1. Introduction
Ecological function area (EFA), designated as a critical zone for environmental protection and ecosystem service delivery, is pivotal for supporting sustainable urban development [
1]. By strategically utilizing reserve space, EFAs help create integrated urban functional areas that support high quality agricultural production and enhance ecosystem services, which promotes new industries (such as the low-carbon and carbon sink industries) to support regional green development [
2]. However, the EFA faces two interrelated challenges stemming from the prolonged absence of systematic territorial spatial planning (TSP). Firstly, inefficient ecosystem services (provisioning, supporting, regulating, and cultural services) and poorly circulated ecological products hinder EFAs from meeting urban populations’ multidimensional demands, undermining regional sustainability [
1]. Secondly, farmers in an EFA often ignore the ecological function and corresponding benefits to depend on limited and underdeveloped livelihoods (such as supplying primary agricultural products). As a result of the EFA’s ecological conservation strategy and the simplified framework for farmers’ livelihoods, the shrinking space for economic land use can perpetuate low economic returns to ecological goods and services, which suppresses farmers’ incomes and exacerbates the urban–rural income gap [
3]. Therefore, how to identify systematic TSP shaping farmers’ incomes has emerged as a critical research priority to resolve intertwined ecological and economic challenges in an EFA.
In general, territorial spatial planning (TSP) is understood to be the spatial reallocation of ecological and economic spaces based on the various land uses and characteristics, which can mediate the trade-off between economic growth and environmental protection [
4]. Previous studies highlight that governments utilize TSP to optimize the ratio of ecological to economic land use, thereby enhancing regional ecological functions [
5,
6]. Some research demonstrates that expanding ecological land space not only safeguards environmental integrity but also transforms farmers’ livelihoods by providing ecological goods and services [
7]. This transformation enables farmers to make the transition from traditional agricultural methods to eco-agriculture through the integration of factors of production such as capital, labor, and technology, which can generate diversified sources of income through participation in the ecological industrial chain [
8]. Therefore, research on effective TSP and its corresponding policies (e.g., land consolidation, returning farmland to forests, ecological compensation mechanisms, etc.) to improve the efficiency of land use and increase farmers’ incomes has become the focus of attention of many scholars [
9,
10,
11,
12]. For instance, Cao et al. have analyzed Ziwuling’s Natural Forest Protection Plan to show that the plan’s costs were borne disproportionately by the local population: prohibitions on logging and grazing hindered livestock farming and decreased revenue [
13]. Similarly, Collins et al. have argued that environmental policies often neglect economic trade-offs, inadvertently lowering local incomes [
14]. Deng et al. have proposed the expansion of ecological land curtails agricultural activities while directly diminishing the land available for cultivation, which could reduce farmers’ incomes [
15]. All the above research works indicated that a scientific and efficient design of TSP and corresponding strategies could change the economic interests of farmers, which would confront the risk of tensions between economic growth and ecological preservation for further sustainable development objectives.
The Sustainable Livelihoods Framework (SLF) is regarded as an effective manner in that farmers respond to government TSP, which refers to the capacity of individuals and communities to collectively mobilize resources, address challenges, enhance resilience, and protect natural resources [
16]. Building on this framework, previous scholars have employed a number of methods such as livelihood capital indices, vulnerability assessments, income diversity metrics, and the entropy-weighted TOPSIS method to capture sustainable livelihood indicators through spatial differentiation of livelihood capital and natural resource distribution [
17,
18,
19]. Meanwhile, various studies revealed the interplay between sustainable livelihoods and ecosystem services, climate change, and ecological compensation. These factors shaped sustainable livelihoods by driving income diversification, influencing economic stability, and fostering the residents’ level of participation [
20,
21]. Sustainable livelihoods continue to be extremely vulnerable to TSP decisions, especially in an EFA where land serves as both a primary asset and a constraint [
22]. Thus, scholars have investigated TSP’s impact on sustainable livelihood strategies. For example, Willson found TSP combined with environmental protection programs could promote advanced livelihood transformation, which would prevent a resurgence of deforestation brought on by farmer economic pressures [
23]. Alexander et al. demonstrated that TSP in an EFA could be grounded in community consensus, which could highlight the importance of participatory frameworks in ensuring sustainable development by striking a balance between improved farmer livelihoods and ecological conservation [
24]. Fanta et al. evaluated the effects of community-based TSP in Ethiopia to find that participating households could achieve higher crop yields and agricultural incomes compared to non-participants [
25]. Similarly, Xia et al. studied the role of Land Consolidation Programs (LCPs) in reducing rural poverty and showed that well-designed LCPs enhance livelihoods through increasing agricultural productivity, land registration, direct income, public welfare, and tourism-driven economic development [
26]. Yet these studies seldom quantify how livelihood upgrading dynamically amplifies ecological land resources’ income-promoting effects in EFAs. We further reveal that higher levels of dynamic livelihood-upgrading enhance the positive impact of ecological land on farmers’ incomes. Thus, investigating how an EFA can successfully raise farmers’ standard of living and thereby carry out their function of raising farmers’ incomes becomes essential. Nevertheless, existing studies grounded in the SLF predominantly focus on preserving livelihood stability under external shocks, neglecting the dynamic process of livelihood upgrading through intentional capital reallocation and strategy innovation. To address this gap, we propose the concept of advanced livelihoods (ALI), which prioritizes proactive transitions from survival-oriented activities to development-driven livelihoods. Consequently, given the insufficient supply of ecosystem services and the underdeveloped livelihoods of farmers in an EFA, this study aims to integrate ALI as a critical regulator between ecological land resources and farmers’ income growth in EFA, grounded in ecological economics and policy optimization theories [
27,
28]. We seek to address the following gaps: (i) Quantify how ecological land expansion under TSP differentially impacts farmers’ incomes across protection-oriented and development-oriented zones. (ii) Identify whether ALI amplifies income gains through livelihood diversification, efficiency enhancement, or sustainability transitions. (iii) Determine the threshold combinations of TSP interventions and ALI-driven adaptations that maximize ecological-economic synergies. (iv) Determine how to combine fixed effects with machine learning for causal identification and policy simulation. Through policy scenario simulations, we further demonstrate ALI’s moderating role in bridging land conservation and income growth.
To address this gap, this study selected Beijing, China as a typical case to conduct the impact of ecological land resources on farmers’ income. Beijing’s EFA spans the areas of Mentougou (core conservation area) and Fangshan (restoration area), which is critical for the protection of water resources and biodiversity in China’s capital region. However, TSP under the ecological redline policy has constrained traditional farming development and has also shrunk economic land space, trapping farmers in low-value agricultural activities. This tension underscores the urgent need to reconcile ecological integrity with income growth through innovative livelihood transitions.
Therefore, this study constructs the ecological land resources on the farmers’ incomes (FELI) framework, which can address how government territorial spatial planning (TSP) (expansion of ecological land resources and contraction of economic land resources) in EFAs can increase farmer incomes by influencing ecosystem functioning and integrating factors of production to influence farmers’ production methods and livelihood capital choices. Advanced livelihood approaches can be considered in FELI to moderate the impact of ecological land resources on farmers’ incomes, which benefits farmers in terms of productivity and diversification of income sources. To capture the nonlinear dynamics between ecological land use, livelihood transitions, and policy interventions, we integrate advanced econometric models with machine learning techniques. This approach enables both causal inference and predictive scenario simulations. The obtained results can not only provide theoretical references for the government’s further TSP planning of EFA but also provide a better understanding of the ecological function zones from the perspective of advanced livelihoods for regional farmers. Building on this foundation, the contributions of this study are as follows: (1) The FELI framework integrates ecological economics with policy optimization, quantifying how TSP reconfigures land resources and how ALI amplifies income gains via three pathways: livelihood diversification, efficiency enhancement, and sustainability transitions. (2) Methodologically, we pioneer a causal–predictive synthesis combining econometric models with machine learning. This identifies threshold combinations of TSP interventions and ALI adaptations that maximize synergies while revealing spatial heterogeneity. (3) We empirically validate ALI’s moderating role in Beijing’s EFA—demonstrating how policy-livelihood co-adaptation operationalizes Ostrom’s governance theory [
28] and China’s “Two Mountains” doctrine. By proving that high ALI levels transform land conservation from an income constraint to a development accelerator, this study offers a transferable paradigm for global EFA.
2. Theoretical Analysis
Within the institutional reconfiguration of EFA driven by land function transformation from economic use to ecological protection, a series of challenges emerges: (1) Territorial spatial planning (TSP) by governments associated with ecological land resources expanding under ecological protection policies can reduce the scale of cultivated land space (agricultural production) for farmers, which would bring about pressure on regional economic development in an EFA; (2) Various TSP strategies such as returning farmland to forest (RFF) can guide farmers’ livelihood to a sustainable way with consideration of ecological-value-oriented industries (such as ecotourism services and green agriculture) instead of traditional agriculture activities. (3) Insufficient livelihood capital (such as financial capital, human capital, natural capital, etc.) supply on account of production factors can restrict farmers’ livelihood transformation, which requires a comprehensive governmental TSP and environmental regulation in an EFA for regional ecological protection and farmers’ income improvement.
Therefore, drawing on ecosystem services valuation theory and Ostrom’s institutional analysis of commons [
27,
28], a theoretical analysis and empirical framework associated with the impact of ecological land resources on farmers’ incomes (FELI) in Beijing’s EFA was constructed, which reflects the complex relationship between ecological land resources and farmers’ incomes through the moderating role of advanced farmers’ livelihoods (as shown in
Figure 1). The core proposition is that government-led TSP reconfigures land systems through two interdependent pathways consistent with the “Two Mountains” theory: Firstly, expanding ecological land can amplify regulating services and cultural services, thereby promoting income-generating assets. In general, the government implements differentiated allocation of economic land and ecological land through TSP, which sets up ecological function areas and promotes ecological restoration projects. On the one hand, it can enhance the regional ecological service functions by increasing ecological land resources; on the other hand, land use control changes farmers’ disposable resource endowment so that they can adjust their choice of livelihood capital and strategies, which creates a transmission chain of “government land resource planning–land use transformation–farmers’ livelihood response”. On this basis, ecological land resources can be deemed as an important ecological factor in FELI, which can be planned by the government to prompt regional economic outcomes and ecological goals. Secondly, TSP-induced land use transitions alter farmers’ access to natural capital while incentivizing the reallocation of human capital and financial capital. Under these situations, farmers deemed as “small-scale production units” can adjust their livelihood options based on various ecological and economic factors (such as ecological land resource, capital, labor, and technique) in combination with the sustainable livelihoods framework. Furthermore, by adjusting production methods and livelihood strategies, it ultimately affects farmers’ incomes. In this process, farmers’ advanced living standards play an important role as a moderating variable, which means that the higher the advanced living standards, the stronger the ability of farmers to optimize the allocation of their livelihood capital and realize the transformation of their livelihood activities so that they can more effectively transform the ecological benefits into their own income growth. Furthermore, policy scenarios are set up in intervention types of government regulation and farmers’ livelihood transformation to simulate the changes in farmers’ incomes under different circumstances in order to identify the optimal intervention pathway and explicitly test how policy can enhance ALI’s bridging role in realizing “lucid waters and lush mountains as invaluable assets”.
4. Result and Discussion
The delineation of Beijing’s ecological functional areas follows the “Regulations on Ecological Protection and Green Development of Beijing’s Ecological Cultivation Areas”. Based on the layout of Beijing’s urban master plan, the entire area of the five districts of Mentougou, Pinggu, Huairou, Miyun, and Yanqing and the mountainous areas of Fangshan and Changping are included in the ecological conservation area, which covers a total area of 11,300 square kilometers, 68 percent of the city’s area. The region faces various challenges as follows: (1) the vulnerability of the ecosystem is outstanding. The high proportion of planted forests has led to low carbon sink capacity, such as Yanqing District, where the forest unit volume is only 63% of the national average; (2) people’s livelihoods are lagging behind. The per capita disposable income of rural residents in the five districts is 18% lower than that of the city, and 70% of the low-income villages are concentrated in the region; (3) the ecological value of the conversion mechanism is missing. Existing compensation standards for public welfare forests are insufficient to cover the cost of care, while market-based compensation such as carbon trading is still in the exploratory stage. Therefore, the seven districts (Mentougou District, Fangshan District, Changping District, Huairou District, Pinggu District, Miyun District, and Yanqing District) of Beijing were selected as the research object. The variables are selected as follows.
The explanatory variable is farmers’ income (FI2), which is measured using rural per capita income, and the data were logarithmized to eliminate heteroskedasticity and denoted as lnFI2. The explanatory variable is the area of ecological land resources (lnLL), which is measured using the total area of grasslands, woodlands, and water bodies, and the data were logarithmized to eliminate heteroskedasticity. Control variables include the following: (1) Government investment (lnGI). Grounded in public investment theory, government expenditure on energy conservation and environmental protection directly improves farmers’ production conditions through ecological compensation, infrastructure development, and environmental governance, thereby reducing ecological protection costs. Concurrently, it indirectly enhances income through green employment creation and technology promotion. The data were logarithmically transformed to mitigate heteroskedasticity. (2) Fertilizer application (lnCA). Based on induced technological change theory, chemical fertilizer inputs increase agricultural income by enhancing land productivity. However, excessive application may lead to environmental degradation, creating a trade-off with the environmental constraints of ecological land use. The data were logarithmically transformed to mitigate heteroskedasticity. (3) Revenue from services (lnms). Following the sustainable livelihoods framework, ecological land provides resource foundations for rural tourism and wellness industries through landscape value and biodiversity, directly augmenting non-agricultural income. This control variable helps distinguish between the “resource effect” and “industrial effect” of ecological land, preventing service industry revenues from obscuring the independent impact of ecological land. The data were logarithmically transformed to mitigate heteroskedasticity. (4) Primary industry value-added ratio (lncz). In accordance with industrial structure theory, the agricultural proportion reflects economic structural transformation that directly affects farmers’ income sources and efficiency. Ecological functional zones may inhibit non-agricultural development through industrial access restrictions. The logarithmic transformation of this ratio enhances sensitivity in capturing heterogeneous impacts of industrial transformation on income, specifically revealing the pathway through which ecological land affects farmers’ income via industrial development constraints.
Data from Beijing Statistical Yearbook. The study area is seven districts (Mentougou, Fangshan, Changping, Huairou, Pinggu, Miyun, and Yanqing), and the sample period is from 2013 to 2022 based on data availability. The software used for the calculations and regressions was STATA 16.0. Descriptive statistics for each variable are shown in
Table 2.
4.1. Empirical Analysis of the Effects of Land Resources on Farmers’ Income in Ecological Function Areas
4.1.1. Benchmark Regression Results
Table 3 (1) shows that ecological land resources have a significant positive effect on farmers’ income due to the farmers’ production-manner adjustment guided by the governmental green strategy and corresponding TSP in an EFA. Based on the TSP of the EFA, ecotourism, forest recreation, and other new industries based on ecological land resources have emerged through green strategy guidance. Farmers would respond to the governmental strategy to adjust production manner, which is beneficial to convert ecological resources into economic value instead of selling agricultural products; meanwhile, farmers can directly earn business and labor income by participating in tourism service positions. It indicates that ecological land resources would increase farmers’ income, which is consistent with the extended C-D production function model. On the other hand, the government subsidizes farmers for ecological land designated for the protection of the ecological environment and the restriction of development, which provides farmers with a stable ecological compensation payment that becomes an important part of their income. Furthermore, the inclusion of economic land resources (arable land and garden land) (lnNL) in the regression equation (as shown in
Table 3 (2)) reveals that the increase in economic land resources has a significant negative effect on farmers’ income in an EFA. The reasons are summarized as follows: first, economic land compression directly leads to the loss of contiguous land for some farmers, which makes it difficult to carry out large-scale cultivation. Meanwhile, the difficulty in sharing the cost of mechanical operations and irrigation makes the production cost per unit area increase instead of decrease; second, documents such as the “Regulations on Ecological Protection and Green Development of Beijing’s Ecological Culvert Areas” create harsh constraints on the use of pesticides and fertilizers and the selection of crop varieties; third, GlobeLand30 data analysis shows that the increase in construction land in Beijing from 2000 to 2020 has exacerbated the degradation of arable land quality, which directly restricts the efficiency of agricultural production and the added value of crops; finally, the China Natural Resources Development Report (2023) points out that the imperfections in ecological compensation and policy regulation mechanisms have led to the obstruction of agricultural productivity enhancement, exacerbating the difficulties in increasing farmers’ incomes. Particularly, the coefficient of service income is not significant, probably because the income from informal economic activities such as agro-industry and handicraft sales may not be included in the statistics, which leads to underestimation of the data; on the other hand, services such as ecotourism need to be cultivated for a long period of time in order to show economic benefits, and if the study period is relatively short (e.g., at the early stage of the project), it may not be able to capture the dynamic process of income growth.
In addition, the increase in “share of primary sector value added” may reflect only the expansion of inefficient agriculture rather than quality improvements. The positive pull effect on income is thus offset by multiple structural contradictions, manifesting a statistically negative but insignificant relationship. On the one hand, the strict restrictions on agricultural activities in ecological functional areas have compressed the space for expansion of traditional agriculture, making it difficult to realize large-scale cultivation, and increasing unit production costs have offset the benefits of increased yields. On the other hand, despite the fact that Beijing has adopted GEP-R accounting for the transformation of ecological value, the current low compensation standards and the lack of a long-term mechanism have made it difficult for farmers to obtain sufficient economic returns from ecological protection.
Thus, governmental guidance and TSP can facilitate farmers in the EFA to prefer ecological land use for higher value-added production activities and industries with lower environmental restrictions and costs, which would change farmers’ production manner and their livelihood choices.
4.1.2. Robustness Testing
To test the robustness of the model (4), two methods are used: the supplementary variable method and the lagged variable method. (1) Supplementary variable method: Variables added to the
Table 3 (1)(2) test include the number of agro-tourism parks (lngy), rural electricity consumption (lnyd), and the number of township and village enterprises (lnxz). Among them, the number of agro-tourism parks (lngy) indicator directly reflects the degree of transformation of ecological land to a tourism service function, which is an important indicator to measure the ability of realizing ecological value. Therefore, it is used as a control variable to isolate the interference of tourism’s economic effects on farmers’ income. The growth of rural electricity consumption reflects the increased level of agricultural mechanization, facility-based agriculture, and rural electrification, which is a visual representation of the process of agricultural modernization. Therefore, the rural electricity consumption (lnyd) indicator can isolate the direct impact of energy consumption upgrading on income. The number of township and village enterprises (lnxz) reflects the industrial agglomeration effect, and township and village enterprises directly increase farmers’ wage income and business income by absorbing surplus rural labor and promoting the de-farming of the industrial structure.
Variables added to the
Table 3 (2) test include agricultural mechanization technical efficiency (am) and number of laborers (nl). Among them, agricultural mechanization technical efficiency affects the level of intensive land use and production efficiency. Efficient mechanization can reduce labor intensity, improve crop yields and quality, and thus increase farmers’ operating income. However, over-reliance on machinery may exacerbate ecological risks, and it is important to avoid technological effects masking the impacts of economic land. The number of laborers reflects the regional population carrying capacity and the intensity of agricultural labor inputs. The abundant labor force can improve the land output rate through refined farming, but it may also lead to the overexploitation of ecological land due to population pressure, which can be used as a control variable to strip out the direct impact of the demographic dividend on income.
