Next Article in Journal
Understanding the Open Innovation Trends: An Exploratory Analysis of Breadth and Depth Decisions
Previous Article in Journal
The Emergence and Rise of Industry 4.0 Viewed through the Lens of Management Fashion Theory
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Effect of Monetary Incentives on Individual and Organizational Performance in an Italian Public Institution

1
Department of Mechanical, Energy, Management and Transportation Engineering, University of Genoa, Via Opera Pia 15, 16145 Genoa, Italy
2
LIUC, Cattaneo University, Corso G. Matteotti 22, 21053 Castellanza (VA), Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Adm. Sci. 2019, 9(3), 72; https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci9030072
Submission received: 29 May 2019 / Revised: 12 September 2019 / Accepted: 14 September 2019 / Published: 19 September 2019

Abstract

:
This paper addresses the role of monetary incentives with regard to the performance of employees and organizations. The distribution of monetary incentives among employees in public administration has been investigated. Specifically, the traditional approach of bureaucracy that pays a premium to each employee, based on the position held, is compared with a merit approach which tends to recognize and reward individual contributions. A task advice centrality indicator and a value index have been defined and used to study the performance of employees. The results show a modification of individual behaviors, in line with the theoretical foundations and predictions formulated.

1. Introduction

Alignment between the objectives of an organization and those of its members is considered the most important aspect to improve the efficiency of an organization and, implicitly, its performance (Milgrom and Roberts 1992; Davis et al. 1997; Laffont and Martimort 2001; Boswell et al. 2006). This is true for both public sector organizations and private companies (Katou 2011).
In order to foster this alignment, in public sectors, New Public Management (NPM) has guided many reforms in the last 30 years. One of the key ideas of NPM is that public sector organizations need to introduce performance management based on targets, monitoring, and incentives. In other words, in the public sector, a performance improvement requires a transition from a “bureaucratic culture” to a results-based one that emphasizes outcomes rather than inputs or processes. It is well known that a firm’s performance is modified by the use of economic motivation (Bannò and Sgobbi 2010).
Focusing on incentives and, in particular, on monetary incentives, the balance reached by operating on their architecture has been enriched with all those conceptual tools that research into Human Resource Management (HRM) has developed over time. The ability to identify the consequences of the incentives scheme design to be adopted is highly dependent on how services are defined and measured (Zehavit 2019).
In the literature (see the survey on the subject by Perry et al. 2009), particular attention is devoted to the application of extrinsic incentive mechanisms, but without reaching conclusive results. Perry et al. (2009) report that “generally” speaking, Performance-Related Pay (PRP) has failed to produce the expected changes. It is worth remembering that a variety of contextual factors moderate the effectiveness of PRP: organizational context, scheme design, performance indicators, the form of the incentive, etc. (Spano and Monfardini 2018). The application of PRP to public services often encounters some resistance due to the non-market logic of government organizations (Weibel et al. 2009; Frey et al. 2013; Belle 2015; Atkinson et al. 2014).
This paper studies the actual and potential impact of economic incentives on performances, both at the individual and organizational level (Barnard and Simon 1947) in Public Administration (PA). In particular, this study investigates the relationship between the introduction of a meritocratic-based system of monetary incentives to evaluate individual, group and overall performance. The main research questions are designed to test whether the introduction of a competitive system, structured as a “closed-rank tournament”, encourages employees (non-managers) to improve their performance and whether it induces virtuous behavior in employees.
The results show that a well-suited design scheme of economic incentives has positive effects on individual performance, whereas too high a pay-difference within the working group undermines solidarity and collaboration.
Section 2 of this paper presents a literary review defining the main research questions, Section 3 presents the empirical data used, Section 4 provides the methodology, Section 5 the results and discussion. Finally, Section 6 provides the conclusions of the study.

2. Literature and Main Research Questions

In the literature, many studies have been presented in order to evaluate the performance of employees and organizations and the role of incentives (Andersen 2007). Agency theory is one of the main ideas developed in this field. According to this thory, a dilemma exists when employees are motivated to act in their own best interests, which are contrary to those of the organization, and this is an example of a moral hazard (Eisenhardt 1989). It is worth noting that the effectiveness and efficiency of an organization are associated with commonality of purposes, and alignment between the objectives and the values shared between employees and the organization.
Focusing on monetary incentives, one of the most important theories is PRP, which unlike a mechanism that pays a bonus based on seniority, is a tool that is capable of boosting work motivation, and increasing the performance of employees (Chang 2011; Lah and Perry 2008; Salzman 1999). It is worth remembering that PRP is not an invention of NPM, but is connected to principles of Weberian bureaucracy, see (Dahlström and Lapuente 2017) for further details.
Other theories help us to understand the causal link between incentives and motivation (Berumen et al. 2016). The first of these is expectancy theory, which is the analytical framework most frequently called on to understand how a pay system could prove to be motivating. This approach, in terms of rational choice, makes it possible to demonstrate how pay that is linked to individual performance can motivate employees to provide a high level of effort. It is worth remembering that there are three conditions that must be fulfilled. The individual must believe that s/he is able to perform at the desired level of performance; her/his performance will lead to the outcomes, and the value of the reward is positive (Van Eerde and Thierry 1996).
Second, reinforcement theory, which is based on the principle and techniques of organizational behavior modification, focuses on the relationship between the target behavior (e.g., performance) and the motivational tool (e.g., pay for performance) (Luthans 1973; Skinner 1984; Stajkovic and Luthans 1997). Third, equity theory, according to which, each individual compares his/her contribution made to the organization with the advantages gained from their job (Adams 1963). Individuals also compare their advantage/contribution ratio with those of other colleagues taken as points of reference. The concept of distributive justice is linked to that of procedural justice. According to procedural justice, individuals assess the procedures that the organization introduces to distribute rewards. Performance appraisal and the promotion scheme represent central determinants of the feeling of procedural justice (Greenberg 1990). The most critical aspects of a theory aiming to tie the contribution of individuals to organizational performance can be traced to the measurability of individual effort when the result is closely linked to the contribution of others and, consequently, to the relationship between the individual and the organization (Booth and Frank 1999).
In the context of PA, an economic incentive takes on the characteristics of a paradox, faced with its re-statement by policy makers (especially in the USA) for over thirty years, the evidence offered by the literature is negative or at least ambiguous (Perry et al. 2009). In particular, Belle and Cantarelli (2015) studying the effects of financial incentives on the effort made by public managers and how different types of work motivation (i.e., intrinsic, extrinsic, and public service motivation) can moderate these effects, and using experiments, found that monetary rewards had no significant effect on the managers’ effort. Furthermore, the relationship between financial incentives and managers’ effort, which was insignificant overall, was negatively moderated by the intrinsic motivation of the participants, positively moderated by extrinsic motivation, and unaffected by public service motivation. Only in some contexts, such as the medical one for example, is their effect largely positive (see Heneman et al. 1988; Krasnik et al. 1990; Davidson et al. 1992; Hutchison et al. 1996; Dowling and Richardson 1997; Kouides et al. 1998; Shaw et al. 2002; Andersen 2009). Partially positive results were also obtained in the education and public safety sectors.
The aspects that contribute to a more complex relationship between incentive and performance in PA can be grouped into: specificity of cultural dimension, market relations, bonus size, and non-expandable business constraints. In Anglo-Saxon countries, the executive has the choice of hiring or firing employees directly, taking on the responsibilities of building an efficient team. In Italy, the recruitment of civil servants is carried out through competitions, so a manager finds people he did not choose in his team and that he can scarcely fire. Bonus sizes are influenced by public expectations regarding the responsible stewardship of resources (Miller and Whitford 2007). Non-expandable business constrains the “creation” of funds for incentives (recent boosts to spending reviews in the public budget setting). Reinforcement theory suggests that the total incentives should increase by 10-15 per cent a year (Perry et al. 2009).
In the remaining part of this section, two main themes are discussed to define our research hypotheses:
  • Difficulty in identifying objectives measurable and comparable for all task outputs. When criteria able to pick out a different “proactivity” of employees were used, difficulty in sharing and legitimizing the evaluation criteria were found.
  • The organizational division of work implies a relationship between the individual and the working group: the individual works in cooperation in any case. We can wonder whether the individual monetary incentive, when promoting ambition, might undermine the solidarity inside groups.

2.1. Measurability and Performance

The contribution of employees must be objectively identified. Whereas this is easier in private firms where the results of operations or financial activity (increased productivity) are clear, it is more difficult in the public sector, where the primary goal is not profit, but the level of user (the citizen) satisfaction. Although you cannot locate certain criteria and uniform evaluation for employees, you can adopt the evaluation schemes designed to capture the different levels of competence and predisposition of individuals to make greater effort in the workplace. Credibility and acceptance of the evaluation criteria are related to the ability of organizations to be transparent.
The difficulty in detecting individual comparable performances was overcome by the researchers (in particular scholars of organizational behavior) observing intermediate variables (e.g., attitude, such as the level of employee satisfaction or sense of justice of the appraisal system) that appear to be in a positive relationship with performance.
The network analysis approach allows us to use the centrality in the advice network as a proxy of individual performance (Boissevain and Mitchell 2018). The exchange of task advice and information is likely to be positively related to job performance. Individuals share information, advice and assistance, in connection with their work. Centrality in the advice network means the involvement of each individual in the exchange of assistance with other colleagues and availability to put effort into problem solving. Central individuals are less dependent on others (Cook et al. 1983). A central individual can accumulate knowledge about many problems over the years (Baldwin et al. 1997). As others become dependent on a central individual for some important advice, he/she gains power and authority (Cook et al. 1983).
Thus, the first research question is the following:
Hypothesis 1 (H1).
Is the monetary incentive also positively related to individual performance in PAs?
In other words, H1 investigates whether critical issues, associated with the use of incentives as a motivational tool in the public sector, emerge by analyzing the behavior of the employees of companies that use contingent pay systems.
Legislative Decree no.150/2009 states that PAs in Italy must promote merit and performance improvement using selective reward systems. Employees who achieve the best performance should be rewarded through the selective allocation of economic and career incentives.
The introduction by decree of a “closed-rank” tournament system could be an efficient method for determining labor compensation when measuring the performance of individual employees is more difficult than organizing them through ranking. Little research has been developed, however, regarding the use of rank-order tournaments in the public sector. Rank order tournaments solve managers’ difficulty in the identification of synthetic indicators of performance that allow the glimpsing of cardinal differences (typical of the PRP systems) between employees. According to this theory (Lazear and Rosen 1979), wage differences are based not on marginal productivity but instead upon relative differences between individuals. Furthermore, this system could overcome the problem of budget constraint, since the ability of employees to increase their bonus (earning it at the expense of someone else) is not limited. Rank-order tournaments represent a system of non-linear bonus given because each additional unit of performance does not necessarily translate into an additional unit of reward (Whitford 2006). The intention of those who apply this incentivizing system is to produce positive results continuously, discouraging people from taking opportunistic attitudes. Managers who create the tournament rules seek to discourage risk-aversion, affirmation of which would lead instead to a crystallization of the system. This would cause a double negative effect: the less efficient employees will not be stimulated to improve, considering the required results out of reach, while the most deserving ones will consider a performance just enough to be rewarded sufficient, beating their colleagues of the lower classes. After the first year, the distribution of the bonuses will form an incentive for the performance of the following year. Thus, the second research question reads as follows.
Hypothesis 2 (H2).
Does a monetary incentive induce virtuous behavior at an individual level in PAs?
In other words, H2 investigates whether introduction of monetary incentives gives impetus to competition that pushes all employees to achieve better positions through higher performance.

2.2. Incentives to Individual and Organizational Performance

The most critical considerations about the coexistence of individual rewards and positive overall performance are those expressed by scholars of game theory. In particular, Ladley et al. (2015) examined the effect of individual versus group evaluation, reward systems, and performance. They found that in order to enable the group members and all the group to perform better, one person of the group has to sacrifice him/herself.
Rank-order tournaments lead employees into competition, promoting individualism. For this reason, a higher pay dispersion “can undermine feelings of internal equity and damage cooperation and any sense of common purpose across the workforce as a whole” (Beaumont and Harris 2003).
Many studies have been conducted in sports contexts, in which individual and team achievement are easily identified (football, hockey), whereas few experiments have been conducted in enterprises, especially because it is not easy to obtain the data of real salary and monetary incentives. A study (Bloom 1999) performed in a sports context (baseball), where the level of interdependence between the players was high, which showed that a high dispersion of payment was negatively related to individual and organizational performance. Lazear (1989) has shown that in a highly competitive environment, there is a compression of wage range. You must distinguish when the difference in payment is due to salaries, and therefore is durable, and when the difference in payment is temporary, due to a distribution of bonuses. The literature clearly distinguishes between vertical and horizontal dispersion of pay. While the former is about wage differences between managers and non-managers, the latter concerns the differences between siblings. Positive results have been obtained from the application of PRP systems when non-manager employees, whose job responsibilities are fairly concrete and measurable (Mavor and Broderick 1991), were involved.
Explicit in the foundation of tournament theory is that pay differentials are performance based, that performance can be effectively evaluated, and that the workforce is homogeneous in terms of ability (Knoeber and Thurman 1994; Rosen 1985).
It is fundamental for a positive use of monetary incentives to have employees recognize the legitimacy of the appraisal of their superiors and the objectivity of the criteria used. Employees should feel that they have the same chance to achieve their initial goals at each repetition of the tournament. A study of the various public firms in Britain (Marsden and French 2002) has shown that employees’ motivation will be reduced where performance-based pay is not operating fairly, unless it is seen to be internally equitable and externally competitive. An exploratory case study, using the situation in a manufacturing company in Ghana (Boachie-Mensah and Dogbe 2011), revealed that the use of performance-based pay was fair and motivating, and there were no adverse effects of the system on teamwork (Ouchi 1977, 1979).
Shaw et al. (2002) argued that the relationship between pay dispersion and organizational performance rested on two contingencies: whether the dispersion could be explained by legitimate or normative accepted sources (e.g., individual incentives) and whether work was interdependent.
Individual incentives would therefore seem to adapt better to companies in which the occurrence of group work is low. As one’s position inside the network structure should be related to individual performance, so the social network structure of the entire group should be associated with the performance of the same. Network density describes the overall level of interaction of various kinds reported by network members. In particular, the higher the density of the exchange of communication between members of the group is, the greater cooperation, information sharing, and sense of responsibility with a reduced inclination to laziness should be. According to Molm (1994), interdependence supports cooperation and this improves group performance. High network density in the advice network promotes the fluidity of information. The more information is shared, the higher the quality of group decisions is (Larson et al. 1998). Conversely, groups with low network density may not be able or willing to exchange information, ideas or implicit knowledge related to their work (Hansen 1999). The introduction of individual incentives may have weakened the spontaneity in the exchange of advice between the groups. Thus, the third research question is the following.
Hypothesis 3 (H3).
Within business units, is the dispersion of incentive levels inversely related to the density of trade advisory?
If H3 is empirically verified, the existence of a particular threshold level of the Gini coefficient (Gini 1921) when an employee experiences a negative effect on the density of trade advisory (network density <0.30) will be demonstrated.

3. Data

We conducted a study in a public independent institute, i.e., an Italian chamber of commerce, to investigate the effect of the introduction of a new incentive system on the performance of civil servants. We focus on Italy, because in the PA a new incentive system has been implemented starting from 2011, and it was possible to observe the effect of the transition.
Prior to 2011, in the Italian PA, monetary incentives were distributed equally among the employees of the same level, without considering individual performance. In particular, monetary incentives were distributed equally among the business unit, and then divided among the single employees according to a hierarchical logic, i.e. with a fraction proportional to the tenure, predetermined according to the role in the organization. With L.D. 150/09, a new incentive system has been introduced and according to it PAs should promote merit and performance improvement using selective reward systems.
In particular, with a second decree of August 2011, it was decided that only companies with more than fifteen employees and with added resources can use these criteria. This is the result of fierce trade union opposition.
It is worth noting that in Italy the changes in PA have to be enacted by law. According to the new mechanism, employees must be ranked according to their performance and employees who achieve the best performance should be rewarded through the selective allocation of economic and career incentives. In particular, employees ranked according to their performance are divided into three different sets, each related to the different levels of performance, so we have:
  • Set 1: high performance level, in which 25% of the employees is placed, which accounts for 50% of the resources allocated for the optional pay related to individual performance;
  • Set 2: intermediate performance level, in which 50% of the employees is placed, which accounts for 50% of the resources allocated for the optional pay related to individual performance;
  • Set 3: low performance level, in which the remaining 25% of the employees is placed, which does not collect the assignment of any optional pay related to individual performance.
Table 1 summarizes the new incentive system. In particular, it is important to notice that only employees belonging to set 1 and 2 receive a reward. This is a great change. Indeed, it is worth remembering that before the reform organizations had a certain heterogeneity of criteria in the evaluation systems that, in the absence of guidelines, also allowed an “indiscriminate donation”, purely hierarchical-based and not related to any selective criteria. In order to have a smooth transition, in the years after the introduction of L.D. 150/09, to avoid employees being placed in the low level not receiving any optional pay, in the public institution considered, it was decided to divide the total resources in two parts in order to combine the new optional pay system with the previous one. The two monetary incentives combined represent just over a quarter of the total amount received by employees (average value: 26%). Management, constantly negotiating with the labor unions, intends to increase the percentage quota of the new incentive mechanism (which we will call “new”) compared with the old indiscriminative incentive mechanism (which we will call “old”). In the first year, the new incentive represents 53% of the resources allocated to the optional pay; this percentage rises to 64% in the second year.
A double data analysis was performed: the first in February 2011, the second in January 2013. Data was collected through a questionnaire administered directly by the research team to the employees to minimize misunderstandings and highlighting its anonymity, the private use of the data and the agreement with the trade unions. In the first analysis, the total number of employees was 131 and 126 questionnaires were collected because four employees were absent, and one was politically appointed as temporary secretary. At the second analysis, there were 123 interviewees out of 126. It is worth noting that the total number decreased because there were some retirees and, confirming the financial crisis, the employment rate was lower than the retirement rate.
The questionnaire given to the workers was composed of the following parts: personal data of the interviewees (age, gender), position occupied (tenure, organizational area), skills (problem solving, team working, determination, customer oriented, self-organizing), and intra-organization relationships.
The indication about intra-organizational relationships was used for the construction of “task advice centrality”, a proxy for individual performance. “Task advice centrality” means the relations between an employee and other employees and, in particular, indicates how an employee is involved in the activities of other employees. Task advice centrality for each employee is the centrality of the individual in the social consulting network. The intra-organizational relationship reflects the recognition given to a single employee by her/his colleagues for both her/his skills and her/his opportunity of participating in working life. In particular, it indicates how an employee is necessary to perform the other employees’ activities. Thus, it is a proxy of the employee’s performance.
The same data was used to build the “density of working groups”. Employees were divided into 15 working groups; only 11 of them were used for analysis of network density variation in three years; 4 were too small to be considered.
The “density of working groups” represents a proxy for the performance of the working groups.
Moreover, data was collected from the questionnaires in the human resources department of the authority, which provided all the data on optional pay for the years 2010–2012 and information on salary levels of employees.
Accounting information led to the individuation of four predictive factors:
  • Old monetary incentive, which is the part of the bonus (expressed in euros) granted to employees of the organization based on criteria that were used until the current change.
  • New monetary incentive, which is the quota of incentives (expressed in euros) which was allocated based on the evaluation of the department managers, according to new criteria of merit.
  • Salary level, divided into 12 levels, 8 of which are reserved for employees with a non-executive work position.
  • Value index, an indicator of the effort made by each employee.

4. Methodology

The task advice centrality indicator was constructed from the intra-organizational section of the questionnaire. Employees were asked to declare which 10 members of the organization they need to relate to more directly and more frequently, in order to improve or facilitate the conduct of their activities. The Likert scale used ranged from 1 (contacts infrequent, some once a month) to 7 (several times a day). Through the information collected, it was possible to build an adjacency matrix, squared and not symmetrical (oriented curves). We consider only the relationships between employees belonging to the same level, to detect only those that can be defined “horizontal”. The centrality index for each node is the sum of all incoming curves ( c j , i are the incoming branches of employee i) multiplied by their weight ( g j , i ) and it represents the centrality of the individual in the social consulting network, as defined in Equation (1).
Task   Advice   Centrality = j c j , i g j , i
Employees were ordered cardinally using the Task Advice Centrality. To construct the density of the working groups and the density of the entire institution, we refer to the graph G = (N, A), where N is the number of nodes and A the number of arcs, defined by the results of the interviews. The density of an oriented graph (Δ) was defined as Δ = L/n (n − 1), where n is the cardinality of N (the number of nodes) and where L is the cardinality of A (the number of arcs). The density value goes from 0 (completely isolated nodes) to 1 (maximum interconnection between the nodes). To calculate the density of each working group, we consider only the graph with horizontal connections among members belonging to each group (excluding managers and executives).
For the evaluation of skills, interviewees were asked to indicate how often they smartly achieve some organizational behavior. Each behavior is measured on a Likert scale from 1 to 7, which refers to a frequency that goes from “rarely” to “nearly always”. These organizational behaviors contribute to constituting various dimensions of competence (Ashton et al. 1999). We have chosen the following five skills as they effectively synthesize the qualities required to perform the kind of work that takes place within the institution (problem solving, team working, self-organizing, technology knowledge and customer oriented).
The “value index” is an indicator of the effort made by each employee. To realize it, a number from 1 to 10 was given together with the management of the organization; this number corresponds to the added value of each of the 140 activities represented in the job description of the institution and recorded daily by the management control. The indicator represents the average benefit of the activities carried out daily by each employee. In formulas;
V a l u e   I n d e x = i = 1 140 T i V i
where V is the value (from 1 to 10) assigned to the activity i and T is the time devoted to the same activity by the employee.
In order to verify the hypothesis H1 defined in Section 2, a linear regression was performed. In this regression, the dependent variable is the task advice centrality for the year 2011 (first detection) and the independent variables are the two monetary incentives (referred to 2010), the tenure (in years of service), the salary level (in eight levels), the five skills.
TaskAdviceCentralityi = β0 + β1OldMonetaryInc.i + β2NewMonetaryInc.i + β3Tenurei + β4LevelSalaryi + β5ProblemSolvingi + β6TeamWorkingi + β7SelfOrganizingi + β8TechnicalKnowledgei + β9CustomerOrientedi + β10ValueIndexi + β11χi + εi
Among the control variables, we can mention four different areas inside the PA considered. Table 2 summarizes the activity of each area. It is worth noting that we do not consider Area 5 in the analysis because it is only devoted to the proper functioning of the institution.
A preliminary regression analysis between predictors to test the independence of the factors was conducted and the significance of the model was verified with ANOVA test.
Then, to test hypothesis H2 another linear regression was performed using the same model with data of the second detection (year 2013, 2012 for the two monetary incentives).
To verify H3, we analyzed the horizontal pay dispersion calculating an estimated linear regression curve using the density in network consulting within the working groups and the Gini coefficient as variables.
Gini coefficient is defined as in Equation (4), see (Deaton 1997) for more details:
G = N + 1 N 1 2 N ( N 1 ) μ ( i = 1 n P i X i )
where   μ is mean income of the population P i is the income rank P of person i, with income X, such that the richest person has rank 1 and the poorest N. To better interpret the data, a non-parametric Loess strategy was also conducted to fit smooth curves to the empirical data (Jacoby 2000).

5. Results and Discussions

Table 3 shows the bivariate correlation between the variables used as predictive factors in the first hypothesis test (year 2011). Overlooking some intuitive correlations between the skills, the correlation between the two incentives “old” and “new” stands out (0.514**). That is because a part of their determinants is the same for the two incentive mechanisms, in particular the total working time. For the same reason the value index is significantly related to the two incentives (0.495** with the “old” one and 0.625** with the “new” one) and with the salary level (0.376**): it represents how individual employees occupy their time usefully for the institution. Moreover, observing the correlations between the areas with the other variables, there is a negative correlation (−0.2*) between area 3 and technical skills, because employees who belong to that area only work with their computers. It is worth noting that the value index and salary are positively correlated to one skill for two reasons. The first reason for this could be survey bias, since employees had to evaluate themselves and second, because the employees’ answers related to their skills were merged in summary indicators.
Table 4 shows the results of the regression test between the task advice centrality, i.e. employees’ performance, (dependent variable) and the predictors used. The adjusted R-square for this test was 0.245, and this is in line with the results obtained in the field of social sciences involving aspects related to human behavior (Achen 1982). The part of the variance explained by the predictors is slightly less than 40 percent (R2 = 34.2%), thus, the significance of the model is verified. Looking at the coefficients of the regressors, H1 is verified: one percentage point increasing in the task of advice centrality corresponds to 0.31 percentage points of new monetary incentive (p < 0.006). The negative coefficient (−0.19) of the old monetary incentive (p ≤ 0.069) is interesting, while the positive one (0.19) of the team working skills (p ≤ 0.067) is expected, because intuitively correlated with the ability to be central in the task advice network. The predictor “value index” is significant (p ≤ 0.046): there is a positive relationship between being central in the network and to carrying out intensive activities with high added value. The correlation with a negative beta value (−0.24) that links the centrality to area 4 is due to the fact that in this area employees are included who are frequently in contact with external institutions and some of them are technicians who work offsite. The fifth area, about internal services, was excluded from the predictive variables, and the other four areas are compared to this one.
Table 5 shows the bivariate correlations between the predictor variables of the second analysis (year 2013). Comparing with the first one (Table 3), the correlation between the new and the old incentive (0.633 **) becomes stronger. It also strengthens the positive relationship between salary level and the two incentives (0.246 * with the old and 0.368 with the new).
Table 6 shows the results of the regression between task advice centrality (the dependent variable) and the predictors used for the second analysis (year 2013). The adjusted R-square for this test was 0.264, a value similar to that obtained in the first test. The same applies to the explained variance (R2 = 36.5%). Looking at the individual predictors, there is a renewed significance of the new monetary incentive (p < 0.02); the coefficient (β) is 0.30; similar to the one of the first analysis (0.31). It highlights an inverse relationship that is stronger (−0.40) and more significant (p < 0.001) for the old incentive. The relationship between the task advice centrality and skills: team working loses significance while customer oriented gains (p < 0.082). We can observe a more significant convergence on the individual belonging areas, even though the angular coefficients are all negative. The highest coefficient (−0.43) is significantly related to the area 3 (p < 0.001): members belonging to this area are the least central, actually they are employees who work in open space in direct contact with external customers. The actual data shows that 14.8% of the employees considered (108, non-executives and managers) changed its performance rank. Specifically, nine people lost one, while seven gained one. These results support hypothesis H2.
A detailed analysis of the variation of cardinal task advice centrality in the network can be more precisely observed from the employees’ rank changes.
Table 7 underlines how people who received a lower incentive are the same who obtained the best performances (compared to the average). Those who saw their high level of incentive being confirmed also saw (on the average) their centrality in the network decreasing more.
This would seem to cause effects in opposition to those desired by the institution. The closed-rank distribution system does not encourage people who have already been rewarded during the previous year to improve their performance, even only with a slight increase, because it will be sufficient to be better performing than their colleagues.
The second aspect, positive for the objectives of the institution, is a consequence of the choice of the lower-class employees of accepting the competitive system. Employees were asked if monetary incentives were distributed based on the effectiveness of performance, i.e., if they consider them fair (“Fair Incentives”). This variable regresses positively (beta = 0.245) with the differential between the task advice centrality of year 2011 and the one of year 2013. This differential represents the performance variation (∆ performance). The other control variables (age, gender, tenure, area, skills) used in the regression model were not significant. Figure 1 shows the non-parametric Loess curve. It is possible to observe that it indicates a decline in a straight linear relationship with those employees who, to the question in the questionnaire “how fair are the incentives that you received?” indicated the answer “incentives are very fair” (7 on Likert scale). It is worth noting that it is possible that some employees hid their thinking behind this highest rating.
To observe the extent of the inequality of the distribution of monetary incentives within individual business units, the Gini coefficient was used. It is worth remembering that it is a measure of concentration and ranges between 0 (pure equal distribution) and 1 (maximum inequality) (Bloom 1999; Donaldson and Weymark 1980). We compared this indicator with the density of trade consulting within the working groups for each survey year (see Figure 2). We used the program UCINET 6 (Borgatti et al. 2002) to calculate the density of the working groups. The regression test was significant, and the angular coefficient β was negative in both investigations. β was equal to −0.548 in the first survey and β equal to −0.732 for the second one. Therefore, hypothesis H3 is verified. Usually, according to social network analysis, low levels of interaction correspond to a density lower than 0.30 and to a Gini coefficient larger than 0.25. Observing Figure 2, the Gini coefficient is less than 0.20 and 0.23 in the first and second case, respectively. In the literature, the total wage is used to calculate the Gini coefficient, and we normally study the national coefficients that have a range of between 0.25 and 0.40 for developed countries. Levels around 0.20 are therefore considered already very low, even if they are related to a single public-sector entity characterized by a very competitive environment.
Summarizing the results, first the introduction of a competitive system, structured as a “closed-rank tournament rank”, encourages employees (non-managers) to improve their performance (H1 hypothesis is verified). Second, the angular coefficient of the new monetary incentive predictor is analogous to that of the previous test and there are 14.8% of employees that changed their rank (H2 hypothesis is verified). Moreover, it is worth noting that in the literature there is a great debate about whether monetary incentives are a bonus for the good performance or a stimulus to do a better job in the next period of observation. In this paper, we also implicitly investigate this issue. With H1 and H2 we investigate whether monetary incentives are a stimulus for good behavior and the answer is positive. It is worth noting that when we study the performance of year 2011, we consider the monetary incentives of 2010, and when we consider the performance of 2013, we consider the monetary incentives of 2012.
Comparing the results of the investigation of H1 and H2, in some way we also answer the reverse causality because if the monetary incentives induce a virtuous employees’ behavior, it also means that the monetary incentives are distributed according the employees’ performance, which means that the monetary incentives represent a bonus for the employees’ performance.
Finally, the density of the overall network decreases, but we cannot prove that this is due to the new system of incentives. The inverse relationship between the Gini coefficient and the density of trade consultancy within individual working groups corroborated the H3 hypothesis. A high dispersion of pay levels appears to inhibit relationships within the organization.

6. Conclusions

This study is one of the first attempts, in the public sector, to test the response behavior of employees (belonging to the same level) to the introduction of a merit-based incentive system that follows a “rank-order tournament” logic. The management has disclosed transparently what the objectives of the incentive system are, trying as much as possible to ensure fairness in the evaluation criteria. The results have shown a modification of individual behaviors, in line with the theoretical foundations and with the predictions initially formulated. This occurred despite the use of an ordinal, and not cardinal system type, to compare the performance of individual employees. Employees do not have to compete only with themselves, but their performance will be evaluated in relation to the ones of others and the result of the comparison will be known only at the end. This study observed the results of the interaction between monetary incentives and employees’ performance for a cycle of application. Using this system in the next period of evaluation increases employees’ responsiveness to incitation from managers, as suggested by Homans and other supporters of the theory of social exchange. The primary objective of those who control the pay system design is to avoid the crystallization of the rank-order to discourage behaviors that tend to reduce the effort of individual employees. This has not happened in this case because there were 14.8% of employees who changed their incentive level of merit. A closer observation of what happened in the two years considered shows how those who saw a higher incentive level being confirmed decreased their performance more (on average). This is in line with the deprivation-satiation proposition, according to which the more frequently a person has received major rewards in the recent past, the less s/he will confer a value to any further reward (Homans 1974). We observed a decrease in overall density of trade advisory. Performing a detailed analysis of the performance of the individual working groups, it was seen that as a high density of trade advisory is negatively connected to high inequality in the distribution of monetary incentives. In the long term, therefore, this system seems to inhibit collaboration among employees. This is in line with the claims of other scholars (Shaw et al. 2002; Shaw 2014) who argue that in environments that require another interdependence among workers, a low compression of levels of pay are preferable. We underline that the lack of group-reward logic may have played a decisive role in this outcome.

