Global Innovation Contests
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. The Model
2.1. Overview
2.2. The Knowledge-Creation Process
2.3. Production Technology
2.4. Households
2.5. Innovation Contests
2.6. National Labor Markets
3. The Growth Effects of Globalization
3.1. Trade Openness
3.2. Multinational Firms
3.3. Discussion
4. Concluding Remarks
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Derivation of Equation (23)
Appendix B
Patterns of Production in the Integrated-World Equilibrium
1 | The term Schumpeterian growth refers to a particular type of R&D-based (exogenous or endogenous) long-run growth generated through the introduction of new products or processes according to Schumpeter’s [1] description of the process of creative destruction. |
2 | For example, in their survey of more that 30 such studies, Lewer and Van den Berg [6] report that about 9 percent of cross-sectional and more than 15 percent of time-series growth regressions find a negative or non-significant correlation between trade and growth. In his more recent survey of studies of trade reforms in the late 1980s and early 1990s, Irwin [7] affirms the heterogeneity of the effects of these reforms on economic growth across developing countries. However, he also concludes that this effect is positive. |
3 | |
4 | |
5 | Amiti et al. [17] and Fajgelbaum et al. [18] describe the evolution of the 2018-19 trade war and analyze its economic effects. Marioti [19] offers an overview of the global economic consequences of the Russian-Ukrainian war. See also Stiglitz [20] and Bhagwati [21] who provide influential overviews of, as well as valuable reflections on, the pros and cons of globalization. Morgan et al. [22] discuss, among other things, geopolitical types of stress on globalization through policymakers’ widespread reliance on economic sanctions as tools of foreign policy. |
6 | A famous case of contested innovation (in which incumbent firms managed to suppress the introduction of a higher-quality product) is Tucker 48. This was an automobile invented by Preston Tucker in 1948 that had better safety and speed features than existing models. In 1949, after producing 50 cars, the company was forced to declare bankruptcy due to negative publicity initiated by the news media, a Securities and Exchange Commission investigation, and a heavily publicized stock fraud trial with unproven allegations. Tucker claimed that the Big Three automakers and Michigan Senator Homer S. Ferguson played instrumental roles in the Tucker Corporation’s bankruptcy. |
7 | |
8 | In contrast, Dinopoulos and Syropoulos [23] assume that the production of RPAs uses only high-skilled labor, whereas the production of R&D services and manufacturing of final products uses only low-skilled labor. |
9 | Salient contributions to the general literature on contests include: Skaperdas [27] who axiomatized contest success functions; Clark and Riis [28] who examined rent-seeking contests with multiple winners and showed that rent is fully dissipated as the number of players grows large; Gradstein and Konrad [29] who focused on contests with multiple rounds when random factors are important; and, Baye and Hoppe [30] who analyzed the conditions under which rent-seeking contests are strategically equivalent to innovation tournaments. Influential works on elimination contests include: Rosen [31] who demonstrated that an elimination contest requires an extra prize for the overall winner to maintain performance incentives throughout the game; Brown and Minor [32] who argued that elimination tournaments often are designed to identify high-ability candidates in environments where innate talent cannot be readily observed; Stracke et al. [33] who investigated the incentives provided by single prizes versus multiple prizes; Cohen et al. [34] who examined the incentives provided by head starts awarded to the winners of early rounds; and Fu and Wu [35] who explored the optimal disclosure scheme in elimination contests to show that transparency yields a higher expected winner’s total effort while opacity leads to greater total effort. |
10 | The dynamic structure of our model also differentiates it significantly from the contributions of Dinopoulos and Syropoulos [36] who model the international diffusion of expertise as an outcome of appropriative imitation and costly self protection, and from Camacho et al. [37] who investigate how insecurity in the outlays of knowledge conditions the incentives of technology leaders to share their knowhow and of laggards to accept it. |
11 | This insight is rooted in the celebrated Stopler-Samuelson [38] theorem which provides a formal link between commodity prices as real rewards (wages) to factor owners (workers). |
12 | The integrated equilibrium is defined as the steady-state equilibrium that would emerge if, in addition to free trade in goods, all factors of production were perfectly mobile internationally. In other words, the integrated-world equilibrium treats the global economy as a closed economy in which, as standardly assumed, all goods and resources are intersectorally mobile. |
13 | The FPE set is defined as the set of possible allocations of factor endowments between the two countries that ensure factor prices (wages) do not differ internationally, goods are produced under the skill intensities that emerge in the integrated-world equilibrium, and every factor of production is fully employed in each country. |
14 | Importantly, using the terminology of Parente and Prescott [46], one could think of rent-protection activities as a barrier to innovation and growth that serves the purpose of removing the scale-effects property while preserving the endogenous nature of long-run Schumpeterian growth. |
15 | In general, parameter may differ across countries and may depend on the resources devoted to enforcing the protection of intellectual property. Ginarte and Park [48] provide more information and evidence on cross-country differences in the strength of patent protection for a sample of 110 countries. However, to keep the analysis simple and direct, in this paper we assume that this parameter is identical across countries. |
16 | See Varian [49] for more details on the properties of unit-cost functions. |
17 | A proper modeling of skill formation requires an endogenous division of population between high-skilled and low-skilled labor that results in a higher wage rate for high-skilled workers as compared to the wage rate for low-skilled workers, as shown in Dinopoulos and Segerstrom [39]. To maintain our focus on the interaction between skill abundance and skill intensities, we abstract from issues associated with endogenous skill formation. |
18 | We assume that, if two products command the same quality-adjusted price, consumers buy the higher quality product, although they are formally indifferent between the two products. |
19 | The Economist (10-22-2005) reported that IBM, a top patent holder, pledged 500 out of its 3,248 software patents at the time to the open-source community and placed them in a patent “commons”. In addition, Friedman [50] documents the fascinating case of “Apache”, a web server that was developed by an open-source self-organized scientific community in the absence of any patent protection. |
20 | For example, constant per-capita consumption expenditure () implies that , as indicated by (11). Moreover, the per-capita levels of RPAs , of R&D services , and of manufacturing output are also constant over time and identical across industries. Equation (15) implies that the long-run price of final consumption good p is also time invariant. Equation (3) implies that the per-capita level of RPAs satisfies , which is also constant over time and equal across industries. As a result, Equation (15) implies that per-capita value of innovation is also time invariant and thus the long-run value of grows at the constant rate of population growth ; that is, . |
21 | See Grossman and Helpman ([4]) for further details. |
22 | For instance, in quality-ladders growth models where innovation either improves the quality of intermediate inputs or results in total factor productivity improvements, captures the level of final per-capita output. See Grossman and Helpman [9] for additional details. |
23 | Inequality can be expressed in terms of skill intensities for . The definition of implies and yields . Thus, |
24 | O’Rourke and Williamson [51] document the factor-price reversal in Great Britain, which occurred in period 1840-1936. During that period the country went from a relatively closed-economy status to an open-economy status following the liberalization of the grain trade and the acceleration of technological progress stemming from the industrial revolution. Globalization and technological progress were equally important in generating this long-run change in factor prices. |
25 | Because there is a continuum of structurally identical industries of measure one, the output of each activity aggregated over all industries equals its indusry-level output. For example, the aggregate per-capita output of RPAs is equal to |
26 | One can easily check how the results of the analysis would change if one modified the ranking of skill intensities displayed in Assumption 1. |
27 | This assumption is supported by the empirical studies of Katz and Murphy [52], Huang and Whalley [53], Ciccone and Peri [54], and Autor et al. [55], which conclude that the value of the elasticity of substitution between low-skilled and high-skilled labor is significantly higher than unity (about 1.50). |
28 | If the skill intensity of RPAs is lower than that of R&D, then a sufficient condition for a downward-sloping relative demand for high-skilled labor is that the elasticity of factor substitution in manufacturing of final goods must be sufficiently greater than one and that the elasticities of factor substitution in the other two activities must be equal or greater than unity. |
29 | Ventura [41] has used the concept of an integrated-world equilibrium to analyze the effects of trade on growth in the context of the Ramsey (as opposed to an R&D-based) growth model. While feasibility and complexity considerations confine our analysis to a comparison of steady-steady equilibria, Ventura also analyzes the transitional dynamics associated with a move from autarky to free trade. |
30 | The distribution of per-capita factor endowments between Home and Foreign in the integrated-world equilibrium is illustrated by point in Figure A1 of Appendix B. |
31 | However, if the skill intensity of R&D exceeds the skill intensity of PRAs, then globalization causes Home’s long-run growth to fall and Foreign’s long-run growth to rise. Of course, one could readily introduce factor intensity reversals and obtain the same changes in the growth rate of both countries as they move from autarky to the integrated-world equilibrium. |
32 | For instance, Lewer and Van den Berg [6], who have surveyed an extensive set of empirical studies that include more than 190 cross-section and more than 400 time series regressions, report that about 9 percent of the cross sectional regressions and 18 percent of the time series regressions find a non-positive correlation between trade and GNP growth. In addition, Warciarg and Welch [60](Appendix 4) list 13 countries that have experienced negative or zero post-liberalization growth changes. Ben-David [61] documents the effect of economic integration on per-capita income for the original European Union (EU) members during the formation of the EU. Finally, Irwin [7] argues that the extensive trade reforms of the late 1980s and early 1990s increased average economic growth by about 1.0–1.5 percentage points but the growth effect was heterogeneous across developing countries. |
33 | The reasons for this property can be attributed to the assumptions that (i) all industries are symmetric, and (ii) the various activities within each industry are connected to each other dynamically. One could add another degree of freedom by assuming the existence of an outside-good produced under perfect competition, as in Dinopoulos et al. [5] and Grossman and Helpman [4], or by introducing differences in skill intensities in the production of final goods. This extension of the model is straightforward. |
34 | Furthermore, if the skill intensity of R&D is higher than the corresponding intensity of RPAs the model generates outsourcing of RPAs (as opposed to R&D services) for endowment-distribution points located in the interior of triangle OAB. |
References
- Schumpeter, J. The Theory of Economic Development; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1934. [Google Scholar]
- Rivera-Batiz, L.A.; Romer, P.M. Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth. Q. J. Econ. 1991, 106, 531–555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rivera-Batiz, L.A.; Romer, P.M. International Trade with Endogenous Technological Change. Eur. Econ. Rev. 1991, 35, 971–1004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Grossman, G.M.; Helpman, E. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Oehmke, J.F.; Segerstrom, P.S. High-Technology Industry Trade and Investment: The Role of Factor Endowments. J. Int. Econ. 1993, 34, 49–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Krugman, P. A Model of Innovation, Technology Transfer, and the World Distribution of Income. J. Political Econ. 1979, 87, 253–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Irwin, D.A. Does Trade Reform Promote Economic Growth? A Review of Recent Evidence; Working Paper 19-9; Peterson Institute for International Economics: Washington, DC, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Aghion, P.; Howitt, P. A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction. Econometrica 1992, 60, 323–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grossman, G.M.; Helpman, E. Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1991, 58, 43–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Romer, P.M. Endogenous Technological Change. J. Political Econ. 1990, 98, S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Segerstrom, P.S.; Anant, T.C.A.; Dinopoulos, E. A Schumpeterian Model of the Product Life Cycle. Am. Econ. Rev. 1990, 80, 1077–1091. [Google Scholar]
- Jones, C.I. Time-series Tests of Endogenous Growth Models. Q. J. Econ. 1995, 110, 495–525. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Thompson, P. Scale Effects in Neo-Schumpeterian Models of Economic Growth. J. Evol. Econ. 1999, 9, 157–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jones, C.I. Growth: With of Without Scale Effects? Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 1999, 89, 141–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Sener, F. New Directions in Schumpeterian Growth Theory. In Elgar Companion to Neo-Schumpeterian Economics; Hanusch, H., Pyka, A., Eds.; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Jones, C.I. The Past and Future of Economic Growth: A Semi-Endogenous Perspective. Annu. Rev. Econ. 2022, 14, 125–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Amiti, M.; Redding, S.; Weinstein, D.E. The Impact of the 2018 Trade War on U.S. Prices and Welfare. J. Econ. Perspect. 2019, 33, 187–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fajgelbaum, P.D.; Goldberg, P.K.; Kennedy, P.J.; Khandelwal, A.K. The Return to Protectionism. Q. J. Econ. 2020, 135, 1–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Mariotti, S. A Warning from the Russian-Ukrainian War: Avoiding a Future that Rhymes with the Past. J. Ind. Bus. Econ. 2022, 49, 761–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stiglitz, J.E. Globalization and Its Discontents; W. W. Norton: New York, NY, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Bhagwati, J. Defense of Globalization; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Morgan, C.C.; Syropoulos, C.; Yotov, Y.V. Economic Sanctions: Evolution, Consequences, and Challenges. J. Econ. Perspect. 2023, 37, 3–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Syropoulos, C. Rent Protection as a Barrier to Innovation and Growth. Econ. Theory 2007, 32, 309–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cohen, W.M.; Nelson, R.R.; Walsh, J.P. Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (Or Not); NBER Working Paper 7552; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Katz, L.F.; Murphy, K.M. Changes in Relative Wages, 1963–1987: Supply and Demand Factors. Q. J. Econ. 1992, 107, 35–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Klein, M.A. Secrecy, the Patent Puzzle, and Endogenous Growth. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2020, 126, 103445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Skaperdas, S. Contest Success Functions. Econ. Theory 1996, 7, 283–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clark, D.J.; Riis, C. A Multi-Winner Nested Rent-Seeking Contests. Public Choice 1996, 87, 177–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gradstein, M.; Konrad, K.A. Orchestrating Rent-Seeking Contests. Econ. J. 1999, 109, 536–545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baye, M.R.; Hope, H.C. The Strategic Equivalence of Rent-Seeking, Innovation, and Patent-Race Games. Games Econ. Behav. 2003, 44, 217–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rosen, S. Prizes and Incentives in Elimination Tournaments. Am. Econ. Rev. 1986, 76, 701–715. [Google Scholar]
- Brown, J.; Minor, D.B. Selecting and Best? Spillover and Shadows in Elimination Tournaments. Manag. Sci. 2014, 60, 3087–3102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Stracke, R.; Hochtl, W.; Kerschbamer, R.; Sunde, U. Optimal Prizes in Dynamic Elimination Contests: Theory and Experimental Evidence. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2014, 102, 43–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cohen, N.; Maor, G.; Sela, A. Two-Stage Elimination Contests with Optimal Head Starts. Rev. Econ. Des. 2018, 22, 177–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fu, Q.; Wu, Z. Disclosure and Favoritism in Sequential Elimination Contests. Am. Econ. J. Microeconom. 2022, 14, 78–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Syropoulos, C. International Diffusion and Appropriability of Technological Expertise. In Advances in Applied Microeconomics; Baye, M.R., Ed.; JAI Press: Stamford, CT, USA, 1998; Volume 7, pp. 115–137. [Google Scholar]
- Camacho, O.; Garfinkel, M.R.; Syropoulos, C.; Yotov, Y.V. Output Insecurity and Ownership Disputes as Barriers to Technology Diffusion; School of Economics Working Paper Series, Working Paper 2022-10; Drexel University: Philadelphia, PA, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
- Stolper, W.F.; Samuelson, P.A. Protection and Real Wages. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1941, 9, 58–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Segerstrom, P.S. A Schumpeterian Model of Protection and Relative Wages. Am. Econ. Rev. 1999, 89, 450–473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Stiglitz, J.E. Factor Price Equalization in a Dynamic Economy. J. Political Econ. 1971, 78, 456–488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ventura, J. Growth and Interdependence. Q. J. Econ. 1997, 112, 57–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sener, F. Schumpeterian Unemployment, Trade and Wages. J. Int. Econ. 2001, 54, 119–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Klein, M.A.; Yang, Y. Blocking Patents, Rent Protection, and Economic Growth. SSRN 2022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grieben, W.-H.; Sener, F. Globalization, Rent Protection Institutions, and Going Alone in Freeing Trade. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2009, 53, 1042–1065. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dinopoulos, E.; Segerstrom, P.S. Intellectual Property Rights, Multinational Firms, and Economic Growth. J. Dev. Econ. 2010, 92, 13–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Parente, S.; Prescott, E. Monopoly Rights: A Barrier to Riches. Am. Econ. Rev. 1999, 89, 1216–1233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bloom, N.; Jones, C.I.; Van Reenen, J.; Webb, M. Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find? Am. Econ. Rev. 2020, 110, 1104–1144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ginarte, J.C.; Park, W.G. Determinants of Patent Rights: A Cross-National Study. Res. Policy 1997, 26, 283–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Varian, H.R. Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd ed.; Norton: New York, NY, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
- Friedman, T.L. The World is Flat; Farrar, Straus and Giroux: New York, NY, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- O’Rourke, K.H.; Williamson, J.G. From Malthus to Ohlin: Trade, Industrialization, and Distribution Since 1500. J. Econ. Growth 2005, 10, 5–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lewer, J.J.; Van den Berg, H. How Large is International Trade’s Effect on Economic Growth? J. Econ. Surv. 2003, 17, 363–396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huang, H.; Whalley, J. The Use of Literature Based Elasticity Estimates in Calibrated Models of Trade-Wage Decompositions: A Calibmetic Approach; NBER Working Paper 10137; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Ciccone, A.; Peri, G. Long-run Substitutability Between More and Less Educated Workers: Evidence from the US States 1950–1990. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2005, 87, 652–663. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Autor, D.H.; Katz, L.F.; Kearney, M.S. Trends in US Inequality: Revising the Revisionists. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2008, 90, 300–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jones, C.I. R&D-based Models of Economic Growth. J. Political Econ. 1995, 103, 759–784. [Google Scholar]
- Segerstrom, P.S. Endogenous Growth Without Scale Effects. Am. Econ. Rev. 1998, 88, 1290–1310. [Google Scholar]
- Trefler, D. International Factor Price Differences: Leontief Was Right! J. Political Econ. 1993, 101, 961–987. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trefler, D. The Case of Missing Trade and Other Mysteries. Am. Econ. Rev. 1995, 85, 1029–1046. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wacziarg, R.; Welch, K.H. Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence. World Bank Econ. Rev. 2008, 22, 187–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ben-David, D. Equalizing Exchange: Trade Liberalization and Income Convergence. Q. J. Econ. 1993, 108, 653–677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Dinopoulos, E.; Syropoulos, C.; Tsoulouhas, T. Global Innovation Contests. Games 2023, 14, 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14010018
Dinopoulos E, Syropoulos C, Tsoulouhas T. Global Innovation Contests. Games. 2023; 14(1):18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14010018
Chicago/Turabian StyleDinopoulos, Elias, Constantinos Syropoulos, and Theofanis Tsoulouhas. 2023. "Global Innovation Contests" Games 14, no. 1: 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14010018
APA StyleDinopoulos, E., Syropoulos, C., & Tsoulouhas, T. (2023). Global Innovation Contests. Games, 14(1), 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/g14010018