The result shows (as shown in
Table 4 (1)(3)) that the explanatory variables are still significant after the addition of variables that may have been omitted, which implies that the core findings of this paper are robust. In addition, the coefficient of lncz becomes positive after adding the variables (
Table 4 (1)). This is because before adding control variables, the model may have ignored variable bias due to the omission of key variables related to farmers’ income and primary sector share, which masks the true impact of the primary sector share. The addition of control variables absorbs some confounding factors and weakens the correlation between lncz and the error term, which turns the regression coefficient from negative to positive and significant. This suggests that the primary sector has a positive pull on income through technological empowerment or structural optimization under ecological constraints, and the original model underestimates its role by not controlling for endogenous disturbances.
(2) Lagged variable method: There is a time lag effect in the impact of land and control variables on farmers’ income; therefore, the regression analysis is rerun with the explanatory variables lagged by one period in the regression model. The regression results are shown in
Table 4 (2)(4), and the explanatory variables are still significant after lagging for a period of time, which means that the core findings of this paper are robust. The coefficient of the lagged term is found to be significantly positive and larger than the baseline regression result, which may be related to the ‘self-reinforcing mechanism’ of ecological protection investment. Farmers may invest part of their earnings in eco-friendly technologies after increasing their income in the previous period, which further generates an income-enhancing effect.
4.1.3. Heterogeneity Analysis
- (1)
Heterogeneity analysis across ecological function
The EFA of Beijing can be divided into core ecological reserve areas and ecological restoration areas. Among them, the core ecological reserve areas include Miyun District (denoted as MY), Yanqing District (denoted as YQ), and Huairou District (denoted as HR), which bear key ecological functions such as water conservation and water quality protection. The ecological restoration areas include Mentougou (denoted as MTG), Pinggu (denoted as PG), Changping (denoted as CP), and Fangshan (denoted as FS) districts. These areas are characterized by complex topography and rich biodiversity, which are important ecological barriers for Beijing and need to focus on protecting biodiversity. The results of the heterogeneity analysis show that ecological land resources in the core ecological reserve areas have a non-significant impact on farmers’ income (as shown in
Table 5 (1)), while ecological land resources on farmers’ income in the ecological restoration area are significantly positive at the 1% level with an impact coefficient of 36.74 (as shown in
Table 5 (2)). The results indicate that the development of the core ecological reserve areas has ecological protection as its top priority. The strict ecological protection measures have led to the restriction of some industrial activities that may have an impact on the ecological environment, which affects the opportunities for farmers to increase their income through industrial development. However, the ecological restoration area has focused on combining ecological restoration with industrial development while promoting ecological restoration, which has provided farmers with more channels to increase their income through the development of eco-tourism, green agriculture, and other industries.
- (2)
Heterogeneity analysis across economic development
Based on the economic development within the study area, it was categorized into higher economic development zones (including FS, CP, HR, and PG) and lower economic development zones (including MTG, MY, and YQ). It was found that the effect of ecological land resources on farmers’ income within the lower economic development zones was not significant (as shown in
Table 6 (1)), while the effect of ecological land use on farmers’ income within the higher economic development zones was positively significant (as shown in
Table 6 (2)). The obtained results show the following: (a) The lack of financial support and dependence on traditional agriculture in the lower economic development zones lead to an insignificant impact of ecological land use on farmers’ income in the region. The lower economic development zones may face the problem of a low economic base. These districts may lack sufficient financial support and technical inputs to effectively develop and utilize ecological land resources, thus limiting their contribution to the growth of farmers’ income. In addition, these districts may rely too much on traditional agriculture, while new industries such as eco-agriculture and green industry have not yet been fully developed, which results in the limited contribution of eco-land to farmers’ income. (b) The tertiary industry is more complete in the areas with higher economic development, which leads to the positive impact of ecological land use on farmers’ income. Higher economic development areas have a stronger economic base, which can invest more capital and technology to develop and utilize ecological land resources. By promoting the development of new industries such as eco-agriculture and green industries, they can significantly increase farmers’ income. In addition, these regions may have optimized and upgraded their industrial structure, which makes eco-agriculture, green industry and other new industries an important pillar of economic growth. Therefore, ecological land use can better serve economic development and thus promote the growth of farmers’ income.
Furthermore, government investment has not contributed to increasing farmers’ incomes. This indicates that the prioritization of ecological protection has limited the intensity of agricultural development and the choice of industries, resulting in investments focused on environmental management rather than on direct income-generating projects.
4.2. Moderating Effect Mechanism Test Based on Advanced Livelihoods
4.2.1. Heterogeneity Analysis of the Advanced Livelihood Indicator (ALI)
According to an indicator system for the farmers’ advanced livelihoods (with consideration of diversity, sustainability and efficiency) in
Table 1, ALI calculations from 2013 to 2022 can be obtained in
Figure 4. Among them, the legend shows the range of ALI values, and the colors indicate the different intervals of ALI values. It is due to the result of the two-way role of the government strategies and the individual farmers. On the one hand, the government introduced policies such as ecological compensation and industrial support. Both protect the economic interests of farmers sacrificed due to ecological protection and guide them to participate in ecological industries with incentives such as financial subsidies and tax concessions. On the other hand, farmers break through the traditional business model to explore new business subjects. According to market demand, take the initiative to expand the sale of ecological products and utilize e-commerce platforms and other channels to transform ecological advantages into economic benefits. Specifically, Mentougou District (MTG) has the lowest ALI level and Fangshan District (FS) has the highest ALI level. In 2013, MTG had an ALI value of 2151.3 and FS of 9414.2; in 2016, MTG had an ALI value of 2449.5 and FS of 9174.8; in 2019, MTG had an ALI value of 2540 and FS of 7391.7; and in 2022, MTG had an ALI value of 3029.3 and FS of 7553.1. The results indicate that MTG has a lower ALI due to mountainous terrain restrictions and ecological protection positioning, which limits the extension of the agricultural industry chain and the transfer to non-agricultural industries. FS is located in the southwest of Beijing (far from the city center) but has a beautiful natural environment and rich tourism resources and diversified farmers’ livelihoods. Therefore, the differences in regional positioning and functions between FS and MTG have led to large differences in the ALI.
4.2.2. Moderating Effect of Advanced Livelihoods
Table 7 shows the results of the moderating effect mechanism test, which revealed that ecological land resources are significantly positively associated with farmers’ income; the interaction term is significantly positively associated with farmers’ income; and livelihood advancement is significantly negatively associated with farmers’ income. Specifically, livelihood advancement plays a positive moderating role in the impact of ecological land use on farmers’ income. In other words, as the level of livelihood advancement increases, the promotion effect of ecological land resources on farmers’ income will be further enhanced. This is due to the fact that livelihood advancement brings about the extension of the agricultural industry chain, the development of high value-added industries such as agricultural product processing and branding, and the transfer to non-agricultural industries such as the service industry and manufacturing industry, which increases the sources and channels of farmers’ incomes.
4.3. Scenario Analysis
4.3.1. Scenario Setting
The fixed-effects model identifies the core impact pathways and moderating effects of ecological land on farmers’ incomes, in which the results of its parameter estimation (e.g., coefficients of key variables, nonlinear thresholds) provide theoretical constraint boundaries for the GA-SVR model; subsequently, the GA-SVR model takes the significant variables screened in the fixed-effects model as the core input features and optimizes the kernel function parameters and penalty factors of the support vector machine through genetic algorithms so as to enhance the prediction accuracy of complex nonlinear relationships (e.g., time-lag effects of policy shocks, multi-scenario interactions) while retaining the rigor of statistical inference. Although the two do not construct an end-to-end joint loss function, they not only avoid the limitations of linear assumptions of fixed-effects models in scenario simulation but also avoid the black-box risk of pure machine learning models, forming a closed-loop framework of “statistical inference/prediction optimization”.
In order to reflect the land use changes under the government’s environmental protection policy enforcement, which enables farmers to make livelihood strategy choices and thus impact arm incomes, scenarios were set up to simulate farmers’ incomes in 2022 under different scenarios from both the government (returning farmland to forest (RFF) and government investment (lnGI)) and farmer (ALI) perspectives. Specifically, (1) 2022 is used as the baseline scenario to set S0. It means that the variables lnGI, ELA, and ALI are all actual values in 2022 without any adjustment. (2) From the government’s point of view, increases of 30%, 20%, and 10% are made to lnGI, whereby scenarios S1, S2, and S3 are set up. Specifically, using the Overall Plan for Major Projects for the Protection and Restoration of Nationally Important Ecosystems (2021–2035) as the policy benchmark, combined with the local matching fund linkage mechanism, the actual increase in comprehensive inputs can reach 20–30%. The scenario is therefore policy feasible. (3) From the farmer’s point of view, increases of 30%, 20%, and 10% are made to ALI, whereby scenarios S4, S5, and S6 are set up. Specifically, the target of the “New Professional Farmer Cultivation Project” in the “14th Five-Year Plan for Promoting Modernization of Agriculture and Rural Areas” is that the total number of high-quality farmers will exceed 20 million by 2025 (with an average annual growth rate of about 15 per cent). The scenario is therefore policy feasible. (4) From RFF’s point of view, 30%, 20%, and 10% increases are made to the ecological land resources area share (ELA), whereby scenarios S7, S8, S9 are set up. Specifically, based on the National Land Greening Plan (2022–2030), which proposes to complete afforestation and greening of more than 50 million mu per year during the 14th Five-Year Plan period, an increase of about 18% compared with the actual completion during the 13th Five-Year Plan period, the scenario parameters are set to match the policy intensity. Therefore, the parameters of the scenario match the strength of the policy. (5) From the hybrid scenario is (a) Scenario S10, a 20% increase in lnGI and ELA. Scenario S10 is set up according to “Beijing Municipal Opinions on Improving the Follow-up Policies for Returning Farmland to Forests”, where the policy requires the government to support the implementation of the policy of returning farmland to forests by increasing investment, including the provision of land resource transfer fees, forest maintenance fees, and agricultural subsidies, in order to promote ecological environment improvement and the increase in farmers’ incomes; (b) Scenario S11 includes a 20% increase in ELA and ALI. According to the “Beijing Municipal People’s Government’s Implementation Plan on High-Quality Promotion of Ecological Protection and Green Development in Ecological Culvert Areas in the New Era” for scenario S11, the policy proposes to strictly control ecological space and encourages rural professional cooperatives to dock with e-commerce and to actively develop e-commerce and other new business forms; (c) Scenario S12 features a 20% increase in lnGI and ALI. Scenario S12 is set according to “Several Measures on Promoting the Increase of Farmers’ Income in the City”, which proposes to promote the development of rural tourism, steadily raise the level of security for urban and rural residents, increase the support for agricultural science and technology and human resources, and guide the standardized and orderly transfer of contracted land resource management rights and other aspects (as shown in
Figure 5).
4.3.2. Simulation Results Under Various Scenarios
In order to measure the prediction accuracy of the GA-SVR model, the coefficient of determination (R2), root mean square error (RMSE), and mean average error (MAE) evaluation metrics are further calculated.
Table 8 shows that the model has good fitting performance and can be further used for scenario prediction.
Figure 6 shows farmers’ incomes in an EFA under different scenarios (individual policy and hybrid policy) associated with government and farmer perspectives. FI2 (farmers’ income) is in RMB, but here it is logarithmized to become dimensionless and denoted as lnFI2 in order to reduce the effect of extreme values on the model. The results show that farmers’ income is highest under S10 with 1.78813554. In other words, the highest level of farmers’ income was achieved when both government investment and RFF were implemented at the same time. Specifically, MTG and HR have the highest farmers’ incomes in the S3 scenario; FS and YQ have the highest farmers’ incomes in the S10 scenario; CP has the highest farmers’ incomes in S4 and S5; and PG and MY have the highest farmers’ incomes in the S0 scenario.
Specifically,
Table 9 shows the value of income or the percent change from S0 for each area under each scenario; this indicates that different scenarios have heterogeneous impacts on different districts due to factors such as developmental orientation, economy, environment, and industrial structure.
Therefore, a sensitivity analysis of farmers’ incomes was conducted for the hybrid scenarios (S10–S12) and can be obtained in
Figure 7, where 10–30% growth for RFF, lnGI, and the ALI was re-entered into the model.
Figure 7a shows that farmers’ income was highest under scenario S10 at a 30% increase in RFF and a 10% increase in lnGI.
Figure 7b shows that farmers’ income was highest under scenario S12 at a 25% increase in ALI and 15% increase in lnGI.
Figure 7c shows that farmers’ income is highest under scenario S11 at a 25% increase in RFF and 25% increase in the ALI. It indicates the following: (1) Increasing green vegetation cover and improving the ecological environment has a significant effect on enhancing farmers’ income. It indicates RFF promotes the development of eco-agriculture, improves the ecological service function and productivity of the land resources, or provides opportunities for farmers to participate in new industries such as ecotourism. (2) Government support should be moderate. Instead of over-investing, the government should focus on efficiency to ensure that funds and resources are used in a precise way to promote farmers’ income growth.
(3) Upgrading the ALI is an important way to achieve the optimization of the livelihood structure and sustainable growth of farmers’ income.
4.4. Discussion
Above all, to advance understanding of EFA governance and policy formulation, we ground our findings in theoretical frameworks that address critical gaps in prior studies. In contrast to Deng’s results that the expansion of ecological land not only restricts agricultural activities but also directly reduces the amount of land available for farming, which may reduce farmers’ incomes [
15], this study empirically analyzes the complex impact mechanism of ecological land on farmers’ incomes in Beijing’s EFA and introduces ALI as a moderating variable. Specifically, drawing on Ostrom’s social/ecological systems theory, which rejects simplistic panaceas, we identify the ALI as a context-adaptive moderator. And then we find that in the EFA, as the level of the ALI increases, the promotion effect of ecological land resources on farmers’ income will be further enhanced. This demonstrates how locally tailored livelihood diversification strategies, such as Beijing’s eco-tourism, convert resource constraints into sustainable income pathways. Simultaneously, the “Two Mountains” theory provides the value-realization mechanism. Unlike the findings of Cao’s study in Northwest China, which showed that the costs of environmental policies are disproportionately borne by local residents, thereby reducing farmers’ incomes [
13], our evidence shows that the ALI bridges restricted land access to non-farm revenue streams, operationalizing the concept of “lucid waters and lush mountains” as invaluable assets rather than liabilities through market-based channels and cultural-ecosystem services. This study further extends the existing research by simulating policy scenarios to analyze the changes in farmers’ incomes from the perspectives of both the government and farmers. Crucially, policy effectiveness depends on leveraging the ALI’s dual role. Moreover, this study shows that the diversified income-generating channels (e.g., eco-tourism, carbon trading) in Beijing’s EFA may explain the heterogeneity of the moderating effect. As an Ostromian adaptive tool, promoting the ALI requires polycentric governance structures. For instance, participatory co-design of compensation schemes aligned with local income structures avoids omnipotent approaches and empowers communities to self-organize around resource/income synergies. As a “Two Mountains” converter, authentically utilizing the ALI’s moderating role demands policy instruments, like digital platforms connecting farmers to eco-product buyers or payments for watershed services, which explicitly translate ecological stewardship into transactional livelihood benefits.
5. Conclusions
In this study, an ecological/economic synergy analysis framework was constructed by coupling the fixed-effects model and the GA-SVR model. The fixed-effects model effectively stripped away the interference of spatial heterogeneity and clarified the causal relationship between ecological land use and farmers’ incomes, while the GA-SVR model optimized the parameters through genetic algorithms to realize the dynamic simulation of the complex nonlinear effects and multi-scenario interactions. Taking the Beijing ecological functional area as the study area, it is found that ecological land has a positive impact on farmers’ income, and its effect is significantly amplified by the advanced livelihoods (ALI) of farmers. And there is regional heterogeneity that ecological restoration zones and high-development areas have a greater impact on the growth of farmers’ income; the policy simulation shows that the simultaneous implementation of the combination strategy of returning farmland to forests and government investment can optimally balance ecological protection and rural development, which provides a scientific path for the precise implementation of policies.
The corresponding suggestions are recommended as follows: (1) Land resource utilization policies need to be diversified upon various functional positions, which should take human well-being and ecological services into account comprehensively. Heterogeneity analysis reveals that ecological land resources in ecological restoration zones and high economic development zones are more effective in increasing farmers’ income. Therefore, priority should be given to scaling up eco-agriculture practices, strengthening forestry-based industrial chains, and improving processing and marketing systems to enhance resource conversion efficiency. In high-economic development zones, promoting eco-tourism, wellness industries, and eco-industrial integration could maximize the economic potential of land resources through intensive utilization. Conversely, in core ecological reserves and low-economic development zones where ecological land exhibits limited income effects, a dynamic ecological compensation mechanism must be institutionalized. This mechanism should quantitatively assess direct conservation costs and development opportunity costs, allocating compensation funds to targeted environmental protection, education, healthcare, and livelihood enhancement programs, while establishing differentiated compensation standards proportionate to regional economic development levels. (2) Leveraging the moderating power of the ALI is critical. Therefore, regionally tailored ecological skills training programs should be implemented to cultivate interdisciplinary talents proficient in modern agro-technologies, thereby optimizing labor/ecological resource matching efficiency. A tiered ALI-linked compensation framework ought to be designed, prioritizing fiscal transfers to low-ALI regions, and it should adopt synergistic eco-technology and industrial upgrading models to catalyze a virtuous cycle of capacity enhancement, resource optimization, and income growth. These multidimensional strategies aim to reconcile ecological preservation, economic vitality, and equitable livelihood improvements. (3) The synergistic effects of government regulation and livelihood pattern adjustment need to be considered to improve the efficiency of policies. Beijing’s EFA must create a mechanism that connects ecological protection and fiscal support, combining targeted fiscal transfer payments, ecological environment protection, and land resource governance. This strategy seeks to bring about shared ecological prosperity for the area’s farmers. Sensitivity analysis shows that farmers’ income can be maximized by extending the RFF policy by 30% and increasing government investment by 10%. Thus, it is essential to create a dynamic adjustment mechanism that, while keeping overall fiscal expenditure under control, gives priority to fiscal transfer payments to regions exhibiting both industrial growth and ecological protection.
In future research, further improvements can be made in the following aspects: (1) Measuring ecological land resources from multiple dimensions (quality of ecological land resources, diversity of ecological functions, and value of ecological services) can more accurately evaluate the impacts on farmers’ livelihoods and incomes. (2) Consider the spatial correlation and spillover effects of ecological land resources, farmers’ incomes, and livelihood advancement. Changes in ecological land resources in different regions may affect farmers’ incomes in neighboring regions through ecological corridors, markets for agricultural products, and labor mobility, while the process of livelihood advancement may also involve mutual learning and imitation among different regions. Consideration of spatial effects can lead to a fuller understanding of the relationship between variables and an accurate grasp of the mechanism of synergistic development between regions. (3) Analyzing the impact of ecological land resources on farmers’ income from a micro perspective. The study mainly analyzes the impact of ecological land resources on farmers’ incomes and the regulating effect of livelihood advancement from the macro level. Future researchers will further study the behavioral decision-making process, motivation, and constraints of farmers in the face of ecological land resource changes from a micro perspective. (4) There are problems of endogeneity due to time-varying omitted variables and potential reverse causality in the empirical tests, which will be compensated for in subsequent studies by using nonlinear methods, instrumental variable methods, etc., to compensate for the limitations of this study.