Author Contributions

G.C.C., F.D., and L.P. designed research, performed research, analyzed data, and wrote the paper.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge the Camera di Commercio di Genova for useful discussions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Achen, Christopher H. 1982. Interpreting and Using Regression. Sage University Paper series on Quantitative Applications in the Social Sciences; Beverly Hills: Sage. [Google Scholar]
  2. Adams, J. Stacy. 1963. Towards an understanding of inequity. The Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 67: 422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Andersen, Lotte Bøgh. 2007. Professional norms, public service motivation and economic incentives: What motivates public employees. In Ikke angivet. Aarhus: Department of Political Science, University of Aarhus. [Google Scholar]
  4. Andersen, Lotte Bøgh. 2009. What determines the behaviour and performance of health professionals? Public service motivation, professional norms and/or economic incentives. International Review of Administrative Sciences 75: 79–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ashton, David, Bryn Davies, Alan Felstead, and Francis Green. 1999. Work skills in Britain. SKOPE Monograph 1: 4. [Google Scholar]
  6. Atkinson, Michael M., Murray Fulton, and Boa Kim. 2014. Why do governments use pay for performance? Contrasting theories and interview evidence. Canadian Public Administration 57: 436–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Baldwin, Timothy T., Michael D. Bedell, and Jonathan L. Johnson. 1997. The social fabric of a team-based MBA program: Network effects on student satisfaction and performance. Academy of Management Journal 40: 1369–97. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bannò, Mariasole, and Francesca Sgobbi. 2010. Firm participation in financial incentive programmes: The case of subsidies for outward internationalisation. Journal of Policy Modeling 32: 792–803. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Barnard, C., and Herbert A. Simon. 1947. Administrative Behavior. A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organizaztion. New York: Macmillan. [Google Scholar]
  10. Beaumont, Phillip B., and Richard ID Harris. 2003. Internal wage structures and organizational performance. British Journal of Industrial Relations 41: 53–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Belle, Nicola. 2015. Performance-Related Pay and the Crowding Out of Motivation in the Public Sector: A Randomized Field Experiment. Public Administration Review 75: 230–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Belle, Nicola, and Paola Cantarelli. 2015. Monetary incentives, motivation, and job effort in the public sector: An experimental study with Italian government executives. Review of Public Personnel Administration 35: 99–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Berumen, Sergio A., Luis P. Pérez-Megino, and Karen Arriaza Ibarra. 2016. Extrinsic motivation index: A new tool for managing labor productivity. International Journal of Business Science & Applied Management (IJBSAM) 11: 1–17. [Google Scholar]
  14. Bloom, Matt. 1999. The performance effects of pay dispersion on individuals and organizations. Academy of Management Journal 42: 25–40. [Google Scholar]
  15. Boachie-Mensah, Francis, and Ophelia Delali Dogbe. 2011. Performance-Based pay as a motivational tool for achieving organizational performance: An exploratory case study. International Journal of Business and Management 6: 270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Boissevain, Jeremy, and J. Clyde Mitchell, eds. 2018. Network Analysis: Studies in Human Interaction. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter GmbH & Co KG. [Google Scholar]
  17. Booth, Alison L., and Jeff Frank. 1999. Earnings, productivity, and performance-related pay. Journal of Labor Economics 17: 447–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Borgatti, Stephen P., Martin G. Everett, and Linton C. Freeman. 2002. UCINET for Windows: Software for social network analysis. Harvard, MA: Analytic Technologies 6: 12–15. [Google Scholar]
  19. Boswell, Wendy R., John B. Bingham, and Alexander JS Colvin. 2006. Aligning employees through line of sight. Business Horizons 49: 499–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Chang, Eunmi. 2011. Motivational effects of pay for performance: A multilevel analysis of a Korean case. International Journal of Human Resource Management 22: 3929–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Cook, Karen S., Richard M Emerson, Mary R Gillmore, and Toshio Yamagishi. 1983. The distribution of power in exchange networks: Theory and experimental results. American journal of sociology 89: 275–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Dahlström, Carl, and Victor Lapuente. 2017. Organizing Leviathan: Politicians, Bureaucrats, and The Making of Good Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  23. Davidson, Stephen M., Larry M. Manheim, Mina M. Hohlen, Stephen M. Werner, Beth K. Yudkowsky, and Gretchen V. Fleming. 1992. Prepayment with office-based physicians in publicly funded programs: Results from the children’s Medicaid program. Pediatrics 89: 761–67. [Google Scholar]
  24. Davis, James H., F. David Schoorman, and Lex Donaldson. 1997. Toward a stewardship theory of management. Academy of Management Review 22: 20–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Deaton, Angus. 1997. The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. Washington: World Bank Publications. [Google Scholar]
  26. Donaldson, David, and John A. Weymark. 1980. A single-parameter generalization of the Gini indices of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 22: 67–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Dowling, Bernard, and Ray Richardson. 1997. Evaluating performance-related pay for managers in the National Health Service. International Journal of Human Resource Management 8: 348–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Eisenhardt, Kathleen M. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review 14: 57–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Frey, Bruno S., Fabian Homberg, and Margit Osterloh. 2013. Organizational control systems and pay-for-performance in the public service. Organization Studies 34: 949–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Gini, Corrado. 1921. Measurement of Inequality of Incomes. The Economic Journal 31: 124–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Greenberg, Jerald. 1990. Organizational justice: Yesterday, today, and tomorrow. Journal of Management 16: 399–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Hansen, Morten T. 1999. The search-transfer problem: The role of weak ties in sharing knowledge across organization subunits. Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 82–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Heneman, Robert L., David B. Greenberger, and Stephen Strasser. 1988. The relationship between pay-for-performance perceptions and pay satisfaction. Personnel Psychology 41: 745–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Homans, George C. 1974. Social Behavior: Its elementary Forms, rev. ed. Oxford: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. [Google Scholar]
  35. Hutchison, Brian, Stephen Birch, Jeremiah Hurley, Jonathan Lomas, and Fawne Stratford-Devai. 1996. Do physician-payment mechanisms affect hospital utilization? A study of Health Service Organizations in Ontario. CMAJ: Canadian Medical Association Journal 154: 653. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  36. Jacoby, William G. 2000. Loess: a nonparametric, graphical tool for depicting relationships between variables. Electoral Studies 19: 577–613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Katou, Anastasia. 2011. Test of a causal human resource management-performance linkage model: evidence from the Greek manufacturing sector. International Journal of Business Science & Applied Management (IJBSAM) 6: 16–29. [Google Scholar]
  38. Knoeber, Charles R., and Walter N. Thurman. 1994. Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production. Journal of Labor Economics 12: 155–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Kouides, Ruth W., Nancy M. Bennett, Bonnie Lewis, Joseph D. Cappuccio, William H. Barker, and F. Marc LaForce. 1998. Performance-based physician reimbursement and influenza immunization rates in the elderly. American Journal of Preventive Medicine 14: 89–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Krasnik, Allan, Peter P. Groenewegen, Poul A. Pedersen, Peter von Scholten, Gavin Mooney, Adam Gottschau, Henk A. Flierman, and Mogens T. Damsgaard. 1990. Changing remuneration systems: effects on activity in general practice. Bmj 300: 1698–701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  41. Ladley, Daniel, Ian Wilkinson, and Louise Young. 2015. The impact of individual versus group rewards on work group performance and cooperation: A computational social science approach. Journal of Business Research 68: 2412–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and David Martimort. 2001. The Theory of Incentives: The Principal-Agent Model. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton university press. [Google Scholar]
  43. Lah, T. J., and James L. Perry. 2008. The diffusion of the Civil Service Reform Act of 1978 in OECD countries: A tale of two paths to reform. Review of Public Personnel Administration 28: 282–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Larson, Jr, James R, Caryn Christensen, Timothy M. Franz, and Ann S. Abbott. 1998. Diagnosing groups: the pooling, management, and impact of shared and unshared case information in team-based medical decision making. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 75: 93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  45. Lazear, Edward P. 1989. Pay equality and industrial politics. Journal of Political Economy 97: 561–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Lazear, Edward P., and Sherwin Rosen. 1979. Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. Journal of Political Economy 89: 841–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Luthans, Fr. 1973. The contingency theory of management: A path out of the jungle. Business Horizons 16: 67–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Marsden, David, and Stephen French. 2002. Performance pay in the United Kingdom. New York: ME Sharpe. [Google Scholar]
  49. Mavor, Anne S., and Renae F. Broderick. 1991. Pay for Performance: Evaluating Performance Appraisal and Merit Pay. Washington: National Academies Press. [Google Scholar]
  50. Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts. 1992. Economics, Organization, and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. [Google Scholar]
  51. Miller, Gary J., and Andrew B. Whitford. 2007. The principal’s moral hazard: Constraints on the use of incentives in hierarchy. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 17: 213–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Molm, Linda D. 1994. Dependence and risk: Transforming the structure of social exchange. Social Psychology Quarterly, 163–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Ouchi, William. G. 1977. The relationship between organizational structure and organizational control. Administrative Science Quarterly 22: 95–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Ouchi, William. G. 1979. A conceptual framework for the design of organizational control. Management Science 25: 833–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Perry, James L., Trent A. Engbers, and So Yun Jun. 2009. Back to the Future? Performance-Related Pay, Empirical Research, and the Perils of Persistence. Public Administration Review 69: 39–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Rosen, Sherwin. 1985. Prizes and incentives in elimination tournaments. No. w1668. National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Salzman, James. 1999. Labor Rights, Globalization and Institutions: The Role and Influence of the Organization and Development. Michigan Journal of International Law 21: 769. [Google Scholar]
  58. Shaw, Jason D. 2014. Pay dispersion. Annual Review of Organizational Psychology and Organizational Behavior 1: 521–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Shaw, Jason D., Nina Gupta, and John E. Delery. 2002. Pay dispersion and workforce performance: Moderating effects of incentives and interdependence. Strategic Management Journal 23: 491–512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Skinner, B. F. 1984. Theoretical contingencies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 7: 541–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Spano, Alessandro, and Patrizio Monfardini. 2018. Performance-Related Payments in Local Governments: Do They Improve Performance or Only Increase Salary? International Journal of Public Administration 41: 321–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Stajkovic, Alexander D., and Fred Luthans. 1997. A meta-analysis of the effects of organizational behavior modification on task performance, 1975–95. Academy of Management journal 40: 1122–49. [Google Scholar]
  63. Van Eerde, Wendelien, and Henk Thierry. 1996. Vroom’s expectancy models and work-related criteria: A meta-analysis. Journal of applied psychology 81: 575. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Weibel, Antoinette, Katja Rost, and Margit Osterloh. 2009. Pay for performance in the public sector? Benefits and (hidden) costs. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 20: 387–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Whitford, Andrew B. 2006. Incentives and tournaments in public organizations. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=873488 (accessed on 14 September 2019).
  66. Levitats, Zehavit, and Eran Vigoda-Gadot. 2019. Emotionally Engaged Civil Servants: Toward a Multilevel Theory and Multisource Analysis in Public Administration. Review of Public Personnel Administration. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Estimated linear regression curve.
Figure 1. Estimated linear regression curve.
Admsci 09 00072 g001
Figure 2. Estimated linear regression and Loess curve (50% points to adapt, kernel uniform) for 2011 and 2013.
Figure 2. Estimated linear regression and Loess curve (50% points to adapt, kernel uniform) for 2011 and 2013.
Admsci 09 00072 g002
Table 1. Employees sets according to L.D. 150/09.
Table 1. Employees sets according to L.D. 150/09.
SetPerformance Level% of Employees% of Optional Pay
1High2550
2Medium5050
3Low250
Table 2. Area 1- Area 5 description.
Table 2. Area 1- Area 5 description.
SymbolActivityDescription
Area 1Support, Staff & PersonnelPresidential services, secretariat, Human Resource services
Area 2Promotional ActivitiesBack office work. Personalized services to companies with high added value.
Business support, promotion of economic development and monitoring, studying and analysis of local economic data
Area 3Registry servicesFront-office service in open space. Help citizens to compile files, updating of registers and lists with the main events that characterize the life of every enterprise.
Area 4Market regulationBack office work. Regulator of the market, less contact with the public except for the settlement of disputes arising from economic relations between businesses.
Area 5Internal ServicesAcquisition of goods and services necessary for the operation of internal offices. Maintenance of the property of the institution.
Table 3. Pearson correlations between predictors of the first detection.
Table 3. Pearson correlations between predictors of the first detection.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Old monetary incentive (1)1
New monetary incentive (2)0.514 **1
Problem solving (3)0.1040.1491
Team working (4)−0.0270.0930.364 **1
Self-organizing (5)0.0490.217 *0.454 **0.338 **1
Technical knowledge (6)0.1460.1620.389 **0.318 **0.314 **1
Customer oriented (7)0.0380.0660.430 **0.427 **0.367 **0.331 **1
Value index (8)0.495 **0.625 **0.1260.1080.1450.198 *0.0171
Salary level (9)0.1710.308 **0.099−0.0540.0820.0510.1410.376 **1
Tenure (10)−0.082−0.072−0.160−0.004−0.179−0.1390.0980.0710.0001
** The correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (two-tailed). * The correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (two-tailed).
Table 4. First detection (year 2011).
Table 4. First detection (year 2011).
Dependent Variable: Task Advice Centrality
PredictorsCoefficientSEpSign.
(Constant) 32.550.631
Old monetary incentive−0.190.010.069*
New monetary incentive0.310.000.006***
Problem solving0.013.020.905
Team working0.192.570.067*
Self-organizing−0.142.600.200
Technical knowledge0.122.400.216
Customer oriented−0.152.870.189
Value index0.230.000.046**
Salary level0.054.870.638
Tenure0.140.340.119
Area 10.079.650.506
Area 2−0.1510.070.216
Area 30.058.210.702
Area 4−0.2410.380.043**
R2 adjusted0.245
ANOVA Test F3.499<0.000
Table 5. Pearson correlations between predictors of the second detection.
Table 5. Pearson correlations between predictors of the second detection.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Old monetary incentive (1)1
New monetary incentive (2)0.633 **1
Problem solving (3)0.0600.1561
Team working (4)−0.040−0.0200.461 **1
Self-organizing (5)0.1840.1580.547 **0.362 **1
Technical knowledge (6)0.0460.0930.496 **0.415 **0.466 **1
Customer oriented (7)−0.0190.0230.464 **0.456 **0.551 **0.500 **1
Value index (8)0.604 **0.645 **0.047−0.0160.0270.031−0.0311
Salary level (9)0.246 *0.368 **0.093−0.0090.152−0.0620.0610.309 **1
Tenure (10)−0.0210.021−0.0180.0160.058−0.1340.0760.023−0.0231
Note: ** The correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (two-tailed). * The correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (two-tailed).
Table 6. Second detection (year 2013).
Table 6. Second detection (year 2013).
Dependent Variable: Task Advice Centrality
PredictorsCoefficientSEpSign.
(Constant) 28.320.029
Old monetary incentive-0.400.010.001***
New monetary incentive0.300.000.020**
Problem solving-0.072.060.554
Team working-0.062.160.564
Self-organizing-0.082.250.499
Technical knowledge-0.192.470.120
Customer oriented0.212.580.082*
Value index0.250.000.050**
Salary level0.073.850.543
Tenure0.090.260.333
Area 10.017.460.934
Area 2-0.218.600.095*
Area 3-0.436.730.001***
Area 4-0.219.060.076*
R2 adjusted0.264
ANOVA Test F3.612<0.000
Table 7. The variation of the centrality compared to the change in the levels of incentives.
Table 7. The variation of the centrality compared to the change in the levels of incentives.
Employees’ StatusΔ Centrality (2013 Compared to 2011)
Mean (% total)Variance (% total)
who gained a level of incentive−7.3 (114)5.8 (46)
who remained stable (above the general mean)−10.8 (169)17.1 (134)
who remained stable (under the general mean)−4.7 (73)10.6 (83)
who lost a level of incentive−5.6 (87)13.8 (108)
Total−6.4 (100)12.8 (100)

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Cainarca, G.C.; Delfino, F.; Ponta, L. The Effect of Monetary Incentives on Individual and Organizational Performance in an Italian Public Institution. Adm. Sci. 2019, 9, 72. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci9030072

AMA Style

Cainarca GC, Delfino F, Ponta L. The Effect of Monetary Incentives on Individual and Organizational Performance in an Italian Public Institution. Administrative Sciences. 2019; 9(3):72. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci9030072

Chicago/Turabian Style

Cainarca, Gian Carlo, Francesco Delfino, and Linda Ponta. 2019. "The Effect of Monetary Incentives on Individual and Organizational Performance in an Italian Public Institution" Administrative Sciences 9, no. 3: 72. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci9030072

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop