Next Article in Journal
Would Forest Regrowth Compensate for Climate Change in the Amazon Basin?
Next Article in Special Issue
Climate-Optimised Intermediate Stop Operations: Mitigation Potential and Differences from Fuel-Optimised Configuration
Previous Article in Journal
Incorporating External Knowledge Reasoning for Vision-and-Language Navigation with Assistant’s Help
Previous Article in Special Issue
A Parametric Approach for Conceptual Integration and Performance Studies of Liquid Hydrogen Short–Medium Range Aircraft
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

CORSIA—A Feasible Second Best Solution?

Institute of Air Transport and Airport Research, German Aerospace Center (DLR e.V.), 51147 Cologne, Germany
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Appl. Sci. 2022, 12(14), 7054; https://doi.org/10.3390/app12147054
Submission received: 23 May 2022 / Revised: 7 July 2022 / Accepted: 11 July 2022 / Published: 13 July 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Climate Impact of Aviation)

Abstract

:
This paper studies the feasibility of CORSIA’s carbon neutral growth goal based on verified carbon offsetting. It is motivated by an ongoing general debate about the climate and regulatory integrity of carbon offsetting, thus systematically identifying critical carbon offset characteristics. Using registry data from the largest carbon offset verifiers eligible under CORSIA, we show that the majority of carbon offsets have minor climate integrity. This challenges CORSIA’s neutral growth objective. However, unconditional offset price differentials are only weak signals for climate integrity. To increase environmental effectiveness, a narrower scope of eligibility rules is necessary in order to ensure maximum compliance of projects and strengthen the necessary price effect of carbon offsets. However, it is highly questionable whether there is enough potential supply of offsets to ensure such high integrity, indicating that carbon offsetting should be considered as a transitory measure only.

1. Introduction

In 2010, the International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) decided to achieve Carbon neutral growth [1]. In 2016, ICAO adopted the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA), requiring airlines to purchase carbon offset credits for emissions above average 2019 levels on international flights starting in 2021. Carbon offset projects reduce or store carbon dioxide or other greenhouse gas emissions, by investing in renewable energy or the preservation of forests, for example, in order to compensate for emissions elsewhere. In aviation, carbon offsetting is a potential second best solution, because sectoral marginal abatement costs are relatively high and potential best solutions such as carbon taxes or cap and trade systems [2] have not proven politically feasible.
CORSIA’s success will depend highly upon the offsets used. For example, storing global emissions by planting trees has become widely considered as challenging due to the lack of available land and the fact that the existence of large woodlands would have to be secured forever, or for at least 100 years [3]. As a consequence, forest carbon credits have been kept out of several key carbon markets, such as the European Union’s Emission Trading Scheme [4]. Instead of carbon storage, carbon reduction by increasing energy efficiency has become more popular for offsetting, although it is controversial as well. Frequently, carbon reduction projects do not depend on offsets and would have occurred anyway, which can induce adverse effects if policy makers do not implement policies to address emissions [5].
Due to the ambiguous climate benefits of carbon offsetting, offset prices are important to incentivize emission reductions in the buying sector. It is expected that a carbon price of 40–80$ per ton of CO2e in 2020 would be consistent with achieving the Paris Agreement of keeping temperature rise below 2 degrees [2]. Currently, the carbon offset market is characterized by a structural oversupply. Today, offsetting a ton of CO2 under CORSIA would cost less than one US Dollar. The drop in air traffic from the COVID-19 pandemic makes it unlikely that the airline sector will be required to offset any emissions in the next several years [6], resulting in a window of opportunity for improving CORSIA’s regulations.
This paper is motivated by these drawbacks of carbon offsetting. It tries to answer the question of whether CORSIA is a feasible second best solution for the ICAO’s carbon neutral growth goal. Therefore, we systematically identify critical offset characteristics. Based on these findings, we empirically analyze the carbon offset market supply that is currently eligible under CORSIA and discuss how the market will likely interact with airlines. We focus on offsets’ carbon reduction potential and adverse effects. Furthermore, given today’s high price variation of eligible carbon offsets (for example, a German nonprofit organization called Atmosfair offers voluntary offsets for USD 28 per ton under the CORSIA-eligible Gold Standard certification, whereas other Gold Standard offsets from other providers are available for USD 3), we evaluate whether prices are useful as a signal for climate and regulatory integrity.
While the basic economic idea behind carbon offsetting resembles cap and trade systems, differences in their realization are huge. In both cases, differences in marginal abatement cost allow cost-efficient emission reductions by trading CO2 permits. However, cap and trade systems are capped in absolute terms, closed, and balanced. Increases need to be counterbalanced by reductions, often in comparable general regulatory settings within countries, sectors, or economic areas. In most cases, carbon offsetting is uncapped in absolute terms and operates in segregated jurisdictions, potentially requiring extensive bureaucracies to guarantee net emission reductions. Carbon offsetting and cap and trade systems require monitoring, reporting, and verifying of emissions. However, offsetting projects need to fulfill further criteria such as additionality, permanency, non-leakage (climate integrity), and avoidance of adverse effects such as social oppression (regulatory integrity). Quality standards have emerged to certify that most of these important criteria are satisfied.
The complexity of carbon offsetting is expressed by its high transaction costs [7]. Under CORSIA, projects verified by six organizations are eligible in order to offer a heterogeneous portfolio of offsets from all over the world, with different sizes, types, investment costs, developers, verifiers, and prices, even within standards. As a result, guaranteeing full compliance for all registered projects is challenging and the probability of adverse selection depends on project characteristics [8]. In order to better understand the potential drawbacks of CORSIA-eligible offsets, we explain related critical characteristics and their consequences for climate and regulatory integrity. Considering critical characteristics, we evaluate the eligible offset supply using the registry data of the largest suppliers, Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), VERRA, and Gold Standard (GS), which together account for two thirds of all traded offsets [9].
This paper adds to the literature by focusing on characteristics of CORSIA eligible offsets that jeopardize climate and regulatory integrity. In comparison with the related literature, we connect theoretical consideration of critical offset characteristics with the offset composition eligible under CORSIA using corresponding offset registry data. We then discuss how airlines will interact with this offset market. Based on these findings, we show how the eligibility criteria need to be adjusted in order to increase climate and regulatory integrity under CORSIA, and discuss alternative regulation.
The results of our paper indicate that CORSIA’s eligibility criteria increase climate and regulatory integrity. However, a series of challenges remain to achieve carbon neutral growth. Nonetheless, there is high variation in eligible offsets, and many of them challenge climate and regulatory integrity with a high probability. The literature has shown that prices cannot be used as a signal for regulatory integrity [10]. Our results also indicate that carbon offset prices cannot be used as a signal for climate integrity. Project characteristics such as project type are much more important; however, if price does not determine project integrity, then profit-maximizing airlines do not necessarily support offsets with low integrity.
The paper is structured as follows: in Section 2, we present the institutional and technical background explaining the technical boundaries in aviation and critical offset characteristics. In Section 3, we analyze the market for carbon offsets that are eligible under CORSIA using registry data. Section 4 discusses our findings in light of alternative concepts. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Institutional and Technical Background

This section highlights CORSIA’s institutional and technical background, which is important in understanding why it has been implemented and why it has often been criticized. We explain offset characteristics in more detail in order to increase awareness of potential conflicts with climate and regulatory integrity.

2.1. Scope of CORSIA and Eligible Offsets

In October 2016, CORSIA was agreed at the 39th ICAO Assembly after decades of difficult international negotiations (Assembly Resolution A39-3). CORSIA aims at supporting ICAO’s Carbon Neutral Growth (CNG) goal from 2021 onwards. CORSIA is a baseline-and-credit scheme. The baseline above which emissions have to be compensated or abated was initially defined as the average total CO2 emissions of all international flights under the scheme in the years 2019 and 2020, respectively. To reflect the COVID-19-related decline in 2020, this was changed in the meantime to 2019 only. CORSIA is the first global scheme for the limitation of aviation CO2 emissions. However, criticism has been raised concerning CORSIA’s environmental ambitiousness, which we discuss below. CORSIA will capture an increasing number of participating states over time. In the medium term, roughly 90 percent of civil international air traffic will be included. CORSIA is a baseline-and-credit scheme, requiring offsets for all CO2 emissions exceeding the 2019 emission baseline. Of course, a number of exemptions apply. For instance, CORSIA only applies to CO2 emissions from international flights, as ICAO is the UN Agency for international civil air transport while domestic operations are fully under responsibility of the individual states. Other exemptions refer to emissions from small aircraft with an MTOM below 5.7 tons, small emitters emitting less than 10,000 tons of CO2 annually, and humanitarian, medical, and firefighting flights. As ICAO is responsible for civil operations only, military and governmental flights are completely excluded. However, monitoring, reporting, and verification (MRV) of CO2 emissions under CORSIA is mandatory for all ICAO contracting states irrespective of any voluntary or mandatory participation. MRV obligations started in 2019. CORSIA consists of three phases: Pilot Phase (from 2021–2023), Phase 1 (2024–2026), and Phase 2 (2027–2035). Whereas the Pilot Phase and Phase 1 are voluntary, participation in Phase 2 is mandatory for all states with airlines accounting for more than 0.5 of global international RTK in the year 2018. Only least-developed countries, land-locked developing countries, and small island nations are exempted from this obligation. Of course, voluntary participation is possible for any ICAO contracting state. Offset requirements are defined by the routes flown. Only routes between participating states (‘CORSIA States’) are subject to these offsetting requirements. Figure 1 summarizes CORSIA’s main characteristics.
In March 2019, the ICAO Council adopted Emission Unit Eligibility Criteria (EUCs) which specify the requirements for carbon offset credits to be eligible under CORSIA. Carbon-offsetting programs have to fulfil these requirements and need to be approved by the ICAO Council as eligible programs. Currently, six offset program standards are eligible: Clean Development Mechanism, Gold Standard, VERRA, American Carbon Registry (ACR), Climate Action Reserve (CAR), and China Greenhouse Gas Voluntary Emission Reduction Program (GHG). Among these programs, offsets are eligible from projects that started their first crediting period from 1 January 2016 and in respect of emissions reductions that occurred through 31 December 2020. Certain program specific offsets have been declared as non-eligible [11].

2.2. Technical Boundaries Justifying Offsetting

In the past, fuel efficiency in aviation has increased by around two percent per year. These environmental benefits have been outpaced by sustained growth in air traffic, which is likely to double in the next decade [12]. Under such growth scenarios, sector-wide net emission reductions are very ambitious, especially because advanced technologies for clean flying such as synthetic fuel are not yet in operation.
Offsetting seems to be particularly attractive for the air transport industry. This industry is considered to be a ‘hard(er)-to-abate sector’, both for technological and economic reasons. Marginal abatement costs in the aviation sector are considerably higher than in other (transport) sectors. This is because fuel costs have a share of about one third of total production costs in air transport; the sector has constantly been trying to cut fuel costs for decades. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that reducing fuel costs has been in the very interest of the aviation industry for many years, and relatively less expensive solutions have mostly been implemented.
Hydrocarbons, which are the root cause of the carbon emissions of air transport, can be regarded for aviation applications as optimal energy carriers. They feature an optimal combination of chemical characteristics, first and foremost energy density, along with further properties (freezing point, handling safety, storability) and economic characteristics such as ubiquitous availability and affordability.
Alternative energy carriers and propulsion technologies, which can be introduced in ground transport with relative ease, do not work as technological equivalents in air transport. Batteries allow electrical aircraft for the foreseeable future to be operated with only a small payload over distances of less than 500 km. Unless not currently foreseeable progress in battery technology is made, long-haul flights will remain unfeasible on battery power.
While hydrogen would be technologically feasible, it is associated with numerous disadvantages. First, an enormous amount of green electricity would be required to produce hydrogen for the air transport sector alone. Second, storage and distribution is challenging due to its physical properties, such as the propensity to diffuse through tank walls. Third, the low overall efficiency measured as a proportion of final energy content available for propulsion to the energy input required to produce green hydrogen will likely lead to relatively high prices. Fourth, the size and weight of hydrogen tanks would reduce the energy efficiency of aircraft. Last, emissions of water vapor, contrails, and nitrogen oxides (in the case of direct hydrogen combustion in gas turbines) at high altitudes occur with hydrogen powered aircraft and contribute to so-called non-CO2 climate effects. Aviation contributes to climate change by both CO2 and non-CO2 effects, such as ozone and methane changes from NOx emissions or contrails and contrail cirrus. The climate-relevant effects from non-CO2 species can be even larger than the effects from CO2 [13]. Hence, even with an air transport sector hypothetically relying on hydrogen as energy carrier, the need to offset climate impacts will be present to a certain extent. This similarly applies to a situation where hydrocarbons synthetized from water and CO2 captured from ambient air under utilization of green electricity would be utilized. While the CO2 would be subject to a circular economy where the same amount of emitted CO2 is captured and recycled to produce new hydrocarbon fuels, the non-CO2 effects of water vapor, contrails, cloud-inducing ice crystals and nitrogen oxides would persist.
Hence, a completely climate-neutral aviation system is far from being realistic in the foreseeable future, and mitigation of climate impacts of aviation by other means remains a necessity.

2.3. Challenges for CORSIA’s Climate and Regulatory Integrity

Most challenges for regulatory and climate integrity differ by project type, region, and size, and some are unilateral. By implementing safeguard clauses and verification and monitoring procedures, CORSIA-eligible verification standards try to ensure the climate and regulatory integrity of carbon offsetting.
For a better understanding of the eligible carbon offset market under CORSIA, it is important to know that the CDM which laid the foundation of certified offsetting started as a cost-efficient scheme for developing countries to comply with emission reduction targets. Compared with today’s certification procedures, offsets were less regulated [14,15]. Moreover, no particular institutional or financial incentives have been implemented that benefit local communities. As a response, private programs such as the Gold Standard have developed project methodologies take sustainable development benefits and safeguard clauses into account [16]. Offset portfolios and certification procedure have been adjusted in response to shortcomings in regulatory and climate integrity. For example, Gold Standard has decided to exclude controversial project types such as large dams from its portfolio [17]. The CDM has regularly adjusted its monitoring and verification methodology. As a result, project-specific characteristics are much more important for integrity than differences between verification standards [10]. However, challenges remain.

2.3.1. Additionality

Additionality is a basic problem in identifying offsets’ net carbon reductions. The climate effect of carbon offsets hinges on whether the project would have occurred in its absence. If the project would have been conducted anyway, emissions are not reduced by the offset scheme, and are therefore not additional. All project types face the problem of additionality stemming from asymetric information and uncertainty. Due to asymmetric information, the opportunity costs of investors are private knowledge in the form of investment decisions, leading to a free-riders problem by generating additional revenues with carbon offsets. It can be argued that additionality is an inherently uncertain concept due to its dependence on an unobservable counterfactual scenario [18]. Even if it were known that carbon offsets are necessary for today’s investments, there would be uncertainty as to whether tomorrow’s investors would have invested in the same project without carbon offsets. Later investments could be driven by changes in legislation or efficiency gains. For example, many countries have introduced legislation to support the use of efficient lighting, which has been within the scope of several offset projects [19]. Ensuring additionality from nature-based solutions requires an accurate baseline that provides the volume of emissions that would have occurred in the absence of that project. In the case of forest-based carbon storage, the uncertainty of baselines is relatively high [20]. Furthermore, inappropriate tree planting on natural grasslands and peatlands can represent an additional challenge by adding more carbon to the atmosphere than they take up as carbon-rich soils are disturbed [21,22]. In terms of additionality, small-scale projects outperform large-scale projects due to lower economic returns of scale. Most large-scale projects would have occurred independent of offsetting investments either due to their high profitability or due to public investment [5].

2.3.2. Adverse Effects

Adverse effects can challenge carbon offsetting. From the perspective of policy makers, carbon offsetting is complex. It brings together subjects from very different jurisdictions, usually highly regulated carbon emitters and carbon savers that operate in less developed and regulated markets. Frequently, it is not only carbon that is traded, it is regulation of economic activity, which increases the risk of adverse effects such as social oppression or damage to biodiversity. In the case of adverse effects, risk factors include the location, project type, and project size. Furthermore, there is substantial variation in co-benefits and adverse effects across different project types [23,24,25,26,27,28,29]. Biomass, land-use, and wind projects contribute more co-benefits and fewer adverse effects compared to projects targeted on industrial emissions or large dams [14,23,30]. However, variation can be high even within the same project type. For example, the probability of social oppression or negative effects on biodiversity is higher for large-scale projects independent of the project type [31,32,33,34,35].
Currently, small-scale energy efficiency projects targeted to local populations, such as cook stove projects which replace fireplaces with efficient stoves, tend to be the best offsetting practice, especially due to the context of high financial need. From an economic point of view, it appears counterintuitive to invest in inefficient projects. However, this is a simple mechanism to guarantee additionality, and is often used in carbon offset standards. The less profitable a project is, the less likely it is that a private investor would have invested in it anyway. However, the corresponding literature does not analyze how such inefficient investments affect the local economy in the longer term. In theory, they could crowd out more efficient and longer-lasting investments that would have been installed by the local government due to political pressure or by local businesses, thus reducing economic growth [36].
For this reason, the current best practices in offsetting potentially induce a trade-off between additionality and adverse effects. While the importance of this might be limited today due to the small share of such projects, it could became sizable if offsetting increases in importance. More importantly, if projects have a negative impact on the local population they are less likely to be maintained as carbon stores in the long term [37,38].

2.3.3. Permanency and Carbon Leakage

Permanency and carbon leakage are two major challenges in ensuring effective net carbon reductions. However, non-permanency and carbon leakage are problems that are specific to certain project types, especially projects based on natural carbon storage such as reforestation. By declaring regions as protected, carbon leakage may occur if the agricultural industry simply shifts to unprotected locations. Non-permanency occurs, for example, if carbon releases are only delayed. Guaranteeing permanency of carbon storage is important, as it can only develop its climate effect if storage is guaranteed for at least 100 years, assuming that climate change will have been solved by that time [3]. Ironically, climate change challenges natural carbon storage, as it increases the risk of wildfires or drought [39]. Furthermore, human activity affects permanency if the stored biomass competes with other economic interests the economic value of which we do not yet know today [40]. Therefore, the project region can have a sizable impact on the climate integrity, especially with respect to carbon leakage of land use projects. The more attractive the land used for reforestation is for agricultural production, the higher the probability of carbon leakage by cutting unprotected forests as a substitute. Thus, climate integrity is higher in areas with degraded peatlands, for example, which are no longer in agricultural use [41]. The scale of activities matters for permanence risks and leakage as well. Large-scale forest programs, for example, are more difficult to control and predict considering the size of territories, political priority shifts, oscillations in price of agricultural commodities, and variations in government budgetary spending for forest protection [4].

2.3.4. Assessment Procedures

While assessment procedures improve the climate and regulatory integrity of carbon offset projects, they come with their own costs. Safeguard clauses have been developed to identify and reduce adverse effects and verification and monitoring processes have been implemented to ensure additionality, permanency, and avoidance of carbon leakage [16]. However, assessment is partially subjective, as project characteristics are difficult to validate [26] and core indicators can be subject to manipulation [31]. Many certified offset projects are suspected of not being effective in terms of net GHG reduction [5,19]. A critical challenge is determining the optimal balance between compliance and supply. If quality standards are too stringent, desirable projects may not participate [42]. Satisfying requirements with respect to additionality, permanence, and avoidance of adverse effects increases transaction and investment costs. For example, where there is a risk of non-permanence, verification standards require carbon offset projects to insure against it by making use of buffer accounts. Projects contribute a share of carbon credits to a buffer account and, in case of reversals, an equivalent number of buffer credits are canceled. This creates high opportunity costs. These may be reduced by simplifying validation processes, although at the cost of lower climate and regulatory integrity [7]. As a result, adverse selection challenges offset standards [43,44]. Large-scale projects have lower transaction costs than small-scale projects, and transaction costs vary between project types. For example, they are on average lower for carbon storage compared to carbon reduction [45].

2.3.5. Other Unsolved Issues

Outside the scope of verification standards, several additional unsolved issues remain. One example is double counting, where the same emissions reduction is counted by both the host country and the offset purchaser. Prior to the Paris Agreement this was less of a concern, because only developed countries had absolute emission reduction targets. As countries with a reduction target were able to purchase offsets from countries without such targets, the risk of double counting was less relevant. Under the Paris Agreement, all parties have absolute emissions reduction targets. Therefore, it must be ensured that emission reductions counted for offsets are not also counted by the host country’s Paris target as well. It remains unclear how such double counting can be avoided [46].
Taken together, there are several trade-offs between additionality and adverse effects on the one hand and permanency and leakage on the other. Carbon reduction projects suffer more from additionality and adverse effects, while carbon storage schemes such as reforestation are more prone to permanency problems and carbon leakage. Furthermore, there is a trade-off between transaction costs and additionality with regard to project size. Transaction costs are low for large-scale projects; however, large-scale projects have a lower probability of being additional.

3. CORSIA’s Carbon Offset Market

In this section, we describe the current carbon offset market using registry data from the three most important offset certification programs under CORSIA, namely, Gold Standard, VERRA, and CDM. After describing CORSIA’s offset market, we analyse the carbon offset price as a signal for climate and regulatory integrity. We focus on variation in program standards, project types, and sizes, as Section 2.3 has shown how important these characteristics are to assessing offset quality.

3.1. Market Composition

The regulated carbon offset market in form of the CDM has lost relevance in the last decade due to limits on the use of offsets in the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) being reached and to the delay in agreement on a new successor regime for the Kyoto Protocol [47]. Nevertheless, the market rationale survived in the private sector through a host of voluntary carbon offsetting schemes regulated by private offset certification programs. Offsets are traded on the secondary market, on stock exchanges, or by being directly purchased from the initial offset project. The governance of the voluntary offset market is loosely structured.
While offsetting standards set the rules and monitor compliance, there are a number of different types of organizations that generate the offset supply. They may span the entire process, from initiating and implementing greenhouse gas reduction projects and managing their assessment and verification to selling the resulting credits to emitters. Other offset organisations act more like brokers, simply buying and selling offsets [48]. Offset projects are regionally centralized, predominately located in the Global South due to lower marginal abatement costs and development assistance. For example, 60% of the total CDM supply potential comes from China alone [49].
The carbon offset market is concentrated among carbon offset project types. In 2019, around 100 Million tonnes of CO2 equivalents were traded [50]. Renewable energy (RE) and forestry and land use are the most important offset types by far, representing 79% of offsets traded in 2019 (see Figure 2). For example, projects which focus on the exchange of household devices with less energy consumption (HH), such as cook stove projects, only accounted for 6.4% of all traded offsets in 2019.
Offset certification programs are highly concentrated in private companies. The most common standard is VERRA’s Verified Carbon Standard, accounting for around 60% of all offset transactions in 2019. Other popular standards are Gold Standard (17%), CDM (8%), Climate Action Reserve (8%), and American Carbon Registry (3%), all of which are eligible under CORSIA (see Figure 2). Public standards lost importance, as the small share of CDM transactions indicates, due to the collapse of the market in the early 2010s. As a result, only one third of CDM projects have continued to issue offsets. However, the majority of projects continue GHG abatement without issuing offsets, while other project developers have gone bankrupt [19,51]. Especially vulnerable projects did not survive [52]. Nonetheless, the CDM has by far the largest capacities of carbon offsets, although other certification program standards could steadily increase their supply (see Figure 3a).
CORSIA’s selection of eligible certification program standards is essential for the project type composition of CORSIA’s offset supply, as private standards tend to specialize their offset portfolio. Figure 3 shows the program standard-specific composition of offset project types over time by focusing on those three project types per program standard that deliver the largest relative amount of offsets. Smaller project types are summarized under ‘others’. Figure 3b shows that the composition of the CDM is heterogeneous and constant over time. Wind is the most important source, accounting for 16% of supply in 2020, followed by projects that reduce coal mine methane and biomass energy projects, both accounting for around 6% of supply in 2020. Other project types that were smaller than 6% accounted for 71% of supply in 2020. Figure 3c,d shows that the project type composition of Gold Standard and VERRA has become more dynamic. For example, the Gold Standard was heavily focused on wind energy 13 years ago. It has diversified, and is now the leading program standard for domestic energy efficiency projects, which account for 27% of Gold Standard’s total offset supply in 2020. VERRA, on the other hand, has become today’s leading supplier for land-use projects such as reforestation. However, wind energy remains the most important source of offsetting supply in general.
Offset certification programs also differ with respect to project size. Figure 4a shows that the large majority of offset projects are very small, irrespective of the program. The Gold Standard has the largest share of small scale projects. However, Figure 4b reveals that a naive look on the number of small scale projects would be misleading. For example, the largest 20% of offset projects account for 60% of total Gold Standard supply. In case of the CDM, the largest 20% account for 50% of offset supply. VERRAs total offset supply is almost entirely based on large-scale projects. The CDM portfolio is more divers with respect to project size than VERRA or Gold Standard.

3.2. Price as a Signal for Climate Integrity

Section 2.3 has shown the difficulties that arise when selecting offsets. Furthermore, Section 3.1 indicates the heterogeneous compositions of offset portfolios by program standard. In the following, we analyze how well prices can be used as a signal to identify offsets with high climate integrity. Offset prices can reflect differences in offsets’ integrity [53] and influence their trade volume [54]. Carbon offset prices vary substantially by certification program standard and project type. According to Figure 5, there was sizable variation in the amount and price of traded offsets eligible under CORSIA in 2019. Figure 5a shows a negative relation between the program standards trade volume and the average traded prices of the program standards’ offset portfolios. VERRA accounted for almost two thirds of traded carbon offsets in 2019 and offered the lowest prices of relevant program standards by far, stemming from renewable energy (see Figure 5b, which is the cheapest offset type (see Figure 5b).
Figure 5b shows that the relationship between price and trade volume is not as strict as Figure 5a suggests, because forestry and land use was the second most traded type in 2019 and the most expensive offset type on average. This is in line with other findings showing that carbon offset markets are not only determined by prices. Buyers are interested in credits which match their firm’s characteristics, and ’co-benefits’, project type, and location seem to become increasingly important [9,55]. If buyers are not only interested in profit maximization, it would be interesting to know whether higher prices indicate higher offset integrity for them. On the contrary, if buyers are profit maximizers and favor the cheapest offsets, it would be important to know whether this would support offsets with minor climate impact.
In the following, we analyze whether offset prices can be used as a signal for climate integrity using the CDM registry data. This dataset is publicly available and includes detailed information such as the internal rate of return (IRR), IRR benchmarks, project types, amount of generated offsets, and prices of 3496 registered offset project under the CDM. Unfortunately, VERRA and GS do not provide registry data with such a high level of detail; therefore, we focus on the CDM-registry data. We regress prices of offset projects using the difference between their internal rate of return, I R R i , and its benchmark, I R R b e n c h m a r k .
The internal rate of return of an investment is used to estimate the profitability of potential investments. It is the discount rate that makes the net present value of an investment zero. The net present value is the current value of an investment based on discounted future cash flows. Generally speaking, the higher an internal rate of return, the more desirable an investment is to undertake, as it allows very high discount rates. IRR benchmarks are available for each project type, typically based on local capital costs. IRR benchmarks indicating a threshold for IRR above offset projects are considered as non-additional, because such projects would be profitable without offsets [53]. Therefore, in the following we call the difference between the internal rate of return and its benchmark the additionality indicator.
Figure 6a shows the explained variation of the additionality indicator for major offset characteristics. It starts with a regression on the left hand side, where the additionality indicator is regressed on individual offset prices; from left to right, single independent variables such as the offset location are included. The figure indicates that most of the variation in the additionality indicator derives from the project type and the PDD Consultant (the firm that prepares the project design document and accompanies it through the whole process). This is in line with our findings in Section 2.3, highlighting the importance of project type with respect to climate and regulatory integrity. The project size, which is in general an important aspect for climate and regulatory integrity, is not reflected in the additionality indicator. The unconditional price, however, does not explain variation in the additionality indicator.
Figure 6b plots the additionality indicator against the offset project price. The blue line shows a bivariate correlation between additionality indicator and price, indicating no correlation. The red line shows the additionality indicator and price conditional on the project type, region, size, PDD, validator, and year of establishment. The figure shows a statistically significant but economically insignificant correlation. High price increases are necessary for a slight increase in additionality. Detailed numbers for Figure 6a,b are shown in Table A1 in the Appendix A. These results indicate that offset prices cannot be used as a signal for climate integrity. Across offset projects, higher prices do not increase additionality. Within similar project types, very high price differentials are necessary to slightly increase the likelihood of additionality. Instead, a closer look at other project characteristics is necessary to reveal integrity.

4. Discussion

Actual competition in the airline sector varies between different direct and indirect origin–destination markets [56]. Competition may occur from other modes of transport (e.g., cars and trains) on short hauls, from other airlines operating on the same city pairs (or even airport pairs), and from other hub airlines operating alternative routings between a given origin and destination. Consequently, in many cases passengers have a choice between different travel options. Along with other factors (subsidization of carriers, political influence, overcapacities, seasonality of demand), this may partly explain why airlines tend to historically operate with low margins [57].
As a result, it is reasonable to assume that under CORSIA airlines will have the incentive to buy the cheapest offsets available. While this is not per se ineffective from an environmental view, as our results have shown that the offset price is not a sufficient indicator for the offsets’ integrity, we can expect the demand for offsets (from the airline sector) to rise significantly once the COVID-19 crisis has been overcome and air transport begins to surpass 2019 (the baseline year) volumes. This will automatically mean that offsets with low integrity will be purchased, especially as there will hardly be any additional willingness to pay for a premium in offset quality.
While the issue of potentially low offset integrity is less critical for the private voluntary offset market, low offset integrity in a large-scale legally binding setting such as CORSIA lulls industries, policy makers, and eventually consumers into a false sense of integrity.
The only way to increase the effectiveness of CORSIA would hence be a drastic increase of offset requirements with regard to additionality, non-leakage, and permanence, along with improved monitoring and reporting standards. As a result, offset prices would significantly rise. This is unlikely to be accepted at the ICAO level.
However, from an environmental point of view, the situation is urgent now. The impacts of climate change are tangible and technological solutions are only feasible in the long term. In the short term, an alternative approach could be a ‘laissez-faire’ approach regarding CORSIA offset requirements and convincing or forcing a growing number of airlines to voluntarily buy additional better offsets from small-scale well curated projects, or to introduce more ambitious requirements at regional levels, e.g., in the EU.
‘EcoLabelling’ for offsets could be a way to do this, as is known from animal welfare labelling in the meat industry in countries such as Germany, where labels differentiate between, e.g., a lowest score for meat meeting the legal requirements and a highest score for organic meat [58]. Airlines under public ownership could be forced by their public shareholders to buy higher quality offsets, and other airlines might jump at the opportunity for marketing reasons.
However, the more relevant carbon offsetting becomes as an instrument for climate legislation and the more it becomes present in public awareness, the more important rebound effects become. Offsetting negative externalities of consumption increases its utility by lowering the shame of consumption, thereby increasing demand [59]. Such rebound effects can become a serious problem in a situation where carbon offsetting does not hold its net carbon reduction promises, potentially resulting in a net carbon increase. CORSIA’s rebound effects should be addressed by future research.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we show that carbon offsetting, even under well established program standards, can barely support its promise of climate neutral growth in aviation. This finding is based on a systematic review of carbon offset characteristics with regard to climate and regulatory integrity and an empirical analysis of the registry data of the most important offset standards under CORSIA.
These findings have implications for policy. Based on carbon offsets, CORSIA was launched to ensure climate-neutral growth in international flights from 2021 onwards. Thus, airlines need to compensate every additional ton above the 2019 baseline with one equivalent ton released by carbon offset projects. The eligibility criteria established by the ICAO Council specify the requirements for offsets that can be used, currently resulting in six eligible offset program standards.
CORSIA’s climate-neutral growth aspiration would require every offset to mirror net carbon reduction. Many offsets eligible under CORSIA cannot guarantee this, facing the three major challenges of additionality (carbon reductions would not have occurred without the offset project), non-leakage (carbon reduction somewhere does not increase carbon emissions somewhere else), and permanency (today’s reduction might be released tomorrow). Ensuring maximum climate integrity under CORSIA would dramatically reduce the carbon offset supply and increase transaction costs. This stems from the fact that while all eligible offset programs offer projects with high integrity, most of their offset supply is generated in large-scale projects considered to have low integerity, such as renewable energy projects. However, CORSIA’s financial attractiveness is based on these offsets.
Another critical characteristic of eligible carbon offsets are adverse effects. Program standards have considerably improved their regulatory integrity by implementing safeguard clauses which take effects on the local community into account. However, while direct effects on the local community, such as social oppression, can be reduced by monitoring compliance with safeguard clauses, indirect effects such as crowding out are more difficult to observe.
If airlines are not only interested in profit maximization, it would be interesting to know whether higher prices indicate higher offset integrity for them. On the contrary, if airlines are profit maximizers and favor the cheapest offsets, it would be important to know whether this would support offsets with minor climate impact. Our results show that offset prices cannot be used as a signal to maximize climate integrity. Projects with higher offset prices do not guarantee a higher likelihood of additionality.
To ensure the maximum climate and regulatory integrity of CORSIA, policy makers should consider prioritizing carbon reduction projects that are relatively small, aiming at energy efficiency at the consumer level and selected carbon storage projects. Positive examples exists among established climate programs. In the case of small energy-efficient projects, several climate programs have focused on such projects, including the World Bank’s Pilot Auction Facility for Methane and Climate Change Mitigation and the Norwegian purchase program. However, the current supply of such offsets is extremely low and does not meet CORSIA’s demand [60]. Furthermore, it is unclear whether there is enough potential supply. Thus, we emphasize the importance of natural carbon storage under high standards despite its own major weaknesses in order to achieve urgent large-scale carbon reductions and mitigate climate change.
Taken together, our results reveal carbon offsetting as a weak second best solution to achieving carbon neutral growth, which should be considered as transitional. This is in line with the findings of the 2022 IPCC report arguing that CORSIA will not sufficiently decrease aviation carbon emissions in order to be consistent with the temperature goals of the Paris agreement [61]. In order to move closer to the aspiration of carbon-neutral growth, CORSIA’s eligibility criteria need to improve. Moreover, airlines should be further encouraged to invest more in advanced technologies for clean flying. Carbon cap-and-trade schemes can provide important incentives for this.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, All; methodology, F.W.; validation, All; formal analysis, F.W.; data curation, F.W.; writing—original draft preparation, All; writing—review and editing, All; visualization, F.W.; supervision, F.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The study uses the publicly available registry data of CDM, Gold Standard, and VERRA.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Climate integrity and prices.
Table A1. Climate integrity and prices.
Dependent Variable: IRR Benchmark—IRR
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Price in $0.0070.0000.088 ***0.041 ***0.068 ***0.070 ***
(0.013)(0.013)(0.011)(0.012)(0.013)(0.013)
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Project sizeNoYesYesYesYesYes
Project typeNoNoYesYesYesYes
Project regionNoNoNoYesYesYes
PPD consultantNoNoNoNoYesYes
ValidatorNoNoNoNoNoYes
Observations349634963496349634963496
DF347534743455341328582821
R 2 0.0000.0210.3830.4500.6700.682
Adjusted R 2 −0.0000.0150.3750.4370.5970.606
Notes: This table displays the OLS results for the effect of CER prices USD/tCO2 on differences between the offset project IRRi and (IRRbenchmarkIRRi). Each coefficient is the result of a separate regression of offset prices on (IRRbenchmarkIRRi) using a different set of controls. Year FE: Year fixed-effect for the year the credit starts, Project type: Project type dummy of the offset project, such as Solar, Reforestation etc., Project region: Region dummy hosting the project: Africa, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America, Asia and Pacific, Middle-East, Project size: Expected accumulated ktCO2e of the project, Validator: Validator dummy, containing the name of the Designated Operational Entity validating, PDD consultant: PDD Consultant dummy, containing the name of the company, organization etc. who have contributed with calculations of baseline the project. Standard errors are clustered at county level and displayed in parentheses Significance levels: ***: p < 0.01.

References

  1. ICAO. Resolution A39-2: Consolidated Statement of Continuing ICAO Policies and Practices Related to Environmental Protection—Climate Change; ICAO: Montreal, QC, Canada, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  2. Stiglitz, J.E.; Stern, N.; Duan, M.; Edenhofer, O.; Giraud, G.; Heal, G.M.; La Rovere, E.L.; Morris, A.; Moyer, E.; Pangestu, M.; et al. Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  3. Thamo, T.; Pannell, D.J. Challenges in developing effective policy for soil carbon sequestration: Perspectives on additionality, leakage, and permanence. Clim. Policy 2016, 16, 973–992. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Chagas, T.; Galt, H.; Lee, D.; Neeff, T.; Streck, C. Should Forest Carbon Credits Be Included in Offsetting Schemes Such as CORSIA; Climate Focus: Washington, DC, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  5. Cames, M.; Harthan, R.; Fuessler, J.; Lazarus, M.; Lee, C.; Erickson, P.; Spalding-Fecher, R. How Additional Is the CleanDevelopment Mechanism; Öko-Institut: Berlin, Germany, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  6. IATA. Tourism Economics ’Air Passenger Forecasts’ October 2020; ICAO: Montreal, QC, Canada, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  7. Cacho, O.J.; Lipper, L.; Moss, J. Transaction costs of carbon offset projects: A comparative study. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 88, 232–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Broekhoff, D.; Schneider, L.; Tewari, R.; Fearnehough, H.; Warnecke, C. Options for Improving the Emission Unit Eligibility Criteria under the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation; German Emissions Trading Authority (DEHSt): Berlin, Germany, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  9. Hamrick, K.; Gallant, M. Unlocking Potential: State of the Voluntary Carbon Markets 2017; Ecosystem Marketplace: Washington, DC, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  10. Drupp, M.A. Does the Gold Standard label hold its promise in delivering higher Sustainable Development benefits? A multi-criteria comparison of CDM projects. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 1213–1227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. ICAO. CORSIA Eligible Emissions Units; ICAO: Montreal, QC, Canada, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  12. ICAO. Envisioning a ’Zero Climate Impact’ International Aviation Pathway Towards 2050; ICAO: Montreal, QC, Canada, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  13. Lee, D.S.; Fahey, D.; Skowron, A.; Allen, M.; Burkhardt, U.; Chen, Q.; Doherty, S.; Freeman, S.; Forster, P.; Fuglestvedt, J.; et al. The contribution of global aviation to anthropogenic climate forcing for 2000 to 2018. Atmos. Environ. 2021, 244, 117834. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Finley-Brook, M.; Thomas, C. Renewable energy and human rights violations: Illustrative cases from indigenous territories in Panama. Ann. Assoc. Am. Geogr. 2011, 101, 863–872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Newell, P. The political economy of carbon markets: The CDM and other stories. Climate Policy 2012, 12, 135–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Michaelowa, A. Linking the CDM with domestic carbon markets. Clim. Policy 2014, 14, 353–371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Goldstandard. UNFCCC Clean Development Mechanism Methodology—Gold Standard Eligibility; Gold Standard: Geneva, Switzerland, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  18. Gustavsson, L.; Karjalainen, T.; Marland, G.; Savolainen, I.; Schlamadinger, B.; Apps, M. Project-based greenhouse-gas accounting: Guiding principles with a focus on baselines and additionality. Energy Policy 2000, 28, 935–946. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Warnecke, C.; Day, T.; Schneider, L.; Cames, M.; Healy, S.; Harthan, R.; Höhne, N. Vulnerability of CDM Projects for Discontinuation of Mitigation Activities: Assessment of Project Vulnerability and Options to Support Continued Mitigation; German Emissions Trading Authority (DEHSt) at the Federal Environment Agency: Berlin, Germany, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  20. West, T.A.; Börner, J.; Sills, E.O.; Kontoleon, A. Overstated carbon emission reductions from voluntary REDD+ projects in the Brazilian Amazon. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2020, 117, 24188–24194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Friggens, N.L.; Hester, A.J.; Mitchell, R.J.; Parker, T.C.; Subke, J.A.; Wookey, P.A. Tree planting in organic soils does not result in net carbon sequestration on decadal timescales. Glob. Change Biol. 2020, 26, 5178–5188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Dass, P.; Houlton, B.Z.; Wang, Y.; Warlind, D. Grasslands may be more reliable carbon sinks than forests in California. Environ. Res. Lett. 2018, 13, 074027. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Alexeew, J.; Bergset, L.; Meyer, K.; Petersen, J.; Schneider, L.; Unger, C. An analysis of the relationship between the additionality of CDM projects and their contribution to sustainable development. Int. Environ. Agreements Politics Law Econ. 2010, 10, 233–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Ellis, J.; Winkler, H.; Corfee-Morlot, J.; Gagnon-Lebrun, F. CDM: Taking stock and looking forward. Energy policy 2007, 35, 15–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Olsen, K.H.; Fenhann, J. Sustainable development benefits of clean development mechanism projects: A new methodology for sustainability assessment based on text analysis of the project design documents submitted for validation. Energy Policy 2008, 36, 2819–2830. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Schneider, L. Assessing the additionality of CDM projects: Practical experiences and lessons learned. Clim. Policy 2009, 9, 242–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Subbarao, S.; Lloyd, B. Can the clean development mechanism (CDM) deliver? Energy Policy 2011, 39, 1600–1611. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Sutter, C.; Parreño, J.C. Does the current Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) deliver its sustainable development claim? An analysis of officially registered CDM projects. Clim. Change 2007, 84, 75–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Griscom, B.W.; Busch, J.; Cook-Patton, S.C.; Ellis, P.W.; Funk, J.; Leavitt, S.M.; Lomax, G.; Turner, W.R.; Chapman, M.; Engelmann, J.; et al. National mitigation potential from natural climate solutions in the tropics. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B 2020, 375, 20190126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Jagger, P.; Rana, P. Using publicly available social and spatial data to evaluate progress on REDD+ social safeguards in Indonesia. Environ. Sci. Policy 2017, 76, 59–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Haya, B. Failed Mechanism: How the CDM Is Subsidizing Hydro Developers and Harming the Kyoto Protocol; Technical Report; International Rivers: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  32. Cavanagh, C.; Benjaminsen, T.A. Virtual nature, violent accumulation: The spectacular failure of carbon offsetting at a Ugandan National Park. Geoforum 2014, 56, 55–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Veldman, J.W.; Overbeck, G.E.; Negreiros, D.; Mahy, G.; Le Stradic, S.; Fernandes, G.W.; Durigan, G.; Buisson, E.; Putz, F.E.; Bond, W.J. Where tree planting and forest expansion are bad for biodiversity and ecosystem services. BioScience 2015, 65, 1011–1018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Sarmiento Barletti, J.P.; Larson, A.M. Rights Abuse Allegations in the Context of REDD+ Readiness and Implementation: A Preliminary Review and Proposal for Moving Forward; Center for International Forestry Research: Bogor, Indonesia, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  35. Seddon, N.; Smith, A.; Smith, P.; Key, I.; Chausson, A.; Girardin, C.; House, J.; Srivastava, S.; Turner, B. Getting the message right on nature-based solutions to climate change. Glob. Change Biol. 2021, 27, 1518–1546. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Djankov, S.; Montalvo, J.G.; Reynal-Querol, M. The curse of aid. J. Econ. Growth 2008, 13, 169–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Fa, J.E.; Watson, J.E.; Leiper, I.; Potapov, P.; Evans, T.D.; Burgess, N.D.; Molnár, Z.; Fernández-Llamazares, Á.; Duncan, T.; Wang, S.; et al. Importance of Indigenous Peoples’ lands for the conservation of Intact Forest Landscapes. Front. Ecol. Environ. 2020, 18, 135–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Fleischman, F.; Basant, S.; Chhatre, A.; Coleman, E.A.; Fischer, H.W.; Gupta, D.; Güneralp, B.; Kashwan, P.; Khatri, D.; Muscarella, R.; et al. Pitfalls of tree planting show why we need people-centered natural climate solutions. BioScience 2020, 70, 947–950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Scott, N.; Fitzgerald, S.; Keshav, S. Cambridge Zero Policy Forum Discussion Paper: Carbon Offsetting and Nature-Based Solutions to Climate Change; University of Cambridge: Cambridge, UK, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  40. Espejo, A.; Becerra-Leal, M.C.; Aguilar-Amuchastegui, N. Comparing the Environmental Integrity of Emission Reductions from REDD Programs with Renewable Energy Projects. Forests 2020, 11, 1360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. German Emissions Trading Authority. Future of the Voluntary Carbon Markets in the Light of the Paris Agreement; German Emissions Trading Authority: Berlin, Germany, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  42. Chomitz, K.M. Baselines for Greenhouse Gas Reductions: Problems, Precedents, Solutions; Prepared for the Carbon Offsets Unit, World Bank; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 1998; Volume 16. [Google Scholar]
  43. Bushnell, J.B. The economics of carbon offsets. In The Design and Implementation of US Climate Policy; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2011; pp. 197–209. [Google Scholar]
  44. Bento, A.; Ho, B.; Ramirez-Basora, M. Optimal monitoring and offset prices in voluntary emissions markets. Resour. Energy Econ. 2015, 41, 202–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Antinori, C.; Sathaye, J. Assessing Transaction Costs of Project-Based Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading; Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  46. Schneider, L.; Healy, S. Avoiding Double Counting between CORSIA and Nationally Determined Contributions; German Emissions Trading Authority (DEHSt) at the German Environment Agency: Berlin, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  47. Michaelowa, A.; Shishlov, I.; Brescia, D. Evolution of international carbon markets: Lessons for the Paris Agreement. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Change 2019, 10, e613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Lovell, H.; Bulkeley, H.; Liverman, D. Carbon offsetting: Sustaining consumption? Environ. Plan. A 2009, 41, 2357–2379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Schneider, L.; Day, T.; Theuer, S.L.H.; Warnecke, C. Discussion Paper: CDM Supply Potential up to 2020; German Emissions Trading Authority (DEHSt): Berlin, Germany, 2017; Available online: https://www.dehst.de/SharedDocs/downloads/EN/project-mechanisms/CDM-Supply-Potential-up-to-2020.pdf (accessed on 12 December 2021).
  50. Donofrio, S.; Maguire, P.; Zwick, S.; Merry, W.; Wildish, J.; Myers, K. State of the Voluntary Carbon Markets 2020; Ecosystem Marketplace: Washington, DC, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  51. Schneider, L.; Cames, M. Options for Continuing GHG Abatement from CDM and JI Industrial Gas Projects; Öko-Institut: Berlin, Germany, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  52. Kreibich, N.; Obergassel, W. The Voluntary Carbon Market: What May Be Its Future Role and Potential Contributions to Ambition Raising? Wuppertal Institut: Wuppetal, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  53. Michaelowa, A.; Purohit, P. Additionality determination of Indian CDM projects. In Can Indian CDM Project Developers Outwit the CDM Executive Board; University of Zurich: Zurich, Switzerland, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  54. Hamrick, K.; Gallant, M. Voluntary Carbon Markets Insights: 2018 Outlook and First-Quarter Trends; Forest Trends Ecosystem Marketplace: Washington, DC, USA, 2018; Volume 31. [Google Scholar]
  55. Ivleva. Domestic Carbon Initiatives in Europe: Experiences and Opportunities (Workshop Documenta-Tion, 2015); German Emissions Trading Authority: Berlin, Germany, 2015; Volume 31. [Google Scholar]
  56. Maertens, S. A metric to assess the competitive position of airlines and airline groups in the intra-European air transport market. Res. Transp. Econ. 2018, 72, 65–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Taneja, N.K. Airline Survival Kit: Breaking Out of the Zero Profit Game; Taylor & Francis: London, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  58. Sørensen, J.T.; Schrader, L. Labelling as a tool for improving animal welfare-The pig case. Agriculture 2019, 9, 123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  59. Günther, S.A.; Staake, T.; Schöb, S.; Tiefenbeck, V. The behavioral response to a corporate carbon offset program: A field experiment on adverse effects and mitigation strategies. Glob. Environ. Change 2020, 64, 102123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Fearnehough, H.; Warnecke, C.; Schneider, L.; Broekhoff, D.; La Hoz Theue, S. Offset Credit Supply Potential for CORSIA; Umweltbundesamt: Berlin, Germany, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  61. IPCC. Climate Change 2022: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability; Contribution of Working Group II to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change; IPCC: Geneva, Switzerland, 2022. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Principal design of the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA). Notes: This figure highlights the principle design of CORSIA in 2021. Source: Own Figure Maertens et al., Options to Continue the European Union Emissions Trading System for Aviation in a CORSIA-World, Sustainability, 2019.
Figure 1. Principal design of the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA). Notes: This figure highlights the principle design of CORSIA in 2021. Source: Own Figure Maertens et al., Options to Continue the European Union Emissions Trading System for Aviation in a CORSIA-World, Sustainability, 2019.
Applsci 12 07054 g001
Figure 2. Market share of program standards and project types in 2019. Notes: Panel (a) shows the market share of carbon offset certification programs in 2019 based on traded carbon offsets. Panel (b) shows the market share of carbon offset project types in 2019 based on traded carbon offsets. RE: Renewable Energy; HH: Household energy efficiency, Forestry: Forestry and land use; Waste: Waste handling; Industrial: Industrial processes; CDM: Clean Development Mechanism; GS: Gold Standard; ACR: American Carbon Registry; CAR: Climate Action Reserve; GHG: China Greenhouse Gas Voluntary Emission Reduction Program. Source: Donofrio 2020, own illustration.
Figure 2. Market share of program standards and project types in 2019. Notes: Panel (a) shows the market share of carbon offset certification programs in 2019 based on traded carbon offsets. Panel (b) shows the market share of carbon offset project types in 2019 based on traded carbon offsets. RE: Renewable Energy; HH: Household energy efficiency, Forestry: Forestry and land use; Waste: Waste handling; Industrial: Industrial processes; CDM: Clean Development Mechanism; GS: Gold Standard; ACR: American Carbon Registry; CAR: Climate Action Reserve; GHG: China Greenhouse Gas Voluntary Emission Reduction Program. Source: Donofrio 2020, own illustration.
Applsci 12 07054 g002
Figure 3. Supply of carbon verification standards programs and share of offset types by program. Notes: Panel (a) shows the cumulative issued carbon offsets of the CDM, Gold Standard, and VERRA over time. Panels (bd) show the time-varying share of carbon offset projects types for cumulative issued carbon offsets of the CDM, Gold Standard, and VERRA. Source: Own calculation.
Figure 3. Supply of carbon verification standards programs and share of offset types by program. Notes: Panel (a) shows the cumulative issued carbon offsets of the CDM, Gold Standard, and VERRA over time. Panels (bd) show the time-varying share of carbon offset projects types for cumulative issued carbon offsets of the CDM, Gold Standard, and VERRA. Source: Own calculation.
Applsci 12 07054 g003
Figure 4. Distribution of carbon offset supply by project size. Notes: Panel (a) shows the distribution of the normalizes project size measured in ktCO2 for CDM, Gold Standard and VERRA. Panel (b) shows the share of different project sizes for the total total supply for for CDM, Gold Standard and VERRA. Source: Own calculation.
Figure 4. Distribution of carbon offset supply by project size. Notes: Panel (a) shows the distribution of the normalizes project size measured in ktCO2 for CDM, Gold Standard and VERRA. Panel (b) shows the share of different project sizes for the total total supply for for CDM, Gold Standard and VERRA. Source: Own calculation.
Applsci 12 07054 g004
Figure 5. Variation in market share and price of offset verification programs and project types in 2019. Notes: Panel (a) shows 2019 traded offset volume in mtCO2e and price (in USD) per offset program, while Panel (b) shows the same for offset types. RE: Renewable Energy; HH: Household energy efficiency, Forestry: Forestry and land use; Waste: Waste handling; Industrial: Industrial processes; CDM: Clean Development Mechanism; GS: Gold Standard; ACR: American Carbon Registry; CAR: Climate Action Reserve; GHG: China Greenhouse Gas Voluntary Emission Reduction Program. Source: Marketplace 2020, own illustration.
Figure 5. Variation in market share and price of offset verification programs and project types in 2019. Notes: Panel (a) shows 2019 traded offset volume in mtCO2e and price (in USD) per offset program, while Panel (b) shows the same for offset types. RE: Renewable Energy; HH: Household energy efficiency, Forestry: Forestry and land use; Waste: Waste handling; Industrial: Industrial processes; CDM: Clean Development Mechanism; GS: Gold Standard; ACR: American Carbon Registry; CAR: Climate Action Reserve; GHG: China Greenhouse Gas Voluntary Emission Reduction Program. Source: Marketplace 2020, own illustration.
Applsci 12 07054 g005
Figure 6. The relationship between climate integrity and project characteristics. (a) Explained variation of climate integrity; (b) Climate integrity and prices. Notes: Panel (a) shows the relationship of ( I R R b e n c h m a r k I R R i ) and offset price unconditional and conditional on project type, region and year. Panel (b) shows the explained variation of ( I R R b e n c h m a r k I R R i ) for major offset characteristics. From left to right, single independent variables are additionally included. Price: CDM price in USD/tCO2; Year: Year dummy credit starts; Type: Project type dummy of the offset project, such as Solar, Reforestation etc.; Region: Region dummy hosting the project: Africa, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America, Asia and Pacific, Middle-East; Size: Expected accumulated ktCO2e of the project; Vali.: Validator dummy, containing the name of the Designated Operational Entity validating; PDD: PDD Consultant dummy, containing the name of the company, organization, etc., that have contributed the baseline calculations of the project. Source: Own calculation.
Figure 6. The relationship between climate integrity and project characteristics. (a) Explained variation of climate integrity; (b) Climate integrity and prices. Notes: Panel (a) shows the relationship of ( I R R b e n c h m a r k I R R i ) and offset price unconditional and conditional on project type, region and year. Panel (b) shows the explained variation of ( I R R b e n c h m a r k I R R i ) for major offset characteristics. From left to right, single independent variables are additionally included. Price: CDM price in USD/tCO2; Year: Year dummy credit starts; Type: Project type dummy of the offset project, such as Solar, Reforestation etc.; Region: Region dummy hosting the project: Africa, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America, Asia and Pacific, Middle-East; Size: Expected accumulated ktCO2e of the project; Vali.: Validator dummy, containing the name of the Designated Operational Entity validating; PDD: PDD Consultant dummy, containing the name of the company, organization, etc., that have contributed the baseline calculations of the project. Source: Own calculation.
Applsci 12 07054 g006
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wozny, F.; Grimme, W.; Maertens, S.; Scheelhaase, J. CORSIA—A Feasible Second Best Solution? Appl. Sci. 2022, 12, 7054. https://doi.org/10.3390/app12147054

AMA Style

Wozny F, Grimme W, Maertens S, Scheelhaase J. CORSIA—A Feasible Second Best Solution? Applied Sciences. 2022; 12(14):7054. https://doi.org/10.3390/app12147054

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wozny, Florian, Wolfgang Grimme, Sven Maertens, and Janina Scheelhaase. 2022. "CORSIA—A Feasible Second Best Solution?" Applied Sciences 12, no. 14: 7054. https://doi.org/10.3390/app12147054

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop