Next Article in Journal
Management and Land Cover Changes in the Western Carpathian Traditional Orchard Landscape in the Period after 1948
Previous Article in Journal
Investigating Combined Drought- and Heat Stress Effects in Wheat under Controlled Conditions by Dynamic Image-Based Phenotyping
Previous Article in Special Issue
Rapid Acquisition, Management, and Analysis of Spatial Maize (Zea mays L.) Phenological Data—Towards ‘Big Data’ for Agronomy Transformation in Africa
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Marginal Trade-Offs for Improved Agro-Ecological Efficiency Using Data Envelopment Analysis

1
College of Economics and Management, Northeast Forestry University, Harbin 150040, China
2
School of Economics and Management, Yanshan University, Qinhuangdao 066004, China
3
Department of Public Administration, Faculty of Management Sciences, University of Kotli, Azad Jammu and Kashmir, Kotli 11100, Pakistan
4
Faculty of Economics and Social Sciences, Szent István University, 2100 Gödöllő, Hungary
5
TRADE Research Entity, North-West University, Vanderbijlpark 1900, South Africa
6
Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Debrecen, 4032 Debrecen, Hungary
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Agronomy 2021, 11(2), 365; https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy11020365
Submission received: 4 January 2021 / Revised: 9 February 2021 / Accepted: 10 February 2021 / Published: 18 February 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Big Data for Agriculture Monitoring)

Abstract

:
Today’s agricultural management decisions impact food security and sustainable ecosystems, even when operating with back-to-basic operations. In such endeavors, policymakers usually need a quantitative tool, such as trade-offs margins, to effectively adjust resource consumption or production. This paper applies the weighted slack-based measurement (SBM-DEA) program to 136 developing countries’ agricultural performance. First, it finds the current agricultural efficiency and then makes marginal trade-offs on desirable-output variables (such as crop yield and forest area) to see the effective changes in undesirable-output (such as methane and nitrous oxide emissions). The results show that choosing effective marginal trade-offs does not deteriorate the relative efficiency of the decision-making units (DMUs) below the efficient frontier line. Thus, such a method enables the decision-makers to determine the best marginal trade-off points to reach the optimal efficiencies and decide which output factor needs special brainstorming to design effective policy.

1. Introduction

Agricultural efficiency makes an important contribution to the country’s economy [1]. Efficiency improvements become crucial with the involvement of indirect variables [2], such as forest area, and basic agricultural emissions (even when considering machineless agricultural operations). That is, if we separate the CO2 emissions since they are connected to so many other things (i.e., machines), agricultural operations still also accompany the methane and nitrous oxide emissions as an indirect cost [3]. Therefore, resource consumption (undesirable) and production (desirable) are the key activities reflecting economic progress. Massive agricultural activity has become a potential contributor to ecological efficiency as it is directly proportional to the forest area and cultivating emissions (global carbon budget 2016 [4]). If it is not carefully planned, it can cause severe environmental problems. Therefore, to achieve higher agricultural efficiency, indirect variables must also be taken into account for real operational evaluation.
Trade-off techniques have been found widely explained theoretically, and their importance has been increased in the agricultural system to foresee the outcomes [5]. For example, a recent study by Ndiaye et al. (2019) [6] uses trade-offs between sorghum and agronomic performance stability. Kanter et al. (2018) [7] evaluates the trade-offs for sustainable developments considering agricultural systems. Conventionally, the trade-off is such an adjustment which gives the maximum output, and to see its effect on other variables when performed on one variable [8]. Akbar et al. [9] presented the conference paper, in which the trade-off has been performed using statistical techniques.
Moreover, finding an effective mathematical program that can be used to calculate the trade-offs is another difficult task. Data envelopment analysis (DEA) is one of the methods that can help perform marginal trade-offs. Mirzaei et al. [10] have used DEA to calculate the marginal rates of substitution to achieve optimal hydroelectric power plants optimal efficiencies. Khoshandam et al. [11] use trade-off balanced to nondiscretionary (ND) factors. Similarly, Atici and Podinovski [12] use DEA to assess the efficiency of the different agricultural units with production trade-offs. Asmild et al. [13] calculate trade-off margins with the elasticity of substitution. In their study, the new thing is that it can take negative and positive values both.
In this study, our analysis contributes in two ways. First, it enables us to bring improvement in the undesirable outputs by performing trade-offs among the desirable outputs. This means we do not have to reduce the inputs (i.e., resources like land and manpower, etc.). Second, it enables us to design better trade-off margins. Such margins do not disturb the relative efficiency of the DMUs below the frontier line but bring upon optimal efficiencies among the weakly efficient DMUs. By this, we mean that the DMUs may have appeared efficient (i.e., on the efficient frontier), but due to slacks in an undesirable output, they are considered weakly efficient. Hence, their efficiency can be further improved to the optimal level with the help of marginal trade-offs.
This study first uses a weighted slack-based measurement (SBM) model to calculate 136 developing countries’ efficiency. Then, it calculates the margins, by using the method proposed by Krivonozhko et al. [14], with which the trade-offs can be performed. In the second part (the marginal trade-offs), we consider that the inputs which are at the bottleneck and cannot be decreased or increased further (by the operational manager). Hence, the marginal trade-offs are to be considered only among desirable-outputs to improve the efficiency of undesirable-outputs. The rest of the paper is designed as follows; the next section thoroughly discusses the literature on trade-off methods and its computation with DEA. Section 3 puts forward the applicable model of SBM-DEA and marginal trade-offs, followed by an example. Section 4 discusses the measuring variables and analyzes the results. The conclusion is written in Section 5.

2. Literature

Agriculture industry plays an important role in the socioeconomic freedom (a tool to boost financial activities) and environmental sustainability of the developing countries [15,16]. If we use trade-offs as a method to cope with the optimal efficiency difficulties, the definition of trade-offs must be clear. There is a lot of research variations due to the perceived definition of quantitative trade-off methods. Some use trade-offs as a tool to find an effective balance between efficiency-related variables, for example, see the recent study of Akbar el al. [9], while others consider eliminating the trade-offs for sustainable and efficient performance, for example, Gružauskas et al. [17] and Shahbazpour and Seidel [18]. Our work adheres to the previous definition of trade-off, but to find the quantitative margins with which the trade-offs should be performed is rather challenging and new to the literature.
On the contrary, the method selection of trade-offs is also crucial, because it depends on the operational plans and gains. Therefore, we divide our literature in the following two parts. The first part discusses the recent developments in the agricultural efficiency specifically concerning emissions, which not only portrays its importance but also validates our contribution in the existing literature of the agriculture energy efficiency. The second part assesses the best fit of DEA to perform the quantitative trade-offs.

2.1. Developments in the Agro-Ecological Efficiency

Immense literature with considerable effective outcomes has been found for the ecological performance in agricultural operations. The most recent work of Pratt et al. (2020) [19] researched the opportunities where geosphere can support the agricultural system across four key challenges. One of their four findings is to mitigate the emissions of carbon dioxide CO2, methane, and nitrous oxide N2O. An interesting fact indicated is that the increasing geological inputs could increase footprints in an agricultural system. Akbar et al. (2020) [20] work on the reduction of the CO2 up to the sustainable level in an agro-ecological efficiency. They find the important factors affecting agro-ecological growth, such as planting structure, value-added per capita, and scale management etcetera. Bosco et al. [21] focus on the emissions from agriculture cultivation during seasonal crop rotations. They perform trade-offs between the greenhouse gases and the crop productivity within the three cropping systems (GHG).
Most importantly, they show that the organic conversion system does not really contribute to GHG mitigation during crop rotations. Shen et al. [22] work on the methane and nitrous oxide emissions from crops and animals of 69 municipalities. The results show that the direct N2O emissions are larger than indirect emissions, and the maximum N2O emissions were found to be from synthetic fertilizers. Same is the work by Yue et al. [23] and Tang et al. [24] but considering China’s long-term fertilizer management. On the other hand, Audet et al. [25] present that important sources of N2O emissions include forest streams, which is equivalent to 25% of the agricultural N2O emissions in Sweden. Wysocka et al. [26] statistically analyze the N2O and methane emissions from regional agriculture and suggest that best management practice can reduce the burden of environmental emission which may enhance the profitability. In their later work [27], they found that farmers may be asked to find different niches which are profitable and less environmentally troublesome (including GHG). There is a huge pile of literature as we move backward in the literature, however, the work of Zanist et al. [28] differs in a sense that they spot the indirect factors of N2O emissions from headwater streams and the drain fields of agriculture.

2.2. Quantitative Trade-Offs with Data Envelopment Analysis

A plethora of data envelopment analysis (DEA) studies is found in the decision-making units (DMUs). Like many other sectors (banks, hotels, hospitals, and production firms etc.), it has been widely used in the agricultural efficiencies. However, the DEA with trade-off application is rather scarce, and there is further room available for improvement and techniques. There are several DEA studies which contributed to the concept of quantitative trade-offs. Most of them used trade-off for a single measure, i.e., only among two variables, when a change is brought to one variable to see another variable’s effect. Rosen et al. [29] solved the balance between two variables in DEA on the effective boundary. Sueyoshi and Goto [30] used the production method to calculate the trade-off effect, in which a set of variables weighed between them. They use nondiscretionary factors to expand the work of substitution rates. Research by Huang et al. [31] proposed a general method, which changed the rate of change from output to input along the production set’s efficient boundary. Emrouznejad and Yang (2018) [32] revalidated the work of Cooper et al. [33], modified the basic additive DEA model, and used the slack of the result to design an effective trade-off and marginal rate of substitution. Chang et al. [34] also used trade-offs to evaluate the environmental efficiency of transportation. They found better performance considering the greenhouse gases emissions. Watto and Mugera [35] used a trade-off model to estimate the effective use of groundwater. Again, the slacks were used. It turns out that water buyers are not as efficient as pipeline owners.
As mentioned earlier, the above-mentioned work considered the trade-offs among the two variables only. However, our work is related to multivariable trade-off. In our further literature research, there is not much that deals with multiple variables except the few to the best of our knowledge. The work of Miller et al. (2019) [36], tailed by the findings of Mirzaei et al. [10], used elasticity of substitution between input variables. Their paper provide derivatives and parsimonious methods for estimation using DEA. Akbar et al. [37] define the further types of trade-offs among multiple factors and the way to improve the trade-offs. This was followed by their advanced work of identifying the trade-offs using the DEA programs [9] and the statistical methods of performing multivariable trade-offs, conceptually [9]. Considering the work of Miller et al. (2019), we can use support surface bonding with effective boundary points to define different trade-off margins. Such margins do not lose the relative efficiency of the unimproved DMU, but rather promote the weakly efficient DMUs to the best efficiency point. This paper uses the same methodology on rather complex multiple variables with a large amount of data. However, it should be noted that the piecewise linear boundary in DEA technology is not clear in some cases, and the marginal trade-offs of one or more variables can only use a smaller substitution.

3. Model

In this section, we first explain a little the basic model of the slack-based measurement (SBM), then the weighted SBM model is described, which is mainly used for the efficiency measurement of the decision-making units (DMUs), i.e., countries in our case. Next, we explain the trade-off program followed by the marginal trade-offs.

3.1. Slack Based Measurement of DEA

We present here the SBM model to be used with undesirable outputs. The basic model was presented by Ton (2001) [38]. It has two properties, and one is that its unit of the measure remains the same, and another is that it has a monotonous decrease. The following basic program is developed by Tone.
ρ = ( 1 m i = 1 m x i o s i x i o ) ( 1 s r = 1 s y r o + s r + y r o ) 1 .
The ratio ( x i o s i ) / x i o gauges the virtual reduction rate of the input variable i ; therefore, ( 1 / m ) ( x i o s i ) / x i o corresponds to the reduction rate of inputs of the mean proportion. Similarly, the term ( y r o s r + ) / y r o evaluates the proportional expansion rate of the output r and ( 1 / s ) ( y r o + s r + ) / y r o is the mean proportional rate of output. Further, the inputs and outputs can be assigned weights as follows:
ρ = 1 1 m i = 1 m w i s i / x i o 1 + 1 s r = 1 s w r + s r + / y r o ,
where:
ρ = efficiency;
x i o = input variable of unit i ;
y r o = output variable with r ;
s = excesses in inputs;
s + = shortages in outputs; and
r = growth rate.
This choice of weights with i = 1 m w i = m and r = 1 s w r + = s reflect the importance of the input i output r , them being proportional to its average amplitude. Generally, DEA allows more production as outputs with taking relatively fewer inputs, but the further expansion in the SBM program includes the undesirable outputs. The evaluation of the undesirable outputs is different since it also indicates an excessive amount indicating deficiencies. Seiford and Zhu [39] presented the original DEA model in 2002 and used desirable and undesirable output methods. Later, the trade-off (relaxation values) based calculations were modified by Cooper et al. [40]. This method solves the environmental inefficiency by considering undesirable output (such as GHG). One method is to convert the undesired output values to the desired values, but this may result in a misrepresentation of the effective boundary and, therefore, result in a different efficiency score. We, therefore, adopt the undesirable values for our calculations.
Suppose that the n DMUs, each having three factors, are input x , desirable output y g , and undesirable output y b , represented by three vectors x   R m , y g R s 1 , and y b R s 2 , respectively. The matrices X , Y g , and Y b are defined as follows:
X = [ x 1 x n ] R m × n ,
Y g = [ y 1 g y n g ] R n × s 1 ,
Y b = [ y 1 b y n b ] R n × s 2 .
Let us assume that X > 0 , Y g > 0 , and Y b > 0 , then the production possibility set as:
P = { ( x ,   y g ,   y b ) | x X δ , y g Y g δ ,   y b   Y b δ ,   δ 0 } ,
As per the definition of the SBM-undesirable output model, a D M U o   ( x 0 ,   y o g , y o b ) is efficient in the presence of an undesirable output if there is no vector ( x ,   y g ,   y b ) P , such that x 0 x ,   y o g y g , y o b y b . Following this definition, in the case of one input, one good output, and one bad output, the modified SBM of William Cooper et al. is as follows:
ρ = m i n 1 1 m i = 1 m s i x i o 1 +   1 s 1 + s 2 ( r = 1 s 1 s r g y r o g + r = 1 s 2 s r b y r o b ) .
Subjected to
x o = X δ + s ,
y o b = Y b δ + s b ,
y o g = Y g δ s g ,
s ,   s g ,   s b ,   δ   0 .
The function is strictly decreasing when s i ( i ) , s r g ( r ) and s r b ( r ) , and the objective value must be satisfied with the condition 0 < ρ 1 . The vector s R m indicates the excesses in the inputs and s b R s 2 indicates to the excesses in undesirable outputs, while s g R s 1 represents shortages in desirable outputs. In the presence of the undesired output, if D M U o (a decision-making unit) has optimal efficiency ρ = 1 , or we can say if the slacks are equal to zero, i.e., s ,   s g ,   s b = 0 , then the DMUo is called efficient. If the DMUo is inefficienct or if it has low efficiency, i.e.,   ρ < 1 , then it can be improved by reducing excessive inputs and excessive undesirable outputs or increasing the desirable output. The function   ρ is a decreasing function, where   s i / x i o and   s r / b y r o b are bounded by 1, whereas s r g / y r o g is unbounded.
Now, as this paper follows, the above program (7) can be assigned with weights. The weighted ratio of desirable to undesirable output can also be implemented on the SBM-undesirable output model.
ρ = m i n 1 1 m i = 1 m w i s i x i o 1 +   1 s 1 + s 2 ( r = 1 s 1 w r g s r g y r o g + r = 1 s 2 w r b s r b y r o b ) ,
where w i , w r g , and w r b represent the weights to the input i , desirable outputs r , and undesirable outputs r , respectively. Additionally, i = 1 m w i   =   m , w i 0   ( i ) , r = 1 s 1 w r g + r = 1 s 2 w r b = s 1 + s 2 , w r g 0   ( r ) , and w r b 0   ( r ) .

3.2. Model for Trade-Off Balances

Mathematically, the marginal rates (MR) are used to calculate the margins with which trade-offs can be performed. In the multidimensional input and output space, the DEA production possibility set can evaluate agricultural performance without losing mathematical objectivity. By considering a general process, the marginal substitution rate is used, in which the input vector x = x 1 , . , x m R + m . is consumed by the output vector y = y 1 , . , y s R + s . The group of n DMU j :   j = 1 , , n is represented by trade-off vectors z j = ( x j , y j ) t , where x j = x 1 j , , x m j and y j = y 1 j , , y s j are positive vectors and are above zero.
Suppose that the efficient boundary is F ( x , y ) = 0 , we can assume that
δ F ( x , y ) δ x i < 0 i = 1 , , m δ F ( x , y ) δ y r < 0 r = 1 , , s
Assuming that (x, y) is differentiable. Let z o = x o , y o be the efficient frontier; i.e., F ( z o ) = F ( x o , y o = 0 ) . By definition, the trade-off τ at the efficient boundary is as follows:
τ j k + ( z 0 ) = ( δ z j o δ z k o ) z 0 + = lim h 0 + f j ( z 1 o , , z k o + h , , z m + s o ) h τ j k ( z 0 ) = ( δ z j o δ z k o ) z 0 = lim h 0 f j ( z 1 o , , z k o + h , , z m + s o ) h
Asmild et al. [13] gave a program for calculating the trade-off from j to k as mentioned below:
τ j k + ( z 0 ) = z j o z j o h
where z j o is the optimal, efficient point, h is a positive number, and it is the solution to the following linear program:
max z j o s . t . t = 1 n δ t z l t z l o l j , k t = 1 n δ t z j t z j o t = 1 n δ t z k t z k o + h t = 1 n δ t = 1 δ t 1

3.3. Trade-Offs with Desirable and Undesirable Outputs

Assume that managers only focus on the agricultural system’s output without considering explicit inputs (that is, inputs have been regarded as bottlenecks and cannot be reduced). We considered a nonmachine agricultural energy system to make effective trade-offs in need and undesired output. The procedure described below is the same as that designed by Mirzaei et al. [10].
Suppose there are n D M U j :   j = 1 , , n , with two good output vectors y a j = ( y 1 a j , , y s a j ) 0 , y b j = ( y 1 b j , , y s b j ) 0 , and one bad output vector z j = ( z 1 j , ,   z p j ) 0 . By following Shepherd’s [41] assumption, the following linear production technology can be used to solve bad (undesirable) output in the transportation system without the explicit inputs.
T WI = { ( y a , y b , z ) : j = 1 n δ j y a j y a , j = 1 n δ j y b j y b , j = 1 n δ j z j z ,   j = 1 n δ j = θ , 0 θ 1 ,   δ j 0 , j } .
The following linear program using country “o” can be used. min     θ
s . t .     j = 1 n δ j y r a j y r a o ,         r = 1 , , s a j = 1 n δ j y r b j y r b o ,         r = 1 , , s b j = 1 n δ j z p j θ z p o ,         p = 1 , , P j = 1 n δ j = θ 0 θ 1 .   ,   δ j 0 ,   j = 1 , ,   n .
Consider that the bad output is from group N, and sound output belongs to group M. First, we have to choose a small number h (positive number) to solve the linear program problem at the second step.
max p M d p 1 z p + s . t . j = 1 n δ j y r a j y r a o , r = 1 , , s a , r N j = 1 n δ j y raj y rao + h ,   r N j = 1 n δ j y rbj y rbo ,   r = 1 , , s b ,   r N j = 1 n δ j y rbj y rbo + h ,   r N j = 1 n δ j z pj θ z po ,   p = 1 , , P ,   p M j = 1 n δ j z pj z p + ,   p M j = 1 n δ j = θ 0 θ 1 ,   δ j , z p + 0
max p M d p 1 z p + s . t .   j = 1 n δ j y raj y rao ,   r = 1 ,   , s a ,   r N j = 1 n δ j y raj y rao + h ,   r N j = 1 n δ j y rbj y rbo ,   r = 1 , , s b ,   r N j = 1 n δ j y rbj y rbo + h ,   r N j = 1 n δ j z pj θ z po ,   p = 1 , , P ,   p M j = 1 n δ j z pj z p + ,   p M j = 1 n δ j = θ 0 θ 1 ,   δ j , z p + 0
We can calculate the positive and negative trade-off rate by simply replacing -ℎ with ℎ as shown below.
τ p k + ( y a o , y b o , z o ) = z p + z p o h τ p k ( y a o , y b o , z o ) = z p z p o h p M , k N

3.4. Trade-Off Rates

It is assumed that there are objective conditions for basic trade-offs, so when the specific factor increases or even decreases by a small amount, it will determine the extreme change of the specific factor of the output vector. The below program enables us to solve the trade-offs
max z k o s . t . z o T where   z o = ( z 1 o , , z k o + h , , z m + s o )
Notice the new vector above even though it is output or input, and it is increasing function. The above model looks for an effective boundary on which to maximize or minimize a specific variable. However, in any case, the new point is the effective boundary, which is our requirement.

3.5. Illustrative Example

First, the SMB model is applied to the simple dataset in Table 1 of seven decision-making units (DMUs). Then, we show this in Table 2, with two inputs x 1 and x 2 , and one output y 1 , all DMUs are efficient. Mirzaei et al. have used this example with the help of the BCC model. It shows that DMU is useful, but there still exist slacks in the bad output. This makes DMUs weakly efficient, and we want to perform trade-offs which may reduce the bad output to help in getting the optimal efficiency level.
Consider DMUA with z 1 : ( x 11 , x 21 , y 1 ) = ( 0.9 ,   1.63 ,   0.65 ) . The change is needed to x 1 and x 2 when y 1 is changed by 1 unit (i.e., from 0.65 to 0.75). The optimistic method gives a new point on the frontier facet ACE (because in DMUA the four surfaces ABC, ABD, ADE, and ACE have a binding effect), where ( x 11 , x 21 , y 1 ) = ( 1.136 ,   1.704 ,   0.75 ) , where x 11 indicates the first input of the first DMU (i.e., DMU A). The trade-offs rates τ 13 + = 2.364 and τ 23 + = 0.745 are the value change in the first and second input. This change occurs when a single output y 1 increases by 0.1 units. It is worth noting that ( x 11 , x 21 , y 1 ) = ( 1.136 ,   1.704 ,   0.75 ) is the outcome of the following model:
min           z 1 + z 2 s . t .           0.9 δ 1 0.5 δ 2 1.1 δ 3 0.2 δ 4 2.2 δ 5 2.8 δ 6 3 δ 7 z 1 1.63 δ 1 1.36 δ 2 1.55 δ 3 2.15 δ 4 2.04 δ 5 1.4 δ 6 2.04 δ 7 z 2 0.65 δ 1 0.35 δ 2 0.65 δ 3 0.55 δ 4 1.2 δ 5 0.8 δ 6 1.3 δ 7 0.65 + 0.1 δ 1 + δ 2 + δ 3 + δ 4 + δ 5 + δ 6 + δ 7 = 1 δ 1 , δ 2 , δ 3 , δ 4 , δ 5 , δ 6 , δ 7 0
Let all points (i.e., ABC, ABD, and ADE) on the boundary to calculate a new trade-off rate. Changing in the direction would give a new point on a new efficiency frontier. For example, the points ( x 11 , x 21 , y 1 ) = ( 0.815 ,   2.116 ,   0.75 ) are an efficient point of ADE, with trade-offs τ 13 = 0.8462 and τ 23 = 4.8615 . In DMU A , the two trade-off ratios, τ 13 + and τ 23 + indicate that if we increase y1 from 0.65 to 0.75 (see Table 1), and changes are brought to the two inputs (i.e., changed to 1.1364 and 1.7045), DMU A will still stay at the efficient boundary. While τ 13 and τ 23 mean that with ℎ = +0.1, if both the inputs are changed to 0.8154 and 2.1162, respectively, it will remain on the effective boundary. Interestingly, in terms of two different efficient aspects, these two new points have a big difference in them. The point ( x 11 , x 21 , y 1 ) = ( 0.815 ,   2.116 ,   0.75 ) is optimal because of the following program:
min         z 1 + z 2 s . t .         0.9 δ 1 0.5 δ 2 1.1 δ 3 0.2 δ 4 2.2 δ 5 2.8 δ 6 3 δ 7 z 1 1.63 δ 1 1.36 δ 2 1.55 δ 3 2.15 δ 4 2.04 δ 5 1.4 δ 6 2.04 δ 7 z 2 0.65 δ 1 0.35 δ 2 0.65 δ 3 0.55 δ 4 1.2 δ 5 0.8 δ 6 1.3 δ 7 0.65 + 0.1 δ 1 + δ 2 + δ 3 + δ 4 + δ 5 + δ 6 + δ 7 = 1 δ 1 , δ 2 , δ 3 , δ 4 , δ 5 , δ 6 , δ 7 0
Two trade-offs τ 13 + , τ 23 + and τ 13 , τ 23 are calculated (i.e., marginal rate of substitution to throughput N from group M) at an efficient point z o = x o , y o . The following three-step of Mirzaei et al. has been adapted:
  • Decide on the h . This should be a small number for k throughput.
  • Secondly, we solve the two linear program.
    z o +   +   m a x l M d l ( 1 ) z l o s . t .   t = 1 n δ t z t l z l o , l = 1.2 . , m + s t = 1 n δ t = 1 z l o = z l o , l M , N z k o = z k o + h , l N δ t , z l o 0 , t , l
    z o = max l M d l ( 2 ) z l o s . t .   t = 1 n δ t z t l z l o , l = 1.2 . , m + s t = 1 n δ t = 1 z l o = z l o , l M , N z k o = z k o + h , l N δ t , z l o 0 , t , l
    Please note that d l ( 1 ) and d l ( 2 ) are the constant numbers, user-defined.
  • Calculate the trade-off of negative and positive rates from the right, as follows:
    τ j k + ( z o ) = z j o + z j o h τ j k ( z o ) = z j o z j o h j M ,   k N
Trade-offs can be calculated by replacing -ℎ with ℎ. Because both the programs (26) and (25) make projections on the frontier points. Moreover, different trade-offs will result in other weighted vectors d. The weighted vector d is user-defined; it determines the efficient surface direction.

4. Analysis and Discussion

4.1. Efficiency Measuring Variables

Given developing countries, it can be observed from Akbar et al. (2020) [42,43] that the undesirable-outputs in any operations are not separable from the desirable-outputs, i.e., crop production and forest area. Reducing undesirable-output in practice inevitably leads to a reduction in desirable-output variables. Besides, certain undesirable-outputs can have significant effects (inseparable) on specific inputs. For example, emissions of methane and nitrous oxide gases (undesirable-outputs) in agricultural operations are proportional to the forest area and agricultural land area.
To illustrate the trade-offs, we selected the data consist of 136 countries. Here, the latest data set of the year 2019 is composed of multiple outputs and input variables, see Appendix A. For the trade-offs application, only the output variables are considered because the inputs are assumed to have reached the bottleneck in both ways that it cannot be increased or decreased by the managers. Among the four indicators, two are regarded as good-output variables, and two are the bad-output variables. The total crop production in each country is considered the first good-output y 1 g , and the forest area is the second desirable-output y 2 g . It is assumed that the more the forest area a DMU has, the less the area of crop production it utilizes. Not to mention that the crop production symbolizes the soil erosion and other operational activity causing emissions. The undesirable-outputs are methane emissions z 1 b and nitrous oxide emissions z 2 b purely from agricultural activity (considering the nonmachine agricultural operations), which positively correlates the two good-outputs. These indicators also relate to the ecological efficiency of agricultural operations, see Table 3.

4.2. Results and Discussion

The data set was evaluated for the countries’ efficiencies using a program (12), and then we re-evaluated it using the model program (18). The data was taken as a whole without conversion for better analysis. The relative efficiency obtained using the model (12) is listed in Table 4. Countries with efficiency score 1 are fully efficient. We can see that 31 out of 136 countries have appeared efficient (i.e., when DMU = 1).
Suppose M = {1, 2} and N = {1}. We wanted to calculate the effects of the marginal trade-off (i.e., change in the undesirable-outputs, methane emissions z 1 b and nitrous oxide emissions z 2 b ), when applied to the first desirable-output “crop production y 1 g ” and then second desirable-output “forest area y 2 g ”. It is important to note that for all effective countries, ℎ = 0.5 and ℎ = −0.5 proved to be feasible margins. This means that the increase or decrease within the marginal range (i.e., between 0.5 and −0.5) can further improve the macro efficiency due to the reduction in the excessive undesirable-outputs (indirect measures). Additionally, this is of course while maintaining other DMU’s efficiency point on the frontier boundary, even if there is no improvement. In Appendix B, Table A1 and Table A2 show the trade-off effects (of all the 136 countries) on the methane ( z 1 b ) and nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when ℎ = +0.5, 0.5 and d = (1, 1). Here, within the text, only non-zero DMUs will be discussed, and DMUs with zero change are not mentioned (but they can be found in Appendix B).
Now, to explain our experiments concisely, we shall go step by step discussing each bad output separately in order to identify the better trade-off point. Table 5, Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8 show the results of the new value of undesirable outputs ( z 1 b and z 2 b ) when trade-off h = ± 0.5 is applied separately on desirable-outputs y 1 g and y 2 g . The second columns in each resultant table show the trade-off value ( τ ± ) with which trade-off takes place for each DMU.
Now, if we analyze the results in Table 5 when h = +0.5 with d= (1, 1), 67 countries out of 136 showed the trade-off response for methane emission ( z 1 b ). Each good-output ( y 1 g or y 2 g ) is increased individually (one at a time) by 0.5 unit, the excessive bad-output is either increased, decreased, or remained the same. Let us examine three sample DMUs for understanding sake. Table 5 shows that if we increase y 1 g for Austria by 0.5 (i.e., from 89.48 to 89.98), see Table A1 in Appendix A, the methane emission ( z 1 b + ) is reduced to 45.9628 with the trade-off τ 11 + = 0.0018 . However, when y 2 g is increased with h = + 0.5 from 46.99 to 47.49, there is no change observed (i.e., τ 12 + = 0 ), which shows that there exists a lack of forest area. Similarly, when considering Pakistan, z 1 b + is seen with the reduction to 30.4262 with τ 12 + = 0.0306 (when y 1 g is increased from 86.93 to 87.43, see Table A1, Appendix A), while there is no change when the trade-off is applied to y 2 g . In the case of Iraq, there is no change in methane emission z 1 b + , when crop production y 1 g is supposedly increased by h = + 0.5 , i.e., from 84.43 to 83.93 (showing the under-production), but there is an increase in z 1 b + with an increase in y 2 g indicating operational deficiencies i.e., massive soil erosion, etc. It is important to note that the DMUs with an increase in an undesirable-output have a minimal impact. It does not degrade the overall efficiency of those DMUs from their current efficiency point. This is due to the selection of feasible points ( h = + 0.5 ,   0.5 ). The good thing about this trade-off is that there are few DMUs (Bolivia, Madagascar, and UAE, etc.) which improve the efficiency with both undesirable outputs ( y 1 g and y 2 g ). It can easily be seen in Figure 1 that the trade-off in crop production ( y 1 g ) produces better efficiency mostly avoiding the extreme point as compared to the forest area ( y 2 g ).
Next, we look for the effects on methane emissions ( z 1 b ) in Table 6, when the trade-off is applied with h = 0.5 to y 1 g and y 2 g . Again, if we trade-off Austria’s y 1 g with h = 0.5 , i.e., from 49.48 to 48.98, the z 1 b increases minimal with trade-off rate τ 11 = 0.0018 , but it decreases as z 1 b = 45.9624 with trade-off rate τ 12 = 0.0023 when y 2 g is reduced by h = 0.5 (from 46.99 to 46.49). Pakistan’s situation does not fit this trade-off, as it increases or does not change with y 1 g and y 2 g , respectively. In Iraq’s case, it does not make any difference with either reduction (crop production or forest area). Likewise, all the other DMUs can be checked in Table 6. With this trade-off (i.e., when h = 0.5 ), again we found that y 1 g produces a better result as compared to y 2 g (that is when the crop production is improved as compared to the improvement in the forest area), see Figure 2. It does not imply that the area of crop needs to be expanded. Of course, expending crop area will cause more agricultural erosion and maintenance, rather better production techniques for more production with the same crop area is the answer here.
Moving on to the second undesirable-output, the nitrous oxide z 2 b . We again performed the same experiment, when h= +0.5 with d= (1, 1), and the trade-off impact can be seen in Figure 3. However, quantitatively, Table 7 shows that if we increase desirable-output y 1 g for Austria by +0.5 (i.e., from 89.48 to 89.98), see Table A in Appendix A, the nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b + ) are not facing much rise i.e., 38.4120 with trade-off τ 21 + = 0.0006 . However, when y 2 g is increased from 46.99 to 47.49 with h = + 0.5 emissions are reduced to 38.3310 with τ 22 + = 0.0804 , which shows that increasing the forest area would amply reduce the nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b + ). Similarly, when considering Pakistan, there is no effect at all on z 2 b + with either trade-off y 1 g or y 2 g (this is why the DMU “Pakistan” cannot be found in Table 7). In the case of Iraq, again there is no change in nitrous oxide emission z 2 b + , when crop production y 1 g is increased by h = + 0.5 , i.e., from 84.43 to 83.93 or when forest area y 2 g is increased from 1.91 to 2.41, see Table A in Appendix A. The overall efficiency is best seen when the trade-off is applied to y 1 g , it has rather a stable line as compared with y 2 g .
Next, we look for the effects on nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b ) in Table 8, when the trade-off is applied to y 1 g and y 2 g with h = 0.5 . Again, if we trade-off Austria’s y 1 g with h = 0.5 . i.e., from 49.48 to 48.98, the z 2 b decreases to 38.4108 with trade-off rate τ 21 = 0.0006 , but it increases as z 1 b = 38.4927 with trade-off rate τ 12 = 0.0812 when y 2 g is reduced by h = 0.5 (from 46.99 to 46.49), see Table A in Appendix A. Again, Pakistan’s situation does not show any improvement with the trade-off ( h = 0.5 ) to y 1 g and y 2 g , respectively. In Iraq’s case, it again does not make any difference with either reduction (such as crop production and forest area). However, in this trade-off experiment, we found some huge declines in nitrous oxide emissions, such as Iran ( τ 22 = 37.7437 ) and Uzbekistan ( τ 22 = 43.0156 ). Likewise, all the other DMUs can be checked in Table 8. Considering the overall DMUs efficiency (which collectively make a significant contribution to the world ecology), we again find that y 1 g produces a better result as compared to y 2 g (see Figure 4).
Since we applied the same trade-off program with same trade-off margin (i.e., h = ± 0.5 ) to each desirable-output ( y 1 g and y 2 g ) to see the efficient change in each undesirable-output ( z 1 b and z 2 b ), we established at each step that trade-off in y 1 g produced a better result in all four experiments above. Out of the four experiments, two experiments of trade-off h = + 0.5 produced more efficient results among undesirable-outputs ( z 1 b and z 2 b ), see Figure 1 and Figure 3. Now, if we compare it with the original emission values of methane z 1 b and nitrous oxide z 2 b , we can authenticate that trade-off point at h = +0.5 is the optimal trade-off point to achieve indirect efficiency, see Figure 5. There is an improvement in almost all the inefficient countries except those with zero change (Algeria, Angola, and Argentina, etc.). There are no deficiencies to the unchanged DMUs, either they were already at the efficient frontier or below the frontier line. Figure 5 shows the change in emissions in both the methane and the nitrous oxide with trade-off h = 0 to h = + 0.5 . Resultantly, we found that trade-off in the better crop production quantity makes the maximum result out of it. The marginal trade-off is found to be the best and fastest policy action for the majority of the ecological deficiency solutions.

5. Conclusions

Agriculture is becoming the center of concern in terms of food security and ecological betterment. This paper produces unique trade-off methodology unlike the existing trade-offs which uses theoretical logic and hypotheses to hypothesize the maximum change, i.e., when we change one variable, other performance variables will have an impact. However, we used the practical example to the marginal trade-off in the agricultural ecological context.
The DEA weighted slack based measurement was used to analyze the trade-off behavior between undesirable-output variables in terms of efficiencies. We obtained different results from several experiments and found the best efficiency point out of each experiment. It was found that it is possible to get different trade-off margins for each experiment. In our case, 136 developing countries were evaluated for their agro-ecological efficiency, where 31 countries were found efficient. The inefficient countries were further examined with the trade-off model by selecting the marginal range of h = ± 0.5 . The interesting point is that all the values between this margin produced almost the same result. The obtained results prove that the trade-off of h = + 0.5 , in good-output (i.e., crop production y 1 g ) produces efficient results, which means that it not only increases the good-output (which is desirable), but also reduces the undesirable emissions (i.e., methane emission z 1 b and nitrous oxide emissions z 2 b ). This implies that the improved crop production (without increasing the agricultural land area) with effective managerial technique can help in reaching the efficiency frontier boundary. Therefore, we suggest that adopting the crop efficient production technique can yield the best ecological results and also improve the agricultural economic viability.
The results obtained using real numerical data prove this method’s applicability in different agricultural energy efficiency assessments and improvements. This can be very helpful for the policy designers and the decision makers, who are responsible for the resource consumption and production at both the micro and macro level operations. However, this study is made limited to output variables (i.e., two good and two bad variables), which is different from the previous studies. The number of variables adopted in this study is subject to the data availability, therefore indicates the study limitations. Future research can be expanded by considering more output variables or more comprehensive data (including input variables, for example), such as applying marginal trade-offs to more input variables and examining the behavior of alternate output variables to find better results. Moreover, the application research in the conditional DEA method needs to be explored further.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.R. and T.G.J.; methodology, U.A. and M.A.; software, U.A.; formal analysis, U.A.; data curation, A.R.; writing—original draft preparation, A.R., T.G.J. and U.A.; writing—review anediting, J.O. and J.P.; supervision, M.A. and J.O.; project administration, U.A. and M.A.; funding acquisition, J.O. and J.P. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.”

Funding

Project no. 132805 was implemented with support provided from the National Research, Development, and Innovation Fund of Hungary, financed under the K_19 funding scheme and supported by the János Bolyai Research Scholarship of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences.

Data Availability Statement

All the variables and related data is collected from the World Bank (https://data.worldbank.org/). The countries with missing data was eliminated for better results and finally 136 countries were included in the analysis. The Section 4.1 further details the variable collected.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript, or in the decision to publish the results.

Appendix A

The dataset of 136 developing countries. The dataset shows the four inputs namely freshwater consumption ( x 1 ), agricultural land area ( x 2 ), fertilizer consumption ( x 3 ), and total agricultural labor ( x 4 ). Additionally, the four outputs are composed of two desirable-outputs namely production ( y 1 g ) and forest area ( y 2 g ), whereas, the two undesirable-outputs are methane emissions ( z 1 b ) and nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b ).
Table A1. Developing countries.
Table A1. Developing countries.
Country x 1 x 2 x 3 x 4 y 1 g y 2 g z 1 b z 2 b
Afghanistan47.2058.1312.2042.84160.982.0765.5168.93
Albania26.9044.56126.1036.69211.2328.1583.0197.37
Algeria11.3017.6422.309.86202.710.928.0549.48
Angola148.0048.028.0050.38283.9546.0215.0578.09
Antigua and Barbuda0.1020.4513.900.01110.7622.1665.7948.81
Argentina292.0057.8950.300.09149.889.4966.0199.85
Armenia6.9064.60110.5029.64173.6711.6421.5792.19
Australia492.0047.3568.102.56115.6815.9152.2693.26
Austria55.0031.95141.803.5889.4846.9946.4166.86
Azerbaijan8.1057.8114.1035.87129.6014.9235.0781.19
Bahamas, The0.701.47144.002.14162.4451.451.3930.85
Bangladesh105.0069.56289.4038.58167.2610.9063.5686.05
Barbados0.1023.67113.802.6347.8314.6518.3232.92
Belarus34.0041.95146.6011.02114.4643.0148.3871.53
Belgium12.0043.38318.500.9694.7822.7574.2030.75
Belize15.307.16466.2016.85100.1958.8852.5969.22
Benin10.3033.9114.7038.58169.6836.6549.2574.39
Bhutan78.0013.4913.3055.31118.4074.5330.0338.69
Bolivia303.5035.127.6030.71166.5949.1039.9083.99
Bosnia and Herzegovina35.5042.55131.8015.38107.6042.6841.1894.47
Botswana2.4045.7689.6020.69130.6518.3875.41#####
Brunei Darussalam8.503.04141.801.3697.7470.900.1443.09
Bulgaria21.0044.94125.506.39126.5536.438.0855.74
Burkina Faso12.5046.9821.8025.23159.8218.7778.8185.75
Burundi10.1080.185.4092.02105.2712.5514.6154.39
Cambodia120.6032.0317.4032.30286.4850.8669.1825.64
Cameroon273.0021.209.7043.44219.2938.1559.8287.96
Central African Republic141.008.090.3077.32123.0535.4974.0491.89
Chile885.0021.35293.809.00119.2324.1834.7258.16
Congo, Dem. Rep.900.0011.662.5065.43113.1866.7621.8145.92
Congo, Rep.222.0031.191.8034.13138.2065.2419.4374.21
Costa Rica113.0034.68604.9012.11141.5256.0163.0179.62
Cote d’Ivoire76.8066.2851.7040.05135.1932.7616.5830.39
Croatia37.7029.23119.305.96132.2934.5717.8852.04
Cuba38.1059.3349.4017.5179.0233.0458.8072.12
Cyprus0.8010.87196.702.0752.6418.7240.5353.24
Czech Republic13.2044.99196.102.72113.7234.6529.3886.88
Denmark6.0062.07131.102.19111.0414.8559.01#####
Dominica0.2035.4188.100.01117.4456.4458.3247.09
Dominican Republic23.5047.7888.109.02177.4344.3953.2474.37
Ecuador442.4023.86345.4029.20123.3149.3365.4984.55
Egypt, Arab Rep.1.803.90649.2023.79128.620.0827.9466.12
El Salvador15.6076.08132.4016.28115.1312.0650.7474.16
Eritrea2.8075.472.8061.2181.2514.7866.9883.04
Estonia12.7024.85112.703.18197.2551.1619.6570.36
Ethiopia122.0038.8514.4066.13232.0912.0065.8487.96
Fiji28.6023.1946.0036.2667.6455.8479.1189.39
Finland107.007.5580.503.6195.1973.0915.2735.38
France200.0051.87163.102.4496.0631.9241.7081.26
Gabon164.0020.0326.8032.83135.5089.453.1716.28
Gambia, The3.0065.041.2027.12107.1348.9853.4985.37
Georgia58.1032.25170.8041.8269.5541.0341.3650.19
Germany107.0047.45197.201.21103.5932.7954.1655.19
Ghana30.3071.1620.9029.26175.8341.5536.1495.20
Greece58.0046.46123.0011.9885.0332.4736.8065.00
Guatemala109.2032.28303.2031.49188.6431.5148.8460.83
Guinea226.0060.191.6061.74147.0925.3547.4861.37
Guyana241.008.5144.6017.14131.4083.8572.1487.35
Honduras90.7029.65164.3030.26146.4237.6873.6669.59
Hungary6.0055.52128.304.7089.2823.3024.76#####
Iceland170.0018.61181.503.9496.940.5754.9786.42
Iran, Islamic Rep.128.5024.2376.3017.95111.136.7819.2980.02
Iraq35.2020.7635.8018.1084.431.9114.3733.34
Israel0.8023.93280.700.92103.317.6532.1162.06
Italy182.5042.56129.803.6888.8732.5035.3378.07
Jamaica10.8039.6357.2015.93102.4430.8148.0244.59
Japan430.0012.07242.203.4285.3068.5474.6230.71
Jordan0.7011.88112.003.08151.591.0916.8580.20
Kazakhstan64.4080.894.3015.80166.321.2218.35#####
Kenya20.7049.1738.2054.44151.838.1951.5288.58
Korea, Rep.64.9017.08380.304.8890.9663.0433.5080.50
Kuwait0.008.52750.702.01245.800.381.5423.55
Kyrgyz Republic48.9054.5431.4021.17114.912.9268.1886.83
Latvia16.9032.50104.206.75181.4854.6715.0595.64
Lebanon4.8065.88330.9013.6192.8613.5825.9182.48
Lithuania15.5047.32131.906.87204.6035.6323.1234.02
Luxembourg1.0054.56262.101.0177.0835.6883.5158.98
North Macedonia5.4047.3079.3015.38131.4140.4037.2370.64
Madagascar337.0071.705.2064.22136.7021.1163.35#####
Malawi16.1065.9721.6043.65199.3032.1332.1988.20
Maldives0.0022.12314.908.4754.673.330.6024.95
Mali60.0034.4144.2062.59197.213.6478.1377.10
Malta0.1032.43264.600.99102.311.0916.7654.44
Mauritius2.8039.98235.306.0776.8718.6514.1853.39
Mexico409.0054.88114.0012.61131.1933.7246.8673.72
Moldova1.6073.6524.4035.9399.9713.2316.1172.61
Mongolia34.8070.0040.0027.42362.878.6194.48#####
Morocco29.0068.3171.1034.69143.0313.1846.8576.83
Mozambique100.3064.353.7070.33185.4047.1927.3026.38
Namibia6.2047.1326.1022.13128.338.0890.2597.74
Nepal198.2028.3774.1065.00155.0024.9479.9976.31
Netherlands11.0053.16288.902.04112.4611.3343.8677.92
Nicaragua156.2041.2761.5030.65143.1023.9370.5886.48
Niger3.5038.800.4075.06266.680.8740.6671.34
Nigeria221.0077.525.5035.10122.326.5733.2590.05
Norway382.002.64203.902.0690.6033.177.8761.94
Oman1.404.80468.104.56151.710.015.7154.98
Pakistan55.0046.63144.3036.66125.411.7457.1178.92
Panama136.6030.5149.1013.9586.9361.2474.9776.40
Papua New Guinea801.002.87112.1058.32133.1374.0812.0927.33
Paraguay117.0057.43110.3020.13198.4136.3282.74#####
Philippines479.0043.67157.4023.41124.1326.7855.1580.24
Poland53.6044.05172.809.23114.3731.1721.9856.24
Portugal38.0038.98199.405.85112.0034.2627.0959.44
Romania42.4058.1059.9021.7197.2530.2130.7663.40
Rwanda9.5073.9810.9062.41185.0221.6332.5083.92
Saudi Arabia2.4080.64176.902.4072.520.455.9843.69
Senegal25.8047.2616.4030.05176.8242.1563.8487.55
Slovak Republic12.6037.07125.802.1899.4340.4828.1432.72
Slovenia18.7034.12258.905.2383.1262.1828.0572.78
South Africa44.8079.3658.505.09118.097.6224.9171.23
Spain111.2051.00144.004.09106.5138.0458.8365.86
Sri Lanka52.8046.50131.9024.52142.6632.5956.8160.84
St. Kitts and Nevis0.0019.780.500.0014.9442.3123.3952.95
St. Lucia0.3015.97170.9017.2738.5932.9044.7536.60
Suriname99.000.55217.707.52185.1198.1867.90#####
Sweden171.007.3396.301.65116.4068.8724.6661.85
Switzerland40.4038.13214.402.9597.9732.1558.5360.35
Tajikistan63.5034.6781.4044.92181.472.9660.3592.60
Tanzania84.0047.4312.6065.31221.6150.3557.9988.34
Thailand224.5045.17161.7031.61133.6531.8454.8566.14
Togo11.5073.0311.0037.70152.452.7628.0966.29
Trinidad and Tobago3.8010.07356.002.9746.3745.250.2686.63
Tunisia4.2065.4559.3013.03135.067.1422.2479.08
Turkey227.0048.36137.7018.38122.2915.8223.8571.90
Uganda39.0075.721.9072.6775.508.8856.6691.70
Ukraine55.1071.6052.7014.48200.8516.6813.0333.77
United Arab Emirates0.204.52714.901.4145.194.595.6732.76
United Kingdom145.0071.81252.901.03103.4313.1746.4563.12
Uruguay92.2081.24143.708.12232.2011.5892.7694.71
Uzbekistan16.3062.57232.7023.92187.107.5921.5795.29
Venezuela, RB805.0024.50183.508.3198.6252.3938.6871.47
Vietnam359.4040.77429.8037.36151.6851.0053.5083.41
Yemen, Rep.2.1044.5316.4028.98142.451.0435.2964.11
Zambia80.2032.7089.6048.84237.0464.5648.9863.47
Zimbabwe12.3042.7822.9066.5496.1833.6466.6391.40

Appendix B

Table A2. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) and nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when ℎ = +0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Table A2. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) and nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when ℎ = +0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Methane Emissions z 1 b Nitrous Oxide Emissions z 2 b
D M U j w.r.t y 1 w.r.t y 2 w.r.t y 1 w.r.t y 2
z 1 b + τ 11 + z 1 b + τ 12 + z 2 b + τ 21 + z 2 b + τ 22 +
Afghanistan11.40420.007111.39710.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Albania34.34140.182634.15880.000037.22370.127437.09630.0000
Algeria0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Angola0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Antigua/Barbuda0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Argentina0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Armenia0.00000.00000.00000.000016.56790.058416.50950.0000
Australia0.00000.00000.00000.000049.3246−0.003449.32800.0000
Austria45.9628−0.001845.96690.002338.41200.000638.3310−0.0804
Azerbaijan0.00000.00000.00000.000011.0237−0.007311.03100.0000
Bahamas0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bangladesh62.13030.000162.13020.000054.28840.002854.28560.0000
Barbados0.00000.00000.00000.00008.4088−0.02188.1748−0.2558
Belarus43.23440.012443.1816−0.040440.80510.015440.7027−0.0871
Belgium43.69600.058743.63730.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Belize51.00520.000051.00720.001933.91640.000033.95930.0429
Benin14.38680.066714.57690.25680.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bhutan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bolivia20.7527−0.000720.7518−0.001515.41150.000515.4105−0.0004
Bosnia/Herzegovina34.95130.012234.8993−0.039762.58390.015162.4832−0.0856
Botswana0.00000.00000.00000.000046.69130.015746.67560.0000
Brunei Darussalam0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bulgaria7.0032−0.00097.00420.000031.6801−0.020931.70100.0000
Burkina Faso0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Burundi0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Cambodia0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Cameroon0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Central African0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Chile33.6971−0.001133.69820.000035.4870−0.025235.51220.0000
Congo, Dem. Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Congo, Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Costa Rica61.9982−0.000161.99840.000145.86740.000045.8621−0.0053
Cote d’Ivoire12.0108−0.004212.01770.00273.4436−0.02603.48970.0201
Croatia16.7472−0.000816.74800.000026.9003−0.017626.91790.0000
Cuba5.52150.02405.51430.016916.98630.009417.03080.0540
Cyprus40.02640.000040.0179−0.008542.00920.000041.8203−0.1889
Czech Republic28.4054−0.001328.40670.000065.2515−0.028465.27990.0000
Denmark0.00000.00000.00000.000058.9339−0.002958.93690.0000
Dominica0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Dominican Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.000018.44750.040318.40720.0000
Ecuador64.6114−0.001064.61350.001254.81780.000354.7752−0.0423
Egypt, Arab Rep.26.8410−0.000926.84190.000041.6727−0.019741.69240.0000
El Salvador0.00000.00000.00000.000030.9759−0.004430.98020.0000
Eritrea28.15640.009028.14740.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Estonia0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Ethiopia0.00000.00000.00000.000014.4607−0.066424.843910.3167
Fiji52.9460−0.007752.97800.024321.70640.013421.75050.0575
Finland0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
France0.00000.00000.00000.000039.49010.000739.4550−0.0344
Gabon0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Gambia, The12.89580.036712.97960.12060.43880.06420.65420.2795
Georgia40.25710.000040.2544−0.002725.58480.000025.5247−0.0601
Germany0.00000.00000.00000.000010.6484−0.020510.67610.0072
Ghana7.17470.01427.36370.20324.80270.09075.15140.4394
Greece32.67850.032232.5415−0.104841.50200.039941.2363−0.2258
Guatemala47.23160.000747.23090.000025.01760.015325.00230.0000
Guinea18.73370.002918.74880.01800.00000.00000.00000.0000
Guyana0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Honduras72.4080−0.000472.40840.000041.7701−0.009341.77950.0000
Hungary0.00000.00000.00000.000088.6208−0.030988.65170.0000
Iceland54.82330.000054.82340.000043.6784−0.001843.68020.0000
Iran, Islamic Rep.17.4403−0.007717.44800.000057.3186−0.044157.36270.0000
Iraq0.00000.00005.33875.33870.00000.00000.00000.0000
Israel0.00000.00000.00000.000028.9126−0.019828.93240.0000
Italy0.00000.00000.00000.000035.70600.004235.6679−0.0339
Jamaica3.9368−0.00253.95950.02020.00000.00000.00000.0000
Japan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Jordan0.00000.00000.00000.000044.63340.000544.63290.0000
Kazakhstan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Kenya0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Korea, Rep.33.3108−0.000733.31230.000842.20380.000242.1734−0.0302
Kuwait0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Kyrgyz Republic0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Latvia0.58980.01500.69660.121834.24980.068634.44480.2636
Lebanon25.1189−0.001825.12070.000064.8009−0.040564.84150.0000
Lithuania0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Luxembourg30.28110.036730.27030.02591.14640.01451.21450.0826
North Macedonia5.98490.01475.97810.007928.22800.006428.24860.0269
Madagascar32.1777−0.001932.1732−0.006440.0645−0.003440.0531−0.0148
Malawi7.43080.01247.59670.17833.19140.07963.49740.3856
Maldives0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Mali0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Malta0.00000.00000.00000.00008.31590.00858.30750.0000
Mauritius13.5227−0.002213.52500.000038.7434−0.049938.79320.0000
Mexico0.00000.00000.00000.000027.9968−0.003328.02640.0264
Moldova0.00000.00000.00000.000039.0884−0.009039.0082−0.0892
Mongolia6.3483−0.54136.88950.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Morocco0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Mozambique0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Namibia1.33880.21131.12750.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Nepal74.4329−0.002974.43750.001843.0448−0.017743.07620.0137
Netherlands0.00000.00000.00000.000038.1764−0.009038.18540.0000
Nicaragua52.32810.004052.38190.057824.39670.025824.49590.1250
Niger0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Nigeria0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Norway7.1694−0.00287.17560.003441.98040.000941.8580−0.1215
Oman4.4126−0.00034.41280.000026.1590−0.006326.16520.0000
Pakistan30.4262−0.030630.45680.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Panama19.09530.093318.8226−0.17940.00000.00000.00000.0000
Papua New Guinea0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Paraguay0.00000.00000.00000.000031.87610.065331.7728−0.0381
Philippines54.0918−0.001054.09280.000056.6386−0.022356.66090.0000
Poland21.0054−0.001321.00660.000034.4932−0.028034.52120.0000
Portugal26.1282−0.001326.12950.000038.1376−0.029438.16700.0000
Romania0.00000.00000.00000.00005.69610.01545.75700.0763
Rwanda0.00000.00000.00000.000011.45510.026111.54630.1173
Saudi Arabia0.00000.00000.00000.000018.3427−0.029518.37220.0000
Senegal31.81840.069131.99670.24750.00000.00000.00000.0000
Slovak Republic21.74000.016021.6718−0.05221.85770.01981.7255−0.1124
Slovenia26.37910.000026.38190.002835.50020.000035.56210.0619
South Africa0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Spain0.00000.00000.00000.00005.7476−0.01395.87350.1120
Sri Lanka55.5878−0.000555.58830.000033.7308−0.011533.74230.0000
St. Kitts and Nevis0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
St. Lucia31.64280.024731.5377−0.08041.73240.03061.5287−0.1732
Suriname0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Sweden0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Switzerland57.7132−0.002757.71920.003341.05460.000940.9359−0.1179
Tajikistan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Tanzania0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Thailand52.6556−0.004452.67080.010938.9072−0.026738.95280.0189
Togo0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Trinidad, Tobago0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Tunisia0.00000.00000.00000.00008.89940.03888.86060.0000
Turkey22.8057−0.001122.80670.000048.6553−0.023448.67870.0000
Uganda14.32030.012340.705526.39740.00000.000061.196261.1962
Ukraine0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
UAE5.3534−0.00245.3531−0.002827.0438−0.037426.9642−0.1170
United Kingdom0.00000.00000.00000.000023.7600−0.013323.77330.0000
Uruguay0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Uzbekistan19.97240.000619.97170.000059.76680.014459.75240.0000
Venezuela, RB38.2000−0.001338.20280.001639.75250.000439.6965−0.0556
Vietnam52.2606−0.000352.26120.000352.78450.000152.7732−0.0112
Yemen, Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Zambia35.7680−0.018435.80490.01840.00000.00000.00000.0000
Zimbabwe35.32270.007935.34080.025927.07980.013827.12610.0601
Table A3. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) and nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when ℎ = 0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Table A3. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) and nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when ℎ = 0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Methane Emissions z 1 b Nitrous Oxide Emissions z 2 b
D M U j w.r.t y 1 w.r.t y 2 w.r.t y 1 w.r.t y 2
z 1 τ 11 z 1 τ 12 z 2 τ 21 z 2 τ 22
Afghanistan11.3900−0.007111.39710.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Albania33.9745−0.184334.15880.000036.9676−0.128737.09630.0000
Algeria0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Angola0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Antigua, Barbuda0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Argentina0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Armenia0.00000.00000.00000.000016.4509−0.058616.50950.0000
Australia0.00000.00000.00000.000049.33140.003449.32800.0000
Austria45.96650.001845.9624−0.002338.4108−0.000638.49270.0812
Azerbaijan0.00000.00000.00000.000011.03840.007311.03100.0000
Bahamas, The0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bangladesh62.1300−0.000162.13020.000054.2828−0.002854.28560.0000
Barbados0.00000.00000.00000.00008.45240.02198.70390.2734
Belarus43.2096−0.012443.26340.041440.7744−0.015440.87900.0892
Belgium43.5784−0.058943.63730.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Belize51.00520.000051.0033−0.002033.91640.000033.8727−0.0437
Benin14.2538−0.066414.0673−0.25280.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bhutan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bolivia20.75410.000720.75490.001515.4104−0.000515.41130.0004
Bosnia, Herzegovina34.9269−0.012234.97980.040762.5537−0.015162.65650.0877
Botswana0.00000.00000.00000.000046.6598−0.015846.67560.0000
Brunei Darussalam0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bulgaria7.00510.00097.00420.000031.72210.021031.70100.0000
Burkina Faso0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Burundi0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Cambodia0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Cameroon0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Central African Rep0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Chile33.69930.001133.69820.000035.53760.025335.51220.0000
Congo, Dem. Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Congo, Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Costa Rica61.99840.000161.9981−0.000145.86730.000045.87260.0053
Cote d’Ivoire12.01930.004312.0124−0.00273.49580.02623.4495−0.0202
Croatia16.74880.000816.74800.000026.93550.017726.91790.0000
Cuba5.4733−0.02415.4802−0.017316.9674−0.009516.9217−0.0552
Cyprus40.02640.000040.03510.008742.00920.000042.20180.1926
Czech Republic28.40800.001328.40670.000065.30850.028665.27990.0000
Denmark0.00000.00000.00000.000058.93980.002958.93690.0000
Dominica0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Dominican Republic0.00000.00000.00000.000018.3667−0.040518.40720.0000
Ecuador64.61330.001064.6111−0.001254.8172−0.000354.86020.0427
Egypt, Arab Rep.26.84280.000926.84190.000041.71220.019841.69240.0000
El Salvador0.00000.00000.00000.000030.98460.004430.98020.0000
Eritrea28.1384−0.009028.14740.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Estonia0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Ethiopia0.00000.00000.00000.000024.962710.435614.52710.0000
Fiji52.96140.007752.9291−0.024521.6796−0.013421.6349−0.0581
Finland0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
France0.00000.00000.00000.000039.4887−0.000739.52410.0347
Gabon0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Gambia, The12.8221−0.036912.7357−0.12330.3101−0.06450.0887−0.2859
Georgia40.25710.000040.25990.002825.58480.000025.64610.0613
Germany0.00000.00000.00000.000010.68970.020810.6618−0.0072
Ghana7.1463−0.01426.9528−0.20774.6209−0.09114.2629−0.4492
Greece32.6142−0.032132.75370.107441.4223−0.039841.69340.2313
Guatemala47.2302−0.000747.23090.000024.9869−0.015425.00230.0000
Guinea18.7279−0.002918.7129−0.01790.00000.00000.00000.0000
Guyana0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Honduras72.40880.000472.40840.000041.78890.009441.77950.0000
Hungary0.00000.00000.00000.000088.68280.031188.65170.0000
Iceland54.82340.000054.82340.000043.68200.001843.68020.0000
Iran, Islamic Rep.17.45580.00780.0000−17.448057.40690.044319.6190−37.7437
Iraq0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Israel0.00000.00000.00000.000028.95230.019928.93240.0000
Italy0.00000.00000.00000.000035.6976−0.004235.73640.0346
Jamaica3.94170.00253.9190−0.02030.00000.00000.00000.0000
Japan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Jordan0.00000.00000.00000.000044.6324−0.000544.63290.0000
Kazakhstan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Kenya0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Korea, Rep.33.31220.000733.3106−0.000942.2033−0.000242.23400.0305
Kuwait0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Kyrgyz Republic0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Latvia0.5596−0.01510.4502−0.124534.1123−0.069033.9119−0.2694
Lebanon25.12250.001825.12070.000064.88230.040864.84150.0000
Lithuania0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Luxembourg30.2075−0.036930.2180−0.02641.1175−0.01451.0476−0.0844
North Macedonia5.9554−0.01485.9622−0.008128.2153−0.006428.1942−0.0275
Madagascar32.18150.001932.18610.006540.07120.003440.08290.0151
Malawi7.4059−0.01257.2361−0.18233.0319−0.07992.7177−0.3941
Maldives0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Mali0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Malta0.00000.00000.00000.00008.2990−0.00858.30750.0000
Mauritius13.52720.002313.52500.000038.84340.050238.79320.0000
Mexico0.00000.00000.00000.000028.00330.003327.9731−0.0269
Moldova0.00000.00000.00000.000039.10640.009039.18790.0905
Mongolia7.43020.54066.88950.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Morocco0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Mozambique0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Namibia0.9161−0.21151.12750.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Nepal74.43860.002974.4339−0.001843.08030.017843.0488−0.0137
Netherlands0.00000.00000.00000.000038.19450.009138.18540.0000
Nicaragua52.3201−0.004052.2650−0.059124.3450−0.025924.2431−0.1278
Niger0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Nigeria0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Norway7.17490.00287.1687−0.003541.9786−0.000942.10220.1227
Oman4.41310.00034.41280.000026.17150.006326.16520.0000
Pakistan30.48750.030730.45680.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Panama18.9085−0.093519.18220.18020.00000.00000.00000.0000
Papua New Guinea0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Paraguay0.00000.00000.00000.000031.7452−0.065631.84910.0382
Philippines54.09380.001054.09280.000056.68330.022556.66090.0000
Poland21.00790.001321.00660.000034.54940.028234.52120.0000
Portugal26.13080.001326.12950.000038.19660.029638.16700.0000
Romania0.00000.00000.00000.00005.6652−0.01555.6028−0.0780
Rwanda0.00000.00000.00000.000011.4028−0.026211.3085−0.1206
Saudi Arabia0.00000.00005.35885.358818.40180.029629.914011.5419
Senegal31.6801−0.069231.5000−0.24920.00000.00000.00000.0000
Slovak Republic21.7080−0.016021.77740.05351.8180−0.01981.95300.1151
Slovenia26.37910.000026.3763−0.002835.50020.000035.4371−0.0631
South Africa0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Spain0.00000.00000.00000.00005.77540.01395.6474−0.1141
Sri Lanka55.58880.000555.58830.000033.75390.011633.74230.0000
St. Kitts and Nevis0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
St. Lucia31.5935−0.024631.70050.08241.6713−0.03051.87930.1774
Suriname0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Sweden0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Switzerland57.71860.002757.7125−0.003441.0528−0.000941.17280.1191
Tajikistan0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Tanzania0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Thailand52.66430.004452.6490−0.010938.96070.026838.9149−0.0190
Togo0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Trinidad and Tobago0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Tunisia0.00000.00000.00000.00008.8217−0.03898.86060.0000
Turkey22.80780.001122.80670.000048.70230.023548.67870.0000
Uganda14.2958−0.012314.30810.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Ukraine0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
United Arab Emirates5.35830.00255.35890.003027.11870.037627.20350.1223
United Kingdom0.00000.00000.00000.000023.78670.013423.77330.0000
Uruguay0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Uzbekistan19.9711−0.00060.0000−19.971759.7380−0.014516.7369−43.0156
Venezuela, RB38.20250.001338.1997−0.001639.7516−0.000439.80820.0562
Vietnam52.26110.000352.2606−0.000352.7843−0.000152.79570.0113
Yemen, Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
Zambia35.80490.018435.7679−0.01860.00000.00000.00000.0000
Zimbabwe35.3069−0.007935.2883−0.026527.0521−0.013927.0044−0.0615

References

  1. Ivanic, M.; Martin, W. Sectoral productivity growth and poverty reduction: National and global impacts. World Dev. 2018, 109, 429–439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Picazo-Tadeo, A.J.; Gómez-Limón, J.A.; Reig-Martínez, E. Assessing farming eco-efficiency: A data envelopment analysis approach. J. Environ. Manag. 2011, 92, 1154–1164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Liu, L.-C.; Wu, G. The effects of carbon dioxide, methane and nitrous oxide emission taxes: An empirical study in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 142, 1044–1054. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Le Quéré, C.; Andrew, R.; Canadell, J.G.; Sitch, S.; Korsbakken, J.I.; Peters, G.P.; Manning, A.C.; Boden, T.A.; Tans, P.P.; Houghton, R.A. Global carbon budget 2016. Earth Syst. Sci. Data 2016, 8, 605–649. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Klapwijk, C.J.; Van Wijk, M.T.; Rosenstock, T.S.; van Asten, P.J.A.; Thornton, P.K.; Giller, K.E. Analysis of trade-offs in agricultural systems: Current status and way forward. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain. 2014, 6, 110–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Ndiaye, M.; Adam, M.; Ganyo, K.K.; Guissé, A.; Cissé, N.; Muller, B. Genotype-environment interaction: Trade-offs between the agronomic performance and stability of dual-purpose sorghum (Sorghum bicolor L. Moench) genotypes in Senegal. Agronomy 2019, 9, 867. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Kanter, D.R.; Musumba, M.; Wood, S.L.R.; Palm, C.; Antle, J.; Balvanera, P.; Dale, V.H.; Havlik, P.; Kline, K.L.; Scholes, R.J. Evaluating agricultural trade-offs in the age of sustainable development. Agric. Syst. 2018, 163, 73–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Da Silveira, G.; Slack, N. Exploring the trade-off concept. Int. J. Oper. Prod. Manag. 2001, 21, 949–964. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Akbar, U.; Fan, R.N.; Li, Q.L. A route option for different commodity groups in international trade: China Pakistan economic corridor. In Communications in Computer and Information Science; Springer Nature: Singapore, 2019; Volume 1102, pp. 446–464. [Google Scholar]
  10. Mirzaei, M.; Kordrostami, S.; Amirteimoori, A.; Chegini, M.G. Alternative trade-offs in data envelopment analysis: An application to hydropower plants. Math. Probl. Eng. 2016, 2016, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Khoshandam, L.; Amirteimoori, A.; Matin, R.K. Marginal rates of substitution in the presence of non-discretionary factors: A data envelopment analysis approach. Measurement 2014, 58, 409–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Atici, K.B.; Podinovski, V. V Using data envelopment analysis for the assessment of technical efficiency of units with different specialisations: An application to agriculture. Omega 2015, 54, 72–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Asmild, M.; Paradi, J.C.; Reese, D.N. Theoretical perspectives of trade-off analysis using DEA. Omega 2006, 34, 337–343. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Krivonozhko, V.E.; Utkin, O.B.; Volodin, A.V.; Sablin, I.A.; Patrin, M. Constructions of economic functions and calculations of marginal rates in DEA using parametric optimization methods. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2004, 55, 1049–1058. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Loizou, E.; Karelakis, C.; Galanopoulos, K.; Mattas, K. The role of agriculture as a development tool for a regional economy. Agric. Syst. 2019, 173, 482–490. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Oláh, J.; Aburumman, N.; Popp, J.; Khan, M.A.; Haddad, H.; Kitukutha, N. Impact of Industry 4.0 on environmental sustainability. Sustainability 2020, 12, 4674. [Google Scholar]
  17. Gružauskas, V.; Baskutis, S.; Navickas, V. Minimizing the trade-off between sustainability and cost effective performance by using autonomous vehicles. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 184, 709–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Shahbazpour, M.; Seidel, R. Strategic manufacturing system and process innovation through elimination of trade-offs. Int. J. Comput. Integr. Manuf. 2007, 20, 413–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Pratt, C.; Kingston, K.; Laycock, B.; Levett, I.; Pratt, S. Geo-agriculture: Reviewing opportunities through which the geosphere can help address emerging crop production challenges. Agronomy 2020, 10, 971. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Akbar, U.; Li, Q.L.; Akmal, M.A.; Shakib, M.; Iqbal, W. Nexus between agro-ecological efficiency and carbon emission transfer: Evidence from China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. Int. 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bosco, S.; Volpi, I.; Antichi, D.; Ragaglini, G.; Frasconi, C. Greenhouse gas emissions from soil cultivated with vegetables in crop rotation under Integrated, organic and organic conservation management in a mediterranean environment. Agronomy 2019, 9, 446. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Shen, J.; Melaku, N.D.; Treu, R.; Wang, J. Inventories of methane and nitrous oxide emissions from animal and crop farms of 69 municipalities in Alberta, Canada. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 234, 895–911. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Yue, Q.; Wu, H.; Sun, J.; Cheng, K.; Smith, P.; Hillier, J.; Xu, X.; Pan, G. Deriving emission factors and estimating direct nitrous oxide emissions for crop cultivation in China. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2019, 53, 10246–10257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  24. Tang, H.-M.; Xiao, X.-P.; Wang, K.; Li, W.-Y.; Liu, J.; Sun, J.-M. Methane and nitrous oxide emissions as affected by long-term fertilizer management from double-cropping paddy fields in Southern China. J. Agric. Sci. 2016, 154, 1378–1391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Audet, J.; Bastviken, D.; Bundschuh, M.; Buffam, I.; Feckler, A.; Klemedtsson, L.; Laudon, H.; Löfgren, S.; Natchimuthu, S.; Öquist, M. Forest streams are important sources for nitrous oxide emissions. Glob. Chang. Biol. 2020, 26, 629–641. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Wysocka-Czubaszek, A.; Czubaszek, R.; Roj-Rojewski, S.; Banaszuk, P. Methane and nitrous oxide emissions from agriculture on a regional scale. J. Ecol. Eng. 2018, 19, 206–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Wysocka-Czubaszek, A.; Banaszuk, P.; Czubaszek, R. Methane and nitrous oxide emissions from agriculture in the Podlaskie voivodeship in years 1999–2015. Pol. J. Nat. Sci 2018, 33, 433–453. [Google Scholar]
  28. Hama-Aziz, Z.Q.; Hiscock, K.M.; Cooper, R.J. Indirect nitrous oxide emission factors for agricultural field drains and headwater streams. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2017, 51, 301–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Rosen, D.; Schaffnit, C.; Paradi, J.C. Marginal rates and two-dimensional level curves in DEA. J. Product. Anal. 1998, 9, 205–232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Sueyoshi, T.; Goto, M. Returns to scale, damages to scale, marginal rate of transformation and rate of substitution in DEA environmental assessment. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 905–917. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Huang, Z.; Li, S.X.; Rousseau, J.J. Determining rates of change in data envelopment analysis. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 1997, 48, 591–599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Emrouznejad, A.; Yang, G. A survey and analysis of the first 40 years of scholarly literature in DEA: 1978–2016. Socioecon. Plann. Sci. 2018, 61, 4–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Cooper, W.W.; Park, K.S.; Pastor Ciurana, J.T. Marginal rates and elasticities of substitution with additive models in DEA. J. Product. Anal. 2000, 13, 105–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Chang, Y.T.; Zhang, N.; Danao, D.; Zhang, N. Environmental efficiency analysis of transportation system in China: A non-radial DEA approach. Energy Policy 2013, 58, 277–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Watto, M.A.; Mugera, A.W. Irrigation water demand and implications for groundwater pricing in Pakistan. Water Policy 2016, 18, 565–585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Miller, N.J.; Bergtold, J.S.; Featherstone, A.M. Economic elasticities of input substitution using data envelopment analysis. PLoS ONE 2019, 14, e0220478. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  37. Akbar, U.; Kumar, A.; Khan, H.; Khan, M.A.; Parvaiz, K.; Oláh, J. Trade-offs in competitive transport operations. Economies 2020, 8, 56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Tone, K. Slacks-based measure of efficiency in data envelopment analysis. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2001, 130, 498–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Seiford, L.M.; Zhu, J. Modeling undesirable factors in efficiency evaluation. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2002, 142, 16–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Cooper, W.W.; Seiford, L.M.; Tone, K. Data Envelopment Analysis: A Comprehensive Text with Models, Applications, References and DEA-Solver Software, 2nd ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2007; ISBN 0387452818. [Google Scholar]
  41. Shephard, R.W. Theory of Cost and Production Functions; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2015; ISBN 9781400871087. [Google Scholar]
  42. Akbar, U.; Khan, M.A.; Akmal, M.; Tóth Naárné, É.Z.; Oláh, J. Trade-offs for the optimal energy efficiency of road transportation: Domestic cases in developing countries. Energies 2020, 13, 6538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Akbar, U.; Popp, J.; Khan, H.; Khan, M.A.; Oláh, J. Energy efficiency in transportation along with the belt and road countries. Energies 2020, 13, 2607. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Trade-off effects on methane emissions ( z 1 b ), when h = + 0.5 .
Figure 1. Trade-off effects on methane emissions ( z 1 b ), when h = + 0.5 .
Agronomy 11 00365 g001
Figure 2. Trade-off effects on methane emissions ( z 1 b ), when h = −0.5.
Figure 2. Trade-off effects on methane emissions ( z 1 b ), when h = −0.5.
Agronomy 11 00365 g002
Figure 3. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b ), when h = +0.5.
Figure 3. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b ), when h = +0.5.
Agronomy 11 00365 g003
Figure 4. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b ), when h = 0.5 .
Figure 4. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide emissions ( z 2 b ), when h = 0.5 .
Agronomy 11 00365 g004
Figure 5. The efficiency change with trade-off h = + 0.5 values with desirable outputs ( y 1 g + ).
Figure 5. The efficiency change with trade-off h = + 0.5 values with desirable outputs ( y 1 g + ).
Agronomy 11 00365 g005
Table 1. The data set.
Table 1. The data set.
Decision-Making Units (DMUs)
ABCDEFG
Inputs and output x 1 0.90.51.10.22.22.83
x 2 1.631.361.552.152.041.402.04
y 1 0.650.350.650.551.20.81.3
Table 2. The efficiency and the slacks.
Table 2. The efficiency and the slacks.
DMU x 1 x 2 y 1 ρ s s g + s b Ref
A0.91.6301001A
B0.51.360.351001A
C1.11.550.651000.7A
D0.22.150.551000.4A
E2.22.041.21000.8A
F2.81.400.81000G
G32.041.31000G
Table 3. Variables for the agro-ecological efficiency.
Table 3. Variables for the agro-ecological efficiency.
VariablesUnit of MeasureSource
Inputs
x 1 Freshwater consumptionBillion cubic metersWorld Bank
x 2 Agricultural land areaPercentage of landWorld Bank
x 3 Fertilizer consumptionPercentage of fertilizer productionWorld Bank
x 4 LaborPercentage of total employmentWorld Bank
Desirable Outputs
y 1 g ProductionCrop production indexWorld Bank
y 2 g Forest areaPercentage of land areaWorld Bank
Undesirable Output
z 1 b Methane emissionsPercentage of total emissionsWorld Bank
z 2 b Nitrous oxide emissionsPercentage of total emissionsWorld Bank
Table 4. The efficiency results of 136 decision making units “DMUs” (countries).
Table 4. The efficiency results of 136 decision making units “DMUs” (countries).
DMUsEff.DMUsEff.DMUsEff.DMUsEff.
Afghanistan0.09Estonia1.00Eritrea0.18Zimbabwe0.23
Albania0.25Ethiopia0.34Namibia0.13Yemen0.11
Algeria1.00Fiji0.36Nepal0.24Zambia0.58
Angola1.00Finland1.00Netherlands0.12Vietnam0.07
Antigua, Barbuda1.00France0.16Nicaragua0.21Ukraine1.00
Argentina1.00Gabon1.00Niger1.00UAE0.18
Armenia0.20Gambia0.58Nigeria0.15UK0.12
Australia0.20Georgia0.12Norway0.25Uruguay0.14
Austria0.22Germany0.18Oman0.00Uzbekistan0.07
Azerbaijan0.33Ghana0.45Pakistan0.02Venezuela0.16
Bahamas, The1.00Greece0.14Panama0.38Malta0.08
Bangladesh0.06Guatemala0.11Papua New Guinea1.00Mauritius0.10
Barbados0.31Guinea0.39Paraguay0.24Mexico0.19
Belarus0.17Guyana1.00Philippines0.13Moldova0.49
Belgium0.21Honduras0.16Poland0.14Mongolia0.46
Belize0.12Hungary0.15Portugal0.14Morocco0.16
Benin0.91Iceland0.01Romania0.19Dominica1.00
Bhutan1.00Iran0.15Rwanda0.51Domin. Rep.0.36
Bolivia0.63Iraq0.11Saudi Arabia0.01Ecuador0.09
Bosnia, Herzegovina0.17Israel0.22Senegal0.58Egypt0.00
Botswana0.16Italy0.17Slovak0.30Mozambique1.00
Brunei Darussalam1.00Jamaica0.27Slovenia0.19El Salvador0.09
Bulgaria0.22Japan1.00South Africa0.18Trinidad, Tobago1.00
Burkina Faso0.35Jordan0.07Spain0.17Tunisia0.24
Burundi1.00Kazakhstan1.00Sri Lanka0.18Turkey0.13
Cambodia1.00Kenya0.17St. Kitts, Nevis1.00Uganda0.11
Cameroon1.00Korea0.16St. Lucia0.28Madagascar0.21
Central African1.00Kuwait1.00Suriname1.00Malawi0.54
Chile0.10Kyrgyz0.05Sweden1.00Maldives1.00
Congo, Dem.1.00Latvia0.55Switzerland0.16Mali0.13
Congo, Rep.1.00Lebanon0.06Tajikistan0.07Cuba0.13
Costa Rica0.08Lithuania1.00Tanzania0.62Cyprus0.17
Cote d’Ivoire0.38Luxembourg0.12Thailand0.14Czech Republic0.20
Croatia0.23Macedonia0.31Togo0.18Denmark0.11
Table 5. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) when h = +0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Table 5. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) when h = +0.5 and d = (1, 1).
D M U j w . r . t   y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g D M U j w.r.t. y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g
z 1 b + τ 11 + z 1 b + τ 12 + z 1 b + τ 11 + z 1 b + τ 12 +
Afghanistan11.40420.007111.39710.0000Latvia0.58980.01500.69660.1218
Albania34.34140.182634.15880.0000Lebanon25.1189−0.001825.12070.0000
Austria45.9628−0.001845.96690.0023Luxembourg30.28110.036730.27030.0259
Bangladesh62.13030.000162.13020.0000Macedonia5.98490.01475.97810.0079
Belarus43.23440.012443.1816−0.0404Madagascar32.1777−0.001932.1732−0.0064
Belgium43.69600.058743.63730.0000Malawi7.43080.01247.59670.1783
Belize51.00520.000051.00720.0019Mauritius13.5227−0.002213.52500.0000
Benin14.38680.066714.57690.2568Mongolia6.3483−0.54136.88950.0000
Bolivia20.7527−0.000720.7518−0.0015Namibia1.33880.21131.12750.0000
Bosnia and Herzegovina34.95130.012234.8993−0.0397Nepal74.4329−0.002974.43750.0018
Bulgaria7.0032−0.00097.00420.0000Nicaragua52.32810.004052.38190.0578
Chile33.6971−0.001133.69820.0000Norway7.1694−0.00287.17560.0034
Costa Rica61.9982−0.000161.99840.0001Oman4.4126−0.00034.41280.0000
Cote d’Ivoire12.0108−0.004212.01770.0027Pakistan30.4262−0.030630.45680.0000
Croatia16.7472−0.000816.74800.0000Panama19.09530.093318.8226−0.1794
Cuba5.52150.02405.51430.0169Philippines54.0918−0.001054.09280.0000
Cyprus40.02640.000040.0179−0.0085Poland21.0054−0.001321.00660.0000
Czech Rep.28.4054−0.001328.40670.0000Portugal26.1282−0.001326.12950.0000
Ecuador64.6114−0.001064.61350.0012Senegal31.81840.069131.99670.2475
Egypt26.8410−0.000926.84190.0000Slovak Rep.21.74000.016021.6718−0.0522
Eritrea28.15640.009028.14740.0000Slovenia26.37910.000026.38190.0028
Fiji52.9460−0.007752.97800.0243Sri Lanka55.5878−0.000555.58830.0000
Gambia, The12.89580.036712.97960.1206St. Lucia31.64280.024731.5377−0.0804
Georgia40.25710.000040.2544−0.0027Switzerland57.7132−0.002757.71920.0033
Ghana7.17470.01427.36370.2032Thailand52.6556−0.004452.67080.0109
Greece32.67850.032232.5415−0.1048Turkey22.8057−0.001122.80670.0000
Guatemala47.23160.000747.23090.0000Uganda14.32030.012340.705526.3974
Guinea18.73370.002918.74880.0180UAE5.3534−0.00245.3531−0.0028
Honduras72.4080−0.000472.40840.0000Uzbekistan19.97240.000619.97170.0000
Iceland54.82330.000054.82340.0000Venezuela38.2000−0.001338.20280.0016
Iran17.4403−0.007717.44800.0000Vietnam52.2606−0.000352.26120.0003
Iraq0.00000.00005.33875.3387Zambia35.7680−0.018435.80490.0184
Jamaica3.9368−0.00253.95950.0202Zimbabwe35.32270.007935.34080.0259
Korea, Rep.33.3108−0.000733.31230.0008
Table 6. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) when h = −0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Table 6. Trade-off effects on the methane ( z 1 b ) when h = −0.5 and d = (1, 1).
D M U j w . r . t   y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g D M U j w.r.t y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g
z 1 b τ 11 z 1 b τ 12 z 1 b τ 11 z 1 b τ 12
Afghanistan11.3900−0.007111.39710.0000Luxembourg30.2075−0.036930.2180−0.0264
Albania33.9745−0.184334.15880.0000Macedonia5.9554−0.01485.9622−0.0081
Austria45.96650.001845.9624−0.0023Madagascar32.18150.001932.18610.0065
Azerbaijan0.00000.00000.00000.0000Malawi7.4059−0.01257.2361−0.1823
Bangladesh62.1300−0.000162.13020.0000Maldives0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Belarus43.2096−0.012443.26340.0414Mauritius13.52720.002313.52500.0000
Belgium43.5784−0.058943.63730.0000Mongolia7.43020.54066.88950.0000
Belize51.00520.000051.0033−0.0020Namibia0.9161−0.21151.12750.0000
Benin14.2538−0.066414.0673−0.2528Nepal74.43860.002974.4339−0.0018
Bhutan0.00000.00000.00000.0000Netherlands0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bolivia20.75410.000720.75490.0015Nicaragua52.3201−0.004052.2650−0.0591
Bosnia and Herzegovina34.9269−0.012234.97980.0407Niger0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Botswana0.00000.00000.00000.0000Norway7.17490.00287.1687−0.0035
Bulgaria7.00510.00097.00420.0000Oman4.41310.00034.41280.0000
Chile33.69930.001133.69820.0000Pakistan30.48750.030730.45680.0000
Costa Rica61.99840.000161.9981−0.0001Panama18.9085−0.093519.18220.1802
Cote d’Ivoire12.01930.004312.0124−0.0027Papua New Guinea0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Croatia16.74880.000816.74800.0000Philippines54.09380.001054.09280.0000
Cuba5.4733−0.02415.4802−0.0173Poland21.00790.001321.00660.0000
Cyprus40.02640.000040.03510.0087Portugal26.13080.001326.12950.0000
Czech Rep.28.40800.001328.40670.0000Saudi Arabia0.00000.00005.35885.3588
Ecuador64.61330.001064.6111−0.0012Senegal31.6801−0.069231.5000−0.2492
Egypt26.84280.000926.84190.0000Slovak Rep.21.7080−0.016021.77740.0535
Eritrea28.1384−0.009028.14740.0000Slovenia26.37910.000026.3763−0.0028
Fiji52.96140.007752.9291−0.0245South Africa0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Finland0.00000.00000.00000.0000Sri Lanka55.58880.000555.58830.0000
Gambia, The12.8221−0.036912.7357−0.1233St. Lucia31.5935−0.024631.70050.0824
Georgia40.25710.000040.25990.0028Suriname0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Germany0.00000.00000.00000.0000Switzerland57.71860.002757.7125−0.0034
Ghana7.1463−0.01426.9528−0.2077Tajikistan0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Greece32.6142−0.032132.75370.1074Thailand52.66430.004452.6490−0.0109
Guatemala47.2302−0.000747.23090.0000Togo0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Guinea18.7279−0.002918.7129−0.0179Turkey22.80780.001122.80670.0000
Guyana0.00000.00000.00000.0000Uganda14.2958−0.012314.30810.0000
Honduras72.40880.000472.40840.0000Ukraine0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Iceland54.82340.000054.82340.0000UAE5.35830.00255.35890.0030
Iran17.45580.00780.0000−17.4480UK0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Israel0.00000.00000.00000.0000Uzbekistan19.9711−0.00060.0000−19.9717
Jamaica3.94170.00253.9190−0.0203Venezuela38.20250.001338.1997−0.0016
Japan0.00000.00000.00000.0000Vietnam52.26110.000352.2606−0.0003
Korea, Rep.33.31220.000733.3106−0.0009Yemen, Rep.0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Kuwait0.00000.00000.00000.0000Zambia35.80490.018435.7679−0.0186
Latvia0.5596−0.01510.4502−0.1245Zimbabwe35.3069−0.007935.2883−0.0265
Lebanon25.12250.001825.12070.0000
Table 7. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when h = +0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Table 7. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when h = +0.5 and d = (1, 1).
D M U j w.r.t y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g D M U j w.r.t y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g
z 2 b + τ 21 + z 1 b + τ 22 + z 2 b + τ 21 + z 2 b + τ 22 +
Albania37.22370.127437.09630.0000Jordan44.63340.000544.63290.0000
Armenia16.56790.058416.50950.0000Korea42.20380.000242.1734−0.0302
Australia49.3246−0.003449.32800.0000Latvia34.24980.068634.44480.2636
Austria38.41200.000638.3310−0.0804Lebanon64.8009−0.040564.84150.0000
Azerbaijan11.0237−0.007311.03100.0000Luxembourg1.14640.01451.21450.0826
Bangladesh54.28840.002854.28560.0000Macedonia28.22800.006428.24860.0269
Barbados8.4088−0.02188.1748−0.2558Madagascar40.0645−0.003440.0531−0.0148
Belarus40.80510.015440.7027−0.0871Malawi3.19140.07963.49740.3856
Belize33.91640.000033.95930.0429Malta8.31590.00858.30750.0000
Bolivia15.41150.000515.4105−0.0004Mauritius38.7434−0.049938.79320.0000
Bosnia and Herzegovina62.58390.015162.4832−0.0856Mexico27.9968−0.003328.02640.0264
Botswana46.69130.015746.67560.0000Moldova39.0884−0.009039.0082−0.0892
Bulgaria31.6801−0.020931.70100.0000Nepal43.0448−0.017743.07620.0137
Chile35.4870−0.025235.51220.0000Netherlands38.1764−0.009038.18540.0000
Costa Rica45.86740.000045.8621−0.0053Nicaragua24.39670.025824.49590.1250
Cote d’Ivoire3.4436−0.02603.48970.0201Norway41.98040.000941.8580−0.1215
Croatia26.9003−0.017626.91790.0000Oman26.1590−0.006326.16520.0000
Cuba16.98630.009417.03080.0540Paraguay31.87610.065331.7728−0.0381
Cyprus42.00920.000041.8203−0.1889Philippines56.6386−0.022356.66090.0000
Czech Rep.65.2515−0.028465.27990.0000Poland34.4932−0.028034.52120.0000
Denmark58.9339−0.002958.93690.0000Portugal38.1376−0.029438.16700.0000
Dominican18.44750.040318.40720.0000Romania5.69610.01545.75700.0763
Ecuador54.81780.000354.7752−0.0423Rwanda11.45510.026111.54630.1173
Egypt41.6727−0.019741.69240.0000Saudi Arabia18.3427−0.029518.37220.0000
El Salvador30.9759-0.004430.98020.0000Slovak Rep.1.85770.01981.7255−0.1124
Ethiopia14.4607−0.066424.843910.3167Slovenia35.50020.000035.56210.0619
Fiji21.70640.013421.75050.0575Spain5.7476−0.01395.87350.1120
France39.49010.000739.4550−0.0344Sri Lanka33.7308−0.011533.74230.0000
Gambia, The0.43880.06420.65420.2795St. Lucia1.73240.03061.5287−0.1732
Georgia25.58480.000025.5247−0.0601Switzerland41.05460.000940.9359−0.1179
Germany10.6484−0.020510.67610.0072Thailand38.9072−0.026738.95280.0189
Ghana4.80270.09075.15140.4394Tunisia8.89940.03888.86060.0000
Greece41.50200.039941.2363−0.2258Turkey48.6553−0.023448.67870.0000
Guatemala25.01760.015325.00230.0000Uganda0.00000.000061.196261.1962
Honduras41.7701−0.009341.77950.0000UAE27.0438−0.037426.9642−0.1170
Hungary88.6208−0.030988.65170.0000UK23.7600−0.013323.77330.0000
Iceland43.6784−0.001843.68020.0000Uzbekistan59.76680.014459.75240.0000
Iran.57.3186−0.044157.36270.0000Venezuela39.75250.000439.6965−0.0556
Israel28.9126−0.019828.93240.0000Vietnam52.78450.000152.7732−0.0112
Italy35.70600.004235.6679−0.0339Zimbabwe27.07980.013827.12610.0601
Table 8. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when h = −0.5 and d = (1, 1).
Table 8. Trade-off effects on the nitrous oxide ( z 2 b ) when h = −0.5 and d = (1, 1).
D M U j w.r.t y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g D M U j w.r.t y 1 g w.r.t y 2 g
z 2 b τ 21 z 2 b τ 22 z 2 b τ 21 z 2 b τ 22
Albania36.9676−0.128737.09630.0000Korea, Rep.42.2033−0.000242.23400.0305
Armenia16.4509−0.058616.50950.0000Latvia34.1123−0.069033.9119−0.2694
Australia49.33140.003449.32800.0000Lebanon64.88230.040864.84150.0000
Austria38.4108−0.000638.49270.0812Luxembourg1.1175−0.01451.0476−0.0844
Azerbaijan11.03840.007311.03100.0000North Macedonia28.2153−0.006428.1942−0.0275
Bangladesh54.2828−0.002854.28560.0000Madagascar40.07120.003440.08290.0151
Barbados8.45240.02198.70390.2734Malawi3.0319−0.07992.7177−0.3941
Belarus40.7744−0.015440.87900.0892Malta8.2990−0.00858.30750.0000
Belize33.91640.000033.8727−0.0437Mauritius38.84340.050238.79320.0000
Benin0.00000.00000.00000.0000Mexico28.00330.003327.9731−0.0269
Bolivia15.4104−0.000515.41130.0004Moldova39.10640.009039.18790.0905
Bosnia and Herzegovina62.5537−0.015162.65650.0877Mongolia0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Botswana46.6598−0.015846.67560.0000Namibia0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Bulgaria31.72210.021031.70100.0000Nepal43.08030.017843.0488−0.0137
Chile35.53760.025335.51220.0000Netherlands38.19450.009138.18540.0000
Costa Rica45.86730.000045.87260.0053Nicaragua24.3450−0.025924.2431−0.1278
Cote d’Ivoire3.49580.02623.4495−0.0202Norway41.9786−0.000942.10220.1227
Croatia26.93550.017726.91790.0000Oman26.17150.006326.16520.0000
Cuba16.9674−0.009516.9217−0.0552Panama0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Cyprus42.00920.000042.20180.1926Paraguay31.7452−0.065631.84910.0382
Czech Republic65.30850.028665.27990.0000Philippines56.68330.022556.66090.0000
Denmark58.93980.002958.93690.0000Poland34.54940.028234.52120.0000
Dominican Republic18.3667−0.040518.40720.0000Portugal38.19660.029638.16700.0000
Ecuador54.8172−0.000354.86020.0427Romania5.6652−0.01555.6028−0.0780
Egypt41.71220.019841.69240.0000Rwanda11.4028−0.026211.3085−0.1206
El Salvador30.98460.004430.98020.0000Saudi Arabia18.40180.029629.914011.5419
Ethiopia24.962710.435614.52710.0000Senegal0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Fiji21.6796−0.013421.6349−0.0581Slovak Rep.1.8180−0.01981.95300.1151
France39.4887−0.000739.52410.0347Slovenia35.50020.000035.4371−0.0631
Gambia, The0.3101−0.06450.0887−0.2859Spain5.77540.01395.6474−0.1141
Georgia25.58480.000025.64610.0613Sri Lanka33.75390.011633.74230.0000
Germany10.68970.020810.6618−0.0072St. Lucia1.6713−0.03051.87930.1774
Ghana4.6209−0.09114.2629−0.4492Switzerland41.0528−0.000941.17280.1191
Greece41.4223−0.039841.69340.2313Thailand38.96070.026838.9149−0.0190
Guatemala24.9869−0.015425.00230.0000Tunisia8.8217−0.03898.86060.0000
Guinea0.00000.00000.00000.0000Turkey48.70230.023548.67870.0000
Honduras41.78890.009441.77950.0000Uganda0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Hungary88.68280.031188.65170.0000UAE27.11870.037627.20350.1223
Iceland43.68200.001843.68020.0000UK23.78670.013423.77330.0000
Iran57.40690.044319.6190−37.7437Uzbekistan59.7380−0.014516.7369−43.0156
Israel28.95230.019928.93240.0000Venezuela39.7516−0.000439.80820.0562
Italy35.6976−0.004235.73640.0346Vietnam52.7843−0.000152.79570.0113
Jamaica0.00000.00000.00000.0000Zambia0.00000.00000.00000.0000
Jordan44.6324−0.000544.63290.0000Zimbabwe27.0521−0.013927.0044−0.0615
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Ji, T.G.; Raza, A.; Akbar, U.; Ahmed, M.; Popp, J.; Oláh, J. Marginal Trade-Offs for Improved Agro-Ecological Efficiency Using Data Envelopment Analysis. Agronomy 2021, 11, 365. https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy11020365

AMA Style

Ji TG, Raza A, Akbar U, Ahmed M, Popp J, Oláh J. Marginal Trade-Offs for Improved Agro-Ecological Efficiency Using Data Envelopment Analysis. Agronomy. 2021; 11(2):365. https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy11020365

Chicago/Turabian Style

Ji, Tong Guang, Ali Raza, Usman Akbar, Masood Ahmed, József Popp, and Judit Oláh. 2021. "Marginal Trade-Offs for Improved Agro-Ecological Efficiency Using Data Envelopment Analysis" Agronomy 11, no. 2: 365. https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy11020365

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop