Next Article in Journal
Urban Land-Use Type Influences Summertime Water Quality in Small- and Medium-Sized Urban Rivers: A Case Study in Shanghai, China
Previous Article in Journal
The Transformation of Indigenous Landscape in the First Colonized Region of the Caribbean
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Inter-Provincial Differences in Potential Obstacles to Land Transfer Income to Support Rural Revitalization in China

1
School of Humanities and Law, Northeastern University, Shenyang 110169, China
2
Institute of Geographic Sciences and Natural Resources Research, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100101, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Land 2022, 11(4), 510; https://doi.org/10.3390/land11040510
Submission received: 2 March 2022 / Revised: 26 March 2022 / Accepted: 28 March 2022 / Published: 31 March 2022
(This article belongs to the Topic Climate Change and Environmental Sustainability)

Abstract

:
This study analyzes the triple path obstacles of land transfer income in supporting rural revitalization under the premise of existing policy support. It is innovative to try to de-qualitatively analyze the obstacle factors and quantitatively measure the degree of obstacles. We examined the potential obstacles to land transfer income supporting rural revitalization in China, measured the potential comprehensive obstacle degree of 31 provincial-level administrative divisions’ land transfer income supporting rural revitalization, and constructed a way to resolve the differences. We employed inter alia the entropy method, ideal solution similarity ranking method, and cluster analyses. Potential obstacles were divided into nine types. The resolution path was constructed by combining the original and weighted values of various obstacle factors in the top three obstacle factors. It is of great significance to ensure the effective implementation of China’s “opinions on adjusting and improving the scope of land transfer income to give priority to supporting rural revitalization” (2020). This study addresses the theoretical gap in the analysis of possible paths needed to support rural revitalization in China.

1. Introduction

The scale of land finance and its contribution to local finance illustrates a regional law that encourages economic and social development [1]. Land financing is a dynamic mechanism for rapid urbanization [2,3,4], which helps to secure ample investment funding and the required land for urban public construction in advance. Urban construction mostly centers on industrial use [5,6] as it promotes economic growth and urban development. As a consequence, the level of infrastructure in the east, in developed areas and non-downtown areas, has increased considerably [7,8]. Land finance plays a key role in promoting the supply of economic goods in local infrastructure [9,10,11] but suppresses the provision of non-economic public services such as healthcare, education, and indemnificatory apartments. It has been noted that its impact on the eastern region is less than on the central and western regions [12,13], and that cities with a lower dependence on land finance and stronger financial autonomy have less inhibitory effects [14,15]. Land expropriation gives rise to several high-quality collateral effects; that is, the leverage effect of land mortgage financing accelerates the accumulation of capital and promotes economic development [16]. Land finance has a non-linear effect on economic growth, and the proportion of land revenue relative to the gross domestic product in the eastern and western regions at first promotes and later restrains economic growth [17]. Land finance indirectly improves the quality of economic growth through industrial infrastructure upgrading and urbanization, but its marginal effect decreases gradually after a period of high-level urbanization [18,19]. Land finance, which is effective for improving the quality of economic growth in the short term, has the greatest impact in the central region and the smallest in the eastern region [20]. Land finance also has a significant negative impact on urban total factor productivity as a result of the crowding and cost-pull effects of real estate investment. Land financing is increasing in the western, central, and northeast regions, as well as in small- and medium-sized cities (type I and type II big cities; see Appendix A for details). It increases in the eastern region and super-mega-cities are not significant [21]. The increase in land financial dependence will significantly inhibit the upgrading of productive and high-end service structures, especially in the central and western regions, especially in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis [22,23].
Most of land financing’s raw material, that is, the land itself, is located in rural areas; however, the research on its support toward rural development is still insufficient, especially concerning the “value-added income distribution” of the land. The general consensus is that the scope of agricultural land expropriation is random, the compensation is low, and the income distribution is unreasonable [24,25,26]. The root cause of the aforementioned is that the distribution of the land’s value-added income ignores the contribution of some subjects and the added value should be “returned to society,” not monopolized by a small number of people [27,28,29]. Farmers’ rights and interests can be protected regarding compensation, security, and sharing by improving the mechanism of multi-party consultation and negotiation, supplemented by fundamental rights, judicial arbitration, and third-party professional assessment [30,31,32]. The value-added income of land is the result of the joint action of investment, use, supply, and demand factors.
The “contribution-risk” method embodies the interests, contributions and risks of the state, the collective, and farmers, respectively [33]. To ensure the rights and interests of farmers who had lost their land, 40% of the optimal market price of the relevant land is adopted as concomitant compensation [34,35]. Given the dynamic nature of locations’ conditions, infrastructure, and public service levels, the land tax system was improved and tax rules adapted to provide a guarantee for the rationalization and equitization of land income distribution [36]. The distribution of land value-added income differs from region to region. The following positive developments occurred from 2016 to 2020: the degree of equality among the subjects of distribution was reduced, the distribution gap among the stakeholders in the eastern region was narrowed, the income distribution gap between the central and western regions was enlarged, and the level of social welfare was improved (more so in the eastern region than in the west) [37].
The Central Office and the State Office issued a policy paper titled “Opinions on adjusting and improving the scope of land transfer income to give priority to supporting rural revitalization” in September 2020. The aim of the policy paper is to generate capital investment for rural revitalization and the cultivation of sustainable endogenous rural development. It proposes that, taking the provincial-level administrative divisions (provinces, autonomous regions, municipalities, and special administrative regions) as the measurement unit, the proportion of land transfer income to agriculture and rural areas should be more than 50%, or that it should amount to at least 10% by the end of the 14th five-year plan period. That is, the state began to implement a “land finance” policy that addresses rural and agricultural development.
Internationally, there are also practices of many other governments’ financial support for rural revitalization. For example, the US government has continuously improved the policy system and adjusted the structure of agricultural development, established a relatively perfect policy system of financial support for rural and agricultural development, and promoted rural construction [38,39]. Germany promotes the development of rural industry and commerce through the integration of traditional and modern innovation and the increase of diversified industrial structure models [40]. France promotes the transformation of agriculture to specialization through fiscal expenditure, and promotes rural construction by revitalizing agriculture through science and technology [41]. Because of its special national conditions, China supports rural development according to the land transfer income with local characteristics.
It is against this background that this study analyzed 31 provincial-level administrative divisions (PLADs) and constructed a plan to resolve those potential obstacles. It provides a theoretical starting point for effectively resolving the obstacles related to land transfer income to support rural revitalization and has practical reference value for PLADs, and to formulate more targeted policies to ensure that income derived from land transfers supports rural revitalization.

2. Materials and Methods

2.1. Data Sources

The data for this study were mainly obtained from the China Statistical Yearbooks from 2002 to 2018, the China Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook, and the Main Data Bulletin of the Third National Agricultural Census. The said data included land transfer data, local financial data, rural population data, and industrial output data. The Statistical Yearbook of China’s Land and Resources was only issued until 2018; therefore, the data in this study are only until 31 December 2017.

2.2. Study Scope

The scope of this study encompasses 31 PLADs in China. In the People’s Republic of China, PLADs form the highest level of administrative divisions under the Central People’s Government, including 23 provinces, five autonomous regions, four municipalities (directly under the Central Government), and two special administrative regions, amounting to 34 PLADs. The scope of this study does not include the two special administrative regions or Taiwan Province. China has developed special national conditions under the “one country, two systems” approach, the latter being the basic national policy put forward by the Chinese Government to realize the peaceful reunification of the country. According to Deng Xiaoping’s exposition, “one country, two systems” means that under the aegis of one China, the main body of the state adheres to the socialist system, while Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan retain the original capitalist system. In view of the fact that the land-related policies and systems of the latter three are different from those of China’s other provinces, there is a dearth of data on them; therefore, they were not included in the scope of this study. The obtained data are, therefore, only from 22 provinces, five autonomous regions, and four municipalities.

2.3. Research Methodology

(1) The entropy method was used to calculate the weight of each potential obstacle factor. According to the weight of factors at three levels in Table 1, they are divided into “+” and “−“ directions according to the impact of each such impediment. The “+” direction means a higher value of obstacle factors. The entropy method is an objective weighting method, which determines weights according to the information provided by the values of various factors. This allows the researcher to avoid the subjectivity of artificial weighting and the overlap of multivariable information. The calculation process is as follows:
Dimensionless standardization of obstacle factors ( x ¯ ij ):
positive : x ¯ ij = x ij min x j max x j min x j negative : x ¯ ij = max x j x ij max x j min x j
The specific gravity of after dimensionless standardization ( R ij ):
R ij = x ¯ ij i = 1 m ( x ¯ ij ) ; m   =   j   = 2 , 2 , 4
Entropy of item j ( e j ):
e j = k i = 1 m ( R ij × l n R ij ) ;   k   =   1 l n m ;   m =   j   =   2 , 2 , 4
Weight of index j ( Q j ):
Q j = 1 e j m i = 1 m e j
In Equations (1)–(4), X ¯ ij is the original value of the factor, i is the province (city and district) (i = 1,2,…,31), and j-j represents the indicator or index (j = 2,2,4); that is, there are two, two, and four obstacle factors within the local government, land finance, and the countryside itself, respectively: if X ¯ ij = 0, then Rij = 0, Rij × LnRij = 0.
(2) The technique for order of preference by similarity to ideal solution (TOPSIS) sorting method was used to calculate the comprehensive obstacle degree. TOPSIS is a commonly used decision-making technique in system engineering when analyzing multi-objective decision-making. It is a method of ranking according to the proximity of a limited number of objects to the idealized target. By measuring the similarity of “positive” and “negative” ideal solutions during the period 2001–2017, the order of relative advantages and disadvantages could be determined. The equation for a weighted decision matrix and the calculation process of “positive” and “negative” ideal solutions was formulated as follows:
C ij = Q j x ¯ ij
In Equation (5), Cij is the weighted standard value of each evaluation index, j = 1,2,…,8; i = 1,2,…,31.
The positive and negative ideal solutions were determined from the weighted sum values of eight obstacle factors in 31 PLADs. The “positive” ideal solution refers to the highest obstacle scheme and the “negative” ideal solution refers to the lowest obstacle scheme.
C + = max ( C ij ) i = 1 , 2 C ij = Q j x ¯ ij , , 31 = C 1 + , C 2 + , , C 8 + C = mix ( C ij ) i = 1 , 2 , , 31 = C 1 , C 2 , , C 8
In Equation (6), C+ and C are the highest obstacle scheme (positive ideal solution), and the lowest obstacle scheme (negative ideal solution), respectively.
The distances from the weighted standard value to the “positive” and “negative” ideal solution in the time series (year) was then calculated:
D i + = j = 1 8 ( C j + C ij ) 2 D i = j = 1 8 ( C j C ij ) 2  
In Equation (7), D i + and D i are the distances from the weighted standard value of each province to the “positive” and “negative” ideal solution, respectively.
The degree of obstacle and the closeness of the highest obstacle value in 31 PLADs were subsequently calculated, using the following formula:
T i = D i D i + D i +
In Equation (8), Ti is the highest obstacle value (comprehensive obstacle degree). The value range is [0,1]—the closer it is to 1, the higher the obstacle degree is.
The comprehensive obstacle degree of 31 PLADs was calculated according to Equations (5)–(8) and the logarithmic values were arranged in descending order, as shown in Table 2.
(3) IBM’s SPSS software (the method of determining the “average connection between groups”) was used to classify the original numerical values of eight obstacle factors in 31 PLADs, as depicted in Table 3. A significant advantage is that the maximum similarity among PLADs of the same type and the minimum similarity of PLADs within different types could be determined.

3. Results

The entropy value and weight of each obstacle factor were calculated according to Equations (1)–(4) (Table 1).
The weighted sums of potential impediments to rural revitalization are shown in Table 3.
According to the classification of obstacle degree and the order of function degree at each level, the comprehensive obstacle degree of 31 PLADs in Table 3 shows that the overall difference, from the highest value of Chongqing (0.579) to the lowest value of Hainan (0.407), was not significant because the three levels of obstacles were different. Even if the comprehensive obstacle degree of the PLADs were similar, there still were differences in the influence of three or eight obstacle factors on the comprehensive obstacle degree. The comprehensive obstacle degree was divided into three sections: high (>0.535), which included nine PLADs of Chongqing and Tianjin; medium (0.465–0.535), which included 14 PLADs of Ningxia, Yunnan, and Ningxia; and low (<0.465), which included eight PLADs of Hainan and Xinjiang (Table 2). Classes V and VI’s clustering results are shown Table 4.
Table 4 indicates that, in the results of Classes V and VI, Jiangsu and Zhejiang were always similar, as were Beijing and Shanghai. The difference between the two classifications is that Tianjin, Guangdong, Fujian, Shandong, Chongqing, and Anhui were separated from Class V and became the third category in Class VI. Class VI reflected that the change of the obstacle degree of land transfer income supporting rural revitalization was related to the level of economic and social development and location. For example, with the exception of Hubei, Classes V and VI were all underdeveloped PLADs, such as the three PLADs in Northeast China, Inner Mongolia, and Guizhou in the southwest.
The PLADs with high, medium, and low comprehensive obstacles were subdivided into two, four, and three types, respectively (Table 3). The results coincided with the cluster analysis in Table 4, which showed that the classification of obstacles in 31 PLADs to support rural revitalization was reasonable, with Shanghai, Beijing, Jilin, and Liaoning being cases in point. Zhejiang and Jiangsu were alike.
The following five countermeasures were arrived at:
(1) Optimize the performance evaluation system to encourage and restrain the income from land sales to support rural revitalization. Table 6 shows that the “proportion of cities and towns in fiscal expenditure” in 31 PLADs was more than 85%. Jiangsu, Zhejiang, and the other nine provinces exceeded 90%, and 13 PLADs, such as Shandong and Anhui, ranked among the top three in the weighted sum of “proportion of cities and towns in fiscal expenditure,” as shown in Table 3.
The reason was that the performance evaluation system encouraged local fiscal expenditures to be biased toward cities and towns to obtain political benefits. Therefore, all PLADs quantified the achievements of rural revitalization on the local government performance evaluation system to encourage local governments to gradually balance their financial expenditure between cities and rural areas. The income derived from the transfers of agricultural land, in particular, had sufficient endogenous power to support rural revitalization to the extent of solving the dependence of local financial expenditure on urban construction and promoting economic growth.
(2) Perfecting the tax-sharing system to balance the local government’s administrative and financial powers. Only eight PLADs’ income from land transfers could exceed the local fiscal deficits, such as Jiangsu and Zhejiang, as shown in Table 6. In the weighted sum value of obstacle factors of 25 PLADs, “land transfer income to make up for the fiscal deficit” ranked first in 23 of them, Jiangsu and Zhejiang being the only exceptions. It follows that the financial and administrative powers the PLADs are given on the national level should be reasonably divided to balance the financial revenue and power and to promote payments from the central finance for the provision of basic public services in underdeveloped PLADs. The PLADs’ governments should be given the authority to borrow money in accordance with the law and to implement a debt management policy, a risk liability system, introduce the market-oriented operation of infrastructure funds, build-operate-transfer (BOT), public-private partnership (PPP), and other financing models.
(3) To construct the land financial model in such a way as to ensure a sustainable supply of land and money. Table 2 shows that the “land finance” of seven provinces, such as Tibet and Qinghai, played the highest role in respect of their three highest-ranked obstacles, while 18 PLADs ranked toward the middle. Countermeasures PLADs could introduce to ameliorate the scarcity of arable land and reserve resources include the following: resuscitating abandoned land renovation projects, improving the efficiency of transferring rural land to the construction market, supplying land indicators for new urbanization, and continuing with providing funding.
Table 3 shows that the weighted value of “the ratio of tax to land financial funds” in 24 provinces, such as Zhejiang and Jiangsu, ranked among the top three in their own provinces. It should be endeavored to lower tax rates, for example, by widening the tax base and optimizing income from real estate tax by linking it with those levied by cities and towns. A well-considered and sustainable property tax rate can ultimately become a sustainable source of local revenue.
(4) To develop policies and facilities for the agglomeration of elements in rural areas and equality between urban and rural areas. ① Give equal rights to urban and rural construction land, improve the unification of urban and rural land markets, and restrain land expropriation by local governments. For example, Inner Mongolia, Guizhou, and the three northeastern provinces “increase[d] the per capita area of land expropriation of urban population” above 200 m2. ② The Main Data Bulletin of the Third National Agricultural Census announced that there had been 207.43 million operating agricultural households in 2016, accounting for 1.92% of the total. Therefore, through land and services to jointly promote agricultural scale operation, enhance rural industrial profits. ③ The “rural population reduction ratio” in Chongqing, Jiangsu, and the other 11 provinces was more than 30%. The weighted value of this factor in the four provinces of Jiangsu and Inner Mongolia ranked in the top 3 of the provinces. There was a need to improve the social security system to realize the “unified urban and rural” model and ensure the smooth flow of urban and rural labor. ④ Strengthen the national transfer payment system for the construction of rural basic conditions in underdeveloped areas (high II; moderate III and VI; and low I provinces, Inner Mongolia, and Shanxi), so that all areas can develop markets in the countryside. ⑤ Promote rural industry by increased resource grants and facilitate the flow of factors to rural areas that would to stimulate new industries and the manufacture of high-quality products.
(5) To highlight the countermeasures to solve the highest-ranked obstacles in PLADs. The number one obstacle factor of each PLAD should be highlighted and effectively addressed. ① The autonomous regions and municipalities that are in high class I, moderate class I and III, and low class I and II should focus on balancing the financial power of the local government. ② Tibet in the high II category; Yunnan, Guizhou, Gansu in the moderate VI category; and Jiangsu and Zhejiang in the low III category should increase the proportional contribution of land and real estate-related taxes. ③ Qinghai in the high II category and Ningxia in the moderate VI category should increase the proportion of auctions and agreements in the supply of state-owned construction land. ④ Guangdong, Beijing, and Shanghai in the moderate II category should increase the proportion of financial expenditures spent in agricultural and rural areas.

4. Discussion

During the period of social transformation, the Party and the State established the basic line of “taking economic construction as the center,” and implemented a decentralized financial system and a performance evaluation system based on economic growth, which resulted in local governments displaying “economic man” behavior. Local governments were entrusted with the development of urbanization and industrialization to promote the economic growth of their area of jurisdiction, with their core behavior mode being urban management. Their powers included land expropriation, leases, and mortgage financing to obtain land and funding for infrastructure and urban space expansion, which effectively promoted urban economic growth and political performance benefits.
The formation of a reciprocating economic and social development model and successive governments’ deep-seated dependence on land finance directly or indirectly contributed to the obstacle factors faced by local governments in their pursuit of revitalizing income from the transfer of rural land and its mechanical operation framework, as shown in Figure 1. The state’s “opinions on adjusting and improving the scope of land transfer income to give priority to supporting rural revitalization” involved three main elements: local government, land transfer income, and rural revitalization. The relationship between the three can be depicted as follows:
(1) The income from land transfer made up for the fiscal deficit. The tax-sharing system produced a clear deficit, and the land transfer revenue played an important role in reducing the budget deficit. Revenue from land transfers as a proportion of local fiscal deficit showed a fluctuating upward trend from 2001 to 2017, with a high of 86.2% in 2013 (Figure 2, left-hand graph). Local budget revenue and expenditures totaled 71.67114 trillion yuan (USD 11.2531 trillion) and 127.71339 trillion yuan (USD 20 trillion), respectively, over those 17 years, with a total deficit of 56.04225 trillion yuan (USD 8.7992 trillion). Land transfer revenue totaled 35,458.63 billion yuan (USD 5567.38 billion), accounting for 63.3% of the local budget. Therefore, the financial pressure that resulted if the revenue did not match the expenditure and the land transfer revenue could not make up for the local government’s fiscal deficit; it became an obstacle to the local government’s intent to finance rural revitalization with income from land transfers.
(2) The structure of fiscal expenditure is significantly biased toward cities. Various industries in cities and towns are the focus of local expenditure, and the scale of cities and towns’ expenditures on agriculture, forestry, and water had consistently increased from 2001 to 2017. The proportion of expenditure increased from 6.2% in 2001 to 10.5% in 2009, and the value appeared to have stabilized at 10% over the following eight years, as shown in Figure 2 (right-hand graph). The reason was that, due to China’s dual development pattern of urban and rural areas and the tax-sharing financial system, urbanization is an important carrier of the country’s economic growth. The “promotion incentive mechanism” was centered on economic growth and drove local governments to adopt the expenditure strategy of emphasizing urban infrastructure construction, and neglecting basic public services in rural areas.
(3) The expropriation and lease of agricultural (cultivated) land are not sustainable. The China Statistical Yearbook shows that the area of cultivated land in 2017 was 134.9 million hm2, which was 4.86 million hm2 more than in 2000. Assuming that 7.275 million hm2 of the total supply area of state-owned construction land from 2001 to 2017 came from cultivated land as shown in Figure 3 (left-hand graph), it meant that 12.135 million hm2 of cultivated land had been developed in 17 years. The highest annual figure of 751,000 hm2 recorded in 2013 suggests that 12.9 million hm2 of the existing arable land relative to the 1.8 billion hm2 red line would be consumed by 2034. Likewise, the proportion of the total supply area of state-owned construction land decreased from 75.9% in 2006 to 37.2% in 2017, indicating that more state-owned construction land had been “allocated” to public welfare undertakings. The decline in the matter of state-owned construction land and land transfer began in 2014, which had led to a reduction in land financial funds, as shown in Figure 3 (right-hand graph). Therefore, the unsustainability of “land expropriation and leasing” has become a potential obstacle to supporting rural revitalization.
(4) The tax system related to land and real estate is imperfect. To date, foreign mainstream land income levies taxes on land retention and transfer, which was the main source of local finance [42]; it played a positive role in controlling the speculative bubble of real estate and the rapid rise of housing prices [43], and it was an effective policy to restrain urban expansion and drive the intensive use of urban land [44]. From 2001 to 2017, the total scale of land financial funds (land transfer income, cultivated land occupation tax, property tax, deed tax, urban land use tax, and land value-added tax), and the proportion of five kinds of taxes in the 31 PLADs during that period ranged between 14% and 31%, as shown in Figure 3 (right-hand graph). The total scale of land finance was 46.90763 trillion yuan, of which tax revenue was 11.449 trillion yuan, accounting for 25% of the former. Most PLADs had not instituted a property tax on holding links yet, and supporting rural revitalization made it difficult for local governments to reduce land sales income by 10% through land and property taxes. Therefore, the incomplete and underdeveloped land and real estate tax system indirectly formed a potential obstacle to land transfer income that could support rural revitalization.
(5) One-way flow of rural factors of production into cities and towns. The separation of agricultural and rural development from urban and rural development was formed under the auspices of the urban–rural dual economic structure system. This system resulted in the isolation of agricultural and rural development from industrialization and urban development, with the most important factors of production, such as land, labor, and capital, having flowed to industries in cities and towns. The collective ownership of rural land belongs to the national ownership of urban land, and several land resources needed for industrialization and urbanization were requisitioned from rural land. For example, the area of land expropriated from 2001 to 2017 was 45,067.0 km2, as shown in Table 5. Concerning population, many surplus rural working people went to the cities to find employment. The state’s “opinions on promoting the Reform of the Household Registration Management system in small towns” (2001) stipulates that planned target management would no longer be implemented for those who applied for permanent residence in small towns. The rural population had decreased at an average annual rate of about 13 million from 2001 to 2017, and the proportion of people employed in the primary industrial sector had dropped from 50% in 2001 to 27% in 2017 (Table 5).
Having combined the changes of obstacle factors at the national level in Figure 1, Figure 2 and Figure 3 and Table 5, we constructed a system of potential obstacle factors of 31 PLADs, covering 2001 to 2017, that supported rural revitalization, as shown in Table 6. The specific meaning of each obstacle factor and the basic law of inter-provincial differences are as follows:
(1) At the level of the government. ① The ratio of land transfer income to the deficit: it reflects the compensation degree of land transfer income to the local fiscal deficit—the smaller the ratio is, the weaker the compensation effect, and the greater the obstacle for local governments to use land transfer income to support rural revitalization. The basic conclusion was that the ratio of land transfer income to deficit showed a regional law that converged with the level of economic and social development. ② The proportion of fiscal expenditures in cities and towns: the greater the value, the greater the proportion of urban expenditure. The path-dependence effect of promoting urban economic growth and obtaining political performance benefits made it more difficult for local governments to support rural revitalization with land transfer income. The value also reflects the regional law of convergence with the level of economic and social development.
(2) Land finance. ① The ratio of transfer of the total supply area of state-owned construction land. When measuring the sustainable degree of collection, expropriation and lease of agricultural land, the ratio of economically developed PLADs was found to be higher, while those of less developed PLADs were lower, which indicated that the urban infrastructure of developed PLADs had been improved. Payment by money transfer was mostly used in the supply of state-owned construction land, but to improve urban infrastructure, the supply of state-owned construction land in underdeveloped PLADs was more in the way of allocations. Given the limitations of cultivated land and reserve resources, the smaller the proportion of land transfer was to the total area of state-owned construction land, the greater the obstacle to land transfer income to support rural revitalization would become. ② The ratio of tax to land financial funds. The smaller the value was, the less the land and real estate tax revenue was relative to the land transfer income. In addition, the reduced land sales revenue from local government support for rural revitalization could not be effectively compensated for by land and property taxation, and the resulting obstacles were even higher. The value did not change with a change in the region’s law or rules. This presented a great obstacle, as there was no obvious regional rule for the value.
(3) The countryside itself. ① Increase the per capita area of land expropriation of urban population. The greater the value, the faster the speed of land urbanization, compared with population urbanization. This was caused by inter alia the low cost of rural labor and the large number of laborers flowing from rural areas to towns and their industrial parks, resulting in a higher degree of obstacles. The value showed the regional law as opposed to the level of economic and social development. ② Ratio of rural population reduction. The greater the value, the greater the relative reduction of the rural population, and the greater the obstacle to the income from land sales to support rural revitalization. There was no obvious regional law for this value, i.e., the size of this value did not change if there were a change in the region’s laws. ③ The per capita income gap between urban and rural areas in 2017. The greater the value, the greater the per capita income gap between urban and rural areas, and the greater the obstacle. ④ The gap in per capita industrial output value between urban and rural areas in 2017. The greater the value, the greater the gap between urban per capita secondary and tertiary industrial output value and rural per capita primary industrial output value. The numerical values of the above two obstacle factors basically showed the regional law of convergence as it pertains to economic and social development.

5. Conclusions

The research content of this paper was mainly developed from the unique research background of rural revitalization in China, and on the basis of China’s unique national conditions. Obstacles that might arise in the process of implementation of the existing policy guidance were examined to clarify their mechanisms and degrees of action. For China, the revenue obtained from land in the past tended to be used for urban development, and the total expenditure was not small, while the funds for rural development were very limited indeed. That situation gave full play to the advantages of China’s concentration of efforts to do great things, and Chinese cities have been able to develop rapidly, which had made a great contribution to China’s modernization. Yet, at the same time, it had also led to slow rural development and multiple problems in rural areas. The latter problem needs to be solved urgently, and the solution is to return to rural revitalization. The purpose of this study was to analyze the possible obstacles in the process of rural development and lay the groundwork for the actual situation. At the same time, for the world, rural revitalization is the theme that many countries pay close attention to, and because the conditions of each country are different, the sources of funds, the use of funds and specific paths for rural revitalization are different as well. However, in general, the source of funding is national finance, and other sources of land tax or rent. The money obtained from the sale of land has a public attribute, and it is understandable that this funding supports the revitalization of the countryside. As for how to make better use of the money obtained from land, it is the researcher’s opinion that China’s approach provides a possible reference for other countries and opens up new ideas for rural revitalization. According to the research of this paper, and at the same time draw lessons from the typical cases of domestic and foreign financial support for rural revitalization, such as the specific practices of the United States, Britain and France to support rural construction. This article provides some reference opinions on domestic and foreign financial support for rural development.
For China, possible policies are as follows. 1. Improve the legal and regulatory system for the rural revitalization of fiscal expenditures. Although the existing policy guidance points out specific expenditure guidance, in the process of a specific implementation, according to the obstacles that may be encountered, the support of rural revitalization by land transfer income still lacks clear laws and regulations to constrain it. In order to ensure the clear implementation of rural revitalization by land transfer income, relevant laws and regulations shall be improved and promulgated, and guiding policies shall be clearly defined, providing an in-depth education to grassroots organizations that have little knowledge of policies and regulations. 2. Since the Chinese Constitution stipulates a unitary framework for the relationship between the central and local governments, that is, centralized power, sovereign power is held by a single state agency, and local governments need to act in accordance with the will of the central government. There is a lot of information opacity between the central and local governments. Especially for village-level organizations in China, there are shortcomings such as opaque financial management expenditures. The part of the funds that are spent on rural construction and development needs to be used reasonably, and the local government needs to strengthen the clarification of the use of funds, not only knowing how much to use but also knowing where to use it according to the gap between local and policy requirements, establishing a reasonable and appropriate mechanism to ensure the smooth implementation of funds. For example, the effectiveness of rural construction is regularly inspected. Not only that, in order to reasonably use a variety of supervision to monitor the flow of funds to the village government, it is suggested here that a combination of new media supervision and mass supervision can be used to ensure that the use of funds is reasonable and efficient. 3. Increase the driving force of government officials to support rural revitalization funds. In the past, behaviors with performance appraisal as an incentive mechanism and economic-centered policy propositions tended to make certain achievements in industrialization and urbanization for government officials. As a result, government officials tend to prefer towns to villages when making decisions about fiscal spending. Now, in order to make the funding channels for rural revitalization go smoothly, it is necessary to appropriately transform the policy leadership and encourage local government officials to shift the focus of development to the countryside. The current urbanization is too saturated. The way to solve the problems of over-urbanization and alleviate various types of rural areas is rural revitalization. 4. Grasp the implementation approach of differentiated policies. Our research has identified barriers and differences in barriers to land grant revenue supporting rural revitalization across provinces. Therefore, for each region, the specific implementation of the policy should be adapted to local conditions. According to the types of areas with high, medium and low barriers, and considering the local development during the specific implementation process, it is necessary to know where the barriers are high, where to start, and how to make the implementation path smoother. For example, in some developed regions, the barriers are low, due to their high degree of modernization, the ratio of land transfer income to the deficit is high, and the overall level of support for agriculture is higher than that of underdeveloped regions. This is largely due to the extremely high level of urbanization. The main source of support for economic development in developed regions is not land finance, but other local tax revenues. Due to the spillover of economic development, the overall situation of rural development in these regions is better than that in other regions. Therefore, for these areas, the land transfer income and expenditure should be inclined to the weak areas of rural development or consider how suitable areas in rural areas can be connected to urban development while retaining their own characteristics.
Many developed countries abroad, such as the United States, Japan, France, etc., have an earlier history of rural revitalization due to their earlier modernization time. Many of their practices and experiences are of great inspiration to China and other agricultural developing countries. The research topic of this paper is briefly summarized. 1. Support agricultural and rural development projects. According to the different development conditions of each country, this part of the funds should be used for ecological construction, infrastructure construction, rural customs and civilization investment or basic farmland protection and other investment in rural development projects that should be focused and selected according to the actual situation. 2. Improve the agricultural subsidy policy. In the process of rural revitalization, agriculture has always been the top priority that cannot be ignored. Agriculture involves food security, and food security is the lifeblood of a country. Conditional large agricultural countries should pay attention to basic agricultural conditions according to their own development conditions, and improve subsidy policies suitable for agriculture. 3. Innovate the source of investment funds. Due to its different national conditions and systems, each country has different sources of funds to support rural development, innovatively seek new sources of funds from the original sources of funds, and invest reasonably in local rural development. 4. Strengthen the integration and management of financial support for agriculture. There may be different sources and channels of financial support for agriculture, and there is a lack of unified management of funds. Each country can set up special offices of relevant departments or other public welfare organizations according to specific systems to manage the sources and use channels of local funds, so as to make expenditures more affordable. Use is clearly documented.
In short, countries do not necessarily copy the existing experience, but extract useful enlightenment for agricultural developing countries from these existing experience models. It can also be traced back to other types of obstacles generated in the process of financial support for rural development, so that obstacles can be solved purposefully and rural construction can be carried out more smoothly.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.W.; methodology, Y.W.; data curation, Y.W., Y.X.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.W.; writing—review and editing, Y.X.; visualization, Y.X.; supervision, Y.W., J.X.; funding acquisition, Y.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by the 2020 Central University Basic Scientific Research Funding Program (grant no. N2014005) and the National Natural Science Foundation of China 2020 (grant no. 42071248).

Data Availability Statement

Except for the noted quotation, the data are from the authors’ own research.

Acknowledgments

The authors acknowledge all colleagues and friends who voluntarily reviewed the translation of the survey and study manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

“Type I and type II big cities”: this statement comes from the notice on adjusting the criteria for dividing the size of cities; that is, the new standard for dividing the size of cities takes the resident population in urban areas as the statistical caliber. Type I big cities represent cities with a resident population of more than 3 million and less than 5 million, while type II big cities represent cities with a resident population of more than 1 million and less than 3 million.

References

  1. Wang, Y. Regional difference of linkage between land finance and urban land scale and population growth. Econ. Geogr. 2019, 39, 172–182. [Google Scholar]
  2. Shao, C.; Su, D.; Deng, H. Housing price, land finance and city agglomeration characteristics: The road of China’s city development. Manag. World 2016, 2, 19–32. [Google Scholar]
  3. Tong, D.; Chu, J.; Han, Q.; Liu, X. How Land Finance Drives Urban Expansion under Fiscal Pressure: Evidence from Chinese Cities. Land 2022, 11, 253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Yu, H.; Yang, J.; Sun, D.; Li, T.; Liu, Y. Spatial responses of ecosystem service value during the development of urban agglomerations. Land 2022, 11, 165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Yang, H.; Zhang, J. Study on the mechanism and effect of urban space production driven by land finance: A case study of Hexi New Town in Nanjing. Int. Urban Plan. 2018, 33, 68–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Yu, J.; Shen, K. The impact of urban land quota allocation on China’s housing market. Econ. Res. 2019, 4, 116132. [Google Scholar]
  7. Zhang, W.; Xu, H. Effects of land urbanization and land finance on carbon emissions: A Panel Data Analysis for Chinese Provinces. Land Use Policy 2017, 63, 493–500. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Zhong, T.; Zhang, X.; Huang, X.; Liu, F. Blessing or Curse? Impact of Land finance on rural public infrastructure development. Land Use Policy 2019, 85, 130–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Du, J.; Chen, Z. An empirical study on the impact of land finance on the satisfaction of urban infrastructure supply. Explor. Econ. Issues 2019, 4, 46–58. [Google Scholar]
  10. Fan, X.; Qiu, S.; Sun, Y. Land finance dependence and urban land marketization in China: The perspective of strategic choice of local governments on land transfer. Land Use Policy 2020, 99, 105023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Yan, Y.; Wang, M.; Zhang, J. Is land-based finance the prominent cause of the imbalanced structure in the public goods supply. J. Beijing Norm. Univ. 2019, 2, 146–157. [Google Scholar]
  12. Fu, Y. Fiscal decentralization governance and non-economic public goods provision. Econ. Res. 2010, 45, 4–15 + 65. [Google Scholar]
  13. Tian, C.; Li, M.; Li, S. Land fiscal and local public goods provision: Evidences from cities. Public Manag. 2014, 11, 38–48 + 141. [Google Scholar]
  14. Lu, J.; Li, B.; Li, H. The Influence of land finance and public service supply on peri-urbanization: Evidence from the counties in China. Habitat Int. 2019, 92, 102039. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Chen, S.; Zeng, L. Fiscal autonomy, land finance dependence and the level of public service supply: Evidence from the panel data of 286 cities above prefecture level in China. J. Huazhong Norm. Univ. 2016, 55, 42–53. [Google Scholar]
  16. Chen, J.; Song, L. From land finance to land financialization-The transformation of land-based financing mode. Financ. Res. 2021, 1, 86–101. [Google Scholar]
  17. Hu, H.; Liu, H. Land Revenue, productive expenditure and economic growth. Theory Pract. Financ. Econ. 2020, 41, 78–85. [Google Scholar]
  18. Wang, Z.; Cao, C.; Chen, J.; Wang, H. Does land finance contraction accelerate urban shrinkage? A study based on 84 Key cities in China. J. Urban Plan. Dev. 2020, 146, 04020038. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Guo, W.; Zhou, Y. Will land finance promote high-quality economic development: Based on the perspective of intermediary effect of urbanization and industrial structure upgrading. South. Financ. 2020, 10, 28–39. [Google Scholar]
  20. Zhan, X.; Miao, Z. Research on the quality effects of economic growth in land finance from the perspective of “five development concept”. J. Tianjin Univ. Financ. Econ. 2020, 7, 14–28. [Google Scholar]
  21. Li, R.; Liu, Y.; Wang, W. China’s urban land financial expansion and transmission routes to economic efficiency. Acta Geogr. Sin. 2020, 75, 2126–2145. [Google Scholar]
  22. Qun, W.; Yongle, L.; Siqi, Y. The incentives of China’s urban land finance. Land Use Policy 2015, 42, 432–442. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Li, M.; Li, L.; Yin, S. Estimation of farmland resources ‘value loss in process of farmland expropriation—Taking Hunan Province as an example. Econ. Geogr. 2015, 35, 184–188. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Zhu, P.; Tang, P. Mechanism innovation on land benefit distribution in rural land expropriation: A case study Jiangsu Province. J. Nanjing Agric. Univ. 2013, 13, 66–72. [Google Scholar]
  25. Hu, X. The exploration on the dilemma and outlet of Chinese land expropriation compensation-Based on the observation of law and practice. J. Northeast Norm. Univ. 2014, 02, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Zhang, G.; Sun, Z.; Ai, Y. Land finance, factor misallocation and laggard service industry structure upgrading. J. Shanxi Univ. Financ. Econ. 2021, 43, 57–70. [Google Scholar]
  27. Zhang, X.; Wang, J.; Song, W.; Wang, F.; Gao, X.; Liu, L.; Dong, K.; Yang, D. Decoupling analysis between rural population change and rural construction land changes in China. Land 2022, 11, 231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. de Oliveira, G.; McKay, B.M.; Liu, J. Beyond Land Grabs: New Insights on Land Struggles and Global Agrarian Change. Globalizations 2021, 18, 321–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Zhang, M.; Chen, Q.; Zhang, K.; Yang, D. Will rural collective-owned commercial construction land marketization impact local governments’ interest distribution? Evidence from mainland China. Land 2021, 10, 209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Wei, Z.; Yan, Y.; Shi, X. Research on the land revenue distribution in the transformation of urban shanty towns: A case of Songyuan in Jilin Province. China Land Sci. 2017, 31, 24–31. [Google Scholar]
  31. Xie, X.; Dries, L.; Heijman, W.; Zhang, A. land value creation and benefit distribution in the process of rural-urban land conversion: A case study in Wuhan city, China. Habitat Int. 2021, 109, 102335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Zheng, X. Spatio-temporal deconstruction of land rent and right reproduction-exploration on the distribution mechanism of value-added income of “non-agriculturalization” of rural land. Sociol. Stud. 2017, 4, 70–95. [Google Scholar]
  33. Xu, J.; Xu, Y.; Pang, X. Study on land incremental value distribution based on contribution-risk analysis of farmland acquisition. China Land Sci. 2017, 31, 28–35. [Google Scholar]
  34. Han, D.; Han, L.; He, L. Research on the quantified distribution ratio of rural land incremental revenue based on land development right and cooperative game: Samples analysis of Sichuan and Chongqing. China Land Sci. 2017, 31, 62–72. [Google Scholar]
  35. Lin, R.; Zhu, D. A spatial and temporal analysis on land incremental values coupled with land rights in China. Habitat Int. 2014, 44, 168–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Wang, R.; Tan, R. The enlightenment of German land tax system and its reform exploration: From the perspective of land income sharing. China Land Sci. 2015, 29, 81–87. [Google Scholar]
  37. Cai, M.; Fan, J.; Ye, C.; Zhang, Q. Government Debt, Land financing and distributive justice in China. Urban Stud. 2021, 58, 2329–2347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Rose-Ackerman, S. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Nations Are so Rich and Some so Poor. Polit. Sci. Q. 1999, 114, 167–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Kiechel, W. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. Harv. Bus. Rev. 2000, 78, 149. [Google Scholar]
  40. Baruth, B.; Astrand, P.J.; Poidevin, D.; Pecci, J. The use of remote sensing to control selected area based rural development measures over France, Germany and Spain. In Remote Sensing for Agriculture, Ecosystems, and Hydrology V; Owe, M., D’Urso, G., Moreno, J.F., Calera, A., Eds.; International Society for Optics and Photonics: Bellingham, WA, USA, 2004; Volume 5232, pp. 162–172. [Google Scholar]
  41. Daniel, F.-J. Variations in Rural Development: A Comparative Analysis of the Application of the Rural Development Regulation Framework in France and the Netherlands. NJAS Wagen. J. Life Sci. 2008, 56, 7–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Bryon, J.R. Urban assets and the financialization fix: Land tenure, renewal and path dependency in the city of Birmingham. Ambridge J. Reg. Econ. Soc. 2017, 10, 455–469. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Cocconcelli, L.; Medda, F.R. Boom and bust in the Estonian real estate market and the role of land tax as a buffer. Land Use Policy 2013, 30, 392–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Kwak, S.; Mak, J. Political Economy of Property Tax Reform: Hawaii’s Experiment with Split-Rate Property Taxation. Am. J. Econ. Sociol. 2011, 70, 4–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. Operational framework of the potential obstacle mechanism of land transfer income supporting rural revitalization.
Figure 1. Operational framework of the potential obstacle mechanism of land transfer income supporting rural revitalization.
Land 11 00510 g001
Figure 2. Proportion of land transfer income to fiscal deficit and scale and proportion of local finance expenditure on cities and towns, agriculture, forestry, and water.
Figure 2. Proportion of land transfer income to fiscal deficit and scale and proportion of local finance expenditure on cities and towns, agriculture, forestry, and water.
Land 11 00510 g002
Figure 3. Scale and proportion of tax revenue in state-owned construction land, land transfer area, and land financial funds.
Figure 3. Scale and proportion of tax revenue in state-owned construction land, land transfer area, and land financial funds.
Land 11 00510 g003
Table 1. Action direction, entropy value, and weight of obstacle factors.
Table 1. Action direction, entropy value, and weight of obstacle factors.
Stratification PlaneObstacle FactorsUnitDirectionEntropy Value (ej)Weight (Qj)
Local governmentRatio of land transfer income to deficit%0.21340.4841
Proportion of fiscal expenditure in cities and towns%+0.16170.5159
Land financeRatio of transfer to total supply area of state-owned construction land%0.15910.5001
Ratio of tax revenue to land financial funds%0.15930.4999
The countryside itselfIncrease the per capita land requisition area of urban populationm2+0.08590.2487
The ratio of the reduction of rural population to that of rural population%+0.07740.2511
2017 per capita income gap between urban and rural areasTen thousand yuan+0.08510.2490
The gap of per capita industrial output between urban and rural areas in 2017Ten thousand yuan+0.07670.2512
“+” represents a high degree of obstacles, “−“ means a low degree of obstacles.
Table 2. Thirty-one PLADs’ land transfer income supports the potential comprehensive obstacles and types of rural revitalization.
Table 2. Thirty-one PLADs’ land transfer income supports the potential comprehensive obstacles and types of rural revitalization.
PLADsWeighted Sum of Obstacles at All LevelsComprehensive Obstacle Degree (Descending Order)Classification of Obstacle Degree and Order of ActionPLADs
Local Government aLand Finance bThe Countryside Itself c
Chongqing0.68930.55850.46000.579HighHigh class I
a > b > c
Chongqing
Tibet0.52660.88440.28720.570HighFujian
Qinghai0.59900.77110.28570.569HighSichuan
Fujian0.59470.53610.49770.549HighHubei
Sichuan0.61680.59910.35100.544HighShanxi
Hubei0.64190.54410.38960.544HighHunan
Shanxi0.65730.58560.29420.544HighTianjin
Hunan0.64020.54870.39590.543HighHigh class II
b >a > c
Tibet
Tianjin0.76890.42490.33870.536HighQinghai
Yunnan0.56210.65450.30580.532MediumModerate Class I
a > b > c
Anhui
Guizhou0.55620.59560.42090.529MediumShaanxi
Anhui0.61030.54600.35110.525MediumHenan
Shaanxi0.63530.48790.41190.523MediumGuangxi
Shanghai 0.69910.37310.47960.521MediumGuangdong
Henan0.65560.46660.35000.513MediumJiangxi
Guangxi0.60940.51550.32360.508MediumModerate class II
a > c > b
Shanghai
Gansu0.51850.64730.25860.508MediumBeijing
Guangdong0.73110.35250.34440.503MediumModerate class III
a > c > b
Jilin
Jilin0.60710.42080.43130.495MediumLiaoning
Liaoning0.68950.35110.39210.494MediumModerate class VI
b > c > a
Yunnan
Jiangxi0.57160.48510.33230.488MediumGuizhou
Beijing0.57140.31770.52580.474MediumGansu
Ningxia0.46350.51810.33220.466MediumNingxia
Xinjiang0.54920.49560.15360.463LowLow class I
a > b > c
Xinjiang
Hebei0.61180.36580.29720.461LowHebei
Heilongjiang0.52030.46270.25290.458LowHeilongjiang
Zhejiang0.28720.55330.53740.458LowHainan
Inner Mongolia0.52730.30950.49270.451LowLow class II
a > c > b
Inner Mongolia
Jiangsu0.26690.40780.61330.428LowShandong
Shandong0.54430.24160.43260.418LowLow class III
c ≅ b > a
Zhejiang
Hainan0.52940.32750.19550.407LowJiangsu
The weighted sum of obstacles at all levels (local government, land finance and the countryside itself) are represented by a, b, and c, respectively.
Table 3. Thirty-one PLADs’ land transfer income supports the weighted sum value of potential obstacles to rural revitalization.
Table 3. Thirty-one PLADs’ land transfer income supports the weighted sum value of potential obstacles to rural revitalization.
PLADsRatio of Land Transfer Income to DeficitProportion of Fiscal Expenditure in Cities and TownsRatio of Transfer to Total Supply Area of State-Owned Construction LandRatio of Tax Revenue to Land Financial FundsIncrease the per Capita Land Requisition Area of Urban PopulationThe Ratio of the Reduction of Rural Population to that of Rural Population2017 per Capita Income Gap Between Urban and Rural AreasThe Gap of per Capita Industrial Output between Urban and Rural Areas in 2017
Chongqing0.3670.3220.2290.3300.0580.2510.0510.100
Tibet0.4840.0430.3840.5000.0610.0000.0590.167
Qinghai0.4790.1200.5000.2710.0660.1000.0520.067
Fujian0.3120.2830.2300.3060.0780.1850.0840.151
Sichuan0.4270.1900.2940.3050.0460.1980.0390.069
Hubei0.4140.2280.2580.2860.0920.1720.0350.091
Shanxi0.4480.2090.2840.3020.0420.1510.0380.064
Hunan0.4400.2000.2970.2520.0540.1940.0660.082
Tianjin0.2690.5000.1280.2970.0370.0310.0400.231
Yunnan0.4540.1080.3920.2620.0750.1270.0670.036
Guizhou0.4540.1020.4280.1680.1200.1940.0580.050
Anhui0.3870.2230.1820.3640.0440.2020.0430.061
Shaanxi0.4540.1810.2710.2170.0510.1960.0610.104
Shanghai 0.1820.5170.2260.1470.0260.0000.2120.241
Henan0.4360.2200.2450.2210.0330.2070.0220.088
Guangxi0.4480.1620.3110.2040.0780.1630.0470.036
Gansu0.4710.0470.3590.2880.0260.1570.0520.023
Guangdong0.2920.4390.1810.1710.0080.0810.1110.145
Jilin0.4570.1500.2720.1490.2490.0760.0060.100
Liaoning0.3780.3110.1490.2020.1190.1540.0690.050
Jiangxi0.4190.1530.2100.2750.0600.1800.0340.059
Beijing0.1630.4080.0450.2730.0000.0260.2490.251
Ningxia0.4640.0000.2580.2600.0700.1400.0420.080
Xinjiang0.4720.0770.4140.0820.0380.0000.0520.063
Hebei0.4120.1990.0470.3190.0150.1880.0310.064
Heilongjiang0.4650.0550.3380.1240.1540.0990.0000.000
Zhejiang0.0180.2690.1680.3860.0770.1470.1220.191
Inner Mongolia 0.4590.0680.3100.0000.1420.1750.0880.087
Jiangsu0.0000.2670.0370.3710.0410.2480.1030.222
Shandong0.3130.2320.0000.2420.0390.1750.0730.145
Hainan0.4330.0960.2340.0940.0510.1060.0330.005
Table 4. Thirty-one PLADs’ land transfer income supports rural revitalization obstacles V and VI clustering results.
Table 4. Thirty-one PLADs’ land transfer income supports rural revitalization obstacles V and VI clustering results.
Provinces Class IVProvincesClass IVProvincesClass ⅤProvincesClass Ⅴ
Jiangsu1Yunnan3Jiangsu1Yunnan4
Zhejiang1Ningxia3Zhejiang1Ningxia4
Beijing2Qinghai3Beijing2Qinghai4
Shanghai2Hainan3Shanghai2Hainan4
Tianjin3Shanxi3Tianjin3Shanxi4
Guangdong3Shaanxi3Guangdong3Shaanxi4
Fujian3Gansu3Fujian3Gansu4
Shandong3Xinjiang3Shandong3Xinjiang4
Chongqing3Tibet3Chongqing3Tibet4
Anhui3Liaoning4Anhui3Liaoning5
Jiangxi3Hubei4Jiangxi4Hubei5
Henan3Guizhou4Henan4Guizhou5
Hebei3Inner Mongolia 4Hebei4Inner Mongolia 5
Hunan3Heilongjiang4Hunan4Heilongjiang5
Sichuan3Jilin5Sichuan4Jilin6
Guangxi3 Guangxi4
Table 5. The gap between the area of land expropriation and the rural employed population and the per capita output value of urban and rural areas.
Table 5. The gap between the area of land expropriation and the rural employed population and the per capita output value of urban and rural areas.
YearArea of Land Expropriation
(km2)
Reduce the Population in Rural Areas (10,000)Ratio of the Employed Population of the First Production (%)Per Capita Income (yuan)Per Capita Industrial Output Value (yuan)
Cities and TownsRural AreasGap Between Urban and Rural AreasUrban Secondary and Tertiary IndustriesRural Primary IndustryGap between Urban and Rural Areas
20011101.81274.050.06907.12366.44540.719,840.315,502.517,891.9
20021378.41322.050.08177.42475.65701.821,016.316,190.218,947.1
20032860.31390.049.19061.22622.26439.022,997.516,970.220,789.3
20041564.61146.046.910,128.52936.47192.125,963.220,904.323,201.9
20052333.71161.044.811,320.83254.98065.829,444.321,806.726,518.9
20062537.81384.042.612,719.23587.09132.233,647.023,317.030,459.9
20072231.21664.040.814,908.64140.410,768.339,985.527,788.036,098.9
20082232.11097.039.617,067.84760.612,307.245,953.332,753.241,300.8
20093511.71461.038.118,858.15153.213,704.948,815.734,161.843,860.2
20103451.91825.036.721,033.48119.512,913.955,789.639,362.649,924.5
20113958.41457.034.823,979.29833.114,146.164,149.446,163.157,118.3
20123884.71434.033.626,959.010,990.715,968.368,762.550,902.360,836.5
20133375.81261.031.426,467.09429.617,037.473,848.755,329.165,060.9
20142919.61095.029.528,843.910,488.918,355.078,171.658,343.568,741.0
20152985.91520.028.331,194.811,412.719,782.181,460.460,862.171,374.9
20162561.41373.027.733,616.212,363.421,252.885,741.563,672.874,944.5
20172177.91312.027.036,396.213,432.422,963.893,630.365,467.682,276.4
Table 6. Potential obstacle factors of land transfer income supporting rural revitalization in 31 PLADs 2001–2017.
Table 6. Potential obstacle factors of land transfer income supporting rural revitalization in 31 PLADs 2001–2017.
PLADs
(Cities, Districts)
Local GovernmentLand FinanceThe Countryside Itself
Ratio of Land Transfer Income to Deficit
(%)
Proportion of Fiscal Expenditure in Cities and Towns
(%)
Ratio of Transfer to Total Supply Area of State-Owned Construction Land
(%)
Ratio Of Tax Revenue to Land Financial Funds
(%)
Increase the per Capita Land Requisition Area of Urban Population
(m2)
The Ratio of the Reduction of Rural Population to that of Rural Population (%)2017 per Capita Income Gap between Urban and Rural Areas
(Ten Thousand yuan)
The Gap of per Capita Industrial Output between Urban and Rural Areas in 2017
(Ten Thousand yuan)
Jiangsu345.290.469.717.9113.841.52.4513.21
Zhejiang 332.490.557.816.9171.924.62.6311.89
Beijing 229.493.569.024.448.94.33.8214.44
Shanghai216.095.852.532.790.0-58.23.4814.02
Tianjin154.195.461.522.8107.45.21.8513.60
Guangdong 138.194.156.631.161.513.52.529.96
Fujian 124.090.852.122.2173.730.92.2710.22
Shandong 123.189.773.126.5111.629.32.179.96
Chongqing84.791.652.220.6141.742.11.968.06
Liaoning76.691.459.529.1238.625.82.125.95
Anhui 70.589.556.518.4119.333.91.896.42
Hebei52.389.068.821.472.531.41.776.54
Hubei51.289.649.523.5195.328.81.817.66
Jiangxi47.988.053.924.3144.430.11.806.33
Sichuan42.288.846.322.3121.633.11.856.72
Hainan 37.586.851.836.3130.517.81.794.03
Henan 35.889.450.727.8101.734.61.687.56
Hunan32.989.046.025.8135.132.52.107.28
Guangxi27.388.244.729.0173.027.31.925.35
Shanxi27.289.247.222.5115.525.31.836.52
Guizhou22.986.934.131.4240.132.42.025.93
Shaanxi22.988.648.428.1129.932.92.058.20
Yunnan22.587.037.325.1169.121.32.115.35
Jilin20.687.948.332.7445.812.71.548.07
Inner Mongolia19.186.244.942.5276.129.42.317.49
Ningxia16.084.749.625.2161.223.41.877.20
Heilongjiang14.785.942.234.3294.216.61.483.82
Gansu10.485.740.323.490.226.31.974.81
Xinjiang9.886.335.337.1110.2-1.11.976.47
Qinghai5.187.327.524.5153.916.81.976.67
Tibet1.485.638.19.3146.3-11.42.0310.89
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, Y.; Xue, Y.; Xi, J. Inter-Provincial Differences in Potential Obstacles to Land Transfer Income to Support Rural Revitalization in China. Land 2022, 11, 510. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11040510

AMA Style

Wang Y, Xue Y, Xi J. Inter-Provincial Differences in Potential Obstacles to Land Transfer Income to Support Rural Revitalization in China. Land. 2022; 11(4):510. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11040510

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Yubo, Yuyu Xue, and Jianchao Xi. 2022. "Inter-Provincial Differences in Potential Obstacles to Land Transfer Income to Support Rural Revitalization in China" Land 11, no. 4: 510. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11040510

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop