3.1. Behavior in a Sequence of One-Shot Interactions
We first examine the results in the RM treatments, in which workers are matched with different firms in every round, thus leaving no opportunity for building up reputation or applying dynamic strategies. We start by using a robust rank order test to pairwise compare across countries. The
p-values of these comparisons are shown in
Table B1 in the Appendix. When pairwise comparing wage offers across countries, we find that German subjects adopting the roles of firms offer the highest wages (significantly higher than their counterparts from Spain, the USA and Japan). Spanish subjects representing firms offer significantly lower wages than those from the other countries (except for the USA). In addition, we observe that hardly any firm offers the SPE wage of 20 or 21 (less than 2% in any of the subject pools). When such a wage offer is observed, the worker either rejects it or selects the minimum effort level.
9
Figure 1.
Mean wage and effort levels (with standard errors) for accepted offers in the random- and fixed-matching treatment over Rounds 2–9.
Figure 1.
Mean wage and effort levels (with standard errors) for accepted offers in the random- and fixed-matching treatment over Rounds 2–9.
Next, we want to learn how wage offers affect rejection and effort levels. For this purpose, we use the Hurdle model specification (see [
38]) to capture the worker’s two-stage decision: whether or not to reject the wage offer (by a logit model) and, if not rejected, which effort level to choose (by a truncated linear regression).
10Table 3 indicates that, first, rejections depend (significantly) negatively on the wage offers for all subject pools, but we observe no significant difference in the “propensity to reject” across countries. Second, we observe that in all countries, effort levels depend (significantly) positively on the wage offers.
11 We find no difference in reciprocity (effort levels per wage offer) across countries, except for a lower reciprocity in Spain (the significance level is
). This means that for an average wage offer of 60 ECU (in Round 5), the average effort in both Germany and the USA is equal to 0.23, but in Spain, it is only 0.13. For an average wage offer of 80 ECU, the average efforts in Germany and the USA are 0.35 and 0.33, but only 0.15 in Spain.
Table 3.
Hurdle model estimation for the random-matching treatments.
Table 3.
Hurdle model estimation for the random-matching treatments.
| Rejection | Effort Level |
---|
Germany | 3.677 (2.386) | −0.063 (0.130) |
Spain | −0.031 (94.991) | 0.144 (0.108) |
Israel | −1.679 (3.240) | −0.001 (0.175) |
Japan | 1.827 (8.048) | 0.034 (0.108) |
Wage | −0.151 *** (0.051) | 0.005 *** (0.002) |
Wage × Germany | −0.130 (0.090) | 0.001 (0.003) |
Wage × Spain | −0.021 (3.804) | −0.004 * (0.002) |
Wage × Israel | 0.036 (0.107) | −0.000 (0.004) |
Wage × Japan | −0.121 (0.393) | −0.000 (0.002) |
Round dummies (2–10) | yes | yes |
Constant | 4.00 ** (1.439) | −0.017 (0.110) |
Observations | 1080 | 1030 |
Wald chi2 | 314.94 *** | 9223.03 *** |
Pseudo / | 0.37 | 0.29 |
Although workers reciprocate with higher effort when receiving higher wages, they do not attempt to split payoffs evenly. In fact, for no pair of matched subjects did the firm earn a positive payoff equal to the worker’s payoff. For all matched pairs, workers’ payoffs are found to be significantly larger than the firms’ payoffs.
12 Even though on average the payoff ratios range between 3.81 (Germany) and 5.06 (Spain), we find no statistical difference between the subject pools.
13 Finally, in terms of surplus (measured by the joint payoffs of the firm and the worker), we find that Germans perform better than Spanish and U.S. Americans. Spanish subjects perform worse than subjects from all other countries, except for U.S. Americans. Our first result can now be formulated as follows:
Result 1 (random matching): In the treatments representing a sequence of one-shot relationships, we find that: (i) German subjects offer higher wages than the other subject pools (except for Israelis), while Spanish offer lower wages than the other pools (except for U.S. Americans); (ii) rejections and effort levels (per given wage offer) are not different across countries, except for Spanish subjects, who reciprocate with less effort (per wage) than their counterparts in the other countries; (iii) payoff inequality between workers and firms is not different across countries; and (iv) as to surplus, German subjects outperform Spanish and U.S. American subjects, while Spanish subjects fall behind all of the other countries’ subjects, except for the U.S. Americans.
Models of social preferences are often used to explain the higher levels of effort observed in gift-exchange experiments compared to the standard economic prediction. Along these lines, we estimate country-specific parameters of the inequity aversion model of [
21] and use these estimates to show how different norms regarding social preferences may explain observed differences across countries. As noted above, in the FM treatments, there are other reasons why workers may give high effort that are not based on social preferences, so we focus only on the RM treatments for this analysis. In their model, Fehr and Schmidt assume that individual utility depends on an individual’s payoff, but is also negatively affected by the difference between the individual’s payoff and the partner’s payoff. Formally, the utility of worker
j is:
where
denotes the payoff of worker
j, receiving a wage offer
from the respective firm and choosing an effort
. Similarly,
represents the payoff of firm
i offering a wage offer
and receiving an effort
from the respective worker.
The β and α parameters are the worker’s marginal utility loss from advantageous and disadvantageous inequality, respectively. Fehr and Schmidt further assume that
and
. In the gift-exchange game, workers with a high β may choose a higher effort level to reduce the disutility from an unequal payoff. However, the α parameter will not affect a worker’s choice in most situations (see [
39]). The α parameter is defined so that it only affects a worker’s choice when a worker is earning less than the firm. In most situations in the gift exchange game, a worker can prevent earning less than the firm by choosing a low enough effort.
14 In the range of (high) efforts where α does affect utility, a decrease in effort will both increase the worker’s payoff and reduce payoff inequality. Therefore, the inequity aversion model predicts that the worker would always want to reduce effort and avoid earning less than the firm (for any value of α). Hence, in the following, we estimate only the “aversion to advantageous inequity” parameter, β.
In the context of the worker decision in a gift exchange game, the inequity aversion model of social preferences offers similar behavioral predictions to models based on reciprocity. With both models of social preferences, workers are inclined to respond to high wages with high effort, either to reduce payoff inequality or to reciprocate with respect to the generous wage offer. It is not our goal to determine whether high effort levels stem from inequity aversion or reciprocity; instead, we consider the β estimates to be informative about whether there are some kinds of social preferences that influence worker behavior in gift-exchange games and how those social preferences vary across countries.
To estimate β, we assume that workers choose the effort level with the highest utility where utility for each effort level is determined as described in Equation (
3) plus an error term. We assume that the random error terms for each effort level have an independent, identical extreme value distribution. This framework leads to multinomial logit choice probabilities. Let
denote the set of possible effort levels, and let
denote the effort chosen by worker
j. Then, the probability that a worker chooses effort level
is:
We estimate β by maximum likelihood and bootstrap standard errors. Estimates for each country are shown in
Table 4. The baseline model shows a single estimate for each country. To allow for heterogeneity among subjects, we also estimate a finite mixture model with multiple types of subjects in each country. Each type has a distinct β, and the proportion of subjects (θ) of each type is estimated along with the β estimates. To determine how many types to use, we continued to add types as long as the addition results in an improvement to the Bayesian information criterion (BIC). The BIC is equal to
, where
is the log likelihood,
k is the number of parameters and
n is the number of observations.
15
Table 4.
Estimates of the aversion to advantageous inequity parameter.
Table 4.
Estimates of the aversion to advantageous inequity parameter.
Country | Parameter | Baseline | Mixture Model |
---|
Model | Type 1 | Type 2 | Type3 |
---|
Germany | β | 0.24 *** (0.02) | 0.26 *** (0.08) | 0.10 (0.08) | |
θ | | 0.72 *** (0.20) | | |
Spain | β | 0.02 (0.01) | | | |
θ | | | | |
Israel | β | 0.20 *** (0.04) | 0.48 ** (0.21) | 0.30 (0.21) | 0.04 (0.12) |
θ | | 0.11 (0.14) | 0.30 (0.20) | |
USA | β | 0.19 *** (0.03) | 0.31 *** (0.07) | 0.18 *** (0.06) | 0.00 (0.27) |
θ | | 0.16 (0.20) | 0.51 *** (0.14) | |
Japan | β | 0.21 *** (0.02) | 0.24 *** (0.08) | 0.09 (0.08) | |
θ | | 0.57 *** (0.13) | | |
Looking at the baseline model, note that Spain, the country with the lowest effort levels, has a β close to zero and that is not statistically significant (
), indicating that Spanish workers gain little utility from reciprocal behavior that reduces the inequality in earnings between themselves and their firm. All of the other countries, on the other hand, have β estimates that are close to 0.2 and are statistically significant at
(with Germany a little higher than the other three countries). These subjects do have some utility gain from reciprocating with respect to their firms. Notably, our β estimates in the four countries other than Spain are quite close to the original calibration by [
21] that had a median value of 0.25.
The mixture model provides more insight into the distribution of β within each country. First, note that in Spain, the addition of a second type did not improve the BIC, so no results are reported for the mixture model. In particular, both types estimated for Spain had β close to zero and that was statistically insignificant, not very different than in the baseline model. In both Germany and Japan, the mixture model leads to two types, one with a β of about 0.25 and another with β close to 0.1 (and not statistically significant). In these countries, a large fraction of subjects are of the type with the higher β (0.72 in Germany, 0.57 in Japan). From this, it appears that between three quarters and one half of the subjects in Germany and Japan are averse to advantageous inequity, while the remaining subjects show little to no aversion. The mixture model leads to three types in Israel and the USA. The USA is similar to Germany and Japan with about two thirds of the subjects demonstrating significant aversion to advantageous inequity. Finally, in Israel, slightly more than half of the subjects are not averse to advantageous inequity, but the remaining subjects have greater aversion than in the other countries. In short, the mixture model demonstrates that all countries have a considerable proportion of subjects who exhibit little or no aversion to advantageous inequity. Further, the distribution of β varies somewhat, but not greatly among four of the countries, while Spain stands alone in having no subjects with significantly positive β.
3.2. The Effect of a Repeated Relationship
To examine behavior in repeated relationships (like most existing labor markets), we conducted fixed matching (FM) treatments where the same firm and worker are matched together in all 10 rounds. In the following, we are using the robust rank order test to pairwise compare (i) between the RM and FM treatments (a within-country comparison that isolates the effect of a repeated interaction between a firm and a worker) and (ii) across the FM treatments (a between-country comparison in the treatments with a repeated interaction between a firm and a worker). The
p-values of these comparisons are shown in
Table B2 and
Table B3 in the Appendix. When comparing the performance between the random matching (RM) and fixed matching (FM) treatments within each country and across subject pools, we find that wage offers are significantly higher under FM than under RM in all countries, except for Japan (and in the FM treatments, we find no systematic differences in wage offers across countries in the pairwise tests). Further, we also observe that a repeated relationship increases effort levels in all countries. As for the difference across countries in the FM treatments, we observe that effort is the highest in Germany (
for all countries, except for Japan with
).
Next, when inspecting the workers’ payoffs, we find these to be significantly larger than the firms’ payoffs in all treatments. A repetitive relationship reduces payoff inequality between workers and firms for German and Japanese subjects, but not for Spanish, Israeli and American subjects. Moreover, in the FM treatments, we find that payoff inequality is lower in Germany and Japan than in each of the other countries ( in all pairwise comparisons). Finally, for all subject pools, we observe that repeated relationships increases surplus (joint payoff of firms and workers). Germany has significantly higher surplus than all countries, expect for Israel. However, in FM treatments, the surpluses of Spanish subjects are not lower than those of Israelis, Americans and Japanese. We summarize these results below.
Result 2 (fixed matching): In the treatments with a repeated relationship between a firm and a worker, we find that: (i) wage offers do not systematically differ across countries; (ii) Germans choose the highest effort levels; (iii) the lowest payoff inequality between workers and firms is observed among German and Japanese subjects; and (iv) Germans obtain the highest surplus, but by and large we observe no differences in surplus among the other subject pools.
Result 3 (random vs. fixed matching): The effect of repeated relationship between a firm and a worker leads to: (i) higher wage offers for all subject pools, except for the Japanese; (ii) higher effort levels in all countries; (iii) a reduction in payoff inequality between workers and firms among German and Japanese subjects; and (iv) higher surplus for all subject pools.