Next Article in Journal
Analysis of Effects on the Dual Circulation Promotion Policy for Cross-Border E-Commerce B2B Export Trade Based on System Dynamics during COVID-19
Next Article in Special Issue
Optimal Asynchronous Dynamic Policies in Energy-Efficient Data Centers
Previous Article in Journal
Examining the Influence of Moral Norms on Dockless Shared Bicycle Users’ Parking Behavior—An Exploratory Study Based on the Theory of Planned Behavior
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Simulation of Cooperation Scenarios of BRI-Related Countries Based on a GVC Network

1
College of Economics and Management, Beijing University of Technology, Beijing 100124, China
2
College of Economics & Management, Shenyang Ligong University, Shenyang 110170, China
3
International Business School, Beijing Foreign Studies University, Beijing 100089, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Systems 2022, 10(1), 12; https://doi.org/10.3390/systems10010012
Submission received: 20 December 2021 / Revised: 20 January 2022 / Accepted: 28 January 2022 / Published: 3 February 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Data Driven Decision-Making for Complex Production Systems)

Abstract

:
The inter-country input–output table is appropriate for presenting sophisticated inter-industry dependencies from a global perspective. Using the above table one can perceive the amount of production resources that sectors obtain from their upstream ones, as well as the number of productive capacities that sectors provide for their downstream ones. In other words, competition/collaboration occurs when sectors share the same providers/consumers because all sectors’ products and services outputted to downstream ones are limited. Thus, inter-industry competition for inputs from upstream sectors, or collaboration on outputs to downstream sectors, may be quantified with input–output matrix transformation. In this paper, a novel analytical framework of inter-industry collaborative relations is established based on the bipartite graph theory and the resource allocation process. The Collaborative Opportunity Index and Collaborative Threat index are designed to quantitatively measure the industrial influence hidden in the topological structure of the global value chain (GVC) network. Scenario simulations are carried out to forecast the potential and trends of international capacity cooperation within Asian, European, and African nations related to the Belt and Road Initiative, respectively.

1. Introduction

Belt and Road Initiative (BRI) is a transcontinental long-term policy and investment program which aims at infrastructure development and acceleration of the economic integration of countries along the route of the historic Silk Road. The initiative was unveiled in 2013 by China‘s President Xi Jinping.
At present, China has entered the “New Normal” development stage of the economy, and the BRI is being implemented in depth. In March 2015, China issued an action plan which described the main objectives of the BRI. The BRI-participating economies represent more than one-third of global GDP and over half of the world’s population. In September 2016, General Secretary Jinping Xi pointed out in the keynote speech at the opening ceremony of the B20 Summit (a major support group for the G20 from industrial and commercial circles): “China’s development benefits from the international community and is willing to provide more public goods to the international community. China has proposed the ‘One Belt and One Road Initiative’, which aims to share China’s development opportunities and achieve common prosperity with countries along the routes.” China is actively promoting the economic development of BRI-related nations, supporting and driving domestic superior and surplus production capacity to countries/regions that have fewer comparative advantages. Finally, to construct a fair and reasonable international order, China will offer both value ideas and institutional design ideas that reflect Chinese wisdom and China’s plans.
BRI is based on the concept of mutually beneficial cooperation [1]. It plays an important role in foreign direct investment, infrastructure, international cooperation, and economic growth in countries along the route [2,3,4,5,6]. According to the report “Building the Belt and Road Initiative: Progress, Contribution and Prospects” released by the Ministry of Commerce in April 2019, the BRI has gained the support of 125 countries and 29 international organizations for its construction. According to the data published by the World Bank, the combined GDP of the countries along the BRI in the five years after its introduction (2013–2017) was 141 trillion dollars, which is 39.6% higher than that in the five years before the initiative (2008–2012). In addition, the World Bank Group’s 2019 release “The Belt and Road Economy: Opportunities and Risks of Transport Corridors” quantifies the impact of the Belt and Road. According to the article, the Belt and Road can expand trade, increase foreign investment, and reduce poverty by reducing trade costs. Full implementation of the Belt and Road Initiative could increase world trade by 1.7% to 6.2% and global real income by 0.7% to 2.9%.
Rapidly promoting China’s position and competitiveness on the Global Value Chain (GVC) and shaping new comparative advantages in the context of BRI is either the important guarantee for the continuous and in-depth development of Global Cooperation on Production Capacity strategy or the realistic requirement for China’s industrial restructuring and factor allocation optimization at this stage. BRI aims to build an open, inclusive, and balanced regional economic cooperation architecture for the 21st century, strengthen the weak points of globalization, and transform partial globalization into an inclusive one. Under this context, there is an urgent need to rationally distribute international productivities to enhance the competitive advantages of both China and BRI-related nations. Therefore, how to realize the positive interaction between China’s industrial structure and foreign trade upgrade in the process of international economic integration and BRI, and how to fully utilize the institutional dividend brought by such a cooperative strategy to build a new regional trade system, will definitely be the key research direction at the national strategic level for a long period in the future.
Based on a mature industrial system, the high-cost performance of equipment capacity, mighty construction abilities, enhancement on the international capacity cooperation with nations along the route, are feasible ways for China to achieve mutual benefits and the win-win goal. Nevertheless, the paradox is that international public opinion has many doubts and even dissatisfaction with China’s BRI. Some countries believe that the BRI is China’s economic plunder of countries along the route, and it is a Chinese version of the Marshall Plan. It has become an important driving factor for the threat inflation phenomenon of some Western countries’ perception of China. In recent years, some countries have implemented a series of measures to weaken China’s role and status on the GVC. The U.S. plans to start investing in 5 to 10 major infrastructure projects around the world in 2022 as part of the Group of Seven (G7) Build Back Better World (B3W) program to counter China’s BRI. The EU and the UK have launched similar programs to invest in global infrastructure. The Global Gateway Initiative and the Clean Green Initiative have been proposed so that less developed countries will opt out of the streamlined and unconditional BRI. These approaches are equivalent to treating international trade as a zero-sum game, thus failing to achieve a win-win goal. Of course, under the perspective of systems science, it is impractical and will inevitably lead to negative impacts flowing along the GVC and ultimately leading to a decline in the global competitiveness of the industrial sectors within many countries. Accordingly, our econophysics framework will be adopted to simulate the international trade process under different policy backgrounds and development scenarios. We hope the network-based measurements proposed in this paper can be used as the evaluation criteria to deeply understand the policymaking of international trade and its long-term consequences.
As the result of globally economic integration, various countries and regions in the world have gradually formed a global economic system through increasingly deepened trade exchanges with each other. As the subsystems of this system, countries in the world have also evolved their internal Industrial Value Chains (IVCs) as an organic whole, and they play a specific role on a global scale. Therefore, economists began to systematically and comprehensively study global macroeconomic issues from the perspective of system theory. The GVC network reflects the topological structure of the global economic system, depicts the vertical division of labor and complex input–output relationships in global industrial sectors, and provides a theoretical framework and application basis for analyzing global economic issues. The popularization and promotion of the Inter–Country Input–Output (ICIO) database provides scientific and accurate data for studying the important role of various industries and economies on the GVC network. The IO table can be directly or slightly modified as an adjacency matrix to establish a network model [7], and measure the importance of industrial sectors through network characteristic indicators. Input–Output Analysis (IOA) can be performed on issues such as the impact of consumption shocks [8] on the economic system and the balance of supply and demand [9] in a free market economy. Sectoral production characteristics, such as the degree of industrial sector participation in vertical specialization trade [10], the number of stages required for production on the GVC and the stage between production and final consumption [11], are measured. In recent years, Wang, et al. proposed a series of indicators such as average production length and relative upstream degree [12] to measure the production structure of each economy. Xu et al. combined the input–output model with the social network analysis method to measure the economic structure in the global economic system [13]. Yang et al. established a community detection optimization algorithm based on biogeography to find the community structure in the network [14]. Piccardi et al. evaluated the importance of communities in the world input–output network based on the random walk Markov chain method [15]. Guan et al. established a global industrial resource competition network model based on the bibliographic coupling method to analyze the competitive relationship between industrial sectors [16]. Xing et al. used the Markov process to measure the degree of globalization [17] and industrial influence [18] of the industrial sectors and based on the Revised Floyd–Warshall Algorithm (RFWA), proposed the Strongest Relevance Path Length (SRPL) algorithm to measure the pivotability degree [19] of the input–output relationship between sectors and connectivity and tightness [20] of the value chain network. At the same time, the competition and cooperation relations [21] between industrial sectors are also described through the citation network, but the relationship generated in the citation network lacks precise similarity.
In the first section of the paper, the development status of the BRI and the research on the input–output relationship between various industrial sectors on the GVC are presented. In the second section, the Global Production Capacity Collaboration Network (GPCCN) model is formulated. The model is based on the bipartite graph theory, on the resource allocation process and on the selection of research data. In the third section are introduced two indicators: the Collaborative Opportunity Index (COI) and the Collaborative Threat Index (CTI) from the national and sectoral levels based on the GPCCN model. The indicators measure the state of cooperation between countries and sectors, and at the same time, measure the correlation between COI and Competitive Strength Index (CSI) at the national level. In the fourth section, scenario simulations are carried out in order to forecast the potential and trends of international capacity cooperation within Asian, European, and African nations related to the Belt and Road Initiative. In the fifth section, the laws and reasons for the differences in cooperation among BRI-related nations are explained. In the last section, the main contributions of the paper are summarized and some new directions for the research are indicated.

2. Methodology

2.1. Resource Allocation Process

In a bipartite graph G the node set V is divided in two nonempty sets P and O with no intersection in between. Let G = P , O , E be a bipartite graph where E is the set of edges, P = P 1 , P 2 , , P n and O = O 1 , O 2 , , O m are the two sets of nodes. Of course, the intersection of P and O is empty. The nodes from the set P will be called participants and the nodes from the set O will be called objects. We take an example to describe its topological structure, where n = 9 and m = 3 , as shown in Figure 1.
In Figure 1, the squares in the upper part are the objects (denoted by O 1 ,   O 2 ,   , O 3 ), while the circles below are the participants (denoted by P 1 ,   P 2 ,   ,   P 9 ), and the edges in black belong to the two-mode network. It is more than common to project a two-mode network onto one kind of node, and the resulting edges have been granted the property to reflect a certain relationship. As we can see, the edges in red or green coming from the projection of two black edges constitute two one-mode networks, namely Complete Object Subgraph and Complete Participant Subgraph. Sometimes, there should be weights on the edges, which are gained through the definition of co-occurrences and used to measure the potential relationship of two participants in the same object, or that of two objects in the same participant. For instance, we can quantify the relationship between two scientists (participants) by the number of papers (objects) they wrote together; similarly, we can also quantify that of two papers (objects) by the number of the same scientists (participants) they have [22]. However, refined calculation on the weight of a projected edge is very difficult, and we must use a specific method to solve a specific problem.
The bipartite graph has a wide application in complex network analysis, including cooperation and competition networks (mainly dealt with through affiliation networks), for either cooperation or competition is the common existence in social networks consisting of units of people. Padrón believed that this modeling process could bring distinctive simulation on the potential cooperation or competition relation [23]. In the field of GVC-related studies, scholars and politicians all want to figure out the inter-country and inter-industry competition and collaboration for the purposes of academic research and policymaking. We have done a lot of work in the research of industrial competition [24,25,26], so we want to focus on the other side of it. If limited industrial resources lead to competition among downstream sectors, then limited market demand leads to cooperation among upstream sectors. Therefore, with the purpose of extracting the inter-industry collaborative relations, the Resource Allocation Process (RAP) is also adopted in this paper as the algorithm of projection [27]. The following is the specific derivation process.
Let f : O P + be a function such that f O h = 1 for all h in 1 , 2 , , m . Firstly, the initial resources needed by the h -th object is f O h 0 . We assume that the O P primary distribution of initial demands is equal, as shown in Figure 2.
The resources demand on the j -th node in P is:
f P j = h = 1 m a j h f O h K O h
where, K O h is the degree of O h , a j h is a n × m matrix:
a j h = 1                   P j O h E 0                 o t h e r w i s e
With all the demand signals converging to set O , the required resources of objects are shown in Figure 3. Note that, the assumption of equal distribution still holds for the secondary distribution.
The satisfied demand on the resources of node O h is:
f O h = j = 1 n a j h f P j K P j = j = 1 n a j h K P j k = 1 m a j k f O k K O k
Obviously, the satisfied demand for objects is not consistent with their initial one, i.e., f O h f O k , which means their status is different in the complete participant subgraph. This difference cannot be reflected just via the co-occurrence projection. Thus, the hidden collaborative relations among them can be expressed by:
f O h = k = 1 m w h k O f O k
where, w h k O   is the measurement of difference produced in the process of two-times resources allocations, and describes the advantage of O h in cooperating with O k to allocate resources of their common participants.
The w h k O in Equation (4) could be written as:
w h k O = 1 K O k j = 1 n a j h a j k K P j
Finally, we get the matrix W O = ( w h k O ) m × m as the weight set of complete participant subgraph through RAP approach, as shown in Figure 4.
Furthermore, in the weighted two-mode network, Equation (5) is expanded to another form by replacing the adjacency matrix A = a j h with weight set W = w j h :
w h k O = 1 S O k k = 1 n w j h w j k S P j
where S O k is the strength of O k , i.e., S O k = j = 1 n w j k ; S P j is the strength of P j , S P j = h = 1 m w j h ; w j h and w j k are the weights on edges connecting O h and O k with P j , respectively.
Therefore, the RAP approach reflects the scarcity of participant nodes resources and limits the resource allocation from participant nodes to object nodes. At the same time, the formation of a complete object subgraph through participant nodes mapping can clearly reflect cooperation relation between various industrial sectors on the GVC, thus providing a method for measuring the potential and trends of international capacity cooperation within Asian, European, and African nations related to the Belt and Road Initiative, respectively.

2.2. Database Selection

As we all know, BRI is a hotly debated topic in the field of the global economy, as well as GVC, which is a global development strategy proposed by the Chinese government involving infrastructure construction and investments in 152 countries and international organizations in Asia, Europe, Africa, the Middle East, and the Americas. “Belt” refers to the overland routes for road and rail transportation, called “the Silk Road Economic Belt”; “Road” refers to the sea routes or the 21st Century Maritime Silk Road. From the Chinese government’s international viewpoints on politics and economy, BRI is supposed to be the developing blueprint that meets the demands of relevant countries and delivers mutual benefits. However, some observers see it as a push for Chinese dominance in global affairs with a China-centered trading network, and even consider BRI as a potential threat to countries involved [28].
For now (2021), there are 66 countries (including China) along the Road and Belt. In ICIO databases, Eora26 has the widest coverage of countries, including all the countries except Palestine, and that is why we use it to build Eora 26-Based Global Industrial Value Chain Network (GIVCN–Eora26) models and conduct an empirical analysis of capacity cooperation between BRI countries. In the analysis process, we further divide these countries into three categories according to their continents, namely Asian nations, European nations, and African nations, as shown in Table 1, Table 2 and Table 3.
With the proposal and promotion of BRI, China is playing a leading role in the Regional Value Chain (RVC) networks constituted of Asian, European, and African nations. Accordingly, the global cooperation with China on production capacity will impact the economic development of BRI-related nations. Therefore, it is necessary to comparatively and empirically analyze how their status will change on the GVC and what kinds of influence the BRI will bring to them.
Before doing this, we need to extract three sub-networks out of the GVICN–Eora26 model, i.e., GIVCN–Eora26–AS, GIVCN–Eora26–EU, and GIVCN–Eora26–AF, reflecting the ICIO relations between China and other economies, respectively. Their brief topological structures in six different periods are as shown in Figure 5, Figure 6 and Figure 7.
To explore the core structure of the original network, this paper takes three sorts of GVICN–Eora26 models based on the ICIO databases of the latest version for example, which are GIVCN–Eora26–AS, GIVCN–Eora26–EU, and GIVCN–Eora26–AF, and statistics for the structural properties of three sub-networks after pruning [29] include number of edges E , average distance d , mean node degree k , clustering coefficient C and the degree–degree correlation from out-degree source nodes to in-degree sink ones r out , in are shown in Table 4, Table 5 and Table 6.
We observe the changing trends of the network backbone over a 25-year period and find that: if the information of edge weight is not considered, all three sub-networks of GIVCN–Eora26 models own a high density of connections, which may give them access to the shorter average path and the greater clustering coefficient (see Table 4, Table 5 and Table 6). Therefore, both are strong evidence that these models belong to the small-world network, i.e., China has a great foundation to carry out BRI–related trade with these regions.

2.3. Network Modeling

To reproduce the collaborative relations between industrial sectors on the GVC, we design a generation algorithm based on RAP approach:
w i j O = 1 w j k = 1 N w i k w j k w k , i j 0 , i = j
where, w i k   ( w j k ) is the i -th ( j -th) row and k -th column element of the adjacency matrix of GIVCN model, representing the upstream sector i ( j ) and downstream sector k respectively; w k is the gross inputs of downstream sector k , and it is numerically equal to the in-degree strength of node k in GIVCN model, say w k = S I N k = i = 1 N w i k ; w j is the gross outputs of upstream sector j , i.e., w j = S O U T j = k = 1 N w j k ; w i j O measures the collaborative attraction from the sector i to j ; upstream sectors i and j are connected by an edge denoted by e i j O in the complete participant subgraph.
Finally, the edge set E O = e i j O and weight set W O = ( w i j O ) reflect all the collaborative relations among sectors in the global production system. We name the graph G = V , E O , W O as the Global Production Capacity Collaboration Network (GPCCN). Accordingly, we separate three types of GPCCN–BRI models from the whole network, which are GPCCN–Eora26–AS, GPCCN–Eora26–EU, and GPCCN–Eora26–AF.

3. Measurement

According to our paper on the application of the complex network theory [18,30], network-based algorithms and indices have great potential to enhance the understanding of the industrial sector’s position and function, given the network-form architecture of GVC. The inter-industry collaboration status has been embodied in the GPCCN model, and out-strength and in-strength as simple yet important tools are hence introduced to quantify industrial sectors’ collaborative opportunity and threat on the GVC, based on which we further carry out econometric, static timing, and simulation analyses.

3.1. Sector-Level Indices

When discussing the cooperation relations in the GPCCN model, we define the sum of the collaborative attraction obtained from other sectors (out-strength) as one sector’s Collaborative Opportunity Index (COI), i.e., the greater the COI, the stronger the collaborative relations between this sector and the others. Additionally, the sum of the collaborative attraction is exerted to other sectors (in-strength) is defined as one sector’s Collaborative Threat Index (CTI). Once the collaboration degree declines, and the uncertainty of industrial development will go up, because a greater CTI indicates that the sector needs to rely on many collaborative relations to maintain its function and status on the GVC. Their statistical formula is as follows:
C O I i = S O U T i = j = 1 N w j i O
C T I i = S I N i = j = 1 N w i j O
As the counterparts of CSI and CWI, we are interested in the distribution and correlation of COI and CTI. As shown in Figure 8, the heavy-tailed distribution of COI for all sectors in GPCCN–Eora26–2015 also follows the levy-stable distribution, but that of CTI is mainly concentrated in a narrow numerical range. The heterogeneity of COI and the homogeneity of CTI together result in no strong correlation between them (Pearson correlation coefficient is only −0.435).
In our opinion, the collaborative opportunities brought by global economic integration to various countries are very different, while the threats of collaboration are almost the same. The fundamental reason is that today’s advanced information technology and convenient supply chains have greatly reduced the difficulty for the industrial sector to find partners.

3.2. Country-Level Indices

On the basis of COI and CTI, notions of National Collaborative Opportunity Index (NCOI) and National Collaborative Threat Index (NCTI) are here introduced:
N C O I u = i τ u C O I i
N C T I u = i τ u C T I i
where N C O I u and N C T I u are used to measure the collaborative opportunity and threat of country u .
Since the difference in collaborative threats is not obvious, we focus on the changes in the NCOIs of BRI-related nations. Table 7, Table 8 and Table 9 list six countries with the highest NCOI in three sub-networks from 1990 to 2015. Obviously, China’s NCOI rankings in the three sub-networks are constantly rising, which shows that the prospects for its cooperation with countries in multiple RVCs are as good as possible.

3.3. Correlation Analysis between Competitive Strengths and Collaborative Opportunities

Xing et al. [26] defined Competitive Strength Index (CSI) as the competitive pressure that an industrial sector imposes on others. By observing the relation of NCSI and NCOI in different years, we find that there is a very significant positive correlation between them, as is shown in Figure 9. In our opinion, the latter is the leading index of the former.
As is well known, vertical specialization and international trade are the foundation and embodiment of global economic integration. In most cases, one country/nation’s economic development is based on making full use of its own and the others’ resource endowments, so reaching a consensus is more important than creating a conflict of interest. The world of the 21st century has long since gotten rid of the colonial and semi-colonial development model. Each nation uses its comparative advantages to engage in economic and political games on the world stage. Therefore, we believe that the reason why countries/nations’ competitive strengths and collaborative opportunities are closely related is mainly because they first establish a connection with the world through cooperation, and then consolidate their industrial function and status on the GVC through competition.

4. Simulations

Three sets of scenario simulations have been designed to observe the effects on national collaborative opportunities of both China and main BRI-related nations under international trade fluctuation in GIVCN and GPCCN models. If the new trade policy was signed or the original trade one was withdrawn between two countries, there will be three possibilities for the volume of import and export trade between them as tariffs may change [30]:
Scenario I: X increases or decreases its export to Y while its counterpart remains stable.
Scenario II: Y increases or decreases its export to X while its counterpart remains stable.
Scenario III: Both parties increase or decrease its export to the counterpart simultaneously (there is no need to distinguish X and Y under this scenario).
Considering that the meaning of BRI is to promote interconnection and trade prosperity for all interested parties, we choose Scenario III as the only possibility. Then, simulations are carried out by increasing the volume of bilateral trade between two given nations from 0% (disruption of both import and export trades) of the initial value to 100% (gross value of trade in the ICIO table), and further up to 200% (both import and export trades doubled) in the specific GIVCN–BRI model, with every 10% as intervals. In the meanwhile, calculations on their NCOIs will be repeated in the corresponding GPCCN–BRI model, and simulation curves are acquired in this way for both parties of X and Y .
Despite trade volumes, we also need to consider the possible trade agreements, which have a more significant influence on international trade itself. We set three kinds of cases to observe how the collaborative status of China and BRI-related nations will change as shown in Figure 10.
Case A: China strengthens its trade collaboration with the others, respectively—As in the initial stage of BRI, China needs to establish mutually beneficial and collaborative relations with one country after another, in order to promote its transfer of excess production capacity.
Case B: Other nations bypass China to form an economic community—This is an undesirable situation for China since its economic development driven by foreign trade will be hindered, just like the TPP initiated by the United States.
Case C: All the nations strengthen the trade collaboration in between under a unified trade agreement—The newly formed RCV will be more beneficial to some nations than in other cases.
Based on these cases under Scenario III, this section lists the NCOI trends of the major economies (China and the top five countries in NCOI) in the GPCCN–BRI–2015 models with China as the core. As shown in Figure 11, Figure 12, Figure 13, Figure 14, Figure 15, Figure 16, Figure 17, Figure 18 and Figure 19, the slope of the simulation result curve represents the elasticity of industrial collaborative ability to changes in trade volume. We try to find a better solution for both China and BRI-related nations in consideration of a win-win outcome.

4.1. Simulation on Asian Nations

According to the simulation results in Figure 11, Figure 12 and Figure 13, we find that: (1) In Case A, China’s NCOI sharply increases as the volume of international trade goes up, while other countries decrease to varying degrees; (2) In Case B, NCOIs of China, Iran (slightly), and Singapore decrease, while Indonesia (sharply), Korea (sharply) and Thailand (slightly after the trade rate is positive) increase; (3) In Case C, NCOIs of China (sharply), Indonesia (sharply), and Korea increase, while Iran, Singapore (sharply), and Thailand decrease.
Figure 11. Influence on China and main Asian nations in Case A.
Figure 11. Influence on China and main Asian nations in Case A.
Systems 10 00012 g011
Figure 12. Influence on China and main Asian nations in Case B.
Figure 12. Influence on China and main Asian nations in Case B.
Systems 10 00012 g012
Figure 13. Influence on China and main Asian nations in Case C.
Figure 13. Influence on China and main Asian nations in Case C.
Systems 10 00012 g013
Next, we will specifically analyze the production capacity cooperation potential between China and major Asian countries.
Though hit by the financial crisis in 2008, Indonesia’s economy managed to maintain a relatively fast growth rate, being the largest and fastest growing in Southeast Asia. Yet in recent years, its economic growth has slowed due to the shrunk volume of imports and exports significantly affected by global demand and prices. As a large agricultural country, Indonesia is the third largest producer of rice and the second largest producer and exporter of palm oil in the world. In the industrial sector, it is dominated by mining, oil and gas, textile, and light industry. China and Indonesia are highly complementary in various fields of industrialization and enjoy a wide scope for cooperation. Not only does Indonesia have a strong willingness to cooperate with China in production capacity, but Chinese companies are also quite attracted to the potential market and fastest growing economy in the southeast region. Chinese investment in Indonesia has mainly taken advantage of its infrastructure needs and labor force, focusing on infrastructure construction, energy development, palm oil plantation industry, and labor-intensive manufacturing industries such as textiles and cell phone assembly.
As one of the major economies in Asia, Iran’s economic strength is second only to Saudi Arabia in the Middle East area, and its total population second only to Egypt, making it a pivotal regional power. The industrial structure of Iran is relatively simple, with the oil industry dominating the national economy. However, suffering from the long-lasting economic sanctions from Europe and the United States, its crude oil exports have been greatly restricted. The Iranian government has been increasing trade with other countries in recent years to revive the export trade volume, so as to free its economy from dependence on oil exports by increasing the income from non-oil products. China has been Iran’s top trading partner for eleven consecutive years, and there is great room for economic cooperation between the two countries. In the energy sector, with its abundant oil and gas reserves, Iran has prioritized the attraction of foreign investment and technology in the oil and gas sector, and meanwhile, China boasts advanced technology and rich experience in energy exploration, exploitation, and equipment export. In the field of infrastructure construction, the current focus of economic and trade cooperation between China and Iran is closely based on interconnection and international production capacity cooperation, carrying out the construction of infrastructure, steel, electricity, railroads, and other projects. In the field of trade, Iran has been able to play the role of a trade hub in Eurasia thanks to its advantages as a transportation hub and a major re-exporting country, and the established free trade zones and special economic zones in Iran have provided convenient conditions and platforms for Chinese enterprises to make a direct investment. In the manufacturing sector, China is promoting the participation of China-invested enterprises with world-leading technologies in the construction of Iran’s high-tech industries, such as high-speed rail, satellite, communications, and nuclear power, to meet the huge demand for manufacturing products in Iran’s domestic market. Overall, the economies of China and Iran are highly complementary. As the BRI progresses, cooperation between the two countries in energy, infrastructure, transportation, communications, machinery manufacturing, and agriculture will be further deepened.
Korea witnessed an economic boom since the 1970s, and then was hit by the Asian financial crisis in 1997, dragging its economy into a stage of medium-rate growth. Due to the limited natural resources, its industrial structure is dominated by manufacturing and services industries. Its manufacturing industry is mainly technology- and knowledge-intensive, and has strong international competitiveness in shipbuilding, automobiles, electronics, and steel, yet the industrial materials of which are all dependent on imports. With China being Korea’s top trading partner, the two countries enjoy broad prospects for cooperation in the manufacturing sector. As China’s industrial structure gradually upgrades, China and Korea are mainly trading on high value-added electromechanical products, and the trading structures of the two countries are highly similar. The establishment of China–Korea FTA will further deepen the trade and investment between the two countries, form strong synergy in manufacturing industries, and become a new growth engine for multilateral cooperation in the Asian region, regional trade markets, and regional industrial development. China and Korea can cooperate more extensively in the future in emerging industries such as the Internet, and also in energy development, finance, and power grid construction in the Asian region.
With its well-developed services sector, Singapore is the fourth largest international financial center and the third largest foreign exchange trading center in the world. The three sectors account for less than 1%, 30%, and 70% of GDP, respectively. Singapore’s unique geographical location has contributed to its status as a world powerhouse in the marine industry; high-quality logistics infrastructure wins it a reputation for reliability and speed of delivery; world-class port and airfreight facilities, excellent warehousing and delivery channels, and unparalleled regional and global connectivity gain it a firm foothold in global sourcing and integrated manufacturing. In terms of existing Sino–Singaporean economic and trade cooperation, Chinese investment in Singapore has seen a surge in recent years, mainly in contract labor, transportation, construction, energy, and other areas. Combined with Singapore’s economic situation and the fruits of Sino–Singaporean economic and trade exchanges, Singapore has a limited role in absorbing and converting China’s excess capacity in industries owing to its high stage of industrialization and services-dominated industrial structure. However, the two countries have potentials for cooperation in capital-intensive manufacturing and services industries. Chinese enterprises can invest in high-end enterprises in Singapore’s manufacturing industry chain to learn from its advanced management experience and technology; additionally, they can take advantage of Singapore’s convenient transportation conditions and its status as an international financial center to develop trade and financial services, etc.
Located in the center of Southeast Asia, Thailand stands at the natural intersection of the ASEAN market and will become a booster rocket for the 21st Century Maritime Silk Road thanks to its relatively sound infrastructure. Thailand’s economy is highly export-dependent, with exports accounting for about 2/3 of its GDP. Agriculture is the country’s traditional economic sector, with agricultural products being one of the main sources of foreign exchange earnings. Thailand is the only net exporter of food in Asia, living up to its reputation as the “breadbasket of Southeast Asia”. Among its top 10 export commodities, six are agricultural products, accounting for about 40% of the total export value. According to Chinese customs statistics, the total bilateral trade volume between China and Thailand accounts for 1/6 of the total bilateral trade between China and ten ASEAN countries, making Thailand China’s fourth largest trading partner among ASEAN countries. Meanwhile, China is Thailand’s largest trading partner, the largest source of imports, and the largest export destination. The trading structure between China and Thailand has been optimized in recent years, depicting a pattern featuring complementary advantages and mutual benefits. Among all the trading products, electrical and mechanical products take the largest share, and the proportion of plastics and their products is also increasing.

4.2. Simulation on European Nations

According to the simulation results in Figure 14, Figure 15 and Figure 16, we find that: (1) In Case A, China’s NCOI sharply increases as the volume of international trade goes up, while other countries decrease to varying degrees; (2) In Case B, NCOIs of China, Austria, and Poland (slightly) decrease, while Italy (sharply), Russia, and Serbia (sharply before the trade rate is positive and then slightly) increase; (3) In Case C, NCOIs of China (sharply), Italy, Russia (slightly), and Serbia (before the trade rate 60%) increase, while Austria (sharply), Poland, and Serbia (after the trade rate 60%) decrease.
Figure 14. Influence on China and main European nations in Case A.
Figure 14. Influence on China and main European nations in Case A.
Systems 10 00012 g014
Figure 15. Influence on China and main European nations in Case B.
Figure 15. Influence on China and main European nations in Case B.
Systems 10 00012 g015
Figure 16. Influence on China and main European nations in Case C.
Figure 16. Influence on China and main European nations in Case C.
Systems 10 00012 g016
Next, we will specifically analyze the production capacity cooperation potential between China and major European countries.
Lying at the south-end of Central Europe, Austria is an important transportation hub in Europe, with an economy growing faster than the EU average. Austria boasts an ample supply of mineral, forest, and hydraulic resources; in particular, its forest coverage accounts for nearly 50% of its total area. In recent years, as Austria’s economy has been developing at a fast pace, the machinery industry is its largest industrial sector, its agriculture and tourism industries are well-developed, and the services industry occupies an important position. China is Austria’s most important trading partner in Asia. China’s rising living standards are attracting more and more Austrian companies to make investments, encouraging Sino–Austrian bilateral trade to continuously grow. With the unique advantages in the metal industry, mechanical engineering, food, chemical, automotive, and environmental protection industries, Austria exports high-tech products to China, and thus becomes an important technology importing source for China in the EU. Besides, Austria’s position as a hub for China’s interconnectivity with the CEE region is also noteworthy. In general, given the highly complementary bilateral trade, the cooperation between Austria and China in the fields of trade, finance, infrastructure construction, and culture will unlock significant potential.
Italy is situated on the northern coast of the Mediterranean Sea in southern Europe. It is the second largest manufacturing country in the EU after Germany, the fourth largest economy in Europe and the eighth largest in the world. Known as the “Kingdom of SMEs”, the number of Italy’s small and medium-sized enterprises accounts for more than 98% of the total number of enterprises. However, in the short supply of natural resources, the country’s oil and gas production can only meet a small portion of its domestic market demand. In addition, though being highly developed, its economy is facing unbalanced development, with a widening gap between the prosperous northern region and the relatively backward southern region, divided by the capital Rome. Italy was among the first batch of European countries to develop trade relations with China. The two countries signed a communiqué on the establishment of diplomatic relations as early as 1970. After the establishment of the China–Italy comprehensive strategic partnership in 2004, the economy and trade between the two countries has grown rapidly. As of 2018, Italy has become China’s fourth largest trading partner, third largest export market, and source of imports in the European Union; likewise, China is Italy’s top trading partner in Asia. Suffice it to say that the BRI between China and Italy can help bring into play the comparative advantages of both sides. To be specific, Italian companies have comparative advantages in high-end manufacturing and services industries, design, aerospace, biomedicine, etc., but lack capital liquidity, which can be complemented by Chinese companies which are seeking to transform and upgrade their value chains with relatively sufficient funds.
Located in Central Europe and south of the Baltic Sea, Poland is the largest and most populous country in Central and Eastern Europe. Poland’s unique geographical advantage guarantees its important role in the Belt and Road. China and Poland have planned to use Poland as a hub for new logistics routes to build a logistics center in Central and Eastern Europe, thereby promoting the inflow and entry of Polish and Chinese products to the European region. As China’s BRI and interconnectivity strategy progresses, a series of China–Europe freight trains by way of Poland have been launched to expand cooperation in trade and investment between the two countries. The economies of China and Poland are highly complementary and have the potential to develop together in the fields of infrastructure and high-tech industries, despite some obstacles such as limited trade volume, insufficient mutual investment, and a small number of large-scale cooperation projects, etc.
Russia, the largest country in the world, straddles the Eurasian continent and includes both the eastern half of Europe and the western part of Asia. Russia’s industrial structure is homogeneous and its economic structure is overly dependent on energy exports. Its secondary industry is supported by heavy and chemical industries, while agriculture and services are relatively underdeveloped. China and Russia are each other’s largest neighbors, and their unique geopolitical advantages facilitate economic and trade cooperation in the border areas of both countries. For a long time, China and Russia have been each other’s important trade partners. China has been Russia’s largest trading partner for eleven consecutive years, while Russia is the tenth largest trading partner of China. The trading structure of the two countries reflects complementarity. China imports Russia minerals, wood and wooden products, and other less processed primary products, while exporting to Russia electromechanical products, textiles, and raw materials; the various products in which the two countries have significant comparative advantages basically do not overlap.
Located in southeastern Europe, Serbia is a landlocked country in the middle of the Balkans that suffered severe damage to its industrial facilities in the 1990s when it was bombed by NATO during the Kosovo War. In the 21st century, with the introduction of privatization, Serbia’s economy has gradually recovered, but the overall economic level is below the European average. The main economic obstacles are the high unemployment rate and large trade deficits. Serbia was the first country in Central and Eastern Europe to establish a strategic partnership with China, and since 2006 China has been Serbia’s top trading partner in Asia and the fifth largest trading partner in the world. At present, though developing at a relatively fast pace, its overall economy is still underdeveloped, especially when it comes to the outdated infrastructure. In the future, China and Serbia have great potential for cooperation in infrastructure construction, energy, chemical industry, mineral products, and other fields.

4.3. Simulation on African Nations

According to the simulation results in Figure 17, Figure 18 and Figure 19, we find that: (1) In Case A, China’s NCOI sharply increases as the volume of international trade goes up, while Algeria, Angola (sharply when the trade rate is very low and then slightly), Kenya, Morocco, and South Africa decrease; (2) In Case B, NCOIs of China (slightly), Angola (slightly), and Kenya decrease, while Algeria (slightly), Morocco (slightly), and South Africa increase; (3) In Case C, NCOIs of China (sharply) and South Africa (slightly) increase, while Algeria, Angola (sharply when the trade rate is very low and then slightly), Kenya, and Morocco decrease.
Figure 17. Influence on China and main African nations in Case A.
Figure 17. Influence on China and main African nations in Case A.
Systems 10 00012 g017
Figure 18. Influence on China and main African nations in Case B.
Figure 18. Influence on China and main African nations in Case B.
Systems 10 00012 g018
Figure 19. Influence on China and main African nations in Case C.
Figure 19. Influence on China and main African nations in Case C.
Systems 10 00012 g019
Next, we will specifically analyze the production capacity cooperation potential between China and major African countries.
Located in northwest Africa, Algeria is the largest country in terms of area and the fourth largest economy in Africa. Rich in underground oil and gas resources, Algeria is the second largest gas exporter in the world, with the fifth largest reserves, so the oil and gas industry underpins its economic development. The industrial cooperation between China and Algeria can be mutually beneficial. Firstly, as Algeria’s largest source of import, China mainly imports energy and mineral resources such as iron ore and LPG from Algeria, and invests in oil and gas, mining, aerospace, nuclear energy, and other fields. Secondly, the cooperation between China and Algeria in high-tech fields has strongly contributed to the economic growth and industrial development of both countries. Thirdly, China’s overseas infrastructure capacity, which is high-level and cost-effective, can help build infrastructure such as roads, railroads, ports, and airports in Algeria.
Situated in sub-Saharan Africa, Angola is the fourth largest economy and one of the largest capital attracting countries in Africa. It has ample oil, natural gas, and mineral resources, and also a large amount of hydroelectric power, as well as resources of agriculture, forestry, and fishery. Its hydropower generation accounts for 3/4 of the country’s total power generation. Angola’s economy is mainly based on agriculture and minerals, and oil, with oil being the mainstay industry. Although it has taken effective measures to promote economic diversification and reduce the dependence of the national economy on the oil industry, the country is still struggling with a low level of economic development and backward infrastructure. China’s imports from Angola mainly include crude oil, natural gas, and other natural resources, and Angola’s imports from China mainly include electromechanical, steel, automobile, and other products. China actively participates in investment in Angola and has obvious competitive advantages in infrastructure construction such as railroads, in addition to many other fields such as oil, construction, power grid, and telecommunication. In recent years, the two countries are making great efforts to promote capacity cooperation in areas such as electricity, ports, highways, agriculture, and manufacturing.
Kenya has the most developed and complete industrial sector in East Africa. Agriculture, services, and manufacturing are the three pillars of Kenya’s national economy, and the oil, mineral extraction, agriculture, livestock and fisheries, and tourism industries are also developing well. Its natural port Mombasa connects East and Central African countries, with good water transport conditions. Kenya boasts well-operating infrastructure in communication, transportation, resources, and energy, rich natural resources, and huge market potential. However, Kenya’s industrial sectors and regions varies greatly in terms of the level of development, so it needs to upgrade its industrialization development with reference to the success stories of other countries. China is Kenya’s largest source of imports, and also has a number of maturely developed industries and redundant production capacity. China is now more than ready to make overseas investments and expand exports while sharing its best practices. China and Kenya enjoy high economic coupling—the capital, technology, and experience of the former can be fully utilized by the latter. The cooperation between the two countries will undoubtedly bring about mutual benefit and win-win.
Morocco is a coastal Arabian country in northwestern Africa and a hub connecting Europe, the Middle East, and Africa. Morocco’s economy ranks fifth in Africa and third in North Africa. Phosphate exports, tourism, and remittances are the main pillars supporting Morocco’s economy. It has a good foundation in agriculture but is not self-sufficient in food. Its rich fishery resources generate the highest production in Africa. But its industry is underdeveloped. The Moroccan government is committed to expanding domestic demand, strengthening infrastructure construction, supporting traditional industries such as textiles and tourism, developing new industries such as information and clean energy, actively attracting foreign investment, and promoting economic growth. As one of the first Arab countries to establish diplomatic relations with China, Morocco’s superior geographical location, stable political environment, and perfect economic governance system provide conditions for further economic and trade cooperation between China and Morocco, and also serve as a bridge for Chinese enterprises to explore the African and European markets. In recent years, trade and investment between the two sides have continued to thrive, and production capacity cooperation in fisheries, infrastructure, telecommunications, automobiles, and other fields has been deepened.
As the second largest economy in Africa, South Africa is an important member of multilateral organizations such as BRICS, G20, and the United Nations. It maintains close relations with China in international organizations and multilateral mechanisms and is considered as China’s important strategic partner. South Africa has abundant natural resources, low labor costs, and relatively complete infrastructure in transportation, electricity and information and communication. Mining and manufacturing are the most important pillar industries in its national economy. The cooperation between China and South Africa in the fields of manufacturing, investment, and trade is flourishing and of great significance. First, South Africa’s manufacturing development has lagged in the past 20 years, and much of the manufacturing industry has been replaced by imports, mainly due to insufficient technology reserves, high factor costs, and insufficient economies of scale. The in-depth cooperation between South Africa and China in the manufacturing sector will enhance its own technological level and international competitiveness. Secondly, South Africa is China’s largest trading partner and the most important investment destination in Africa, and China’s investment in South Africa has promoted the development of its special economic zones. Thirdly, South Africa is now shifting from a mining and manufacturing-dependent economy to a technology- and services-oriented economy, whose domestic market can be further vitalized through its trade with China.

5. Results and Discussions

We try to explain the laws and reasons for the variation of collaboration among BRI-related nations from the following three perspectives.
Firstly, China can transfer its excess production capacity to other countries on the RCV through BRI, and then optimize its own industrial structure to move to the middle and high end of multiple IVCs, thereby enhancing its collaborative ability on the GVC, which is reflected by a substantial increase in the NCOI in Case A and Case B.
Secondly, by strengthening regional cooperation, some nations have made up for the shortcomings of their own industrial structure layout to some extent and enhanced the production transformation capacity within their NVCs. Among them: Satisfying Effect is observed when the collaborative potential of nations with a single industrial structure is satisfied, which is manifested as a decrease in NCOI; Incentive Effect is observed when the collaborative potential of nations with a diversified industrial structure is further stimulated, which is displayed as a rise in NCOI.
Thirdly, under the combined effect of satisfying effect and incentive effect, some nations (e.g., Thailand in Asia, Serbia in Europe, Angola in Africa) have more varying NCOI trends under different cooperation strategies—either rise or fall, which requires to be analyzed specifically on the causes at the sectoral level.
Regional collaboration can promote relevant economies to carry out production capacity cooperation, make full use of their comparative advantages to embed in the RVC network, and gradually achieve a rise in the GVC network. From a long-term perspective, the BRI initiated by China will help GVC restructure toward a win-win cooperation. In this chapter, our study provides a reference for how China can better implement the BRI. For example, in its cooperation with Asia, where most countries are rich in oil and gas and mineral resources, but have poor industrial systems, backward development technologies, and insufficient development capacity, China can cooperate with them in key areas such as oil and gas and mineral resources via helping them establish sound industrial, transportation, and infrastructure systems. In its cooperation with Europe, given the rapid development of the “construction” sector, China can take advantage of the rapid development cycle of European infrastructure, and use its experiences in rail–road industry to tap into the European rail transportation market. Meanwhile, China should also focus on the cooperation with European HMT sectors. In the cooperation with Africa, China should adhere to the humanitarian spirit, guide African industries to be more scientific and internationalized, and bring into play Africa’s comparative advantages in the GVC network.
In the context of drastic changes in the international environment, the traditional countermeasures to the systemic crisis of the national economy have lost efficacy; and the priority is to optimize and upgrade industrial structure. With its complete industrial chain and supply chain and the vast domestic market, China should avoid the “industrial hollowing-out” similar to Japan, the United States, and other countries. From the perspective of economic security, while continuously encourage industrial sectors to “go global”, China needs to respond to its dwindled competitiveness in the whole industrial chain and strengthen independent innovation to supplement the shortcomings. Against the backdrop of GVC reconstruction in the post-pandemic era, China shall explore a new development model, use the domestically economic circulation to drive the internationally economic circulation, take the BRI as the focus, and seize new foreign trade opportunities brought by RCEP. By doing so, it will embrace strengthened ties with other countries, and better integration into the GVC with a higher level of openness. This will be a favorable measure to promote global economic integration and counteract reverse globalization.

6. Conclusions

This paper measures the collaborative relations between industrial sectors and simulates that between countries in consideration of both the actual demand from downstream sectors and the potential industrial-capacity cooperation from upstream ones. We believe this chapter will be helpful to understand the trend of economic globalization and regional economic cooperation. Contributions of this paper are as follows:
(1)
Establish the GPCCN model to embody the collaborative relations among industrial sectors. In consideration of the scarcity of productive capacities, we use bipartite graphs to distinguish the roles of industrial sectors on the GVC as upstream and downstream ones. Then, we extract the collaborative relations hidden in the IO/ICIO table via RAP approach, transforming the GIVCN model into the GPCCN model. The latter depicts collaborations among countries and their industrial sectors.
(2)
Propose network-based measurement tools to reveal the collaboration status on the sectoral level and the national level. After getting the collaborative relations among industrial sectors, the summation of the collaborative attraction that one imposes on others is defined as the COI, and the summation of collaborative attraction that one receives from others is defined as the CTI, which are the out-strengths S O U T and in-strengths S I N of nodes, respectively, in the GPCCN model. As well, NCOI and NCTI standing for the country-level cooperation competence can be further calculated. Of course, we pay more attention on the economies’ collaborative opportunity measured by NCOI in the empirical analysis.
(3)
Simulate collaborative opportunities of BRI-related nations. GVC is the most sophisticated economic system, whose relatedness, heterogeneity, and diversity deserve more attention from the relevant authorities when making international trade policies. Only by studying GVC can China and its trade partners benefit from the BRI. We believe the simulation framework in this paper possesses considerable reference value and will be a guide for analyzing globalization issues with physical statistics.
In this paper, we set three kinds of cases to observe how the collaborative status of China and BRI-related nations will change. The premise of global cooperation on production capacity is the complementarity and coupling of the two cooperating countries on the GVC, emphasizing the utilization of their respective advantages in technology, capital, and resources to achieve mutual benefits and win-win situations.
Empirical analysis has shown that China’s BRI has indeed brought dividends to nations along the route. Especially for some less developed countries in Asia, Europe, and Africa, continued industrial-capacity cooperation with China in key areas has significantly improved their ability of globally synergic production. This further proves that BRI can provide good development opportunities for relevant countries through complementing advantages, resource sharing, and capacity cooperation, and can help achieve common prosperity.
In the next stage, more detailed analysis on the trade between China and BRI-related nations should be carried out from the perspective of their market sizes and industrial layouts.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, L.X. and J.G.; methodology, L.X. and D.W.; software, L.X. and D.W.; validation, D.W. and C.J.; formal analysis, D.W., C.L. and C.J.; investigation, D.W. and C.L.; resources, D.W.; data curation, D.W.; writing—original draft preparation, L.X., D.W. and C.L.; writing—review and editing, L.X., D.W., C.L. and C.J.; visualization, D.W.; supervision, L.X. and J.G.; project administration, L.X.; funding acquisition, L.X. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71971006, 71774008), Humanities and Social Science Foundation of Ministry of Education of the People’s Republic of China (Grant No. 19YJCGJW014).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study are openly available in The Eora Global Supply Chain Database, https://worldmrio.com/ access on 1 December 2021.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Jin, L. The “New Silk Road” Initiative: China’s Marshall Plan? Int. Stud. 2015, 165, 88–99. [Google Scholar]
  2. Zhang, Y.; Yu, J.; Li, D. Measuring and Analyzing the Trade Cost Elasticity between China and Countries of “One Belt, One Road”: Based on Translog Gravity Model. World Econ. Stud. 2018, 289, 56–58. [Google Scholar]
  3. Ramasamy, B.; Yeung, M.C. China’s one belt one road initiative: The impact of trade facilitation versus physical infrastructure on exports. World Econ. 2019, 42, 1673–1694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Hsu, L. Asean and the Belt and Road Initiative: Trust-building in Trade and Investment. China World 2020, 3, 2050002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Xu, P.; Cheng, Q. Economic Growth Effects on B&R Sci-Tech Cooperation. J. Financ. Econ. 2020, 5, 140–154. [Google Scholar]
  6. Wen, S.; Zhang, Y. Financial Development, FDI Spillover and Economic Growth Efficiency: An Empirical Study of the Countries Along the “One Belt and One Road”. World Econ. Stud. 2020, 11, 41–50. [Google Scholar]
  7. Leontief, W.; Dietzenbacher, E.; Lahr, M. Wassily Leontief and Input-Output Economics; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  8. Raa, T.T. The Economics of Input-Output Analysis; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  9. Raa, T.T. Input-Output Economics: Theory and Applications; World Scientific: Singapore, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  10. Hummels, D.; Ishii, J.; Yi, K.M. The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in World Trade. J. Int. Econ. 2001, 54, 75–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Fally, T. On the Fragmentation of Production in the US; University of Colorado Working Paper; University of Colorado: Boulder, CO, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  12. Wang, Z.; Wei, S.J.; Yu, X.; Zhu, K. Characterizing Global Value Chains: Production Length and Upstreamness; NBER Working Papers; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  13. Xu, M.; Ling, S. Input–output networks offer new insights of economic structure. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2019, 527, 121178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Yang, B.; Cheng, W.; Hu, X.; Zhu, C.; Yu, X.; Li, X.; Huang, T. Seeking community structure in networks via biogeography-based optimization with consensus dynamics. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2019, 527, 121188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Piccardi, C.; Riccaboni, M.; Tajoil, L.; Zhu, Z. Random walks on the world input–output network. J. Complex Netw. 2018, 6, 187–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Guan, J.; Xu, X.; Xing, L. Analysis of inter-country input-output table based on bibliographic coupling network: How industrial sectors on the GVC compete for production resources. Int. J. Mod. Phys. B Condens. Matter Phys. 2018, 32, 1850063. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Xing, L.; Guan, J.; Wu, S. Measuring the impact of final demand on global production system based on Markov process. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2018, 502, 148–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Xing, L.; Dong, X.; Guan, J. Global Industrial Impact Coefficient Based on Random Walk Process and Inter-Country Input-Output Table. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2017, 471, 576–591. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Xing, L.; Han, Y.; Wang, D. Measuring economies’ pivotability on the global value chain under the perspective of inter-country input–output network. Mod. Phys. Lett. B 2021, 35, 2150289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Xing, L.; Dong, X.; Guan, J.; Qiao, X. Betweenness centrality for similarity-weight network and its application to measuring industrial sectors’ pivotability on the global value chain. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2019, 516, 19–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Xing, L. Analysis of inter-country input-output table based on citation network: How to measure the competition and collaboration between industrial sectors on the global value chain. PLoS ONE 2017, 12, e0184055. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  22. Newman, M.E.J. The structure of scientific collaboration networks. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2001, 98, 404–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Padrón, B.; Nogales, M.; Traveset, A. Alternative approaches of transforming bimodal in-to unimodal mutualistic networks. The usefulness of preserving weighted infor-mation. Basic Appl. Ecol. 2011, 12, 713–721. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Xing, L.; Guan, J.; Dong, X.; Wu, S. Understanding the Competitive Advantage of TPP-Related Nations from an Econophysics Perspective: Influence Caused by China and the United States. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2018, 502, 164–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Guan, J.; Xu, X.; Wu, S.; Xing, L. Measurement and Simulation of the Relatively Competitive Advantages and Weaknesses between Economies Based on Bipartite Graph Theory. PLoS ONE 2018, 13, e0197575. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Xing, L.; Wang, D.; Li, Y.; Guan, J.; Dong, X. Simulation Analysis of the Competitive Status between China and Portuguese-Speaking Countries under the Background of One Belt and One Road Initiative. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2020, 539, 122895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Zhou, T.; Ren, J.; Medo, M.; Zhang, Y. Bipartite network projection and personal recommendation. Phys. Rev. E 2007, 76, 046115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  28. Chohan, U. What Is One Belt One Road? A Surplus Recycling Mechanism Approach; Social Science Electronic Publishing: Rochester, NY, USA, 2018; pp. 205–219. [Google Scholar]
  29. Xing, L.; Han, Y. Extracting the Backbone of Global Value Chain from High-Dimensional Inter-Country Input-Output Network. In Proceedings of the International Conference on Complex Networks and Their Applications, Madrid, Spain, 30 November–2 December 2021; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  30. Xing, L.; Ye, Q.; Guan, J. Spreading effect in industrial complex network based on revised structural holes theory. PLoS ONE 2016, 11, e0156270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
Figure 1. A two-mode network and its projection onto objects and participants.
Figure 1. A two-mode network and its projection onto objects and participants.
Systems 10 00012 g001
Figure 2. Primary distribution: initial demands from objects are equally sent to participants. Notes: For simplicity, we assume all objects here own an equal size of initial demands, i.e., f O h = 1 . As we can see, O 1 connects to P 1 , P 2 , P 3 , and P 4 , so K O 1 = 4 , a 11 = 1 , a 21 = 1 , a 31 = 1 , and a 41 = 1 . Within them, only P 4 is additionally connected to O 2 , so a 42 = 1 while K O 2 = 5 . Thus, f P 1 = 1 4 , f P 2 = 1 4 , f P 3 = 1 4 , and f P 4 = 1 4 + 1 5 = 9 20 .
Figure 2. Primary distribution: initial demands from objects are equally sent to participants. Notes: For simplicity, we assume all objects here own an equal size of initial demands, i.e., f O h = 1 . As we can see, O 1 connects to P 1 , P 2 , P 3 , and P 4 , so K O 1 = 4 , a 11 = 1 , a 21 = 1 , a 31 = 1 , and a 41 = 1 . Within them, only P 4 is additionally connected to O 2 , so a 42 = 1 while K O 2 = 5 . Thus, f P 1 = 1 4 , f P 2 = 1 4 , f P 3 = 1 4 , and f P 4 = 1 4 + 1 5 = 9 20 .
Systems 10 00012 g002
Figure 3. Secondary distribution: required resources from participants are equally allocated to objects. Notes: When a participant equally allocates its required resource to relevant objects, the secondary distribution depends on the number of relevant objects. Thus, the new amount of object’s satisfied demand is equal to the sum of required resources back from all its participants, e.g., f O 1 = f P 1 K P 1 + f P 2 K P 2 + f P 3 K P 3 + f P 4 K P 4 = 1 4 + 1 4 + 1 4 + 9 20 × 1 2 = 39 40 .
Figure 3. Secondary distribution: required resources from participants are equally allocated to objects. Notes: When a participant equally allocates its required resource to relevant objects, the secondary distribution depends on the number of relevant objects. Thus, the new amount of object’s satisfied demand is equal to the sum of required resources back from all its participants, e.g., f O 1 = f P 1 K P 1 + f P 2 K P 2 + f P 3 K P 3 + f P 4 K P 4 = 1 4 + 1 4 + 1 4 + 9 20 × 1 2 = 39 40 .
Systems 10 00012 g003
Figure 4. Collaborative relations reflected by complete participant subgraph. Notes: In (a), the matrix W O represents the linear relation between each object’s satisfied demand and initial demand, whose different values reflect their different status in the resource allocation process. Therefore, the weighted and directed graph in (b) embodies the unsymmetrically and unequally collaborative relations among three objects, while the values on the diagonal of matrix W O are useless. For example, according to Equation (5), the strength of cooperative relation from node O 2 to node O 3 is w 23 O = 1 k O 3 × a 62 a 63 k P 6 + a 72 a 73 k P 7 + a 82 a 83 k P 8 = 1 4 × 1 2 + 1 2 + 1 2 = 3 8 .
Figure 4. Collaborative relations reflected by complete participant subgraph. Notes: In (a), the matrix W O represents the linear relation between each object’s satisfied demand and initial demand, whose different values reflect their different status in the resource allocation process. Therefore, the weighted and directed graph in (b) embodies the unsymmetrically and unequally collaborative relations among three objects, while the values on the diagonal of matrix W O are useless. For example, according to Equation (5), the strength of cooperative relation from node O 2 to node O 3 is w 23 O = 1 k O 3 × a 62 a 63 k P 6 + a 72 a 73 k P 7 + a 82 a 83 k P 8 = 1 4 × 1 2 + 1 2 + 1 2 = 3 8 .
Systems 10 00012 g004
Figure 5. Topological structure of GIVCN–Eora26–AS models.
Figure 5. Topological structure of GIVCN–Eora26–AS models.
Systems 10 00012 g005
Figure 6. Topological structure GIVCN–Eora26–EU models.
Figure 6. Topological structure GIVCN–Eora26–EU models.
Systems 10 00012 g006
Figure 7. Topological structure GIVCN–Eora26–AF models.
Figure 7. Topological structure GIVCN–Eora26–AF models.
Systems 10 00012 g007
Figure 8. Distribution and correlation of COI and CTI in GPCCN–Eora26-2015.
Figure 8. Distribution and correlation of COI and CTI in GPCCN–Eora26-2015.
Systems 10 00012 g008
Figure 9. Correlation of NCSI and NCOI in GPCCN–Eora26 models. Notes: We use different colors to distinguish the top 10 nations in GDP in each year. In addition, the size of each point is proportional to the GDP of the corresponding nation.
Figure 9. Correlation of NCSI and NCOI in GPCCN–Eora26 models. Notes: We use different colors to distinguish the top 10 nations in GDP in each year. In addition, the size of each point is proportional to the GDP of the corresponding nation.
Systems 10 00012 g009
Figure 10. Three cases of realization of collaboration at the scale of RVC. Notes: We take China and five main BRI-related nations in Asia as examples, and the basic settings are the same as those in the European group and African group.
Figure 10. Three cases of realization of collaboration at the scale of RVC. Notes: We take China and five main BRI-related nations in Asia as examples, and the basic settings are the same as those in the European group and African group.
Systems 10 00012 g010
Table 1. Thirty-six BRI-related Asian nations in Eora26.
Table 1. Thirty-six BRI-related Asian nations in Eora26.
Abbr.CountryAbbr.Country
AFGAfghanistanMNGMongolia
ARMArmeniaMMRMyanmar
AZEAzerbaijanNPLNepal
BHRBahrainOMNOman
BGDBangladeshPAKPakistan
BRNBruneiPHLPhilippines
KHMCambodiaQATQatar
GEOGeorgiaKORKorea
IDNIndonesiaSAUSaudi Arabia
IRNIranSGPSingapore
IRQIraqLKASri Lanka
KAZKazakhstanTJKTajikistan
KWTKuwaitTHAThailand
KGZKyrgyzstanTURTurkey
LAOLaosAREUAE
LBNLebanonUZBUzbekistan
MYSMalaysiaVNMViet Nam
MDVMaldivesYEMYemen
Table 2. Twenty-seven BRI-related European nations in Eora26.
Table 2. Twenty-seven BRI-related European nations in Eora26.
Abbr.CountryAbbr.Country
ALBAlbaniaLUXLuxembourg
AUTAustriaMLTMalta
BLRBelarusMNEMontenegro
BIHBosnia and HerzegovinaPOLPoland
BGRBulgariaPRTPortugal
HRVCroatiaMDAMoldova
CYPCyprusROURomania
CZECzech RepublicRUSRussia
ESTEstoniaSRBSerbia
GRCGreeceSVKSlovakia
HUNHungarySVNSlovenia
ITAItalyMKDTFYR Macedonia
LVALatviaUKRUkraine
LTULithuania
Table 3. Forty-four BRI-related African nations in Eora26.
Table 3. Forty-four BRI-related African nations in Eora26.
Abbr.CountryAbbr.Country
DZAAlgeriaMDGMadagascar
AGOAngolaMLIMali
BENBeninMRTMauritania
BWABotswanaMARMorocco
BDIBurundiMOZMozambique
CMRCameroonNAMNamibia
CPVCape VerdeNERNiger
TCDChadNGANigeria
COGCongoRWARwanda
CIVCote d’IvoireSENSenegal
CODDR CongoSYCSeychelles
DJIDjiboutiSLESierra Leone
EGYEgyptSOMSomalia
ETHEthiopiaZAFSouth Africa
GABGabonSDSSouth Sudan
GMBGambiaSUDSudan
GHAGhanaTGOTogo
GINGuineaTUNTunisia
KENKenyaUGAUganda
LSOLesothoTZATanzania
LBRLiberiaZMBZambia
LBYLibyaZWEZimbabwe
Table 4. Illustration of properties of the GIVCN–Eora26–AS models.
Table 4. Illustration of properties of the GIVCN–Eora26–AS models.
GIVCN–Eora26–AS199019952000200520102015
E 367366373363362362
d 4.7524.7604.5634.5464.3054.261
k 2.4802.4732.5202.4532.4462.446
C 0.5620.5730.5590.5640.5380.531
r o u t , i n 0.5170.5360.5420.5460.5020.489
Table 5. Illustration of properties of the GIVCN–Eora26–EU models.
Table 5. Illustration of properties of the GIVCN–Eora26–EU models.
GIVCN–Eora26–EU199019952000200520102015
E 272270273270277276
d 3.8973.9164.0574.1094.0394.021
k 2.4292.4112.4382.4112.4732.464
C 0.4930.5020.4740.4910.5240.517
r o u t , i n 0.4630.4530.4640.4660.4520.450
Table 6. Illustration of properties of the GIVCN–Eora26–AF models.
Table 6. Illustration of properties of the GIVCN–Eora26–AF models.
GIVCN–Eora26–AF199019952000200520102015
E 499492468482491480
d 5.1564.6064.3994.2494.1474.238
k 2.7722.7332.6002.6782.7282.667
C 0.5580.5920.6120.5900.6250.622
r o u t , i n 0.5400.4950.4570.4210.4280.441
Table 7. Top five BRI-related Asian nations’ NCOIs in GPCCN–Eora26 models.
Table 7. Top five BRI-related Asian nations’ NCOIs in GPCCN–Eora26 models.
Rank199019952000200520102015
CountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOI
1KOR37.992 KOR42.409 CHN49.699 CHN58.448 CHN74.766 CHN77.275
2THA33.407 CHN40.414 KOR41.204 KOR41.015 KOR38.313 KOR37.601
3UZB30.817 THA38.097 THA36.087 THA37.827 THA34.572 THA34.614
4CHN30.440 IDN31.849 IDN29.806 IRN31.301 IRN31.483 IRN31.685
5IRN28.771 SGP30.356 IRN29.651 SGP30.130 SGP29.588 SGP28.839
6IDN28.642 IRN29.870 SAU29.614 SAU28.181 IDN28.238 IDN27.845
Table 8. Top five BRI-related European nations’ NCOIs in GPCCN–Eora26 models.
Table 8. Top five BRI-related European nations’ NCOIs in GPCCN–Eora26 models.
Rank199019952000200520102015
CountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOI
1ITA60.996 ITA67.608 ITA68.827 ITA65.879 ITA63.145 ITA60.212
2RUS54.947 RUS53.430 RUS62.334 RUS56.649 RUS59.270 RUS59.401
3SRB30.137 AUT29.366 CHN31.486 CHN33.962 CHN43.633 CHN44.524
4UKR28.860 SRB29.084 GRC29.172 POL28.177 SRB33.570 SRB37.034
5AUT26.898 CHN28.763 AUT28.746 AUT27.745 POL28.585 POL28.103
6GRC24.992 GRC27.841 POL28.508 GRC27.639 AUT26.809 AUT26.274
Table 9. Top five BRI-related African nations’ NCOIs in GPCCN–Eora26 models.
Table 9. Top five BRI-related African nations’ NCOIs in GPCCN–Eora26 models.
Rank199019952000200520102015
CountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOICountryNCOI
1ZAF48.196 ZAF59.683 ZAF60.514 ZAF59.005 CHN70.547 CHN72.044
2LSO39.341 CHN40.776 CHN46.740 CHN56.222 ZAF52.555 ZAF50.861
3CHN33.572 KEN27.445 KEN29.039 KEN27.919 AGO25.332 AGO25.585
4CIV28.893 NGA26.717 NGA26.535 DZA25.889 KEN25.289 KEN25.577
5MAR26.592 LSO26.425 DZA26.354 AGO25.860 DZA24.708 DZA24.523
6KEN25.619 DZA25.788 CIV25.528 SEN25.529 EGY24.047 MAR24.292
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, D.; Guan, J.; Liu, C.; Jiang, C.; Xing, L. Simulation of Cooperation Scenarios of BRI-Related Countries Based on a GVC Network. Systems 2022, 10, 12. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems10010012

AMA Style

Wang D, Guan J, Liu C, Jiang C, Xing L. Simulation of Cooperation Scenarios of BRI-Related Countries Based on a GVC Network. Systems. 2022; 10(1):12. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems10010012

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Dawei, Jun Guan, Chunxiu Liu, Chuke Jiang, and Lizhi Xing. 2022. "Simulation of Cooperation Scenarios of BRI-Related Countries Based on a GVC Network" Systems 10, no. 1: 12. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems10010012

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop