How Cooperative Are Games in River Sharing Models?
Abstract
1. Introduction
- On the one hand, the upstream riparian has de facto supremacy over the downstream riparian, which leads to a variety of problems:
- -
- In the event of pollution of the watercourse or the discharge or accumulation of water, the downstream party shall bear the damage or the resulting costs. However, the upstream party is responsible for the costs.
- -
- Flood protection measures of the upstream riparian lead to a benefit that is also experienced by the downstream riparian. The upstream riparian often has the most cost-effective flood protection options at its disposal by regulating the volume of water through retention basins and dams. However, the situation is characterised by the fact that the upstream riparian bears the burden and the downstream riparian the benefit of these measures.
- On the other hand, flood protection measures of the downstream riparian can lead to an impairment of the upstream riparian. For example, the raising of dams in the area of the downstream riparian causes a reduced discharge and thus a backwater for the residents further upstream. This phenomenon leads to a “race” of the dams upstream, starting with the downstream riparians and ending with the upstream riparians. One possible solution is for downstream riparians to make areas available to enable rapid runoff and receive compensation payments from upstream riparians in return.
- Conduct a systematic literature review to categorise the river sharing problems;
- Examine the identified axiomatic literature related to TU games with regard to its suitability for real-world application; and
- Present a unifying approach to share investments in flood or pollution control fairly.
2. Principles of International Water Law
“It is clear that the unrestricted disposal by State A of the waters of an international watercourse flowing from that State into State B based on the idea of State A’s absolute territorial sovereignty is incompatible with the unrestricted disposal of those waters to which State B would be likewise entitled on the basis of its absolute territorial sovereignty over the natural resources which nature would ordinarily bring into its territory […]. Unlimited disposal by State A of its territory will make the unlimited disposal by State B of its territory impossible and vice versa. Thus, if not already untenable because of the social and economic injustice to which the application of the principle of absolute territorial sovereignty would lead, such application would already seem impossible because of the legal contradiction inherent in the principle itself.”
“Both absolute principles were effectively dismissed when a 1957 arbitration tribunal ruled in the case that “territorial sovereignty …must bend before all international obligations”, effectively negating the doctrine of absolute sovereignty. Yet the tribunal also admonished the downstream State from the right to veto ‘reasonable’ upstream development, thereby negating the principle of natural flow or absolute riverain integrity. This decision made possible the 1958 Lac Lanoux treaty (revised in 1970), in which it is agreed that water is diverted out-of-basin for French hydropower generation, and a similar quantity is returned before the stream reaches Spanish territory.”
3. Cooperative Game Theory
3.1. Properties of a Game and Solution Concepts
- Players have similar interests and enter into binding agreements so that their goals are to be achieved through cooperation.
- The players’ actions lead to the outcome of the cooperation.
- Every player tries to maximise its utility.
- The outcome of each coalition is known in advance, which requires truthful reporting by the players and reliability of the data.
- A game is essential if Only if this property is fulfilled, then it is a problem of fair sharing. For a so-called inessential game with – an additive game – such a problem does not exist. Inessential games were excluded at the very early stage of game theory development:
- von Neumann & Morgenstern [47] stated for inessential games: “This is a perfectly trivial case, in which the game is manifestly devoid of further possibilities. There is no occasion for any strategy of coalitions, no element of struggle or competition: each player may play a lone hand, since there is no advantage in any coalition. […] [H]e can get this amount even alone, irrespective of what the others are doing. No coalition could do better in toto.”
- See Shapley [48] for a similar argumentation: “If v is inessential [the imputation] is a single point …”
- “It is conceivable that there are games in which no coalition of players is more effective than the several players of the coalition operating alone. […] Such games are called inessential […] Since nothing is gained by forming coalitions in inessential games, it is clear that we cannot expect any theory of coalition formation in that case, and so we shall be concerned only with essential games from now on.” (Luce & Raiffa [49])
- “Suppose, however, it were always true that . Again it would be difficult to imagine the occurrence of coalition-formation inasmuch as rational players would not expend energy to change position if the most they could expect would be the same payoff […] It is clear that for a game in which there is no point to forming coalitions. Indeed […] there is not much of anything for players to do.” (Riker [50])
- The worth of every coalition is non-negative, so for all follows The utility of at least one coalition should be greater than zero. In particular, coalitions that include multiple players should have a value greater than zero in order to justify cooperation.
- A game is superadditive if for . To offer incentives for cooperation, the inequality should hold for at least one coalition.
- A game is convex if for all and all follows: . It claims that a greater coalition generates a higher marginal contribution of player i. Convexity describes a similar effect like superadditivity for coalitions of conjoint elements. Further, convex games are superadditive.
3.2. How to Respectively Not Model Cooperative Games
- Essentiality: If the game is inessential, there is no incentive for players to cooperate, so we can stop further analysis.
- Balancedness (game with a non-empty core): If the game is not balanced, at least one coalition has an incentive to leave the grand coalition. This would not ensure cooperation among all players, so we can stop further analysis. For a balanced game, it should be checked whether the proposed solution lies in the core of the game.
- Superadditivity: Describes the state of synergy, which is the incentive for cooperation. A non-superadditive game implies for the Shapley value that it is not necessarily part of the core.
- Convexity: This state is desirable because it describes an analogous relationship to “increasing returns to scale” with respect to marginal contributions (Shapley [52]). Further, it implies that the Shapley value lies in the non-empty core.
4. Methodology
4.1. Literature Search and Selection Strategy
- ((river OR water) AND (share OR sharing) AND problem) AND (allocation OR game OR rule OR cost)
4.2. Sample Description
5. Content Analysis Result
5.1. Objectives
- the flooding costs (Abraham & Ramachandran [8])
5.2. Principles
5.3. Games, Solutions and Evaluation
- the Local Responsibility Sharing method
- the Upstream Equal Sharing method
- the Downstream Equal Sharing method
- the Harmon rule
- the UTI incremental solution
- the families of rules of Gómez-Rúa [58]
- the Sequential Upstream Proportional Allocation
- the Equal Upstream-Solidarity method
“Finally, the Harmon rule is a controversial rule and our paper should not be interpreted as an ignorant pledge to implement this rule.”
- Weighted Hierarchical solutions
- Sequential Sharing rules
- no-harm rule
- Upstream Responsibility rule
- Upstream Limited Sharing method
- -responsibility method
- Adjacent Downstream Compensation method
- Bilateral Compensation method
- Equal Upstream Responsibility method
- Weighted Upstream Sharing method
- Equal Upstream-Local Responsibility method
- Equal Upstream-Solidarity-Responsibility method
6. Allocation of Common Costs for River Protection Measures
- Flood protection and
- Environmental protection, such as water purification or retention
7. Case Study
8. Discussion
“However, an adequate descriptive theory of coalitions in inessential games will be less simple and more interesting than the normative theory. In fact, such a descriptive theory is of special interest just because of the particular simplicity of the associated normative theory. Just because coalitions are neither advantagous or disadvantagous, extra-normative considerations will have their maximal impact on behaviour. In the absence of logical rationale, psychological factors should be revealed more clearly. The game theorist has good reason to dismiss inessential games as trivial. The behavioural scientist, on the other hand, has good reason to consider them interesting and useful.”
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Game Theory
Appendix A.1. Cost Games
- Essentiality: A cost game is essential if
- Subadditivity: A cost game is subadditive if for
- Concavity: A game is concave if for all and all follows: .
Appendix A.2. Desirable Properties of a Solution Concept
- Efficiency (E):
- Individual rationality (IR):
- Coalitional rationality (CR):
- Symmetry (SYM): For two players with for all follows: .
- Dummy-player-property (DPP): For a player with for all follows: .
- Additivity (ADD): For two games and with fixed N follows:for all .
Appendix A.3. Cost Sharing for Resources with Linear Utilisation
- Distribute the costs of the smallest aircraft type evenly across the entire player set.
- Distribute the additional costs that the second smallest aircraft type incurs, in contrast to the smallest aircraft type, evenly over the entire player set except for the smallest aircraft type.
- Continue this procedure until all costs have been distributed.
Appendix A.4. Related Approaches
Appendix B. Overview of the Literature Review
Problem | Relevant Contributions | Methods | |||||||||||
Published Article | ① | ② | ③ | Fair | Techn. | Applic. | Lit. Rev. | BA | BS | Other | |||
Rogers (1969) | [1] | X | X | X | |||||||||
Suzuki/Nakayama (1976) | [2] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Sheehan/Kogiku (1981) | [93] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||
Straffin/Heany (1981) | [94] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Young et al. (1982) | [95] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Lejano/Davos (1995) | [96] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Dinar/Howitt (1997) | [3] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Becker/Easter (1999) | [97] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Frisvold/Caswell (2000) | [98] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Ambec/Sprumont (2002) | [4] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Kucukmehmetoglu/Guldmann (2004) | [99] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Wu/Whittington (2006) | [100] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Ni/Wang (2007) | [6] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Ambec/Ehlers (2008) | [54] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Kucukmehmetoglu (2009) | [101] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Sumaila et al. (2009) | [102] | X | X | ||||||||||
Khmelnitskaya (2010) | [71] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Kucukmehmetoglu et al. (2010) | [103] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Mahjouri/Ardestani (2010) | [104] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Mahjouri/Ardestani (2011) | [105] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Ansink/Weikard (2012) | [65] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
van den Brink et al. (2012) | [55] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Dong et al. (2012) | [57] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||
Kucukmehmetoglu (2012) | [106] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Ambec et al. (2013) | [107] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Beal et al. (2013) | [11] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Gómez-Rúa (2013) | [58] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
van den Brink et al. (2014) | [56] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Khmelnitskaya (2014) | [108] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Mianabadi et al. (2014) | [109] | X | X | X | X | ||||||||
Read et al. (2014) | [110] | X | X | X | X | ||||||||
Alcalde-Unzu et al. (2015) | [59] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Ansink/Weikard (2015) | [66] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Beal et al. (2015) | [111] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Houba et al. (2015) | [112] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Mianabadi et al. (2015) | [113] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Sechi/Zucca (2015) | [114] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Ansink/Houba (2016) | [115] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Degefu et al. (2016) | [116] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Girard et al. (2016) | [117] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Degefu et al. (2017) | [118] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Osório (2017a) | [119] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Osório (2017b) | [120] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Zomorodian et al. (2017) | [121] | X | X | X | X | ||||||||
van den Brink et al. (2018) | [7] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Jeong et al. (2018) | [73] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Sedghamiz et al. (2018) | [122] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Alvarez et al. (2019) | [123] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Gudmundsson et al. (2019) | [124] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Qin et al. (2019) | [125] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Sun et al. (2019) | [60] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Abraham/Ramachandran (2020) | [8] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Janjua/Hassan (2020a) | [126] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Janjua/Hassan (2020b) | [127] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Janjua et al. (2020) | [128] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Öztürk (2020) | [129] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Qin et al. (2020) | [130] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Tayebikhorami et al. (2020) | [131] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Abraham/Ramachandran (2021) | [132] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Estévez-Fernández et al. (2021) | [133] | X | X | X | X | X | |||||||
Hou et al. (2021) | [61] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Liu et al. (2020) | [134] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Nehra/Caplan (2022) | [135] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Wang (2022) | [136] | X | X | X | X | ||||||||
Cano-Berlanga et al. (2023) | [137] | X | X | X | X | ||||||||
Li et al. (2023) | [62] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Wan et al. (2023) | [138] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Yuan et al. (2023) | [139] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Zhu et al. (2023) | [140] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Hou et al. (2024) | [63] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Lowing (2024) | [64] | X | X | X | X | X | X | ||||||
Qin et al. (2024) | [141] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X | |||||
Zhang et al. (2024) | [142] | X | X | X | X | X | X | X |
References
- Rogers, P. A Game Theory Approach to the Problems of International River Basins. Water Resour. Res. 1969, 5, 749–760. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Suzuki, M.; Nakayama, M. The Cost Assignment of the Cooperative Water Resource Development: A Game Theoretical Approach. Manag. Sci. 1976, 22, 1081–1086. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dinar, A.; Howitt, R.E. Mechanisms for Allocation of Environmental Control Cost: Empirical Tests of Acceptability and Stability. J. Environ. Manag. 1997, 49, 183–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ambec, S.; Sprumont, Y. Sharing a River. J. Econ. Theory 2002, 107, 453–462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McCracken, M.; Wolf, A.T. Updating the Register of International River Basins of the World. Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 2019, 35, 732–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ni, D.; Wang, Y. Sharing a Polluted River. Games Econ. Behav. 2007, 60, 176–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van den Brink, R.; He, S.; Huang, J.P. Polluted River Problems and Games with a Permission Structure. Games Econ. Behav. 2018, 108, 182–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Abraham, A.; Ramachandran, P. A Solution for the Flood Cost Sharing Problem. Econ. Lett. 2020, 189, 109030. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Coase, R.H. The Problem of Social Cost. J. Law Econ. 1960, 3, 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Madani, K. Game Theory and Water Resources. J. Hydrol. 2010, 381, 225–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beal, S.; Ghintran, A.; Remila, E.; Solal, P. The River Sharing Problem: A Survey. Int. Game Theory Rev. 2013, 15, 1340016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dinar, A.; Hogarth, M. Game Theory and Water Resources Critical Review of Its Contributions, Progress and Remaining Challenges. Found. Trends® Microecon. 2015, 11, 1–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dinar, A. Challenges to Water Resource Management: The Role of Economic and Modeling Approaches. Water 2024, 16, 610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lipper, J. Equitable Utilization. In The Law of International Drainage Basins; Garretson, A.H., Hayton, R.D., Olmstead, C.J., Eds.; Oceana Publications: Dobbs Ferry, NY, USA, 1967; pp. 15–88. [Google Scholar]
- Lammers, J.G. Pollution of International Watercourses: A Search for Substantive Rules or Principles of Law; Martinus Nijhoff Publishers: Boston, MA, USA, 1984. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moermond, J.O., III; Shirley, E. A Survey of the International Law of Rivers. Denver J. Int. Law Policy 1987, 16, 139–160. [Google Scholar]
- McCaffrey, S.C. The Law of International Watercourses: Some Recent Developments and Unanswered Questions. Denver J. Int. Law Policy 1989, 17, 505–526. [Google Scholar]
- Gleick, P.H. Pacific Institute for Studies in Development, Environment, and Security. In Water in Crisis: A Guide to the World’s Fresh Water Resources; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
- Dellapenna, J.W. The Customary International Law of Transboundary Fresh Waters. Int. J. Glob. Environ. Issues 2001, 1, 264–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Caponera, D.A.; Nanni, M. Principles of Water Law and Administration, 2nd ed.; Taylor & Francis: London, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
- McIntyre, O. International Water Law: Concepts, Evolution and Development. In Transboundary Water Management: Principles and Practice, 1st ed.; Earle, A., Jägerskog, A., Öjendal, J., Eds.; Earthscan: London, UK; Washington, DC, USA, 2010; pp. 59–72. [Google Scholar]
- McCaffrey, S.C. International Water Cooperation in the 21st Century: Recent Developments in the Law of International Watercourses. Rev. Eur. Comp. Int. Environ. Law 2014, 23, 4–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- de Castro, P.C. The Evolution of International Water Law. Int. J. Sustain. Dev. Plan. 2015, 10, 894–900. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mager, U. International Water Law—Global Developments and Regional Examples; Number 3 in Miscellanea Juridica Heidelbergensia; Jedermann-Verlag GmbH: Heidelberg, Germany, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Devlaeminck, D.J. Reciprocity and the Development of International Water Law. J. Water Law 2016, 25, 80–87. [Google Scholar]
- Kuokkanen, T. Water Security and International Law. Potchefstroom Electron. Law J. 2017, 20, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McCaffrey, S.C. The Law of International Watercourses, 3rd ed.; The Oxford International Law Library, Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Meshel, T. Swimming Against the Current: Revisiting the Principles of International Water Law in the Resolution of Fresh Water Disputes. Harv. Int. Law J. 2020, 61, 135–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tortajada, C.; Araral, E. Global Water Resources: Festschrift in Honour of Asit K. Biswas, 1st ed.; Routledge: London, UK, 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zheng, C.; Spijkers, O. Priority of Uses in International Water Law. Sustainability 2021, 13, 1567. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Meshel, T. The Harmon Doctrine Is Dead, Long Live the Harmon Doctrine! J. Int’l L. 2022, 63, 1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Y. International Watercourses Law and Multilateral Environmental Agreements: A Case for the Integrated Protection and Preservation of Shared Inland Water Ecosystems, 1st ed.; Number 12 in International Water Law Series; BRILL: Boston, MA, USA, 2024. [Google Scholar]
- Wolf, A.T. Criteria for Equitable Allocations: The Heart of International Water Conflict. Nat. Resour. Forum 1999, 23, 3–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tignino, M.; Bréthaut, C. The Role of International Case Law in Implementing the Obligation Not to Cause Significant Harm. Int. Environ. Agreements: Politics, Law Econ. 2020, 20, 631–648. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Salman, S.M.A. The Helsinki Rules, the UN Watercourses Convention and the Berlin Rules: Perspectives on International Water Law. Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 2007, 23, 625–640. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mohammed, Y.A. The Guiding Legal Regime and Institutional Arrangement of Transboundary Watercourse: A Review. Int. J. Water Manag. Dipl. 2022, 1, 75–90. [Google Scholar]
- McCaffrey, S.C. The Harmon Doctrine One Hundred Years Later: Buried, Not Praised. Nat. Resour. J. 1996, 36, 549–590. [Google Scholar]
- Harmon, J. Treaty of Guadalupe Hidalgo—International Law. In Official Opinions of the Attorneys-General of the United States: Advising the President and Heads of Departments, in Relation to Their Official Duties, and Expounding the Constitution, Treaties with Foreign Governments and with Indian Tribes, and the Public Laws of the Country; Number 554; U.S. Government Publishing Office: Washington, DC, USA, 1898; Volume XXI, pp. 274–283. [Google Scholar]
- Naderi, S.; Motallebi, M. Instruments of Criminal Protection of the Right to a Clean Environment in the International Environmental Conventions. CIFILE J. Int. Law 2022, 3, 109–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Poorhashemi, A. Principles of International Environmental Law. CIFILE J. Int. Law 2023, 4, 80–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kilgour, D.M.; Dinar, A. AreStable Agreements for Sharing International River Waters Now Possible? Policy Research Working Paper; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 1995; pp. 1–20. [Google Scholar]
- Loures, F.R. History and Status of the Community-of-Interests Doctrine. In A History of Water: Sovereignty and International Water Law, 1st ed.; Tvedt, T., Woldetsadik, T.K., McIntyre, O., Eds.; Series III; I.B. Tauris: London, UK, 2015; Volume 2, pp. 212–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Maschler, M.B.; Solan, E.; Zamir, S. Game Theory, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Algaba, E.; van den Brink, R. The Shapley Value and Games with Hierarchies. In Handbook of the Shapley Value; Algaba, E., Fragnelli, V., Sanchez-Soriano, J., Eds.; Series in Operations Research; CRC Press; Taylor & Francis Group: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 2020; pp. 49–74. [Google Scholar]
- Peleg, B.; Sudhölter, P. (Eds.) Introduction to the Theory of Cooperative Games, 2nd ed.; Number 34 in Theory and Decision Library, Series C: Game Theory, Mathematical Programming and Operations Research; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mueller, D. The Usability and Suitability of Allocation Schemes for Corporate Cost Accounting. In Game Theory in Management Accounting; Mueller, D., Trost, R., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2018; pp. 401–427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- von Neumann, J.; Morgenstern, O. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, 3rd ed.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1953. [Google Scholar]
- Shapley, L.S. 17. A Value for n-Person Games. In Contributions to the Theory of Games (AM-28); Kuhn, H.W., Tucker, A.W., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1953; Volume II, pp. 307–318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Luce, R.D.; Raiffa, H. Games and Decisions: Introduction and Critical Survey; John Wiley & Sons, Inc.: New York, NY, USA, 1957. [Google Scholar]
- Riker, W.H. The Theory of Political Coalitions, 1st ed.; Yale University Press: New Haven, CT, USA, 1962. [Google Scholar]
- Gillies, D.B. Solutions to General Non-Zero-Sum Games. In Contributions to the Theory of Games (AM-40); Tucker, A.W., Luce, R.D., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NY, USA, 1959; Volume IV, pp. 47–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shapley, L.S. Cores of Convex Games. Int. J. Game Theory 1971, 1, 11–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Page, M.J.; McKenzie, J.E.; Bossuyt, P.M.; Boutron, I.; Hoffmann, T.C.; Mulrow, C.D.; Shamseer, L.; Tetzlaff, J.M.; Akl, E.A.; Brennan, S.E.; et al. The PRISMA 2020 Statement: An Updated Guideline for Reporting Systematic Reviews. Int. J. Surg. 2021, 88, 105906. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Ambec, S.; Ehlers, L. Sharing a River among Satiable Agents. Games Econ. Behav. 2008, 64, 35–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van den Brink, R.; van der Laan, G.; Moes, N. Fair Agreements for Sharing International Rivers with Multiple Springs and Externalities. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2012, 63, 388–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van den Brink, R.; Estévez-Fernández, A.; van der Laan, G.; Moes, N. Independence of Downstream and Upstream Benefits in River Water Allocation Problems. Soc. Choice Welf. 2014, 43, 173–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dong, B.; Ni, D.; Wang, Y. Sharing a Polluted River Network. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2012, 53, 367–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gómez-Rúa, M. Sharing a Polluted River through Environmental Taxes. SERIEs 2013, 4, 137–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alcalde-Unzu, J.; Gómez-Rúa, M.; Molis, E. Sharing the Costs of Cleaning a River: The Upstream Responsibility Rule. Games Econ. Behav. 2015, 90, 134–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sun, P.; Hou, D.; Sun, H. Responsibility and Sharing the Cost of Cleaning a Polluted River. Math. Methods Oper. Res. 2019, 89, 143–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hou, D.; Kong, Q.; Zhang, X.; Sun, H. Adjacent Downstream Compensation Method of Sharing Polluted Rivers. Group Decis. Negot. 2021, 30, 251–265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, W.; Xu, G.; van den Brink, R. Two New Classes of Methods to Share the Cost of Cleaning up a Polluted River. Soc. Choice Welf. 2023, 61, 35–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hou, D.; Feng, Y.; Sun, P.; Sun, H. Sharing the Cost of the Polluted River: A Class of Bilateral Compensation Methods. OR Spectr. 2024, 46, 1241–1264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lowing, D. Responsibility and Solidarity Principles in Sharing the Costs of Cleaning a Polluted River. Oper. Res. Lett. 2024, 57, 107198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ansink, E.; Weikard, H.P. Sequential Sharing Rules for River Sharing Problems. Soc. Choice Welf. 2012, 38, 187–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ansink, E.; Weikard, H.P. Composition Properties in the River Claims Problem. Soc. Choice Welf. 2015, 44, 807–831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van den Brink, R.; van der Laan, G. Comment on ‘Sharing a Polluted River’; Working Paper; VU University of Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Müller, D.; Pisch, M.F.K. An Improper Solution to the Flood Cost Sharing Problem. Econ. Lett. 2024, 238, 111706. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van den Brink, R.; van der Laan, G.; Vasil’ev, V. Component Efficient Solutions in Line-Graph Games with Applications. Econ. Theory 2007, 33, 349–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Houba, H. Computing Alternating Offers and Water Prices in Bilateral River Basin Management. Int. Game Theory Rev. 2008, 10, 257–278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Khmelnitskaya, A.B. Values for Rooted-Tree and Sink-Tree Digraph Games and Sharing a River. Theory Decis. 2010, 69, 657–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mueller, D. A Cost Calculation Model for the Optimal Design of Size Ranges. J. Eng. Des. 2011, 22, 467–485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jeong, H.; Ha, S.; Kim, H. Flood Protection Cost Allocation Using Cooperative Game Theory for Adapting Infrastructure to Climate Change. J. Water Resour. Plan. Manag. 2018, 144, 04018010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Newnan, D.G.; Eschenbach, T.G.; Lavelle, J.P. Engineering Economic Analysis, 11th ed.; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Meinhardt, H.I. MatTuGames, Version 1.9.0.2. 2021. Available online: https://de.mathworks.com/matlabcentral/fileexchange/35933-mattugames (accessed on 20 June 2025).
- Willis, R.H. Coalition Behavior in Inessential Games. In Social Choice; Liebermann, B., Ed.; Gordon and Breach: New York, NY, USA, 1971; pp. 141–162. [Google Scholar]
- Young, H. Chapter 34 Cost Allocation. In Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications; North Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1994; Volume 2, pp. 1193–1235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Littlechild, S.C.; Owen, G. A Simple Expression for the Shapley Value in a Special Case. Manag. Sci. 1973, 20, 370–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- González-Díaz, J.; García-Jurado, I.; Fiestras-Janeiro, M.G. An Introductory Course on Mathematical Game Theory. In Graduate Studies in Mathematics; American Mathematical Society: Providence, RI, USA, 2010; Volume 115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dall’Aglio, M.; Fragnelli, V.; Moretti, S. Sometimes the Computation of the Shapley Value Is Simple. In Handbook of the Shapley Value; Algaba, E., Fragnelli, V., Sanchez-Soriano, J., Eds.; Series in Operations Research; CRC Press; Taylor & Francis Group: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 2020; pp. 441–462. [Google Scholar]
- Potters, J.; Sudhölter, P. Airport Problems and Consistent Allocation Rules. Math. Soc. Sci. 1999, 38, 83–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- González-Díaz, J.; Mirás Calvo, M.Á.; Quinteiro Sandomingo, C.; Sánchez Rodríguez, E. Airport Games: The Core and Its Center. Math. Soc. Sci. 2016, 82, 105–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thomson, W. Axiomatic and Game-Theoretic Analysis of Bankruptcy and Taxation Problems: A Survey. Math. Soc. Sci. 2003, 45, 249–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aumann, R.J.; Maschler, M. Game Theoretic Analysis of a Bankruptcy Problem from the Talmud. J. Econ. Theory 1985, 36, 195–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- O’Neill, B. A Problem of Rights Arbitration from the Talmud. Math. Soc. Sci. 1982, 2, 345–371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thomson, W. Axiomatic and Game-Theoretic Analysis of Bankruptcy and Taxation Problems: An Update. Math. Soc. Sci. 2015, 74, 41–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Peters, H.J.M. Game Theory: A Multi-Leveled Approach, 2nd ed.; Springer Texts in Business and Economics; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Dehez, P. Game Theory for the Social Sciences: Conflict, Bargaining, Cooperation and Power; Springer Series in Game Theory; Springer Nature: Cham, Switzerland, 2024. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nash, J.F. The Bargaining Problem. Econometrica 1950, 18, 155–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kalai, E.; Smorodinsky, M. Other Solutions to Nash’s Bargaining Problem. Econometrica 1975, 43, 513–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kalai, E. Proportional Solutions to Bargaining Situations: Interpersonal Utility Comparisons. Econometrica 1977, 45, 1623–1630. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Myerson, R.B. Two-Person Bargaining Problems and Comparable Utility. Econometrica 1977, 45, 1631–1637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sheehan, M.; Kogiku, K. Game Theory Analyses Applied to Water Resource Problems. Socio-Econ. Plan. Sci. 1981, 15, 109–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Straffin, P.D.; Heaney, J.P. Game Theory and the Tennessee Valley Authority. Int. J. Game Theory 1981, 10, 35–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Young, H.P.; Okada, N.; Hashimoto, T. Cost Allocation in Water Resources Development. Water Resour. Res. 1982, 18, 463–475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lejano, R.P.; Davos, C.A. Cost Allocation of Multiagency Water Resource Projects: Game Theoretic Approaches and Case Study. Water Resour. Res. 1995, 31, 1387–1393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Becker, N.; Easter, K.W. Conflict and Cooperation in Managing International Water Resources Such as the Great Lakes. Land Econ. 1999, 75, 233–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frisvold, G.B.; Caswell, M.F. Transboundary Water Management Game-theoretic Lessons for Projects on the US–Mexico Border. Agric. Econ. 2000, 24, 101–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kucukmehmetoglu, M.; Guldmann, J.M. International Water Resources Allocation and Conflicts: The Case of the Euphrates and Tigris. Environ. Plan. Econ. Space 2004, 36, 783–801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, X.; Whittington, D. Incentive Compatibility and Conflict Resolution in International River Basins: A Case Study of the Nile Basin. Water Resour. Res. 2006, 42, 2005WR004238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kucukmehmetoglu, M. A Game Theoretic Approach to Assess the Impacts of Major Investments on Transboundary Water Resources: The Case of the Euphrates and Tigris. Water Resour. Manag. 2009, 23, 3069–3099. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sumaila, U.R.; Dinar, A.; Albiac, J. Game Theoretic Applications to Environmental and Natural Resource Problems. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2009, 14, 1–5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kucukmehmetoglu, M.; Şen, Z.; Özger, M. Coalition Possibility of Riparian Countries via Game Theory and Fuzzy Logic Models. Water Resour. Res. 2010, 46, W12528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mahjouri, N.; Ardestani, M. A Game Theoretic Approach for Interbasin Water Resources Allocation Considering the Water Quality Issues. Environ. Monit. Assess. 2010, 167, 527–544. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mahjouri, N.; Ardestani, M. Application of Cooperative and Non-Cooperative Games in Large-Scale Water Quantity and Quality Management: A Case Study. Environ. Monit. Assess. 2011, 172, 157–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kucukmehmetoglu, M. An Integrative Case Study Approach between Game Theory and Pareto Frontier Concepts for the Transboundary Water Resources Allocations. J. Hydrol. 2012, 450–451, 308–319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ambec, S.; Dinar, A.; McKinney, D. Water Sharing Agreements Sustainable to Reduced Flows. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2013, 66, 639–655. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Khmelnitskaya, A. Values for Games with Two-Level Communication Structures. Discret. Appl. Math. 2014, 166, 34–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mianabadi, H.; Mostert, E.; Zarghami, M.; Van De Giesen, N. A New Bankruptcy Method for Conflict Resolution in Water Resources Allocation. J. Environ. Manag. 2014, 144, 152–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Read, L.; Madani, K.; Inanloo, B. Optimality versus Stability in Water Resource Allocation. J. Environ. Manag. 2014, 133, 343–354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Béal, S.; Ghintran, A.; Rémila, E.; Solal, P. The Sequential Equal Surplus Division for Rooted Forest Games and an Application to Sharing a River with Bifurcations. Theory Decis. 2015, 79, 251–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Houba, H.; van der Laan, G.; Zeng, Y. International Environmental Agreements for River Sharing Problems. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2015, 62, 855–872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mianabadi, H.; Mostert, E.; Pande, S.; Van De Giesen, N. Weighted Bankruptcy Rules and Transboundary Water Resources Allocation. Water Resour. Manag. 2015, 29, 2303–2321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sechi, G.M.; Zucca, R. Water Resource Allocation in Critical Scarcity Conditions: A Bankruptcy Game Approach. Water Resour. Manag. 2015, 29, 541–555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ansink, E.; Houba, H. Sustainable Agreements on Stochastic River Flow. Resour. Energy Econ. 2016, 44, 92–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Degefu, D.M.; He, W.; Yuan, L.; Zhao, J.H. Water Allocation in Transboundary River Basins under Water Scarcity: A Cooperative Bargaining Approach. Water Resour. Manag. 2016, 30, 4451–4466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Girard, C.; Rinaudo, J.D.; Pulido-Velazquez, M. Sharing the Cost of River Basin Adaptation Portfolios to Climate Change: Insights from Social Justice and Cooperative Game Theory. Water Resour. Res. 2016, 52, 7945–7962. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Degefu, D.M.; He, W.; Yuan, L. Monotonic Bargaining Solution for Allocating Critically Scarce Transboundary Water. Water Resour. Manag. 2017, 31, 2627–2644. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osório, A. Self-Interest and Equity Concerns: A Behavioural Allocation Rule for Operational Problems. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 261, 205–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osório, A. A Sequential Allocation Problem: The Asymptotic Distribution of Resources. Group Decis. Negot. 2017, 26, 357–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zomorodian, M.; Lai, S.H.; Homayounfar, M.; Ibrahim, S.; Pender, G. Development and Application of Coupled System Dynamics and Game Theory: A Dynamic Water Conflict Resolution Method. PLoS ONE 2017, 12, e0188489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sedghamiz, A.; Nikoo, M.R.; Heidarpour, M.; Sadegh, M. Developing a Non-Cooperative Optimization Model for Water and Crop Area Allocation Based on Leader-Follower Game. J. Hydrol. 2018, 567, 51–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Álvarez, X.; Gómez-Rúa, M.; Vidal-Puga, J. River Flooding Risk Prevention: A Cooperative Game Theory Approach. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 248, 109284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Gudmundsson, J.; Hougaard, J.L.; Ko, C.Y. Decentralized Mechanisms for River Sharing. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2019, 94, 67–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qin, J.; Fu, X.; Peng, S.; Xu, Y.; Huang, J.; Huang, S. Asymmetric Bargaining Model for Water Resource Allocation over Transboundary Rivers. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 1733. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Janjua, S.; Hassan, I. Use of Bankruptcy Methods for Resolving Interprovincial Water Conflicts over Transboundary River: Case Study of Indus River in Pakistan. River Res. Appl. 2020, 36, 1334–1344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Janjua, S.; Hassan, I. Transboundary Water Allocation in Critical Scarcity Conditions: A Stochastic Bankruptcy Approach. J. Water Supply: Res. -Technol.-Aqua 2020, 69, 224–237. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Janjua, S.; Hassan, I.; Zarghami, M.; Islam, S. Addressing the Supply-Demand Gap in Shared Rivers Using Water Diplomacy Framework: Utility of Game Theory in the Indus River within Pakistan. Water Policy 2020, 22, 789–810. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Öztürk, Z.E. Fair Social Orderings for the Sharing of International Rivers: A Leximin Based Approach. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2020, 101, 102302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qin, J.; Fu, X.; Peng, S. Asymmetric Benefit Compensation Model for Resolving Transboundary Water Management Conflicts. Water Resour. Manag. 2020, 34, 3625–3647. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tayebikhorami, S.; Nikoo, M.R.; Izady, A.; Adamowski, J. A Novel CVaR-based Conflict Resolution Model for Optimal Allocation of Treated Wastewater under Bankruptcy Conditions. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 252, 119766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Abraham, A.; Ramachandran, P. The Welfare Implications of Transboundary Storage and Dam Ownership on River Water Trade. Math. Soc. Sci. 2021, 109, 18–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Estévez-Fernández, A.; Giménez-Gómez, J.M.; Solís-Baltodano, M.J. Sequential Bankruptcy Problems. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2021, 292, 388–395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, X.; Wang, X.; Guo, H.; An, X. Benefit Allocation in Shared Water-Saving Management Contract Projects Based on Modified Expected Shapley Value. Water Resour. Manag. 2021, 35, 39–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nehra, A.; Caplan, A.J. Nash Bargaining in a General Equilibrium Framework: The Case of a Shared Surface Water Supply. Water Resour. Econ. 2022, 39, 100206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y. The River Sharing Problem with Incomplete Information. Math. Soc. Sci. 2022, 117, 91–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cano-Berlanga, S.; Solís-Baltodano, M.J.; Vilella, C. The Art of Sharing Resources: How to Distribute Water during a Drought Period. Games 2023, 14, 59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wan, F.; Wang, Y.; Zhou, X.; Zheng, X.; Wu, J.; Xiao, L. Study on Balanced Allocation of Water Resources in the Yellow River Basin Based on Water Benefit Sharing. Sustainability 2023, 15, 559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, L.; Wu, X.; He, W.; Degefu, D.M.; Kong, Y.; Yang, Y.; Xu, S.; Ramsey, T.S. Utilizing the Strategic Concession Behavior in a Bargaining Game for Optimal Allocation of Water in a Transboundary River Basin during Water Bankruptcy. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2023, 102, 107162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, J.; Wang, J.; Fang, W.; Yu, S. Schemes for Allocation of Benefits from Contracted Water-Saving: The Case of Irrigated Field Projects in China. Water Econ. Policy 2023, 9, 2340012. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qin, J.; Fu, X.; Wu, X.; Wang, J.; Huang, J.; Chen, X.; Liu, J.; Zhang, J. Transboundary Water Allocation under Water Scarcity Based on an Asymmetric Power Index Approach with Bankruptcy Theory. Water 2024, 16, 2828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, K.; Lu, H.; Wang, B. Benefit Distribution Mechanism of a Cooperative Alliance for Basin Water Resources from the Perspective of Cooperative Game Theory. Sustainability 2024, 16, 6729. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
River | Number of Riparian States | Continent | Area |
---|---|---|---|
Oder/Odra | 3 | Europe | 119,252 |
Elbe | 4 | Europe | 145,157 |
Tigris-Euphrates/Shatt al Arab | 6 | Asia | 868,989 |
Amazonas | 7 | South America | 5,952,595 |
Indus | 7 | Asia | 855,875 |
Nile | 14 | Africa | 2,961,325 |
Danube | 19 | Europe | 800,970 |
Principles | Published Article |
---|---|
ATS | Ambec/Sprumont [4]; Ni/Wang [6]; Ambec/Ehlers [54]; Ansink/Weikard [65]; Dong et al. [57]; van den Brink et al. [56]; Alcalde-Unzu et al. [59]; Ansink/Weikard [66]; van den Brink et al. [7]; Sun et al. [60]; Hou et al. [61]; Li et al. [62]; Hou et al. [63]; Lowing [64] |
UTI: DR | Ambec/Sprumont [4]; Ni/Wang [6]; Ambec/Ehlers [54]; Ansink/Weikard [65]; Dong et al. [57]; Gómez-Rúa [58]; van den Brink et al. [56]; Alcalde-Unzu et al. [59]; Ansink/Weikard [66]; van den Brink et al. [7]; Sun et al. [60]; Li et al. [62]; Hou et al. [63]; Lowing [64] |
UTI: UR | Dong et al. [57]; van den Brink et al. [7]; Sun et al. [60]; Hou et al. [61]; Hou et al. [63] |
TIBS | van den Brink et al. [55]; van den Brink et al. [56]; van den Brink et al. [7] |
Extended Producer Responsibility | Abraham/Ramachandran [8] |
Solidarity | Lowing [64] |
S | ⌀ | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Function | |||||||||
0 | 9 | 13 | 14 | 13 | 14 | 14 | 14 |
Cost of the Jungnang Underground Floodway | USD 476 Million |
---|---|
Parameter k | 0.6913 |
Riparian | Capacity need () |
Dobong (1) | 367,652 |
Nowon (2) | 629,145 |
Seongbuk (3) | 436,177 |
Jungnang (4) | 328,420 |
Dongdaemun (5) | 252,262 |
Seongdong (6) | 299,838 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Pisch, M.F.K.; Müller, D. How Cooperative Are Games in River Sharing Models? Water 2025, 17, 2252. https://doi.org/10.3390/w17152252
Pisch MFK, Müller D. How Cooperative Are Games in River Sharing Models? Water. 2025; 17(15):2252. https://doi.org/10.3390/w17152252
Chicago/Turabian StylePisch, Marcus Franz Konrad, and David Müller. 2025. "How Cooperative Are Games in River Sharing Models?" Water 17, no. 15: 2252. https://doi.org/10.3390/w17152252
APA StylePisch, M. F. K., & Müller, D. (2025). How Cooperative Are Games in River Sharing Models? Water, 17(15), 2252. https://doi.org/10.3390/w17152252