimes. The lower regime corresponds to that part of the state space where the rate of return is below 0.0049 (which is slightly greater than the steady-state value of the rate of return), and the upper regime to the part where the rate of return is above that level. The dynamic properties of the model at different regions of the state space will be discussed later once the rate of return equation is also estimated. The LSTR model for the rate of return is given by
ρ t = 0.0004 ( 0.001 ) + 0.76 ( 0.14 ) λ t 1 + 0.58 ( 0.20 ) λ t 5 0.63 ( 0.06 ) ρ t 1 0.34 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 5 + 0.36 ( 0.11 ) ρ t 6 + 0.21 ( 0.06 ) ρ t 8 + ( 0.006 ( 0.003 ) 10.02 ( 0.27 ) λ t 4 + 10.18 ( 0.38 ) λ t 5 0.82 ( 0.39 ) λ t 7 + 10.10 ( 0.26 ) λ t 8 + 0.57 ( 0.18 ) ρ t 5 0.53 ( 0.19 ) ρ t 6 ) × 1 + e x p 18.81 ( 20.38 ) × 138.50 λ t 7 0.0002 ( 0.0004 ) 1
R 2 = 0.79 S E = 0.007 L M ( 9 ) = 0.93 ( 0.51 ) A R C H ( 1 ) = 7.17 ( 0.01 ) L J B = 0.093 ( 0.95 ) L I N ( ρ t 8 ) = 2.26 ( 0.01 )
where L I N ( ρ t 8 ) denotes the linearity test with ρ t 8 as the transition variable. Concerning the static fit, the LSTR equation for the rate of return again performs better than the linear one. Only the ARCH test indicates miss-specification in the equation.11 However, the estimated model still exhibits uncaptured nonlinearity at variable ρ t 8 of an ESTR type. An appropriate strategy would be to re-estimate the equation using two transition variables, λ t 7 and ρ t 8 , one entering with a logistic and the other as an exponential function.12
The transition parameter is much bigger ( 2605.77 ) for this equation, indicating an even faster transition between the lower (liquidity less than 0.0002—a value less than the steady state of the liquidity) and upper regimes (liquidity greater than 0.0002). Hence, the transition between regimes takes place much more quickly as a response to changes in liquidity (the financial variable) than to the rate of return (the real variable). This could be seen as an indication of the fact that firms adjust their behavior very fast as their liquidity gets closer and crosses over a critical level. The adjustment to the changes in the rate of return, however, takes place more smoothly.
To evaluate dynamic forecast performance, we first used the model estimated for the period 1960.1–1988.4 and calculated both the in-sample (1960.1–1988.4) and multi-step ahead forecasts (1989.1–1991.4). We also repeated this exercise using a Monte Carlo simulation rather than a deterministic one, where we shocked each equation in each period with a normally distributed random term (whose standard deviation is taken to be the standard error of the regression in respective models). We repeated this 1000 times and took the mean of the resulting simulations as our point forecasts.13
Using the deterministic simulation method, we found that the nonlinear model does a better job of simulating the rate of return within the sample. In contrast, the converse is true for the liquidity variable (see row 1960.1–1988.4 under Deterministic Simulations in Table 2). However, the nonlinear model fares slightly better when we use the Monte Carlo simulations (row 1960.1–1988.4 under Monte Carlo Simulations). Out-of-sample forecast performance of the linear model is slightly better using the deterministic simulations. However, when we used Monte Carlo simulations, the nonlinear model performed better in forecasting the rate of return (row 1989.1–1991.4).
We also estimated the equations for the period 1960.1–1985.4 and conducted deterministic forecasts for the periods 1986.1–1991.4 and 1986.1–1988.4 (see rows 1986.1–1991.4 and 1986.1–1988.4 in Table 2). Regarding the shorter period, we found that the nonlinear model has significantly better forecasting performance for both variables. However, for a longer period, the nonlinear model performs better only for the liquidity variable. Although the overall evidence seems to be inconclusive, on average, we can conclude that the linear model has a slightly better forecasting performance for the liquidity variable. In contrast, the nonlinear model has a significantly better forecast performance for the rate of return variable.

5.3. Evaluation of the Dynamic Properties

The theoretical model given by equation system (3) implies through the term h ( λ , ρ ) thresholds for the behavior of the trajectories, generating Dynamics I, II, or III. Those possible dynamics will appear in a continuous time model. However, the empirical model has an important driving force, the logistic function F of the discrete-time Equation (13), which in the extreme takes values of zero and one but also takes infinitely more intermediate values. Due to this fact and due to the existence of many lags in the empirical model, it is not straightforward to establish a one-to-one correspondence between the regimes that appear in the theoretical and empirical models. However, we can roughly say that the specification of the empirical model, considering the limitations mentioned above, is similar to the theoretical model.
The steady-state values of the liquidity and the rate of return have been calculated numerically and found to be equal to 0.0013 for liquidity and 0.0035 for the rate of return.14 The system at the steady state has a pair of complex eigenvalues with a maximum modulus greater than unity, indicating local instability, as the Hopf bifurcation in the continuous time case would suggest. Thus here, too, in the discrete-time case, the fact that there exists one pair of complex eigenvalues whose real part is greater than unity indicates the possibility of a Hopf bifurcation taking place as some parameters change. If this is the case, then one would expect the emergence of a stable limit cycle.15
The system was simulated over extended periods (up to 15,000 iterations), and it was found that this is indeed the case (see Figure 4). The simulations with different initial values inside and outside the limit cycle showed that this periodic motion was stable. The cycles have a period of approximately 26 quarters (or 6.5 years), which conforms well with the definition of the business cycle by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER).16
Thus, we can conclude that the dynamic interaction between liquidity and the rate of return on capital contains essential nonlinearities that lead to sustained fluctuations in both variables, even in the absence of exogenous shocks to the system. However, we could not detect corridor stability (as apparent from the fact that the steady state is locally unstable), which would require a more refined methodology, i.e., a model with multiple threshold variables in the dynamic equations.

6. Conclusions

Business cycles are often accompanied by waves of optimism and pessimism, resulting in fluctuating endogenous credit flows and liquidity. These factors interact with macroeconomic performance, including output and income flows. The recent crunch in credit flows and liquidity that originated in the banking system in the U.S., particularly in California, is throwing new light on the role of liquidity in business cycle dynamics.
In the normal path of the business cycle, liquidity and output (and income) mutually influence each other, and a mean reversion is generally achieved through market forces. When the degree of liquidity dissipation remains low, it does not significantly harm the economic dynamics. However, with larger liquidity dissipation due to bank runs and financial institution failures, followed by contagion effects, tipping points are likely to be reached, leading to major financial disruptions and economic contractions. These circumstances pose significant challenges for liquidity providers, such as corporations, the money market, commercial banks, and central banks. The latter usually react with a delay in letting the market work but then need to restore liquidity flows and trust in stability, avoiding further disruptions and meltdowns. This process involves a combination of positive and negative feedback effects from liquidity providers to corporations, banks, and households.
We explore three types of dynamics: a locally attracting one, resilience against any type of shock, and small or big shocks. However, dynamics following large shocks can lead to resilience breakers and long-term disruptions. To prevent such disruptions, policy measures can be implemented to induce dynamics among driving variables that interact to generate persistent cycles, with the support of timely policy actions. We empirically test the latter type of dynamics in a nonlinear model of the liquidity–macro interaction and econometrically explore those dynamic feedback features for the U.S. economy. Guided by a theoretical model, we use nonlinear econometrics of a Smooth Transition Regression ( STR ) type to study those features by including further policy measures such as regulation and monitoring guidelines and institutional enforcement of rules.
Our empirical analysis has shown that we can use a continuous time regime change model to study state-dependent reactions and regime changes in cross effects between liquidity–macro variables, i.e., the direct method (Euler scheme and Ozaki’s local linearization method), as well as a discrete-time version, which we call the indirect method ( STR methodology).17 Both the application of the Euler method as well as the local linearization procedure of Ozaki are encouraging. Although the first is easier to apply, it may generate instability. The latter is more difficult to employ since the number of observations to be used for a higher dimensional state space is quite large, and the computation is very time-consuming. Although the direct method revealed some expected dynamic behavior, such as regime change behavior, when estimated, lag effects and delay effects do not seem to play an important role. For the latter, see Chen et al. (2022).
Applying the STR methodology is particularly interesting. The data reveals that a linear model also fits well and demonstrates a convergent behavior, suggesting a stable steady state.18 In other words, if one assumes a linear representation of the data, the system would be considered stable around the steady state. Any fluctuations observed would then be attributed to external shocks or factors. As standard models often exhibit, one would always observe a mean reversion behavior of the variables. However, a regime change model, which we claim is a better representation of the data, reveals that the actual dynamics of the system are characterized by a locally unstable steady state contained by stable outer regions.19
Regime change models are capable of exploring and answering more intriguing questions that have been extensively discussed in theoretical literature but have lacked empirical analysis. The results of this paper provide evidence in support of a particular class of credit and output interaction models characterized by an unstable steady state, regime shifts, and asymmetric responses to shocks. This encourages further work to examine regime changes in other macroeconomic relationships, for example, in relations between stock market data and output (see Semmler and Koçkesen 2017) or exchange rate data and output. Time series models based on thresholds seem to be particularly useful in this endeavor.
Higher dimensional models can also be studied where such thresholds exist, not as threshold points but as threshold surfaces. Moreover, existing work shows that the complex dynamics can generate steady states as a trapping region, as bad attractors, where the dynamics nearby can be trapped in a low-level equilibrium with features of persistent traps, as seen in Semmler et al. (2023). They provide examples of this type arising from severe financial and climate disasters with extensive disruptions from normal business cycle dynamics, even for longer time periods.
Following the global financial crisis, central banks increasingly relied on liquidity facilities to manage cross-currency liquidity effectively. Therefore, it is natural to question the factors contributing to another potential financial crisis fifteen years after the previous one. In this context, Albrizio et al. (2023) found that introducing the European Central Bank’s ECB euro liquidity lines led to a decrease in borrowing premiums for foreign entities.20
Though our model might be viewed as depicting more of the earlier time when monetary policy was not guided by the Taylor rule, concerning the liquidity dynamics, it may be worth making a remark on the collapse of SVB in California, and the situation close to an economic-wide disruption could be related to our model. It was, to a great extent, caused by its failure to diversify its investments, which ultimately led to its insolvency and triggered bank runs. The SVB had lent money to the Federal government by purchasing long-term bonds. However, when depositors sought to withdraw their funds, the SVB could not repay, leading to a liquidity crisis that became an insolvency problem. The result was a destructive cycle where the outflow of money from SVB forced the bank to sell bonds at a loss, further exacerbating their financial losses and causing more depositors to withdraw their funds. The absence of active liquidity policies by the monetary authority to prevent such banking crises and minimize losses during asset sales by depositors accelerates the run. It is, therefore, crucial to establish liquidity buffers provided by the Federal Reserve, such as collateralized short-term lending to banks. However, this also did not seem to have been effective during the SVB episode. Stricter government regulations and more forceful liquidity provisions are necessary to prevent future bank failures.21
It is also important to note that the quick escalation of interest rates may have unanticipated economic ramifications. This is exemplified by the ongoing debate surrounding the underlying causes of the current inflation, which can be attributed to various sources of disruptions. If inflation is primarily caused by excessive aggregate demand, it is appropriate to implement monetary policy measures, such as tightening, to reduce overall demand. However, if inflation is mainly driven by supply-side factors, a more targeted approach is needed, which includes implementing fiscal policies that address the constraints on the supply side. A combination of factors seems to have contributed to the recent inflationary conditions, but empirical evidence sheds light on its primary drivers. Stiglitz and Regmi (2023) demonstrated that the present inflation is not a result of an excess demand; specifically, it is not caused by excessive spending during the pandemic but is rather due to disruptions in the supply side, primarily caused by the pandemic (such as chip shortages) and the war in Ukraine, along with changes in demand within specific sectors. While the economy appreciates the restoration of interest rates to a more customary level, which serves to mitigate distortions resulting from prolonged, abnormally low rates, an excessive and swift increase in interest rates presents the potential for a deleterious deceleration of the economy with negligible effects on inflation unless a substantial downturn is experienced.
In essence, mistakes were certainly made, such as a lack of proactive monetary policy before the financial crisis, delayed termination of quantitative easing afterward, and slower withdrawal of monetary support in 2021. However, it is doubtful that any of these measures would have led to a fine-tuning and smooth mean reversion; quite commonly, boom–bust cycles are observable, and sometimes disruptions occur.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, W.S. and G.R.P.R.; Methodology, L.K. and W.S.; Software, L.K. and G.R.P.R.; Validation, L.K., W.S. and G.R.P.R.; Formal analysis, W.S.; Investigation, G.R.P.R.; Resources, L.K., G.R.P.R. and W.S.; Data curation, L.K.; Writing—original draft preparation, W.S. and G.R.P.R.; Writing—review and editing, W.S., G.R.P.R. and L.K.; Visualization, G.R.P.R.; Supervision, W.S.; Project administration, W.S.; Funding acquisition, No funding. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

We acknowledge that certain empirical questions remain unanswered due to data and code loss when a co-author relocated to Europe. Despite this setback, we assert that significant questions were addressed using the available data set, procedures, and codes at the time. The responses to reviewers and the manuscript contain answers to major questions. We note that some answers were implicit in the text or previous manuscripts but have been articulated more explicitly. Due to time constraints, we opted not to reconstruct previous numerical procedures and codes but to affirm their ability to address the primary inquiries effectively.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. State-Dependent Shocks and Persistent Cycles

We found that the system’s response to shocks in the variables is asymmetric. Following Potter (1994), we define a Nonlinear Impulse Response Function (NLIRF) as
N L I R F n ( v ; y t ) = E [ Y t + n | Y t = y t + v , Y t 1 = y t 1 , ] E [ Y t + n | Y t = y t , Y t 1 = y t 1 , ]
which is, in practical terms, simply the difference between the series at time t + n , when y t is perturbed by v (size of the shock) at time t, and the series without the perturbation. Similarly, one can define N L I R F n ( v ; y t ) to denote the impulse response when the shock is negative. In a linear system, the impulse response function is symmetric, and thus
A S Y n ( v ; y t ) = N L I R F n ( v ; y t ) + N L I R F n ( v ; y t )
will be zero. A S Y n ( v ; y t ) can be regarded as a measure of asymmetry; the extent to which it deviates from zero indicates the extent of the asymmetric response to shocks.
We calculated (by simulation) the nonlinear response functions and the measures of asymmetry for both variables (for up to 12 periods) when a single shock perturbs the system to one of the variables (where the size of the shock is one standard deviation of the variable in question). We also calculated the mean asymmetry measures ( MASY ) defined as follows.
M A S Y = 1 T n = 1 T A S Y n ( v ; y t ) σ y
where σ y is the standard deviation of the corresponding series. Thus, a negative MASY will indicate a stronger response to negative shocks, and vice versa.
The initial states where the system is perturbed are given in Table A1.
Table A1. Impulse response analysis in the initial states.
Table A1. Impulse response analysis in the initial states.
State I ρ at max, ρ ↓, λ
State II λ at min, ρ ↓, λ
State III ρ at min, ρ ↑, λ
State IV λ at max, ρ ↑, λ
If one uses the movements of the rate of return as an index of the business cycle, then State I corresponds to the peak, State II to the lower phase of the downswing, State III to the trough, and State IV to the upper phase of the upswing. Table A2 reports the mean asymmetry measures at different states.
Table A2. Mean asymmetry measures.
Table A2. Mean asymmetry measures.
Shocks to LiquidityShocks to Rate of Return
Response ofliquidityrate of returnliquidityrate of return
State I−0.0002−0.0026−0.0001−0.0001
State II−0.1086−0.0992−0.0778−0.0651
State III−0.2194−0.4222−0.1813−0.0291
State IV−0.0617−0.05930.0044−0.0242
Although the response is symmetric for initial periods (5 to 7 periods), it ceases to be so afterward. In general, the extent of the asymmetric response to shocks to liquidity is bigger. In every state of the system, negative shocks to liquidity generate a bigger response by both liquidity and rate of return. The same is true for shocks to the rate of return, except in State IV where the response of liquidity to a positive shock is bigger.22
These exercises point out that the pattern of asymmetric response to shocks in a model of financial–real interaction is very rich. In particular, one should distinguish between shocks of different signs, shocks to real and financial variables, and shocks during the different phases of the business cycles.
Due to the high dimensionality of the dynamical system, it is impossible to study its global stability properties analytically. However, if we can imagine that the model has four distinct regimes (other than the neighborhood around the steady state), which four linear models can approximate, the eigenvalues in those regimes could offer some information.23
The regimes A and D in Table A3 correspond to the upper and lower regimes, respectively, which have been discussed before, i.e., the upper regime corresponds to that region of the state space where liquidity and rate of return are greater than their steady-state values, and the lower regime corresponds to the region where they are smaller. We can see from Table A3 that the eigenvalues at these two regimes are complex, with moduli smaller than one indicating convergent cycles. The cycles in the lower regime have a period of approximately 15 quarters, whereas those in the upper regime exhibit periods of approximately 24 quarters.
Table A3. Maximum moduli and periods in the different states.
Table A3. Maximum moduli and periods in the different states.
StatesMaximum ModulusPeriods
A. ( F 1 = 1 , F 2 = 1 ) 0.9924
B. ( F 1 = 1 , F 2 = 0 ) 0.9724
C. ( F 1 = 0 , F 2 = 1 ) 1.0313
D. ( F 1 = 0 , F 2 = 0 ) 0.9515
If we linearize the system at different states, we can obtain more insight into the nature of the interaction between liquidity and rate of return. Table A4 reports the long-term multipliers for both equations in five different states.
Table A4. Multipliers in the different states.
Table A4. Multipliers in the different states.
StatesLiquidity EquationRate of Return Equation
Steady-State *−0.4331.128
A. ( F 1 = 1 , F 2 = 1 ) −0.3991.188
B. ( F 1 = 1 , F 2 = 0 ) −0.3990.307
C. ( F 1 = 0 , F 2 = 1 ) −0.7061.188
D. ( F 1 = 0 , F 2 = 0 ) −0.7060.307
*: Steady-state values are F 1 = 0.424 , F 2 = 0.937 .
As one would expect, the impact of the rate of return on liquidity is negative, whereas that of liquidity on the rate of return is positive in every state. Furthermore, the effect of the rate of return (which is the transition variable in the liquidity equation) is larger in the lower regime (i.e., regime D) than in the upper regime (i.e., regime A), which lends some support to the idea in Semmler and Sieveking (1993). However, the converse is true for the effect of liquidity on the rate of return, i.e., liquidity exerts a stronger impact on the rate of return in the upper regime than in the lower regime. These results lend support to the models in Section 2, implying that firms will increase their investment expenditures more as a response to an increase in their liquidity ratios if the rate of return on capital and the rate of investment is already higher than their steady-state levels. Based on these results, we can conclude that a liquidity–output interaction model should consider the differences in the system’s response to real and financial disturbances as well as the state (or history)-dependent responses.

Notes

1
For details see Semmler and Sieveking (1993).
2
This system is most simply analyzed with the aid of the following Lyapunov function, which is an approach to study global stability:
H ( ϵ , ρ ) = α log ρ + γ log λ β r δ ϵ ( ϵ > 0 , ρ > 0 )
3
The previously mentioned system (1), which is expressed in terms of growth rates and now perturbed by two additional terms, will be referred to as system (I).
4
One may also argue that a similar effect might occur in expansions. Since booms are usually resource-constrained, we want to neglect this slight complication, which is, of course, important as a driver of inflation rates in expansions.
5
On the other hand, it is worth considering that central banks have the ability to provide liquidity, impacting or modifying these dynamics.
6
It is a Lotka–Volterra system with double perturbations and a scenario with v values.
7
The model described in Section 2 is cast in terms of normalized variables, i.e., liquidity and income normalized by the capital stock. In that sense, their steady-state values are bounded: the growth rate is zero at the steady state. Thus, the cyclical variations implied by the model are cycles around a zero (or, more generally, a constant) growth rate. This is not the case in the data. For the case of growing variables at the steady state, see Chen et al. (2022). Furthermore, the theory behind testing for and estimating STR models has been developed for stationary data. Since the theoretical models that inspired our empirical implementation explicitly refer to business cycles, we use the HP filter as a detrending technique. We should point out that there has been some recent criticism by Hamilton (2018) of the HP filter. In our empirical analysis, we estimated linear VAR models with both first-differenced and HP -detrended data and did not detect any spurious cross-correlations as a result of HP detrending.
8
Note that for our theoretical model, it would be better to use the liquidity variable, a measure from bank balance sheets and bank credit potentially available to firms, for example, credit lines. Since, however, time-series data on credit lines are unavailable for our time period, we simply employ liquid assets for firms as our measure of liquidity. This is equivalent to positing, as our theoretical exposition suggests, a positive covariation between liquid assets, creditworthiness, and credit flows. We do not take actual credit flows as our financial variable as the actual credit flows are not a good measure of creditworthiness.
9
Appropriate lag lengths were determined by using Akaike Information Criterion and diagnostic tests on residuals.
10
Standard errors are in parentheses. SE stands for standard error of regression; LM is the Breusch-Godfrey LM test for serial correlation (F version); ARCH is Engel’s LM test for ARCH effects; LJB is the Lomnicki-Jarque-Bera test for normality; RESET is Ramsey’s RESET test. Numbers in parentheses are the order of the tests, and next to the diagnostic statistics, the probability values are associated with them.
11
Since there is rarely volatility clustering in quarterly data and Engel’s ARCH test is sensitive to outliers, we have not attempted to jointly model the mean and the variance. We are thankful to a referee for pointing this out.
12
Our attempts to do so run into numerical difficulties in the estimation procedure, possibly due to the small number of observations.
13
Simulations have been carried out as a system, but shocks for the equations have been generated independently.
14
Mean trend plus steady state is 0.15 for liquidity and 0.13 for the rate of return, which are both slightly above the means of the series before detrending.
15
Assuming that further conditions hold; see Guckenheimer and Holmes (2013).
16
However, Cogley and Nason (1995) claim that the HP filter implants business cycle periodicity to the filtered data even if the original series is a random walk. This also raises the concern that HP detrended liquidity and rate of return series covary because of this property of the HP filter. To check whether this is the case, we estimated linear VAR models with both first-differenced and HP -detrended data and did not detect any spurious cross-correlations as a result of HP detrending.Though the Hamilton filter is currently discussed as an alternative to the HP filter, a consensus as to the best filter for extracting business cycle frequencies has not been reached.
17
The continuous time method can be found in Semmler and Koçkesen (2017).
18
The linear system for firm data has complex eigenvalues with a maximum modulus of 0.95 and periods of 25 quarters, and the STR variants for the household data show convergence when simulated.
19
A similar comparison of linear and nonlinear systems is already undertaken in Blatt (1978).
20
The decrease in borrowing premium was found in foreign exchange markets compared to currencies not covered by these facilities. Moreover, banks in the euro area, with significant exposure to countries targeted by liquidity lines, experience an approximate 1.75% increase in equity prices.
21
Research such as Bigio (2015) extends on liquidity-driven recessions following surges in the dispersion of collateral quality.
22
Even at State IV, the first 8-period negative response is bigger than the positive response.
23
For a similar analysis, see Granger and Teräsvirta (1993).

References

  1. Albrizio, Silvia, Iván Kataryniuk, Luis Molina, and Jan Schäfer. 2023. ECB Euro Liquidity Lines. IMF Working Papers (WPIEA2023096). Bretton Woods: International Monetary Fund, pp. 1–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Bigio, Saki. 2015. Endogenous liquidity and the business cycle. American Economic Review 105: 1883–927. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Blatt, John M. 1978. On the Econometric Approach to Business-Cycle Analysis. Oxford Economic Papers 30: 292–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Brunnermeier, Markus K. 2021. The Resilient Society. Colorado Springs: Endeavor Literary Press. [Google Scholar]
  5. Chen, Pu, Willi Semmler, and Helmut Maurer. 2022. Delayed monetary policy effects in a multi-regime cointegrated VAR(MRCIVAR). Econometrics and Statistics, in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Cogley, Timothy, and James M. Nason. 1995. Effects of the hodrick-prescott filter on trend and difference stationary time series implications for business cycle research. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19: 253–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. De Gooijer, Jan G., and Kuldeep Kumar. 1992. Some recent developments in non-linear time series modelling, testing, and forecasting. International Journal of Forecasting 8: 135–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Dimand, Robert W. 2005. Fisher, keynes, and the corridor of stability. The American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64: 185–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Eitrheim, Øyvind, and Timo Teräsvirta. 1996. Testing the adequacy of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of Econometrics 74: 59–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Granger, Clive W. J., and Timo Teräsvirta. 1993. Modelling Non-Linear Economic Relationships. Number 9780198773207 in OUP Catalogue. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  11. Guckenheimer, John, and Philip Holmes. 2013. Nonlinear Oscillations, Dynamical Systems, and Bifurcations of Vector Fields. New York: Springer Science & Business Media, vol. 42. [Google Scholar]
  12. Hamilton, James D. 2018. Why You Should Never Use the Hodrick-Prescott Filter. The Review of Economics and Statistics 100: 831–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Hansen, Bruce E. 2011. Threshold autoregression in economics. Statistics and Its Interface 4: 123–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Kloeden, Peter E., and Eckhard Platen. 1992. Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations. Stochastic Modelling and Applied Probability. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Leijonhufvud, Axel. 1973. Effective demand failures. The Swedish Journal of Economics 75: 27–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Luukkonen, Ritva, Pentti Saikkonen, and Timo Teräsvirta. 1988a. Testing linearity against smooth transition autoregressive models. Biometrika 75: 491–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Luukkonen, Ritva, Pentti Saikkonen, and Timo Teräsvirta. 1988b. Testing linearity in univariate time series models. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics 15: 161–75. [Google Scholar]
  18. Mittnik, Stefan. 1994. Asymmetries in Business Cycles: Econometric Techniques and Empirical Evidence. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 331–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ozaki, Tohru. 1985. 2 non-linear time series models and dynamical systems. In Handbook of Statistics. Time Series in the Time Domain. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 5, pp. 25–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Ozaki, Tohru, and Valerie H. Ozaki. 1989. Statistical Identification of Nonlinear Dynamics in Macroeconomics Using Nonlinear Time Series Models. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 345–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Pesaran, M. Hashem, and Simon M. Potter. 1992. Nonlinear dynamics and econometrics: An introduction. Journal of Applied Econometrics 7: S1–S7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Potter, Simon M. 1994. Asymmetric Economic Propagation Mechanisms. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 313–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Sayers, Chera L. 1994. Testing for Chaos and Nonlinearities in Macroeconomic Time Series. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 351–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Semmler, Willi, and Levent Koçkesen. 2017. Liquidity, Credit and Output: A Regime Change Model and Empirical Estimations. Working Papers 1730. New York: New School for Social Research, Department of Economics. [Google Scholar]
  25. Semmler, Willi, and Malte Sieveking. 1993. Nonlinear liquidity-growth dynamics with corridor-stability. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 22: 189–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Semmler, Willi, Fabio Della Rossa, Giuseppe Orlando, Gabriel R. Padró Rosario, and Levent Koçkesen. 2023. Endogenous Economic Resilience, Loss of Resilience, Persistent Cycles, Multiple Attractors, and Disruptive Contractions. Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 1–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Stiglitz, Joseph E., and Ira Regmi. 2023. The causes of and responses to today’s inflation. Industrial and Corporate Change 32: 336–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Teräsvirta, Timo. 1994. Specification, estimation, and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 89: 208–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Teräsvirta, Timo, and Heather M. Anderson. 1992. Characterizing nonlinearities in business cycles using smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of Applied Econometrics 7: S119–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Teräsvirta, Timo, Dag Tjøstheim, and Clive W. J. Granger. 2010. Modelling Nonlinear Economic Time Series. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Tong, Howell. 1990. Non-Linear Time Series. A dynamical System Approach. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Dynamics I: Small local shocks have no big effects, corridor stability.
Figure 1. Dynamics I: Small local shocks have no big effects, corridor stability.
Econometrics 11 00027 g001
Figure 2. Dynamics II: Large shocks and subsequent disruptions, no sufficient liquidity policy.
Figure 2. Dynamics II: Large shocks and subsequent disruptions, no sufficient liquidity policy.
Econometrics 11 00027 g002
Figure 3. Dynamics III: After large shocks, sufficient self-stabilization and liquidity policies.
Figure 3. Dynamics III: After large shocks, sufficient self-stabilization and liquidity policies.
Econometrics 11 00027 g003
Figure 4. Limit cycle, Hopf bifurcation at steady state.
Figure 4. Limit cycle, Hopf bifurcation at steady state.
Econometrics 11 00027 g004
Table 1. Linearity tests: liquidity equation.
Table 1. Linearity tests: liquidity equation.
EquationVariablepp3p2p1
Liquidity
ρ t 6 0.060.430.330.008
Rate of Return
λ t 7 0.0010.0050.310.01
λ t 8 0.020.100.150.04
λ t 4 0.080.500.080.06
λ t 8 0.030.160.100.11
Table 2. Forecast mean squared errors (×1000).
Table 2. Forecast mean squared errors (×1000).
Linear ModelNonlinear Model
LiquidityRate of ReturnLiquidityRate of Return
Deterministic Simulations
1960.1–1988.47.4513.827.8213.00
1986.1–1991.48.0811.505.9912.26
1986.1–1988.49.8514.866.9813.23
1989.1–1991.44.164.526.964.78
Monte-Carlo Simulations
1960.1–1988.47.4213.767.0813.31
1989.1–1991.44.234.436.944.20
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Semmler, W.; Rosario, G.R.P.; Koçkesen, L. Liquidity and Business Cycles—With Occasional Disruptions. Econometrics 2023, 11, 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics11040027

AMA Style

Semmler W, Rosario GRP, Koçkesen L. Liquidity and Business Cycles—With Occasional Disruptions. Econometrics. 2023; 11(4):27. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics11040027

Chicago/Turabian Style

Semmler, Willi, Gabriel R. Padró Rosario, and Levent Koçkesen. 2023. "Liquidity and Business Cycles—With Occasional Disruptions" Econometrics 11, no. 4: 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics11040027

APA Style

Semmler, W., Rosario, G. R. P., & Koçkesen, L. (2023). Liquidity and Business Cycles—With Occasional Disruptions. Econometrics, 11(4), 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/econometrics11040027

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop