Next Article in Journal
Arsenic Transformation in Swine Wastewater with Low-Arsenic Content during Anaerobic Digestion
Next Article in Special Issue
Water Management Reporting in the Agro-Food Sector in South Africa
Previous Article in Journal
Robust Meter Network for Water Distribution Pipe Burst Detection
Previous Article in Special Issue
Model and Growth Stage Based Variability of the Irrigation Demand of Onion Crops with Predicted Climate Change
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Combining Econometric, Cost–Benefit, and Financial Methodologies in a Framework to Increase Diffusion and to Predict the Feasibility and Sustainability of Irrigation Schemes: A Case Study in Kurdistan, Iraq

Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università di Bologna, via Angherà 22, 47900 Rimini, Italy
Water 2017, 9(11), 821; https://doi.org/10.3390/w9110821
Submission received: 27 July 2017 / Revised: 4 October 2017 / Accepted: 20 October 2017 / Published: 26 October 2017
(This article belongs to the Collection Water Policy Collection)

Abstract

:
This paper applies ex ante econometric, cost–benefit, and financial methodologies to increase participation in an irrigation project and predict its financial feasibility and social sustainability in Shahrazoor, Kurdistan, Iraq. I investigated the socio-economic, psycho-cultural, and financial factors that determine participation. The socio-economic part of the econometric analysis showed that the project was appreciated more by poorer and economically weaker farmers who rely on agriculture than by those who rely on livestock activities. The psycho-cultural part of the econometric analysis emphasized that the project was appreciated more by literate farmers who adopt a maximization (rather than habit) approach. The cost–benefit analysis applied to the irrigation project was tailored to poorer and weaker farmers (i.e., costs of the irrigation scheme and benefits from new cultivation patterns were defined with reference to small farms) by including indirect benefits from both irrigation (e.g., flood control) and hydropower (e.g., eliminated GHG emissions), and determined a 7.1% mean internal rate of return; this was affected more strongly by uncertainty in crop prices than by uncertainty in indirect benefits. The financial analysis highlighted values for water prices, financial returns, and loan rates that met government and farmer budgets. A single framework summarized the main relevant social, economic, and financial conditions, and, by including insights from sensitivity analyses, determined the feasibility and sustainability of the irrigation project. Provided that the water price charged to farmers is between 0.32 and 0.57 USD/m3, and the loan interest rate paid by farmers is smaller than 3.0%, the irrigation project in Shahrazoor is financially feasible for 13.6% of all reliable economic solutions and socially sustainable for 35.8% of the solutions.

1. Introduction

Agricultural policy programs, in general, and technological interventions in agriculture, in particular, should be congruent with farmer priorities (i.e., the problems to be solved) and expectations, and should also be appropriate for the long-term socioeconomic, cultural, and agronomic circumstances of the farmers ([1,2,3]). Such policies and technologies would have a greater chance of being accepted and practiced sustainably than programs based on temporary incentives or coercive pressures.
Technological interventions ([4,5,6,7,8,9,10,11]), in general, and irrigation projects ([12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19]), in particular, often result in a low level of awareness among the target group and in a low level of successful diffusion of the project (i.e., dissemination of knowledge leading to participation) because farmers are rarely consulted a priori about their specific circumstances, priority problems, and expectations.
Econometric studies of adoption behaviors and cost–benefit and financial studies of the impacts of an intervention should come before the project’s costs are incurred. This is because approaches based solely on expert knowledge are likely to be biased due to a lack of information on the socio-economic and psycho-cultural attributes of the farmers, and on how these attributes will affect their decisions.
Among the few ex ante econometric analyses of policy or technology adoption by farmers, Batz et al. [20] used linear regression analysis to predict the speed and future ceiling for a dairy technology adoption in Kenya by assuming that data on past adoption behavior would provide information about likely future behavior. However, they did not account for the psycho-cultural characteristics of the farmers. Bekele [21] applied a multinomial logit model to analyze the impact of various types of intervention and of the problems prioritized by the farmers on the preferences of Ethiopian farmers. However, this study did not analyze the feasible distribution of costs among the farmers. Kondoh and Jussaume [22] applied logistic regression analysis to estimate the relative impacts of social networks and life experiences on the willingness of farmers in Washington State (USA) to adopt genetically modified organisms. However, they did not consider the psycho-cultural characteristics of the farmers or the technological features of the proposed interventions. Jaek and Lifran [23] performed a choice experiment to estimate the monetary value attached by farmers in France to six relevant attributes associated with rice cultivation practices, in order to design targeted contracts according to farmer preferences and to persuade the majority of rice growers to adopt environmentally friendly practices. However, they did not perform a financial analysis to implement an effective policy based on differentiated payments.
The purpose of the present paper was to solve these problems by applying ex ante econometric, cost–benefit, and financial methodologies within a single framework to increase diffusion and predict the financial feasibility and social sustainability of an irrigation project in Shahrazoor, Kurdistan, Iraq. To do so, I assessed the socio-economic, psycho-cultural, and financial factors that determine participation in order to identify the target farmers, to adjust the project to meet their needs and desires, and to properly distribute the project costs between this audience, the government, and society as a whole. In other words, the objective was to develop and demonstrate a methodological approach in which the results of the econometric analysis (which identifies the major socio-economic and psycho-cultural factors that influence participation decisions by farmers) affect the cost–benefit analysis (for example, by identifying the target group or the project features). In turn, the financial analysis (which specifies water prices and loan rates charged to farmers) is based on the results of the cost–benefit analysis by assuming that these water prices must be smaller than the economic value of water (otherwise, farmers would pay for benefits that accrue to other people) and that these loan rates must be smaller than the internal rate of return (IRR) of the project (otherwise, farmers would pay for the inefficiency of the irrigation project).
Note that this is unlike more usual contexts, in which farmers receive irrigation deliveries in return for some form of payment (in cash or in kind) after an irrigation scheme has been built ([24,25]). This paper refers to the future decision (at an individual farm level) to participate in a hypothetical program: the conceptual framework is similar to that for technology adoption, in which farmers decide to begin using a new production method or device; in this context, predicting participation in the project means anticipating future adoption by many farmers.

2. Review of the Econometric Literature

This section will identify the main variables applied in the econometric literature to explain technology adoption in agriculture.
I reviewed the literature to determine the key temporal factors. Batz et al. [20] showed that the perceived characteristics of technologies, such as the relative investment, risk, and complexity, were significant. Moreover, Burton et al. [26] applied a duration model in the U.K. to identify the economic and non-economic determinants of the adoption of organic horticultural technology; they found that gender, attitudes to the environment, and sources of information were important factors. Finally, Fuglie and Kascak [27] applied a duration model in the U.S. to estimate the long-term trends in the adoption and diffusion of technologies designed to reduce environmental externalities from agriculture. Long lags in the adoption of a technology turned out to result from differences in land quality, farm size, farmer education, and regional factors.
Similarly, I reviewed the literature to reveal spatial factors. Adesina and Chianu [28] used a logit model to assess the determinants of farmer decisions to adopt and adapt alley farming technology in Nigeria by considering both farmer and village characteristics. They found that farmer origins, previous contacts with agricultural extension agents, the number of years of experience with agro-forestry, land pressures, erosion intensity, and the distance from urban centers were all statistically significant factors. Moreover, Swinton [29] applied both random-effects regression models and spatial auto-regression models in Peru, using time lags in the choice of keeping some fields fallow as the dependent variable, to depict the impacts of household agricultural management practices on the decisions of neighbors. A spatial structure was evident, and the two models provided nearly identical results; thus, random-effects regression could largely eliminate the spatial dependency if the farmers were stratified according to the landscape characteristics. Finally, Abdulai and Huffman [30] employed a duration function to explain the increased use of crossbred cows in Tanzania; they found that proximity to other users of these cows, the level of schooling, access to credit, and previous contacts with extension agents positively affected adoption of these cows.
Among other studies, De Souza Filho et al. [31] applied duration analysis in Brazil to identify the determinants of the probability that a farmer would adopt a certain technology at time t, given that it had not already been adopted by that time. They found that the integration of farmers with farmer organizations, awareness of the negative effects of chemicals on health and the environment, reliance on family labor, being located in an area with better soil, and declining output prices were significant positive determinants for adoption, whereas the farm size and increasing input prices were significant negative determinants. Moreover, Kondoh and Jussaume [22] showed that, apart from a previous lack of experience with farming or with current organic farming practices, gross incomes, market strategies, and education levels positively affected adoption, whereas whether farmers obtained information about farming practices from other farmers, from cooperative personnel, or from both was not significant. Finally, Baerenklau and Knapp [32] developed a dynamic model of technology adoption in California (USA) by incorporating the age of the technology, whether the investment was reversible, variable inputs and outputs, and stochastic prices, and showed that the optimal decision rule was affected by the age of the technology that was currently adopted, by uncertainty due to variability in input and output prices, and by the irreversibility of the adoption decision. In the present study, these factors were disregarded because irrigation projects are new in the study area. Note that Bekele [21] combined the characteristics of the farm and the farmer with the personal costs and benefits expected by the farmer.
Table 1 summarizes the main independent variables used in the econometric literature, based on the arrangement of factors affecting irrigation adoption that was suggested by Alcon et al. [33]. I disregarded papers that relied only on one or two independent variables that have been used in subsequent studies. See Pardey et al. [34] for a broader analysis of innovation and technical change in agriculture.

3. The Study Area and Data Collection

The Iraqi Ministry of Water Resources is planning to implement several irrigation programs, already defined at the end of the 1970s, by revising the original projects in order to achieve an equitable and sustainable use of regional water resources. The goals were to take into account the development of more competitive markets and a more open society, and to integrate water engineering construction with environmental conservation. The present study focuses on the Qara Ali dam and irrigation project that will be implemented in the Shahrazoor basin of Kurdistan (Figure 1).
The Shahrazoor irrigation area is located in northwestern Iraq, within the highlands of the Kurdistan Mountains in Sulaymaniyah Governorate ([39]). The project area is located at an altitude of approximately 560 m a.s.l., and the land drains toward the Derbendikhan reservoir: this reservoir is assumed to be unaffected, although there might be some positive interactions for flood control, and negative interactions for tourism activities. The proposed Qara Ali dam (crest level = 605 m a.s.l.; dam height = 35 m) and reservoir (full storage capacity = 86 × 106 m3; water area = 6.9 km2; total yearly inflow = 177.9 × 106 m3; annual losses due to evaporation = 11.14 × 106 m3) are located within the Tanjero River valley, near the point of origin of the Shahrazoor basin. Construction of the dam is planned upstream of the village of Qara Ali. The irrigation project area is located downstream of the dam, along the right bank of the Tanjero River. This is an important project for the future development of the Suleymaniyah Governorate and the Shahrazoor region. The original development study for the area began during the 1970s, and was completed during the 1980s. The overall irrigation scheme (based on open irrigation canals) was originally designed to be larger than the one that was ultimately selected. The present urban development within the valley, water availability, and socio-economic reasons were the driving factors for the selection of the present layout for both the dam and the attached irrigation project.
The data used in the present analysis were obtained from face-to-face interviews with farmers in the region affected by the project: these individuals were randomly chosen from a list provided by local representatives of the Ministry of Water Resources. The irrigation project will directly affect 15 villages: these are quite similar in terms of irrigation opportunities that might be perceived by farmers (e.g., close to input and output markets, near credit markets). Official statistics ([40]) report that 315 farmers lived in this area in 2011, and specify the land area exploited by each owner and the proportions of rain-fed and irrigated agriculture. Because of time and budget constraints, I only interviewed 46 farmers (15% of the total) in 12 villages (Alan, Daq, Daskara, Hasil-Kanikawa, Jolana, Kani-Bardina, Malwan, Qalawza, Qara-Gol, Shekh-Hasan, Zarayan and, Yakhshi) in April 2012. I initially stratified the population into three farm-size classes and two tenancy classes. I then modified the initial sample plan to account for the actual proportions of farm size and types of tenancy that I observed in the field (Table 2).
Farm size was overestimated in the official data, probably due to division of land among heirs after the original statistics were collected, and the proportion of tenant farmers also appeared to have been underestimated, probably due to subsequent sales of land by farmers. I accounted for these features of the sample in the subsequent econometric analysis. Note that such a distribution of land size (i.e., many small farmers) is quite common in developing countries. Thus, in other developing countries, an irrigation project could also increase total income and reduce income inequality in a given area by targeting small farmers.
The detailed results of my survey are presented in Table A1 and Table A2 of Appendix A. Here, I will discuss only the most important results. The average farmer was relatively old (nearly 51 years), with a family structure that included both grandparents and children. Farms averaged around 12 ha in size, and were most often (65%) rain-fed rather than irrigated. All raw data were obtained in donum, a local unit of measure that is equivalent to 0.25 ha, and were converted into hectares. Most farmers were poorly educated or illiterate, and government agencies were their primary source of access to information; other farmers were not a significant source. Twelve crops accounted for most of the region’s agriculture, and each farmer typically raised both a small number of cows and goats and a larger number of sheep (a mean of 34 per family). Farmers used a mixture of traditional and modern agricultural techniques, and most used their current methods because they had always done so, and had found them to be effective; few used methods because other farmers or the government had advised them to do so. Most felt that increasing prices for agricultural inputs (including labor) were a major concern, despite increasing sales prices for agricultural outputs.

4. Methodology

4.1. The Econometric Analysis

This section will identify a subset of the feasible variables discussed in Section 2 based on the case study characteristics depicted in Section 3, and will develop an econometric model that includes these variables.
As the dependent variable in the present analysis, I chose a decision to be taken in the future rather than decisions already taken in the past; as a result, temporal and spatial aspects of participation could not be assessed. The resulting dependent variable (i.e., the readiness to adopt irrigated agriculture) will be represented by combining data on willingness to adopt the new approach, access to information, and access to credit into a binary outcome variable (with 1 = ready to participate, 0 = unready); the three criteria were whether the farmer was willing to participate, and whether they had access to at least one source of information and at least one source of credit; in this study, 98%, 91%, and 89% of the survey population met these criteria, respectively. Needless to say, willingness to adopt is different from readiness to adopt in terms of knowledge and financial resources. In particular, among the temporal factors, previous contacts with extension agents have been excluded as a variable because no survey respondents reported receiving information from such sources, and the number of years of experience was not analyzed because the irrigation scheme under consideration is new to the study area. Among the spatial factors, the decisions of neighbors were disregarded because the irrigation scheme is new in the area; land quality and regional factors were not analyzed because of the homogeneous and small agricultural area under consideration; the distance from urban centers was excluded because all farmers live in homogeneously distributed villages; and the proximity of farmers to other users of irrigation was not considered because all farmers lived in villages surrounded by farmland, with little use of irrigation in the study area (i.e., 93% of the study area was non-irrigated land). Moreover, as suggested by my preliminary pilot surveys, gender and environmental concerns were not analyzed because the agricultural society in the study area is heavily male-dominated and sufficiently poor that environmental concerns are not a high priority for residents; and farmer origin was not included in the present analysis because all farmers in the study area come from the same Kurdish culture. Finally, land pressure and erosion intensity were excluded, since these are similar throughout the study area, and the characteristics of alternative technologies have not been considered because a single irrigation scheme is being proposed for the whole study area. Note that some previous studies have assumed full information on the part of the farmers, so that differences in access to information do not lead to different decisions, and have recommended solutions for when this assumption was violated (e.g., [41]). However, since no farmers in the study area knew about the proposed irrigation project before my study, all farmers were assumed to have no knowledge. The economic benefits perceived by the farmers (e.g., [42]) were also not included, because irrigated agricultural management is new in the study area and its benefits are therefore not known to farmers. Similarly, no measures were necessary to correct for selection bias (e.g., [43]) because no farmers were aware of this future irrigation project.
For the independent socio-economic variables, I used the estimated gross income as a linear function of crop yields, with crop prices as weighting factors. Indeed, the relationship between farm size and farm income, which would suggest the need to use income per hectare, is likely to be weak (i.e., the average farm dimension was 7.74 ha, with a standard deviation of only 0.68). Other studies chose alternative proxies for income: the farm size ([35]), the estimated gross income ([44]), the estimated consumption per capita ([36]), or the stated yield for the main crop ([27]). Moreover, I introduced a dummy variable to account for direct access to output markets, thereby omitting the alternative reference to local traders ([28]), and I introduced four dummy variables for prices, with good or fair (but not unfair) as the options for output and input prices ([31]). Finally, I used dummy variables for direct access to bank loans ([45]), thereby omitting the alternative reference to other sources (i.e., cooperatives and other farmers), and for whether the percentage of income from livestock activities was greater than 50% ([37]).
Note that the ex ante a priori nature of the present study made it impossible to highlight the impacts of alternative types of adopters; for example, Zhang et al. [46] estimated a higher influence by early successful adopters on the decisions of others. The relatively small size of the farmer families involved in the present irrigation project suggested that differences in available labor could be disregarded, unlike in the study by Dadi et al. [47]. The ex ante nature of the present study also made it impossible to distinguish non-adopters from alternative types of adopter; for example, Barham et al. [48] identified the most significant differences between non-adopters and early adopters, late adopters, and those who adopted and then abandoned the technology. The small and very small numbers of owners and sharecroppers, respectively, in my sample made it impossible to highlight the impacts of alternative types of tenancy; for example, Soule et al. [35] estimated the influence of land tenure on the adoption of conservation practices. The relatively small area involved in the present irrigation project suggested that differences in available technologies could be disregarded, whereas the water shortage perceived by almost all farmers made it impossible to analyze the possibility of a partial participation in the irrigation scheme.
For the psycho-cultural independent variables, the small sample size suggested that I should distinguish literate from illiterate farmers using a dummy variable ([21]) and that I should rank agricultural problems using dummy variables for access to markets and access to additional water, which were ranked as the most urgent problems, and used access to loans as a residual variable (see Table 3). Based on the perception that water shortages mainly occurred during the summer, I created a third dummy variable for summer water availability (always and never), and used water shortages in winter as a residual variable. Moreover, I introduced two variables to account for attitudes towards innovation. To do so, I counted the number of replies that included “I have always done it this way” as the justification for the current choice of crops, fertilizers, output markets, and irrigation technology, and used this as an indicator of a “habit” (status quo) approach to innovation. I also counted the number of responses that represented a “maximization” approach to innovation, where these respondents justified their current choices as follows: “it offers a better price” for the output market, “they show high profitability” for crops, “they are very effective” for fertilizers, and “it is efficient” for irrigation technology. Finally, I used two dummy variables for attitudes towards the future: one for positive expectations (i.e., for the future, increasing output prices and either increasing or stable input prices), and one for uncertainty (i.e., not in a position to express any expectation). I also introduced dummy variables for membership in a cooperative and access to information on agricultural technologies from governmental agencies, other farmers, or cooperatives ([38]). For the project’s potential, I used two dummy variables (changing crops and expanding current crops), since these were ranked as the most significant expectations from the irrigation project (see Table 4). Details on information provided during the interviews can be deduced from the questionnaire, which is available from the author on request.
Table 5 summarizes the main statistics for the independent variables used in this study. The dependent variable had a mean of 0.85 (i.e., based on a value of one in 39 out of 46 observations) and a standard deviation of 0.36, with Max and Min at 1 and 0, respectively.
Binary logistic regression is a standard statistical procedure in which the probability of a dichotomous outcome (in the present case, participation or non-participation) is related to a set of explanatory variables (e.g., [49]). If the responses of farmers in the study region are assumed to be consistent with utility-maximizing behavior, then the irrigation project will be joined by farmers if the net utility obtained from participation exceeds that from non-participation.
The small number of observations suggested that it would be necessary to perform a combined estimation for the socio-economic and psycho-cultural determinants of participation by considering as many variables as possible from among those suggested by the literature. In particular, the probit model to be estimated was:
Prob (rea = 1) = Φ(α + βse xse + βpc xpc)
where rea is the binary outcome variable “readiness to adopt”, xse and xpc are the socio-economic and psycho-cultural determinants of participation (respectively), and Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution; the parameters α and β are maximum-likelihood estimates. Note that Moreno and Sunding [50] estimated a nested logit model and showed that the irrigation technology was selected jointly with land allocation, whereas Useche et al. [51] applied a mixed-multinomial logit model to estimate the effects of technological traits and farm and farmer characteristics on adoption outcome. The probit model was appropriate here because the present study considered a single irrigation scheme with no alternative technological traits, and farmers provided only partial information on potential crop choices.

4.2. The Cost–Benefit Analysis

In general, once the econometric results have suggested the need to focus on a specified group of farmers as those who are most likely to adopt an irrigation technology, a cost–benefit analysis should be tailored to this group. In particular, if the suggested focus is on the relatively poor and economically weak farmers, a cost–benefit analysis must be performed by referring to this group when estimating both the costs, since the irrigation scheme must be designed for small farms, and the benefits, since new cultivation patterns must be intended for small farms.
In the survey sample, four of the 46 farmers (8.7%) farmed more than 25 ha, and a similar proportion were potentially interested in the irrigation project. On this basis, I assumed that 290 of the 315 farmers (92%) reported in official statistics ([40]) for the study area would represent the target group. After excluding the four largest farmers, the average farm size in the sample was 7.99 ha. I have rounded this value to 8 ha and used that value as the farm size for the target farmer, and I have divided the overall irrigation area into 692 representative hydraulic units of 8 ha each, which are directly affected by the irrigation project.
I will refer to the target farmer when suggesting alternative cultivation patterns and potential increases in crop yields. In particular, Table A3, Table A4 and Table A5 in Appendix B depict suggested innovative cultivation patterns that would be permitted by adopting irrigated agriculture and yields based on a farm size of 8 ha, together with market prices for winter, summer, and perennial crops based on market prices that were current as of 2013. Note that the current cultivation pattern is based on few main crops: the most important crops, based on their percentage of the total cultivated area, are wheat at 26%, barley at 23%, and chickpeas at 8% of the total cultivated area in winter, and watermelon at 3%, sunflower at 3%, and melon at 1% of the total cultivated area in summer (with the remainder of the area mostly left fallow). This pattern produces a gross annual income per hectare of 2.358 × 106 Iraqi Dinars. Farmers were asked to state the qualitative impacts on their gross annual income (i.e., small, medium, large) of fertilizers, hired labor, pesticides, and transport costs, as well as the qualitative impacts of product subsidies. It was not possible to quantitatively assess these responses as percentages due to the high illiteracy level observed in the study population. However, it was possible to assign (post hoc) values of 1, 5, and 10% to small, medium, and large impacts, respectively. By applying these percentages as negative values for costs and as positive values for subsidies to the gross annual income for each farmer, I obtained a net annual income per hectare of 1.862 × 106 Iraqi Dinars. I will use 21% (i.e., [1 − (1.862/2.358)] × 100) as a proxy for the farmer’s operating costs to calculate the net additional incomes from the gross additional incomes after irrigation adoption.
Thus, the increases in net income from both agricultural and livestock activities for the target farmer as a result of a changed cultivation pattern or an increased crop yield that will become possible as a result of the irrigation project is estimated to be 5400 USD/ha (at 1 USD = 1250 Iraqi Dinar). Note that the percentages of cultivated area as a result of a changed cultivation pattern do not sum up to 1 because some of the same land is used in subsequent seasons.
Moreover, I will refer to the target farmer when calculating water network costs. In particular, Table A6, Table A7 and Table A8 in Appendix B depict the investment and operating irrigation costs for both the government and each farmer, based on a farm size of 8 ha, together with costs for the dam and hydropower station and expenditures for social and environmental features such as flood control, water quality control, and recreational activities (e.g., swimming in the reservoir and catching fish). Note that within the area that will be occupied by the Qara Ali reservoir, there are no settlements; thus, resettlement will not be required. In addition, there are no historic shrines, temples, mosques, churches, or other culturally or religiously significant structures, so reconstruction will not be required.
Finally, I will refer to the target farmer when calculating the project’s IRR. In particular, the direct benefits from irrigation can be estimated at 29.894 × 106 USD per year (the total irrigated area of 5536 ha multiplied by the income increase of 5400 USD/ha, where 5536 is based on the assumption of 8 ha per hydraulic unit for the 692 units). In addition, I assumed that the indirect benefits from the irrigation project due to improved environmental management would be 10% of the direct benefits for both the farmers directly affected by the project (692, based on the assumption of 8 ha per hydraulic unit, with one farmer per unit) and those who are indirectly affected (1055, which represents the total affected area of 13,976 ha minus the total irrigated area of 5536 ha, then divided by the hydraulic unit area of 8 ha), for a total of 7.547 × 106 USD; this equals the total number of affected farmers (692 + 1055 = 1747) multiplied by the number of 8-ha hydraulic units (one per farmer) and by 10% of the income increase of 5400 USD/ha. Note that the assumed 10% increase can be justified because the additional amount of water from the project that will be used in agriculture is around 90%. Similarly, the direct benefits from hydropower can be estimated at 0.145 × 106 USD per year; this equals the total energy production, which is estimated at 14.490 GWh/year, multiplied by the energy price of 0.01 USD/kWh. In addition, the indirect benefits from hydropower are assumed to be 0.320 × 106 USD per year due to the certified emission reduction (CER) credits received by eliminating greenhouse gas emissions. Note that this figure relies on the assumption that a heavy-oil-fired power plant is the logical alternative to hydropower in this region, and is based on the following calculations: the average CO2 emission for oil-fired power generation (i.e., 893 t/GWh) minus the average CO2 emissions for a large hydropower installation (i.e., 8 t/GWh) is multiplied by the expected price in 2012 (i.e., 25 USD/t) of CER credits and by the expected energy production by the hydropower station each year (14.490 GWh).

4.3. The Financial Analysis

In general, once the cost–benefit analysis has provided scenarios for the average IRR (i.e., AveIRR) and the worst-case IRR (i.e., MinIRR), financial analysis should refer to these figures as the mean and reliable socio-economic values, respectively. In particular, financial analysis must be performed to identify the financial feasibility of the project (i.e., whether the government can meet its budget constraints in terms of revenues from selling water and returns from investing public funds in irrigation or similar projects, whereas farmers must be able to meet their budget constraints in terms of paid water prices and loan rates). Financial analysis must also be performed to identify the social sustainability of the project (i.e., farmers do not pay for benefits that accrue to other people or for inefficiencies of the irrigation project), if some direct economic benefits from irrigation (e.g., selling water to farmers) or some indirect economic benefits from hydropower (i.e., selling CER credits in international markets) are not monetized or are only partially monetized.
The minimum water price (wp) required for the government to break even at an alternative rate of financial return (fr) can be obtained by solving the following equations with respect to wp:
t=5 54(1/(1 + fr)t) (totlan × watuse × wp + dirpowbent + indpowbent) − ∑t=1 4 (1/(1 + fr)t) (damcost + powcost + irrcost + othcost) − ∑t=5 54 (O&Mdamt + O&Mpowt + O&Mirrt) (1/(1 + fr)t) − (1/(1 + fr)34) (damcosrep34 + powcosrep34 + irrcosrep34)
where totlan is the total irrigated land, watuse is the water use, dirpowbent is the direct benefits from selling energy production at time t, indpowbent is the indirect benefits from selling CER credits, damcost is the total dam cost, powcost is the total power station cost, irrcost is the total irrigation cost, O&Mdamt is the operating and management costs related to the dam, O&Mirrt is the operating and management costs related to the irrigation structures, O&Mpowt is the operating and management costs related to the hydropower station, damcosrep34 is the replacement costs linked to the dam in year 34, powcosrep34 is the replacement costs linked to the hydropower station, and irrcosrep34 is the replacement costs linked to the irrigation network.
Note that alternative budgetary scenarios (e.g., a 30-year foreign loan at an interest rate of 1%, a 10-year grace period, a 0.5% commitment fee so that the local government pays 0.5% of the cost to prove their commitment to the project, and a 1% interest rate during construction) could be applied.
Solving the government budget constraint with respect to wp provides all couples (i.e., all possible solutions) of financial returns (fr) and water prices (wp) that characterize the project at the government level: an increasing and convex function wp(fr), where wpwp(fr) meets the government budget constraint. In particular, if CER credits are sold in international markets, wpwp(fr, CER), whereas if CER credits are not sold in international markets, wpwp(fr), with wp(fr) > wp(fr, CER) for each fr. In other words, wp (fr) − wp (fr, CER) depicts the extra water price to be charged to farmers to meet government budget constraints that result from unsold CER credits for each fr. Note that wp at AveIRR and wp at MinIRR measure the total economic value of water on average (AveEVW) and in the worst-case scenario (MinEVW), respectively. Indeed, wp at AveIRR and wp at MinIRR measure the economic value of the irrigation project as represented by IRR in terms of water price in the average and worst-case scenarios, respectively. In other words, the economic value of the irrigation project is expressed in terms of wp, rather than in terms of IRR, by referring to the government break-even point. See Carson et al. [52] and Ready et al. [53] for contingent valuation and hedonic pricing methodologies (respectively) applied to water evaluation. Note that these are not shadow prices, since they are not based on optimization.
In contrast, the maximum wp and the maximum loan rate (lr) that can be afforded by the representative farmer can be obtained by solving the following equation (i.e., their budget constraint) with respect to wp:
t=1 15 farbentO&Mfartwatuset × wp × farlanfarcost (1 + lr)t
where farbent is the farmer benefits at time t, O&Mfart is the operating and management costs related to farmers, watuset is the water use, farlan is the irrigated land per farmer, farcost is the farmer costs, and we assume 7176 m3 is the water consumed per ha (based on local data provided by the Ministry of Agriculture) and 8 ha is the average size of a farm for the target farmer (as described previously). Note that alternative budgetary scenarios (e.g., a 6-year loan-repayment period) can be applied.
Solving the farmer’s budget constraint equation with respect to wp provides all couples (i.e., all possible solutions) of loan rates (lr) and water prices (wp) that characterize the project at a farm level: a decreasing and concave function wp(lr), where wpwp(lr) meets the farmer’s budget constraint. Note that wp = wp(lr) means that farmers are assumed to be willing to renounce up to 100% of their increase in net income due to the irrigation project during the loan period, whereas wp < wp(lr) is consistent with the observation that the estimated annual value of water per hectare obtained by applying the contingent-valuation method (i.e., based on stated preferences; [54]) turned out to be about half of the estimate obtained using the hedonic price method (i.e., based on revealed preferences; [55]) in a nearby area.
Let us define fr*, lr*, and wp* as the financial return, loan rate, and water price at the intersection between wp(fr) and wp(lr). An irrigation scheme is financially feasible if the following conditions hold simultaneously:
wpwp(fr)
wpwp(lr)
Indeed, the water price charged to farmers must allow the government to break even (i.e., meet its budget constraint), although at a financial rate that could be smaller than the IRR, and the water price paid by farmers must allow each farmer to break even, although water and loan charges cannot be larger than the whole irrigation benefits during the loan period.
An irrigation scheme is socially sustainable if the following conditions hold simultaneously:
wp(lr) ≤ MinEVW
lrMinIRR
where MinIRR and MinEVW represent the reliable IRR and the reliable EVW, respectively. Indeed, the water price charged to farmers must be smaller than the water price consistent with MinEVW (otherwise, farmers would pay for benefits that accrue to other people), and the loan rate must be lower than the minimum IRR (otherwise, farmers would pay for inefficiencies of the project). In other words, one should look for solutions at lrlr*.
Within a graphical framework, the conditions for financial feasibility are measured by the area included between wp(lr) and wp(fr) for lrlr*; mathematically, this is represented by ∫0lr*[wp(fr) − wp(lr)] dfr. Moreover, conditions for social sustainability are measured by the area included between wp(lr) and MinIRR for lr > lr* and between wp(fr) and MinEVW for wp < wp*; mathematically, this is represented by ∫0lr*[MinEVWwp(lr)] dlr andwp0wp*[MinIRRwp(fr)] dwp, where wp0 = wp(fr) at fr = 0. Finally, the rectangular area identified by a water price wp in [0, MinEVW] and a loan rate lr in [0, MinIRR] identify all reliable solutions. Thus, it is possible to measure financial feasibility and social sustainability as percentages of all reliable economic solutions.

4.4. Innovative Features of the Suggested Framework

Table 6 summarizes the innovative features of the suggested framework in the form of a flow chart. Note that the suggested framework can highlight some decisional dilemmas: for example, supporting small farmers could increase adoption in terms of farmers (and in terms of land, if there are many small farmers) and social sustainability, but it might imply financial unfeasibility; by contrast, supporting large farmers could increase financial feasibility, but it might imply social unsustainability and a low adoption rate in terms of the number of farmers (although it could ensure a high adoption rate in terms of land area). Next, in contrast with structural and long-run determinants (i.e., which cannot be changed or affected, or can be changed only slightly; these include gender, age, tenancy status, and livestock activity), governmental agencies could use operational and short-run determinants (i.e., which can be changed or affected relatively easily; these include literacy status, membership in a cooperative, access to private credit, good markets, governmental information, and fair input and output prices) to increase adoption or mold adoption (e.g., to balance adoption rates between large and small farmers).
In summary, there are four key innovations of the suggested framework: First, it expresses economic values in terms of water prices to be used as constraints for determining the feasibility and sustainability of the project. Second, it measures the financial feasibility and social sustainability as percentages of all reliable economic solutions. Third, it clearly identifies the phases that require involvement by stakeholders (see the column in Table 6 on strategic decisions), where all crucial information to be discussed is summarized simply and intuitively. Fourth, econometric analysis, cost–benefit analysis, and financial analysis are linked together in a decision-making flow (see the arrows in Table 6), with each analysis relying on results from the previous analysis, with the potential to start over if the results are unfeasible, unsustainable, or both. In particular, if an irrigation project turns out to have a high predicted adoption rate but is financially unfeasible or socially unsustainable, one could change the definition of the target farmers, which would, in turn, change the design of the irrigation scheme, its costs and benefits, and other factors. Provided that these new target farmers are still consistent with the stated strategic objectives, the revised project can proceed; if not, the project should not be implemented, and funds should instead be invested in alternative irrigation projects or different projects.

5. Results

5.1. The Econometric Analysis

The small number of observations suggested that it was necessary to avoid variables that could split the sample (land tenancy and farm size), to eliminate from the analysis variables with a low range of variation (age and family size), and to eliminate from the analysis one of each pair of strongly correlated variables (the one with the smallest range of variation), such as based on the relationship of the dependency ratio with gross income, of cooperative membership with government information, and of farm size with gross income. In particular, I did not consider age, since it turned out to be insignificant: 59% of respondents were aged between 40 and 60. Moreover, the small sample size suggested that it was necessary to include all dummy variables as independent variables in order to increase the variability ([26]). Finally, to obtain a more robust estimate of the variance value, I applied the Huber–White sandwich estimator with the type of tenancy as the clustering variable (since tenancy characterizes farmers more significantly than their village of residence due to the agronomic homogeneity of the area) to allow observations that were not independent within clusters (although they must be independent between clusters).
The following variables turned out to be non-significant and were therefore excluded from the estimation: “water shortages in summer” is likely to be embodied in “water shortages in all seasons”, since 9% of farmers said they had enough water in the winter, versus 0% in the summer. “The most urgent problem” (39% access to markets, 41% access to additional water, and 20% access to credit) might be irrelevant because it was implicitly represented by other included variables (see Table 4). “The ability to predict trends for output and input prices” might be considered as a precondition for stating positive expectations. “The most important project’s potential” is likely to be irrelevant because 94% of farmers expressed a preference to change cultivation patterns rather than to expand the area of current crops (4%) or cultivate additional land (2%) (see Table 5).
The main insights can be summarized as follows (see Table 7). The irrigation project is more likely to be adopted (joined) by: poorer farmers (unlike in [12,16,17,19]), who rely more on agriculture than those who rely on livestock activities (like in [15,25]); farmers who have been informed or trained by governmental agencies (like in [14,18,24]), and who feel that they can obtain fair prices for outputs (like in [13]); literate farmers (like in [12,17]); farmers with positive expectations about the future; farmers who base their decisions on a maximization approach rather than on a habit approach. On the other hand, the irrigation project is less likely to be joined by farmers who feel that they obtain fair prices for inputs (like in [13,14]), who have direct access to product markets, and who have satisfactory access to the private credit (loans) market (similar to [12]). Thus, the irrigation project is appreciated most by poorer and economically weaker farmers. This is consistent with a given potential economic benefit per hectare being perceived to be smaller by larger farmers. In contrast, in an ex post econometric study of the potential factors that determine the adoption of irrigation, Namara et al. [56] showed that the largest proportion of micro-irrigation adopters belonged to the relatively wealthy group of farmers.
In particular, the probability of participation will be 0.9948 for an idealized “target” farmer who may not actually exist (Table 7). Moreover, the probability of acceptance is 0.9931 for a poorer and weaker farmer, who is typically characterized by an illiterate status, a habit approach to innovation, negative expectations about future prices, half the average income in the sample population, no access to fair input and output prices, no access to governmental information, no direct access to product markets, and no access to private credit. Finally, a richer and stronger farmer, characterized by the opposite of these characteristics, will show a probability of participation of 0.4658. Analogously, Harris [57] suggests that inter-sectional analysis (e.g., men vs. women, landless vs. landed) should be carried out in any study of water-related development transformations. In other words, decision-makers in Shahrazoor, Kurdistan, seem to be facing a decisional dilemma: they can propose a financially difficult irrigation scheme that serves the needs of poor farmers, with 99% of the farmers joining it, or a financially easy irrigation project that disregards equity issues, but with only 47% of farmers participating in it.
In the cost–benefit analysis in Section 5.2, I will focus on the poor farmers and disregard the rich farmers in order to maximize the probability of participation. Choosing this farmer group more than doubles the probability of participation.
Note that all effects have the expected signs according to the econometric literature, including the psychological independent variables (i.e., habit approach, maximization approach, perceived needs) and the policy independent variables (i.e., access to suitable information, literacy status, access to fair prices for outputs, expectations), but excluding gross income, access to fair prices for inputs, satisfactory access to bank loans, and direct access to output markets. This is likely to account for the oligopolistic power of richer farmers who would not be ready to adopt the project, in order to make it fail and maintain their economic and social status. In particular, the potential impacts on the participation probability relate to access to suitable information from governmental agencies, to access to good prices for outputs, to the farmer’s positive expectations about future trends for output and input prices, and to the farmer’s literacy status (Table 7). Thus, the existing governmental agencies can play a crucial role in project participation in the short-run by providing information and training, and by promoting access to fair output prices. Similarly, He et al. [49] showed that the credit obtained, the technical training received, and the assistance obtained all had significant positive effects on the adoption of rainwater harvesting and supplementary irrigation technologies. The government can therefore play a crucial role in diffusion of the project in the long run by improving expectations and by reducing illiteracy, which in turn could promote the use of a maximizing approach to innovation instead of a habit approach. In contrast, He et al. [49] showed that the risk preference had no significant influence on the adoption of rainwater harvesting and supplementary irrigation technologies.

5.2. The Cost–Benefit Analysis

Section 5.1 suggested a need to focus on the relatively poor and economically weak farmers. This section describes a cost–benefit analysis that focuses on this farmer group for estimating both the costs, since the irrigation scheme will be designed for small farms, and the benefits, since new cultivation patterns will be intended for small farms.
Thus, applying a standard cost–benefit analysis to the data presented in this section produces an internal rate of return (IRR) of 7.1% with benefits from hydropower, and 7.0% without benefits from hydropower. Wood et al. [58] performed a similar analysis in Australia.
Since the direct benefits from irrigation depend strongly on crop prices, and since the indirect benefits from irrigation were assumed to equal 10% of the direct benefits (Section 4.2), I performed a sensitivity analysis to account for a possible change of 20% for each combination of indirect benefits and crop prices. Table 8 summarizes the impacts of these changes on the estimated IRR. Note that I applied these large changes to account for possible impacts on prices at a local level; indeed, unless the government controls crop markets or fixes price caps, the increase in agricultural production due to the irrigation project is likely to significantly and unpredictably affect crop prices at a local level.
Thus, IRR is more sensitive to crop prices than to indirect benefits. In particular, changes in crop prices produce more than proportional changes in IRR, whereas the opposite occurs for changes in indirect benefits. In other words, a given percentage change in crop prices produces a larger percentage change in the IRR, whereas the same percentage change in indirect benefits produces a smaller percentage change in the IRR. Note that the potential initial or subsequent costs for training farmers are not estimated independently, but are instead included in the indirect benefits from irrigation (i.e., they represent local incomes). However, these costs are unlikely to affect IRR due to the tiny magnitude of these benefits in comparison with the overall investment and operating and management costs for the irrigation project.

5.3. The Financial Analysis

In Section 5.2, I estimated an IRR of 7.1% for the project on average, versus 4.6% in the worst-case scenario. This section will refer to these values as the mean and reliable socio-economic values, respectively.
Figure 2 depicts the main social, economic, and financial features of the Shahrazoor irrigation project at the government and farmer levels. The relationships between wp and fr from the government break-even budget with and without selling CER credits in the international market (i.e., by monetizing and not monetizing an indirect benefit of hydropower) are depicted by the lower increasing curve wp(fr, CER) and the higher increasing curve wp(fr), respectively. The relationships between wp and lr from the farmer’s break-even budget are represented by the decreasing curve wp(lr). The water prices consistent with a government break-even budget at the average IRR (i.e., 7.1%) and at the minimum IRR (i.e., 4.6%) are depicted by AveEVW = 0.92 USD/m3 and MinEVW = 0.66 USD/m3, respectively.
Figure 3 characterizes a hypothetical irrigation project with a lower EVW for a given wp(lr). For example, this may be due to a larger variability observed in the sensitivity analyses performed for other case studies: financial feasibility is then smaller, whereas the project is socially unsustainable, since wp is never smaller than MinEVW. Figure 4 characterizes a hypothetical irrigation project with a higher wp(fr, CER) due to a greater inability of the government to monetize the indirect economic benefits that are relevant in other case studies: the project is financially unfeasible because there are no wp values that meet both farmer and government budget constraints. Note that IRR − fr depicts the differences between economic and financial evaluations linked to indirect benefits from irrigation, whereas wp(fr) − wp(fr, CER) depicts the differences between economic and financial evaluations linked to indirect benefits from hydropower.
Figure 2 shows that the irrigation project in Shahrazoor is feasible and sustainable if wp is between 0.32 and 0.57 USD/m3, the loan rate is smaller than 3.0%, and it is not necessary to sell CER credits in international markets. On this basis, all financially feasible scenarios are socially sustainable, with 13.6% of all reliable economic solutions financially feasible and 35.8% socially sustainable. Indeed, the area including all couples of IRR ≤ MinIRR and wpwp(MinIRR, CER) represents the economic value of the irrigation project, whether in IRR terms or in wp terms or both, whereas the area including all couples of IRR and wp within the curves wp(fr) and wp(lr) represents the financial feasibility of the irrigation project; as a result, the ratio between these areas depicts the extent to which the project is financially feasible. Similar reasoning applies to the ratio of the area representing social sustainability (i.e., wp(lr) ≤ MinEVW, lrMinIRR) to the area representing the economic value of the irrigation project (i.e., IRR ≤ MinIRR and wpwp(MinIRR, CER)). Note that the government could accept a financial return smaller than the MinIRR if social benefits (e.g., a smaller degree of income inequality, reduced conflict among farmers) are expected but not included in the present estimates.

5.4. Application of the Suggested Framework to the Kurdistan Case Study

Table 9 summarizes the results of the Iraqi case study within the framework of the flow chart introduced in Table 6. Note that targeting poor and small farmers produced a decisional dilemma: project managers can achieve 99% expected adoption by small farmers combined with an acceptable financial feasibility (at a calculated 13.6%) or 47% expected adoption by large farmers combined with a good financial feasibility (at an assumed 100%). As is the case in many developing countries, Kurdistan has many farmers with small farms; targeting these poor and small farmers will reduce income inequality and increase total income in the area.

6. Discussion

To reduce the frequency of decisions to reject an innovation as a result of dissatisfaction with its performance, an ex ante study by Karami [59] suggested using the analytical hierarchy process (AHP) with a panel of experts to help four homogenous target groups of farmers (i.e., small farm and young farmer, small farm and old farmer, medium farm, and large farm) make a rational decision when adopting three new irrigation methods (i.e., border, basin, sprinkler). This was based on applying cluster analysis using 11 variables (i.e., future plans, contact with information sources, attitude towards water-saving technologies, knowledge of irrigation methods, level of farm technology, education, farm size, land slope, land fragmentation, loan obtained, soil texture). Karami’s comparison of actual decisions by farmers regarding the adoption of irrigation methods in four Iranian provinces, using the AHP results to appraise the appropriateness of their decisions regarding the choice of irrigation method, revealed that 74% of the farmers made an appropriate decision (16% by adopting and 58% by not adopting sprinkler irrigation), but the remaining 26% made an inappropriate decision (14% by adopting and 12% by not adopting sprinkler irrigation). In particular, the appropriateness of the decision was explained better by farm size than by irrigation method; 100% appropriate adoption was only estimated for large farms.
Karami’s [59] analysis has some features in common with the present study. His decision appropriateness is similar to the present financial feasibility results at the farmer level, and his expert assessments about decision appropriateness are similar to the present financial analysis at the farmer level, but the approaches and insights are different. In particular, Karami [59] looked for target groups of farmers for a given irrigation method by suggesting sprinkler irrigation for large farms. In contrast, I designed the irrigation scheme (i.e., for a target farm size of 8 ha) and I identified the economic incentives (i.e., water prices and loan rates) to increase adoption of the project among poor and weaker farmers (i.e., adoption success was measured in terms of the number of farmers rather than the total area). I also considered the social feasibility (i.e., costs not charged to farmers) and the social sustainability (i.e., benefits that accrue to non-farmers) of the irrigation project. In short, by departing from a long history of irrigation projects in which wealthy farmers become richer and poor farmers receive fewer financial benefits, the present study shows that the irrigation scheme could be tailored to the needs of poor farmers, thereby increasing participation and decreasing income inequality ([60]). In addition, wealthy farmers are likely to join the irrigation project once it has been built ([61]).
In the present paper, significant results were obtained despite relying on a relatively small sample of farmers. The approach combines the main contributions of economists and sociologists by using variables that measure limitations on the available information and thought processes as well as variables that describe the institutional contexts, and by using variables that measure farmer perceptions of irrigation schemes and communication frameworks. In Shahrazoor, if the irrigation project is tailored to the needs of poorer and economically weaker farmers, it turns out to be socially sustainable and financially feasible.
Although I considered a range of potential economic and social determinants of adoption of the project in the present study, I disregarded some important aspects that might be relevant in alternative contexts, as Weick and Walchli [62] have discussed. Torkamani and Shajari [63] showed that farmer-specific relative risk premiums have a positive and significant effect on the decision to adopt new irrigation technologies. Governmental agencies should stress the biological benefits of moving away from outdated and inefficient agricultural management practices (see also [64]). Ersado et al. [65] also showed that the number of days of illness and the opportunity costs that arise from caring for sick family members are significant factors in the adoption of land-enhancing technologies such as irrigation. Governmental agencies should therefore not disregard indicators of well-being when they estimate the potential for successful adoption of a project.
In addition, I did not consider the complexity of the innovation, together with issues of knowledge transfer, with respect to the ability of farmers to understand and use the technology, nor did I consider opportunities for farmers to observe the technology and discuss it with other farmers ([42]). Governmental agencies should therefore organize training courses to explain all the technical details so that farmers can best exploit the innovation (e.g., [66]), by taking into account the costs of administering this training and monitoring its effectiveness. I also disregarded the environmental sustainability of the new cultivation patterns, which is clearly an important criterion ([26,27,47]). Governmental agencies should therefore evaluate the potential impacts of the alternative cultivation patterns by means of agronomic and ecological studies. Lastly, I did not consider problems associated with the viability and longevity of irrigation projects. Governmental agencies should therefore develop or promote the development of management institutions, including guidelines and rules, to solve the collective-action dilemma; should organize training courses to improve irrigation management, thereby ensuring that the project remains viable; and should budget for repairs and replacement right from the start, thereby ensuring that the project has longevity ([67,68,69]).

7. Conclusions

In the present study, I tackled common assessment issues in agricultural policy programs, in general, and technological interventions in agriculture, in particular. The analyzed project was characterized by both economic and financial characteristics and by both direct and indirect aspects. For the irrigation scheme, direct effects on agricultural production (which are relatively difficult to monetize) and indirect effects on flood control and water quality (which are difficult to monetize) must be estimated. For the hydropower station, direct effects on energy selling (easy to monetize) and indirect effects on eliminated emissions CO2 (relatively easy to monetize) must be evaluated.
Combining the econometric, cost–benefit, and financial analyses in the framework described in this paper supports the view that the participation in and success of irrigation projects could be significantly enhanced by accounting for the characteristics of those who will be affected by the project and those who can potentially benefit from irrigation schemes. In Shahrazoor, the current socio-economic factors (i.e., gross income, access to fair input prices, satisfactory access to bank loans, and direct access to output markets) and expected socio-economic factors (i.e., access to fair output prices) reduce the probability of acceptance to a greater extent than current psycho-cultural factors (i.e., literacy status) and expected psycho-cultural factors (i.e., a habit approach rather than a maximization approach to innovation, positive expectations about prices), with the former factors possibly correlated with the latter factors.
In particular, as in other ex ante econometric studies of the potential factors that determine participation in the project, providing farmers with suitable information in the short run and a suitable education in the long run will also increase diffusion of the project (in the present study, by around 94% and 0.2%, respectively). Unlike other ex ante econometric studies, the present study highlighted the fact that the probability of acceptance can be maximized by identifying the target farmers (here, poorer and economically weaker farmers devoted more to agricultural than to livestock activities) and by specifying the maximum water prices and loan interest rates (i.e., prices and rates in the case in which the whole additional income from irrigation is used to pay for water or to repay loans) by means of cost–benefit and financial analysis for these farmers (less than 0.57 USD/m3 and 3.0%, respectively) to the largest possible extent (by around 99% in the present study). To a smaller extent, psycho-cultural aspects (e.g., whether farmers adopt a habit approach or a maximization approach to innovation) could hamper the project diffusion (by around 0.3% in the present study).
Combining social, economic, and financial features in a single framework, as described in this paper, supports the view that both financial feasibility and social sustainability of irrigation projects could be significantly enhanced by focusing on economic benefits that are difficult to monetize and on financial costs that must be charged to the general population. In Shahrazoor, 13.6% of the reliable economic solutions were financially feasible and 35.8% were socially sustainable. In particular, the equilibrium water price (i.e., 0.53 USD/m3) charged to farmers was around 57% (i.e., 0.53/0.92) of the economic value of water (the equilibrium water price divided by the average economic value of water), whereas the financial return missed by the general population (the interest rate divided by the internal rate of return) was around 42% (i.e., 3.0/7.1).

Acknowledgments

I thank Waleed Abdul Alhimeed for his support in performing the field survey.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Additional quantitative variables used to describe the survey population (1 USD = 1250 Iraqi Dinar).
Table A1. Additional quantitative variables used to describe the survey population (1 USD = 1250 Iraqi Dinar).
Quantitative VariableMeanTotalStandard Deviation
Area of rain-fed irrigation (ha)11.12511.2570.62
Irrigated area (ha)0.7936.504.87
Children and elderly family members (number)2.391101.45
Percent increase in output prices perceived to be fair33.335.77
Percent decrease in input prices perceived to be fair37.507.83
Wheat area (ha)2.3498.135.53
Wheat yield (kg/ha)75.307.72
Wheat price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)382.7415.11
Barley area (ha)2.1382.885.55
Barley yield (kg/ha)61.2214.26
Barley price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)257.0516.17
Chick pea area (ha)1.6119.253.82
Chick pea yield (kg/ha)63.5456.09
Chick pea price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)258.33153.75
Sunflower area (ha)1.0510.504.39
Sunflower yield (kg/ha)72.502020.11
Sunflower price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)225.0091.42
Watermelon area (ha)0.9611.501.63
Watermelon yield (kg/ha)704.171822.04
Watermelon price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)119.58110.77
Melon area (ha)1.566.250.54
Melon yield (kg/ha)956.25111.80
Melon price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)70.0044.72
Cucumber area (ha)0.333.000.50
Cucumber yield (kg/ha)175.00150.00
Cucumber price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)255.5616.67
Artichoke area (ha)1.001.000
Artichoke yield (kg/ha)75.000
Artichoke price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)2500
Bean area (ha)0.750.750
Bean yield (kg/ha)37.500
Bean price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)3000
Tomato area (ha)0.301.500.45
Tomato yield (kg/ha)150.00223.61
Tomato price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)11022.36
Okra area (ha)0.250.500
Okra yield (kg/ha)125.000
Okra price (Iraqi Dinar/kg)4000
Number of sheep33.60144566.23
Percent of sheep herd sold per year230.07
Number of cows1.53663.34
Cow milk and yoghurt production (kg per cow per day)2.880.30
Number of goats2.6911624.30
Percent of goat herd sold per year400.20
Table A2. Additional qualitative variables from the survey.
Table A2. Additional qualitative variables from the survey.
Qualitative VariableProportion of Respondents (%)
Education levelIlliteratePrimarySecondary
434611
Access to informationNoneGovernmental agenciesCooperativesOther farmers
98524
Access to loansNoneBanksCooperativesOther farmersOther sources
1111541113
Types of fertilizerOrganicMineralBoth
06337
Reasons for choosing these fertilizersI have always done thisThey are very effectiveI know how to use themOther farmers suggested them to meGovernmental agencies suggested them to me
3070000
Reasons for choosing these cropsI have always done thisThey show a high profitabilityI know how to grow themOther farmers suggested them to meThere is no choice
6162031
Proportion (%) of respondents who felt that their fertilizer costs were:Very highHighFair
83152
Proportion (%) of respondents who felt that their labor costs were:Very highHighFair
57394
Proportion (%) of respondents who felt that their pesticide costs were:Very highHighFair
24706
Use of agricultural equipmentYesNo
8911
Product buyersCooperativeMarketLocal tradersOther
752410
Reason for choosing these buyersI have always done thisIt offers a better priceI know the market channelOther farmers suggested the buyer to meThere is no choice
63170020
Evaluation of output pricesGoodFairUnfair
373924
Trend of output prices in the pastIncreasingStableDecreasing
65350
Expectation about future output pricesIncreasingStableDecreasingI do not know
4341016
Perception of input pricesGoodFairUnfair
94150
Evaluation of past input pricesIncreasingStableDecreasing
50500
Expectation about future input pricesIncreasingStableDecreasingI do not know
3733030
Proportion (%) of respondents who felt that subsidies on revenues were:Very highHighFair
96724
Proportion (%) of respondents who felt that transportation costs on revenues were:Very highHighFair
59410
Enough water in winterYesJust barely enoughNo
93952
Enough water in summerYesJust enoughNo
01783
Source of waterPumped from a wellPumped from the riverI have a personal reservoirI am connected to an existing canalOthers
2203363
Irrigation methodNo irrigation/rain-fedFurrow/surfaceSprinklerPivotDrip
66171700
Reason for using this irrigation methodI have always used itIt is efficientI know how to use itOther farmers suggested this method to meGovernmental agencies suggested this method to me
964000
Knowledge of alternative irrigation methodsYesNo
1387
Willingness to adopt new irrigation methodsYesNo
982
If no, specify which conditions applyThere is no need to change traditional methodsI have no access to the required informationI have no access to the required loansIt is not applied by other farmers
0020
If yes, specify which conditions applyI already have access to the required informationI already have access to the necessary money
1385

Appendix B

Table A3. The suggested cultivation patterns, yields, and prices for winter crops.
Table A3. The suggested cultivation patterns, yields, and prices for winter crops.
Winter CropIntensity (% of Total Cultivated Area)Yield (t/ha)Price (Dinar/kg)
Winter vegetables a530515
Green manure (with supplemental irrigation.)700
Persian clover4600
Barley-vetch (with supplemental irrigation)4.520244
Barley-vetch (non-irrigated)8.512244
Lentils12245
Broad bean12285
Winter–spring vegetables a518551
Wheat (with supplemental irrigation.)74364
Wheat (non-irrigated)72364
Note: a Winter vegetables refer to cabbage, turnip, red beet, radish, carrot, and parsley; winter–spring vegetables refer to onion, parsley, radish, carrot, and red beet.
Table A4. The suggested cultivation patterns, yields, and prices for summer crops.
Table A4. The suggested cultivation patterns, yields, and prices for summer crops.
Summer CropIntensity (% of Total Cultivated Area)Yield (t/ha)Price (Dinar/kg)
Chick pea42245
Spring barley104244
Sorghum55214
Summer vegetables a15251093
Cow-pea (lobia)102451
Maize860
Sunflower63214
Maize for fodder5600
Autumn vegetables a5181330
Note: a Summer vegetables refer to tomato, watermelon, cucumber, okra, eggplant, sweet and hot peppers, melon, and green beans; autumn vegetables refer to cauliflower, garlic, lettuce, beans, and peas.
Table A5. The suggested cultivation patterns, yields, and prices suggested by agronomists for perennial crops.
Table A5. The suggested cultivation patterns, yields, and prices suggested by agronomists for perennial crops.
Perennial CropsIntensity (% of Total Cultivated Area)Yield (t/ha)Price (Dinar/kg)
Apricot1.6201425
Peach3.2201900
Plum2.915950
Pear1.920713
Almond0.811900
Pistachio1.138550
Vineyard (table grape)3.671188
Olive0.98475
Alfalfa135285
Table A6. Investment costs (USD) (at 1 USD = 1250 Iraqi Dinar).
Table A6. Investment costs (USD) (at 1 USD = 1250 Iraqi Dinar).
Year 1Year 2Year 3Year 4Total
Dam costs91,500,000153,245,00058,075,0006,439,000309,259,000
Hydropower costs50,0008,828,5008,878,500
Irrigation costs18,727,39024,684,00812,151,961242,00055,805,359
On-farm infrastructure costs (per farmer)10,00010,000
Environmental measures4,815,0002,000,0002,000,000815,000
Table A7. Replacement costs (USD).
Table A7. Replacement costs (USD).
Dam replacement costsIn Year 343,080,000
Hydropower station replacement costsIn Year 344,941,000
Irrigation project replacement costsIn Year 3414,140,841
On-farm infrastructure replacement costsIn Year 3410,000
Table A8. Operating, maintenance and management (O&M) costs (USD).
Table A8. Operating, maintenance and management (O&M) costs (USD).
O&M costs for damFrom Year 5 To Year 543,154,190
O&M costs for hydropower stationFrom Year 5 To Year 54144,910
O&M costs for irrigation projectFrom Year 5 To Year 541,305,434
O&M costs for on farm (per farmer)From Year 5 To Year 54400

References

  1. Benouniche, M.; Errahj, M.; Kuper, M. The seductive power of an innovation: Enrolling non-conventional actors in a drip irrigation community in Morocco. J. Agric. Educ. Ext. 2016, 22, 61–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Kraaijvanger, R.; Sonneveld, M.; Almekinders, C.; Veldkamp, T. Comparison of methods to identify crop productivity constraints in developing countries: A review. Agron. Sustain. Dev. 2015, 35, 625–637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Mutsotso, B.; Muya, E.; Roimen, H. Farmers knowledge, attitudes and practices (KAP) in Embu and Taita benchmark sites and after below-ground biodiversity project interventions. Trop. Subtrop. Agroecosyst. 2011, 3, 51–58. [Google Scholar]
  4. Beyene, A.D.; Kassie, M. Speed of adoption of improved maize varieties in Tanzania: An application of duration analysis. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2015, 96, 298–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Franco, J.A.; Calatrava, J. The diffusion process of no-tillage with herbicides application in Southern Spain’s olive groves. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2012, 55, 979–1003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Khanal, N.P.; Maharjan, K.L. Socio-economic factors influencing the adoption of soil conservation practices under rice-wheat system in the Tarai region of Nepal. Int. J. Soc. Sustain. Econ. Soc. Cult. Context 2014, 9, 27–39. [Google Scholar]
  7. Legesse, G.; Siegmund-Schultze, M.; Abebe, G.; Valle Zárate, A. Determinants of the adoption of small ruminant related technologies in the highlands of Ethiopia. Trop. Subtrop. Agroecosyst. 2013, 16, 13–23. [Google Scholar]
  8. Mariano, M.J.; Villano, R.; Fleming, E. Factors influencing farmers’ adoption of modern rice technologies and good management practices in the Philippines. Agric. Syst. 2012, 110, 41–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Mottaleb, K.A.; Mohanty, S.; Nelson, A. Factors influencing hybrid rice adoption: A Bangladesh case. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2015, 59, 258–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Posthumus, H.; Gardebroek, C.; Ruben, R. From participation to adoption: Comparing the effectiveness of soil conservation programs in the Peruvian Andes. Land Econ. 2010, 86, 645–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Takahashi, K. The roles of risk and ambiguity in the adoption of the system of rice intensification (SRI): Evidence from Indonesia. Food Secur. 2013, 5, 513–524. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Ali, A.; Behera, B. Factors influencing farmers’ adoption of energy-based water pumps and impacts on crop productivity and household income in Pakistan. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 54, 48–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Cremades, R.; Wang, J.; Morris, J. Policies, economic incentives and the adoption of modern irrigation technology in China. Earth Syst. Dyn. 2015, 6, 399–410. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Dai, X.; Chen, J.; Chen, D.; Han, Y. Factors affecting adoption of agricultural water-saving technologies in Heilongjang Province, China. Water Policy 2015, 17, 581–594. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Jara-Rojas, R.; Bravo-Ureta, B.E.; Díaz, J. Adoption of water conservation practices: A socioeconomic analysis of small-scale farmers in Central Chile. Agric. Syst. 2012, 110, 54–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Kamwamba-Mtethiwa, J.; Namara, R.; De Fraiture, C.; Mangisoni, J.; Owusu, E. Treadle pump irrigation in Malawi: Adoption, gender and benefits. Irrig. Drain. 2012, 61, 583–595. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Singh, P.K.; Patel, S.K.; Trivedi, M.M.; Patel, G.R. Assessing the relative impacts of the factors affecting MIS adoption process. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. World Ecol. 2015, 22, 213–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Wang, J.; Klein, K.K.; Bjornlund, H.; Zhang, L.; Zhang, W. Adoption of improved irrigation scheduling methods in Alberta: An empirical analysis. Can. Water Resour. J. 2015, 40, 47–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Zeweld, W.; Huylenbroeck, G.V.; Hidgot, A.; Chandrakanth, M.G.; Speelman, S. Adoption of small-scale irrigation and its livelihood impacts in Northern Ethiopia. Irrig. Drain. 2015, 64, 655–668. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Batz, F.J.; Janssen, W.; Peters, K.J. Predicting technology adoption to improve research priority-setting. Agric. Econ. 2003, 28, 151–163. [Google Scholar]
  21. Bekele, W. Analysis of farmers’ preferences for development intervention programs: A case study of subsistence farmers from East Ethiopian highlands. Afr. Dev. Rev. 2006, 18, 183–204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Kondoh, K.; Jussaume, R.A. Contextualising farmers’ attitudes towards genetically modified crops. Agric. Hum. Values 2006, 23, 341–352. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Jaek, M.; Lifran, R. Farmers’ preferences for production practices: A choice experiment study in the Rhone River Delta. J. Agric. Econ. 2014, 65, 112–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Genius, M.; Koundouri, P.; Nauges, C.; Tzouvelekas, V. Information transmission in irrigation technology adoption and diffusion: Social learning, extension services, and spatial effect. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2014, 96, 328–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Oostendorp, R.H.; Zaal, F. Land acquisition and the adoption of soil and water conservation techniques: A duration analysis for Kenia and the Philippines. World Dev. 2012, 40, 1240–1254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Burton, M.P.; Rigby, D.; Young, T. Modeling the adoption of organic horticultural technology in the UK using duration analysis. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2003, 47, 29–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Fuglie, K.O.; Kascak, C.A. Adoption and diffusion of natural-resource-conserving agricultural technology. Rev. Agric. Econ. 2006, 23, 386–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Adesina, A.A.; Chianu, J. Determinants of farmers’ adoption and adaptation of alley farming technology in Nigeria. Agrofor. Syst. 2002, 55, 88–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Swinton, S.M. Capturing household-level spatial influence in agricultural management using random effects regression. Agric. Econ. 2002, 27, 371–381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Abdulai, A.; Huffman, W.E. The diffusion of new agricultural technologies: The case of crossbred-cow technology in Tanzania. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2005, 87, 645–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. De Souza Filho, H.M.; Young, T.; Burton, M.P. Factors influencing the adoption of sustainable agricultural technologies: Evidence from the State of Espirito Santo, Brazil. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 1999, 60, 97–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Baerenklau, K.A.; Knapp, K.C. Dynamics of agricultural technology adoption: Age structure, reversibility, and uncertainty. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2007, 89, 190–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Alcon, F.; De Miguel, M.D.; Burton, M. Duration analysis of adoption of drip irrigation technology in southeastern Spain. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2011, 78, 991–1001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Pardey, P.G.; Alston, J.M.; Ruttan, V.W. The economics of innovation and technical change in agriculture. In Handbook of the Economics of Innovation; Elsevier (North Holland Publishing Co.): Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2010; pp. 939–984. [Google Scholar]
  35. Soule, M.J.; Tegene, A.; Wiebe, K.D. Land tenure and the adoption of conservation practices. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2000, 82, 993–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Dillon, A. Do differences in the scale of irrigation projects generate different impacts on poverty and production? J. Agric. Econ. 2010, 62, 474–492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Wale, E.; Yalew, A. Farmers’ variety attribute preferences: Implications for breeding priority setting and agricultural extension policy in Ethiopia. Afr. Dev. Rev. 2007, 19, 379–396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Moser, C.M.; Barrett, C.B. The complex dynamics of smallholder technology adoption: The case of SRI in Madagascar. Agric. Econ. 2006, 35, 373–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. UNDP. Drought: Impact Assessment, Recovery and Mitigation Framework and Regional Project Design in Kurdistan Region (KR); United Nations Development Programme Iraq: Baghdad, Iraq, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  40. Kurdistan Region. Winter and Summer Reports on Agriculture Production in the Kurdistan Region 2011; Iraq Ministry of Agriculture: Baghdad, Iraq, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  41. Dimara, E.; Skuras, D. Adoption of agricultural innovations as a two-stage partial observability process. Agric. Econ. 2003, 28, 187–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Udoh, E.J.; Kormawa, P.M. Determinants for cassava production expansion in the semi-arid zone of West Africa. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2009, 2, 345–357. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Adegbola, P.; Gardebroek, C. The effect of information sources on technology adoption and modification decisions. Agric. Econ. 2007, 37, 55–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Rajasekharan, P.; Veeraputhran, S. Adoption of intercropping in rubber small-holdings in Kerala, India: A Tobit analysis. Agrofor. Syst. 2002, 56, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Koundouri, P.; Nauges, C.; Tzouvelekas, V. Technology adoption under production uncertainty: Theory and application to irrigation technology. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2006, 88, 657–670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Zhang, X.; Fan, S.; Cai, X. The path of technology diffusion: Which neighbors to learn from? Contemp. Econ. Policy 2002, 20, 470–478. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Dadi, L.; Burton, M.; Ozanne, A. Duration analysis of technological adoption in Ethiopian agriculture. J. Agric. Econ. 2004, 55, 613–631. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Barham, B.L.; Foltz, J.D.; Jackson-Smith, D.; Moon, S. The dynamics of agricultural biotechnology adoption: Lessons from rBST use in Wisconsin, 1994–2001. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2004, 86, 61–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. He, X.F.; Cao, H.; Li, F.M. Econometric analysis of the determinants of adoption of rainwater harvesting and supplementary irrigation technology (RHSIT) in the semi-arid Loess Plateau of China. Agric. Water Manag. 2007, 89, 243–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Moreno, G.; Sunding, D.L. Joint estimation of technology adoption and land allocation with implications for the design of conservation policy. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2005, 87, 1009–1019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Useche, P.; Barham, B.L.; Foltz, J.D. Integrating technology traits and producer heterogeneity: A mixed-multinomial model of genetically modified corn adoption. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2009, 91, 444–461. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Carson, R.T.; Flores, N.E.; Martin, K.M.; Wright, J.L. Contingent valuation and revealed preference methodologies: Comparing the estimates for quasi-public goods. Land Econ. 1996, 72, 80–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Ready, R.; Berger, M.C.; Blomquist, G.C. Measuring amenity benefits from farmland: Hedonic pricing vs. contingent valuation. Growth Chang. 1997, 28, 438–458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Mallios, Z.; Latinopoulos, P. Willingness to pay for irrigation water: A case study in Chalkidiki, Greece. In Proceedings of the 7th International Conference on Environmental Science and Technology, Ermoupolis, Greece, 9 September 2001; pp. 566–573. [Google Scholar]
  55. Latinopoulos, P.; Tziakas, V.; Mallios, Z. Valuation of irrigation water by the hedonic price method: A case study in Chalkidiki, Greece. Water Air Soil Pollut. Focus 2004, 4, 253–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Namara, R.E.; Nagar, R.K.; Upadhyay, B. Economics, adoption determinants, and impacts of micro-irrigation technologies: Empirical results from India. Irrig. Sci. 2007, 25, 283–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Harris, L.M. Water rich, resource poor: Intersections of gender, poverty, and vulnerability in newly irrigated areas of southeastern Turkey. World Dev. 2008, 36, 2643–2662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Wood, M.; Wang, Q.J.; Bethune, M. An economic analysis of conservation from border-check to center pivot irrigation on dairy farms in the Murray Dairy Region, Australia. Irrig. Sci. 2007, 26, 9–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Karami, E. Appropriateness of farmers’ adoption of irrigation methods: The application of the AHP model. Agric. Syst. 2006, 87, 101–119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Van Den Berg, M.; Ruben, R. Small-scale irrigation and income distribution in Ethiopia. J. Dev. Stud. 2006, 42, 868–880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Namara, R.E.; Hanjra, M.A.; Castillo, G.E.; Ravnborg, H.M.; Smith, L.; Van Koppen, B. Agricultural water management and poverty linkages. Agric. Water Manag. 2010, 97, 520–527. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Weick, C.W.; Walchli, S.B. Genetically engineered crops and foods: Back to basics of technology diffusion. Technol. Soc. 2002, 24, 265–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Torkamani, J.; Shajari, S. Adoption of new irrigation technology under production risk. Water Resour. Manag. 2008, 2, 229–237. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Carey, J.M.; Zilberman, D. A model of investment under uncertainty: Modern irrigation technology and emerging markets in water. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2002, 84, 171–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Ersado, L.; Amacher, G.; Alwang, J. Productivity and land enhancing technologies in Northern Ethiopia: Health, public investments, and sequential adoption. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2004, 86, 321–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Coughenour, C.M. Innovating conservation agriculture: The case of no-till cropping. Rural Sociol. 2003, 68, 278–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Lam, W.F. Institutional design of public agencies and coproduction: A study of irrigation associations in Taiwan. World Dev. 1996, 24, 1039–1054. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Meinzen-Dick, R. Farmer participation in irrigation—20 years of experience and lessons for the future. Irrig. Drain. Syst. 1997, 11, 103–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Meinzen-Dick, R. Beyond panaceas in water institutions. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2007, 104, 15200–15205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Figure 1. Location of the project area.
Figure 1. Location of the project area.
Water 09 00821 g001
Figure 2. Characterization of a socially sustainable and financially feasible irrigation project. Financial feasibility exists for 13.6% of the reliable economic solutions, versus 35.8% for social sustainability. Black, unreliable solutions, infeasible for farmers and the government; grey, unreliable solutions, feasible for farmers but not for the government; red, infeasible for farmers and for the government; yellow, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; blue, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government without selling CER credits; light red, feasible for farmers but not for the government; light yellow, feasible for farmers and feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; light blue, feasible for farmers and for the government without selling CER credits.
Figure 2. Characterization of a socially sustainable and financially feasible irrigation project. Financial feasibility exists for 13.6% of the reliable economic solutions, versus 35.8% for social sustainability. Black, unreliable solutions, infeasible for farmers and the government; grey, unreliable solutions, feasible for farmers but not for the government; red, infeasible for farmers and for the government; yellow, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; blue, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government without selling CER credits; light red, feasible for farmers but not for the government; light yellow, feasible for farmers and feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; light blue, feasible for farmers and for the government without selling CER credits.
Water 09 00821 g002
Figure 3. Characterization of a financially feasible but socially unsustainable irrigation project. Financial feasibility exists for 13.3% of the reliable economic solutions but no solution is socially sustainable. Black, unreliable solutions, infeasible for farmers and the government; grey, unreliable solutions, feasible for farmers but not for the government; light red, feasible for farmers but not for the government; light yellow, feasible for farmers and feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; light blue, feasible for farmers and for the government without selling CER credits.
Figure 3. Characterization of a financially feasible but socially unsustainable irrigation project. Financial feasibility exists for 13.3% of the reliable economic solutions but no solution is socially sustainable. Black, unreliable solutions, infeasible for farmers and the government; grey, unreliable solutions, feasible for farmers but not for the government; light red, feasible for farmers but not for the government; light yellow, feasible for farmers and feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; light blue, feasible for farmers and for the government without selling CER credits.
Water 09 00821 g003
Figure 4. Characterization of a financially infeasible irrigation project. Financial feasibility and social sustainability account for 0% of the reliable economic solutions. Black, unreliable solutions, infeasible for farmers and for the government; grey, unreliable solutions, feasible for farmers but not for the government; red, infeasible for farmers and the government; yellow, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; blue, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government without selling CER credits; light red, feasible for farmers but not for the government; yellow, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; light yellow, feasible for farmers and feasible for the government if it sells CER credits.
Figure 4. Characterization of a financially infeasible irrigation project. Financial feasibility and social sustainability account for 0% of the reliable economic solutions. Black, unreliable solutions, infeasible for farmers and for the government; grey, unreliable solutions, feasible for farmers but not for the government; red, infeasible for farmers and the government; yellow, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; blue, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government without selling CER credits; light red, feasible for farmers but not for the government; yellow, infeasible for farmers but feasible for the government if it sells CER credits; light yellow, feasible for farmers and feasible for the government if it sells CER credits.
Water 09 00821 g004
Table 1. Independent variables used in the literature. Boldfaced items in the list of variables are associated with boldfaced X’s in the body of the table. FF, farmer features; EF, economic factors; FC, farm characteristics; IF, institutional factors; FP, farmer perceptions; TF, technology features.
Table 1. Independent variables used in the literature. Boldfaced items in the list of variables are associated with boldfaced X’s in the body of the table. FF, farmer features; EF, economic factors; FC, farm characteristics; IF, institutional factors; FP, farmer perceptions; TF, technology features.
Independent VariableF&K (2006)BAeA (2003)BUeA (2003)A&C (2002)A&H (2005)DeA (1999)K&J (2006)B&K (2007)B (2006)SeA (2000)D (2010)W&Y (2007)M&B (2006)
FFFarmer ageX X X
Farmer gender X
Farmer origins X
Farmer education level/literacy statusX X X X
EFGross income X
Per capita economic consumption X
FCFarm size X X
Land tenancy X
Land quality/Soil erosionX X X
Stated yields of the main cropsX
Livestock income (proportion of total) X
Family labor/Family size X
IFMarket access/Market strategies X X
Distance from urban centers X
Information from other farmers X X X X
Membership in a cooperative X XX X
Credit access X X
Extension contacts XXX X
FPDeclining output prices X X
Increasing input prices X X
Health or environmental impacts X X
Rankings of agricultural problems X
TFInvestment size X
Technology risk X X
Technology complexity X
Technology age X
Notes: A&C (2002), [28]; A&H (2005), [30]; B (2006), [21]; B&K (2007), [32]; BAeA (2003), [20]; BUeA (2003), [26]; DeA (1999), [31]; F&K (2006), [27]; K&J (2006), [22]; SeA (2000), [35]; D (2010), [36]; W&Y (2007), [37]; M&B (2006), [38].
Table 2. The revised survey population, stratified according to the actual types of tenancy and farm sizes determined by the survey.
Table 2. The revised survey population, stratified according to the actual types of tenancy and farm sizes determined by the survey.
Type of TenancyFarm Size (ha)
<55–10>10Total
Owner99
Share-cropper11
Tenant1614636
Total16151546
Table 3. Prioritization of issues by the farmers. Priority 1 is more important than 2, which is more important than 3, and so on.
Table 3. Prioritization of issues by the farmers. Priority 1 is more important than 2, which is more important than 3, and so on.
PriorityAccess to (Percent of Responses in Each Ranked Priority)
Alternative Agricultural MethodsMarketsAdditional WaterCredit (Loans)Information
103941200
2132846112
3371513350
4481502413
52201185
Table 4. Ranking of project potentials by the farmers. Potential 1 is more important than 2, which is more important than 3, and so on.
Table 4. Ranking of project potentials by the farmers. Potential 1 is more important than 2, which is more important than 3, and so on.
PotentialMost important potential (Percent of Responses for Each Ranked Potential)
Changing Crop PatternExpanding Current CropsCultivating Additional Land
19442
247620
322078
Table 5. Statistics of quantitative independent variables: * indicates a dummy variable, 1 means yes. EE, expected effects on adoption (+ = increase, − = decrease), according to the econometric literature.
Table 5. Statistics of quantitative independent variables: * indicates a dummy variable, 1 means yes. EE, expected effects on adoption (+ = increase, − = decrease), according to the econometric literature.
Quantitative independent variableMeanSt. Dev.Max.Min.EE
Gross income (×106 Iraqi Dinars)6.237.5340.930.45+
Farm size (ha)12.0776.861251.50+
Farmer age50.6513.568025
Family size7.072.92151+
Dependency ratio (proportion of young (≤14) and old (≥65) family members)0.330.2010
Direct access to output markets *0.070.2510+
Access to fair prices for outputs *0.390.4910+
Access to fair prices for inputs *0.410.5010+
Satisfactory access to bank loans *0.110.3110+
Income from livestock activity greater than 50% of the total *0.500.5110
Literacy status *0.570.5010+
Access to markets as the most urgent problem *0.390.4910
Access to additional water as the most urgent problem *0.410.5010+
Need to cope with water shortages in all seasons *0.480.5110+
Need to cope with water shortages in summer *0.350.4810+
Habit approach to innovation [0, 4]2.500.8141
Maximization approach to innovation [0, 4]0.980.6820+
Predict increased output and input prices or increased output and stable input prices *0.370.4910+
Not in a position to express any expectation *0.350.4810
Cooperative membership *0.830.3810+
Access to suitable information from governmental agencies *0.850.3610+
Changing crop pattern as the most important project potential0.940.2510+
Expanding current crops as the most important project potential0.040.2110+
Table 6. Conceptual flow chart of the innovative framework in the present study. Innovative theoretical features are boldfaced. EA, econometric analysis; CBA, cost–benefit analysis; FA, financial analysis; IB, indirect benefits; EVW, economic value of water.
Table 6. Conceptual flow chart of the innovative framework in the present study. Innovative theoretical features are boldfaced. EA, econometric analysis; CBA, cost–benefit analysis; FA, financial analysis; IB, indirect benefits; EVW, economic value of water.
AnalysisGoals of the Analysis Determinants or Specifications Strategic DecisionsOutcomes of the Analysis
EAIdentify farmers who are more likely to adopt (%) …… dependent on structural and long-run characteristics such as:
  • Male/female
  • Rich/poor
  • Owner/tenant
  • With/without livestock
  • Small/large farm
  • Young/old
State aims, such as to reduce inequality, increase indirect incomes in the area, or maximize the adoption rate in terms of land area or number of farmersTarget farmers
Water 09 00821 i001Identify the costs of the irrigation structuresEconomists/engineersDesign the irrigation scheme
Identify the benefits from the yield increasesEconomists/agronomists
CBAEconomic values of the project …… including direct/indirect and monetized/non-monetized benefits from, and costs of, irrigation and hydropowerAveIRR
MinIRR
Water 09 00821 i001Reference values in terms of water priceswp(AveIRR) = AveEVW
wp(MinIRR) = MinEVW
Introduce these values into the government budget
FAFinancial feasibility …… from government budget
wpwp(fr), wp ≥ wp(fr, IB)
… and from farmer budget
wpwp(lr)
Feasibility (%)
Social sustainability …… from farmer budget
wp(lr)MinEVW
lrMinIRR
Sustainability (%)
End of the analysisValue ranges for wp and lrIdentify acceptable wp and lr values among the feasible and sustainable values, if anySummary for stakeholders to support discussion of all crucial economic and financial values
If necessary, change target farmers and compare new adoption, feasibility, and sustainability rates (%)
Table 7. Impacts on adoption probability. * indicates dummy variables.
Table 7. Impacts on adoption probability. * indicates dummy variables.
Independent VariableReady to Adopt
dΦ/dxStd. Errorz-StatisticpMean
Literacy status *0.002430.0014.280.0000.565
Habit approach to innovation−0.002970.002−9.310.0002.5
Maximization approach to innovation0.005850.0091.480.1380.978
Predict increased output and input prices or increased output and stable input prices *0.006890.00519.460.0000.369
Need to cope with water shortages in all seasons *0.090750.1163.350.0010.478
Gross income−0.001670.001−3.280.0016.234
Income from livestock activity greater than 50% *−0.056880.061−5.120.0000.5
Access to fair prices for outputs *0.028810.0135.210.0000.391
Access to fair prices for inputs *−0.402220.117−56.840.0000.413
Access to suitable information from governmental agencies *0.941050.00213.080.0000.847
Satisfactory access to bank loans *−0.892360.190−5.440.0000.108
Direct access to output markets *−0.214210.221−4.260.0000.065
Note: * dΦ/dx represents the discrete change in the dummy variable from 0 to 1. Standard errors were adjusted for clustering as a function of the type of tenancy. Predicted probability at average values of the dependent variables = 0.9948.
Table 8. Sensitivity analyses for the effects of changing crop prices and changing indirect benefits.
Table 8. Sensitivity analyses for the effects of changing crop prices and changing indirect benefits.
Crop PricesInternal Rate of Return (%)
−20% Indirect BenefitsReference Value for Indirect Benefits+20% Indirect Benefits
−20% crop prices4.64.95.2
Reference value for crop prices6.77.17.4
+20% crop prices8.68.99.4
Table 9. The conceptual flow chart of the innovative methodological procedure. EA, econometric analysis; CBA, cost–benefit analysis; FA, financial analysis; ID, Iraqi Dinars; CER, certified emission reduction.
Table 9. The conceptual flow chart of the innovative methodological procedure. EA, econometric analysis; CBA, cost–benefit analysis; FA, financial analysis; ID, Iraqi Dinars; CER, certified emission reduction.
AnalysisGoals of the Analysis Determinants or Specifications Political DecisionsOutcomes of the Analysis
EAIdentify farmers who are more likely to adopt (99%) as dependent on structural and long-run characteristics:
Rich/poor
Small/large
Literate/illiterate
Reduce inequality and maximize adoption rate by farmersTarget farmers: illiterate, small (<7.7 ha), poor (<1861 ID)
Water 09 00821 i001Identify the costs of the irrigation structuresEconomists/engineersDesign the irrigation scheme for an average farm size of 8 ha
Identify the benefits from the yield increasesEconomists/agronomists
CBAEconomic value of the projectincluding indirect non-monetized benefits from irrigation (flood, recreation) and from hydropower (CER)AveIRR = 7.1%
MinIRR = 4.6%
Water 09 00821 i001Reference values in terms of water pricesAveEVW = 0.92 USD/m3
MinEVW = 0.66 USD/m3
Introduce these values into the government budget
FAFinancial feasibility…from the government budget
wp ≥ wp(fr), wp ≥ wp(fr, CER)
and from the farmer budget
wp ≤ wp(lr)
Feasibility 13.6%
Social sustainability…from the farmer budget
wp(lr) ≤ 0.66
lr ≤ 4.6
Sustainability 35.8%
End of the analysiswp must be in [[0.32, 0.57 USD/m3]
lr must be in [0, 3%]
Identify acceptable values for wp and lrFigure 2

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zagonari, F. Combining Econometric, Cost–Benefit, and Financial Methodologies in a Framework to Increase Diffusion and to Predict the Feasibility and Sustainability of Irrigation Schemes: A Case Study in Kurdistan, Iraq. Water 2017, 9, 821. https://doi.org/10.3390/w9110821

AMA Style

Zagonari F. Combining Econometric, Cost–Benefit, and Financial Methodologies in a Framework to Increase Diffusion and to Predict the Feasibility and Sustainability of Irrigation Schemes: A Case Study in Kurdistan, Iraq. Water. 2017; 9(11):821. https://doi.org/10.3390/w9110821

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zagonari, Fabio. 2017. "Combining Econometric, Cost–Benefit, and Financial Methodologies in a Framework to Increase Diffusion and to Predict the Feasibility and Sustainability of Irrigation Schemes: A Case Study in Kurdistan, Iraq" Water 9, no. 11: 821. https://doi.org/10.3390/w9110821

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop