Next Article in Journal
Does Land Tenure Security Promote Manure Use by Farm Households in Vietnam?
Next Article in Special Issue
A Study on Estimation of Land Value Using Spatial Statistics: Focusing on Real Transaction Land Prices in Korea
Previous Article in Journal
Automobile Industry Strategic Alliance Partner Selection: The Application of a Hybrid DEA and Grey Theory Model
Previous Article in Special Issue
Brownfield Redevelopment Evaluation Based on Fuzzy Real Options
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Sustaining Competitiveness: Moving Towards Upstream Manufacturing in Specialized-Market-Based Clusters in the Chinese Toy Industry

School of Geography, Beijing Normal University, Beijing 100875, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2016, 8(2), 176; https://doi.org/10.3390/su8020176
Submission received: 31 October 2015 / Revised: 10 January 2016 / Accepted: 30 January 2016 / Published: 18 February 2016

Abstract

:
Western industrial cluster literature pays little attention to specialized markets (SMs) and the geographical agglomeration of distributors or sale agencies (SAs). This paper takes Linyin, Shandong, a famous commodity city in Northeastern China, as an example, to discuss the determinants that make SAs in SMs of the toy industry move towards upstream manufacturing. A structured questionnaire survey and subsequent interviews were carried out during 2011 and 2012 to collect data, and a Binary Logistic Regression Model was used to process the data. This paper looks from the perspective of global production networks theory, establishes an analytical framework that combines individual motivations of intra-firm coordination, local inter-firm relationships and dynamic cross-regional level relationships. The findings indicate that the expansion of SAs towards manufacturing allows them to sustain competitiveness under changing circumstances. The local inter-firm relationships within SM-based clusters not only makes it easy to obtain material and human resources with lower manufacturing costs, but also facilitates the access to production knowledge and technologies for an expansion of production scale. Cross-regional relationships with suppliers provide an informal channel for SAs to obtain skills, which is fundamental for an expansion into manufacturing. In addition, it is a preference for strengthening competitiveness rather than the simple pursuit of economic profit that encourages SAs to invest in manufacturing.

1. Introduction

Sales or marketing activities have been addressed in the literature as an indispensable component of value chains in industrial clusters. Intermediary businesses connecting local manufacturers and the international market are considered to be an important factor in the development of clusters [1]. At present, multinational companies have tended to incorporate industrial clusters in developing countries into their global value chains through outsourcing production or contract manufacturing [2,3], which provides a boost to the commercialization of industrial clusters [4] and to the regeneration [5,6] or upgrading [7,8] of these clusters. However, in the literature regarding industrial clusters in Western countries, little consideration has been paid towards the geographical distribution and location of small and medium sales agencies (SAs) that connect manufacturers to customers, and less is mentioned about specialized markets (SMs) as physical exchange platforms or spaces for SAs and their clients. In fact, studies on industrial clusters in developing countries, such as China, have pointed out that SMs and manufacturing clusters have been important driving forces in rural industrialization since the late 1970s [9]. In fact, SMs have triggered the development of local manufacturing clusters or, conversely, local manufacturing clusters have brought about the prosperity in SMs, which also reveals that SAs in SMs have a close relationship with local manufacturing firms [10].
SMs differ from the traditional business model in that they are a two-sided platform model in the small- and medium-sized-enterprise cluster, which provide services for both buyers and sellers and address procurement, price-setting and distribution [11]. SMs are places for trading where a specific kind of utility commodity (in some cases mixed with a small amount of other kinds of commodities) are sold in bulk for both vast domestic and global markets [11]. Those commodities are either made in neighboring areas or further away. According to the statistics from 2013, the average number of SAs (booths) in a SM in China is 612, while some may contain thousands [12]. SAs are generally local independent merchants or sales departments attached to local manufacturers or even external producers in other places. They connect the local manufacturing with external clients and even foreign markets, and act as an important channel of products and information. The first generation of SMs in China formed spontaneously in the early 1980s at local (temporary) fairs. At that time, China implemented a unified distribution system of commodity circulation and prohibited the development of private-owned sectors. Therefore, those SMs were considered as a kind of institutional innovation [13,14,15], and provided an important kind of sale channel for local family-owned factories. SAs in the SMs have their own factories or local suppliers, connect local production networks with customers outside the clusters [11,16], and consequently enhance the prosperity of local economies [17]. As a result of those initial successful experiences, it became popular to construct various types of SMs to trigger local development, especially in regions with weak industrial base. Yiwu city in Zhejiang province and Linyi city in Shandong Province are two typical examples, well known as “commodity market”, situated in the north and south of China, respectively. Even recently, some cities in Mainland China, such as Shenyang in Liaoning Province, Changsha in Hunan Province, Changzhou in Guangdong Province, and Langfang in Hebei Province, have drawn up blueprints to construct or regenerate agglomerations of SMs in their urban planning [18].
In fact, manufacturing companies have become less dependent on local SMs as a result of the diversification of sales channels since the late 1990s, which has caused the degeneration or even demise of SMs as transaction platforms in the coastal areas of China [17]. For a group of dominant SAs, constructing SMs in other regions at home or abroad was an alternative to the serious challenges being faced and was also a positive response to changing circumstances [19]. SMs have encountered another round of crises recently due to the rising popularity of e-commerce. The transmission efficiency of business information has been improved greatly, and transaction costs of product exchanges have decreased. Therefore, the traditional advantages of physical SMs have been further weakened [20]. In line with the fact that sales in commodity markets have decreased or even been forced to close, numerous “Taobao villages” (Taobao is the name of a most popular B2C e-commerce platform in China; a Taobao village is a village where the number of physical shops reaches more than 10% of the local households, and the transactions of electronic commerce amounts to more than 10 million yuan per year), which are more dependent on e-commerce than physical SMs have emerged throughout China. It is therefore urgent for both SMs and SAs to make a prompt transition. Some SMs have turned to focus on the development of information economy [11], intensifying connections with foreign markets as a bridge between China and overseas in fragmented production [16]. It has become the norm for a group of SAs to make expansions into e-commerce services [20].
However, two important points have been neglected in the literature. The first concerns the function of SMs as a bridge between local manufacturers and external customers, and the interactions between SMs and their neighboring manufacturing clusters; while focusing little interest on those SMs which connect remote small- and medium-sized manufacturers with remote clients besides local clients. In fact, in under-developed areas in particular, local SMs were supposed to undertake the crucial role of being a trigger to local industrialization [21]. Second, the literature discusses SMs as a whole and concerns itself little with the various kinds of actors in the SMs, such as SAs. SMs actually appear like “black boxes”. Especially under changing circumstances, it is not clear how those actors respond and what their effects on local economic development are as a consequence.
This paper focus on the response of traditional SMs to the changing circumstances in less industrialized areas, where SMs originally relied on far-way areas instead of local industrial clusters and SAs have been facing diluted profits from traditional manufacturing [22]. According to the field survey, local SAs have been turning to the relevant product manufacturing, which has been paid little attention to in recent literature. The authors have concerned themselves with which factors drive SAs on SM-based clusters to incorporate manufacturing into their intra-firm value chains. Furthermore, which factors cause SAs to expand manufacturing scale and bring about the burgeoning of local manufacturing is also investigated.
Section 2 conducts a review of the literature and forms some hypotheses. Section 3 covers the research area, methodology, and data collection. Section 4 presents the data, analyses and results. The final section then draws conclusions and provides some discussions.

2. Literature Review and Main Hypotheses

The extension of value chains in SM-based clusters (SMBCs) to manufacturing can be understood as an upgrading of regional industries. Literature on industrial clusters discusses some innovation-related topics such as knowledge transfer and learning [23]. Industrial upgrading has also been much debated in strands of literature on global production networks [24,25] (GPNs) or global value chains (GVCs) [26]. From the perspective of GPN theory, chains and networks are merely organizational devices providing opportunities for actor-specific learning, practice, and upgrading [27]. GPN-GVC studies focus on the strategic coupling of clusters and regions within global production systems [28,29], and demonstrate four categories of industrial upgrading [26].
Much of the existing debates on GPNs and GVCs centers around the governance structures of three typical chains, modular, relational, and captive chains [30], and relational network configurations [31]. An updated GPN theory, called “GPN 2.0” by Yeung and Coe, takes an actor-centered focus, highlights the competitive dynamics (optimizing cost–capability ratios, market imperatives and financial discipline) and risk environments, and states their effects on shaping the actors’ organizational relationships within global production networks in different industries. Compared with previous GPN studies, GPN 2.0 states two relationships, intra-firm coordination and extra-firm bargaining, beyond inter-firm control and inter-firm partners. The latter two inter-firm relationships originate from the three types of chains as mentioned above.
Although global production networks are considered as cross-border organizational platforms, GPN theory also attempts to analyze regional development between and within countries in global production systems. Moreover, the updated GPN theory focuses much more on the actors and their organizational relationships shaped by “capitalist dynamics”, and intends to explore their ultimate effects on the developmental outcomes in different regions and countries. In fact, it provides an actor-relationship approach in analyzing cluster upgrading within cross-regional production networks (CRPNs) in a country like China, where there are economic, cultural, and institutional differences between different regions [27,32]. GPN 2.0 not only identifies diverse firm actors, ranging from lead firms, strategic partners, specialized suppliers and generic suppliers to customers, but also introduces non-firm actors, such as the state, international organizations, labor groups, and civil society organizations. However, it pays little attention to such firm or non-firm actors as the gatekeepers or intermediate agents who connect local clusters worldwide and whose importance is highlighted, especially in the learning dynamics of industrial clusters [33].
The authors have selected SAs, local merchants with intensive relationships with the outside, as a targeted firm actor, in order to explore the upgrading of SM-based clusters within CRPNs. It is believed that SAs with a certain amount of capital and technical ability move into manufacturing out of economic interests or o avoid the large pressures from market competition [34]. The pursuit of economic profit is related to the intra-firm factors, and the pressure from competition is most probably caused by a large number of local and external counterparts, and even from abroad (such as international buyers), and the emergence of e-commerce vendors. The increasing competition between local SAs and their counterparts leads to a change in their bargaining power with suppliers [35]. In addition, although SAs can accumulate technical skills through self-learning or their own innovation, it is common practice for them to learn from their peers and longstanding partners. As a consequence, the authors of GPN 2.0 pay special attention to intra-firm coordination, local inter-firm relationships, and cross-regional inter-firm bargaining and partnerships.

2.1. SAs’ Motivations for Setting Foot in Manufacturing as Intra-firm Coordination

“Intra-firm coordination” refers to the internalization and consolidation of value activities, including management and logistics of production, design, research and development (R&D), and monitoring of quality standards and production outcomes within various actors [27]. Through intra-firm coordination, various actors within GPNs can improve firm-specific efficiencies such as cost control, market responsiveness, and higher-quality products or services. Setting foot in manufacturing can be viewed as intra-firm coordination within SAs in the SMs, and it is reasonable to consider that benefits concerning firm-specific efficiencies or competitiveness, in turn become intra-firm motivations for SAs to take on such coordinated strategies.
As previously mentioned, a body of literature believes that that SAs move into manufacturing out of economic interests. It was common for SAs to move into production in the 1980s and 1990s in China when the country had a smaller economy and manufacturing yielded higher profits than ever. However, the situation has dramatically changed recently. As production costs have increased, the profits from traditional product manufacturing have declined. Some manufacturing companies have struggled to make changes, and others have even moved to neighboring countries to take advantage of lower production costs [36]. Under such circumstance, it is in doubt as to whether or not the purpose of improving profits is strong enough for SAs to enter into the traditional manufacturing sector. From the perspective of transaction costs, it would be rational for SAs to move into manufacturing instead of completely relying on external suppliers when the administrative costs of internal production is less than the transaction costs of external purchasing [37]. As a result, setting foot in manufacturing can be considered as SAs’ response in decreasing costs and strengthening their competitiveness (the so-called “cost–capability ratio” as stated by Yeung and Coe) even when there is little profit to be made from the traditional manufacturing.
Meanwhile, with the rapid development of e-commerce services and increasing diversity of demand, more and more small- and medium-sized manufacturers have turned to focus on small batch, customized, and timely production, and have paid more attention to new product development and innovation to obtain and sustain competitiveness [38]. Accordingly, SAs setting foot in manufacturing could hardly survive the increasingly serious competition in manufacturing sectors without the capability of product innovation. From the viewpoint of transaction costs, innovative products are usually those with high asset specificity, and their transaction cost is higher than that of ordinary products [37]. In this case, it is reasonable for SAs to choose self-production rather than outsourcing production for the sake of innovation protection and quality control of new products. The more non-standardized and innovative the products are and the more rapid the change of customers’ tastes, the more likely SAs will turn to depend on internal production.
Therefore, the authors put forward the following hypothesis.
H1: SAs setting foot in manufacturing is positively affected by their motivation for increasing firm-specific efficiency (e.g. cost control, market responsiveness, and higher-quality products or services) rather than that for obtaining greater economic profit in manufacturing.
SAs’ setting foot in manufacturing can lead to the emergence of manufacturing activity in SMBCs. The burgeoning of manufacturing and subsequent SMBC upgrading depends on the SAs’ manufacturing scale, which is also viewed as a continuous intra-firm coordination. Therefore, the authors believe that SAs’ manufacturing scale should be also taken into consideration. Internalization of manufacturing is one kind of firm growth or expansion, and so the intra-firm determinants sustained by SAs’ setting foot into manufacturing could also be attributed to SAs’ manufacturing scale. From the perspective of economic profits, it is reasonable to think the enlargement of production scale is down to chasing scale economies. However, under such circumstances as mentioned before, it is doubtful that SAs have significant enough motivations to expand manufacturing for scale economies. Moreover, according to Penrose’s view of firm growth [39], unused resources within the firm originate sales, managerial, research or productive excess capacity. It is supposed that the motivations to use those unused resources to strengthen firms’ competitiveness lead to diversification or expansion of the firm.
Therefore, the authors put forward the following hypothesis.
H2: SAs’ manufacturing scale is positively affected by their motivations to increase their firm-efficiency by using competitiveness-related resources rather than that for obtaining scale economies.

2.2. Local Inter-Firm Relationships and Accessibility to SMBC-Specific Benefits

It is generally believed that external economies of scope are an excellent advantage of the agglomeration of various SMs in an area where there are intensive formal and informal intensive relationships. Customers can conveniently shop for a variety of commodities in the same place, which decreases the time and financial costs [40,41]. However, it is unclear whether or not external economies of scope have an important impact on expansion of SAs to related manufacturing. In terms of input-and-output linkage between different products in different local SMs, SAs in a specific SM are supposed to get products as raw materials or components from other SMs nearby, which makes SAs competitive when setting foot in manufacturing by reducing transportation and transaction costs as mentioned in literature on industrial clusters [42].
The agglomeration of SAs in SMs can lead to fierce the competition between local SAs, forcing them to improve their innovation capability, which is common in manufacturing clusters [42]. Meanwhile, SMs are a typical kind of information economy, which also bring about external economies of scale. Generally speaking, the agglomeration of SAs makes it more convenient for customers to get access to transparent information about homogeneous commodities for a low transaction cost [43]. Moreover, local firms in the same location share value and cultural traditions in common, which is helpful in building up formal and informal trust-based relationships [44]. The importance of these close and intensive relationships between local firms is highlighted in the decrease of transaction costs and transmission of knowledge and information in particular [45,46]. Once a SA takes the initiative to invest in related manufacturing and achieves great success in business, other SAs in the same SMs and even other SMs of different commodities in the locality would follow up its experience.
With an increasing number of SAs setting foot in manufacturing, local related manufacturing clusters are burgeoning, with external economies of scale being increasingly enhanced [47]. It is easy for SAs and new entrants to get access to a skilled local labor pool, improve the production efficiency, and promote the growth of firms by virtue of local production networks [48]. In addition, intensive local relationships between different organizations provide channels for the transmission of crucial knowledge and skills concerning related production for local manufacturers and SAs after setting foot in manufacturing. The dynamics of local learning are able to sustain a local competitive advantage [49]. Based on the above theoretical analysis, the authors put forward the following hypothesis.
H3: SAs’ setting foot in manufacturing is positively affected by accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationships.
For similar reasons concerning the context of raising H2, the accessibility to local resources or benefits probably has a positive effect on SAs’ manufacturing scale. Moreover, although Penrose highlights the importance of firm’s endogenous growth, she further states that the growth of firms may be consistent with the most efficient use of a society’s resources, and acknowledges the interaction between internal and external factors. Therefore, the authors put forward the following hypothesis.
H4: SAs’ manufacturing scale is positively affected by the accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationships.

2.3. Dynamic Cross-Regional Inter-Firm Relationships and Accessibility to External Knowledge/Technology

The importance of innovation in regional development is highlighted in some strands of literature regarding industrial clusters, learning regions, and regional innovation systems. The inter-organizational networks are believed to underpin the flow of knowledge within and across regions [50], and the dynamic relationships between economic globalization and regional development is one area in particular in which much attention has been paid [28]. Cross-border linkages [51], such as global pipelines [23], and GPNs and GVCs [52], discussed in the beginning of this section, are important channels for local firms in obtaining heterogeneous knowledge and information, and furthermore promote cluster upgrading [53,54]. In addition, competition between same-level suppliers and the high-level requirements for quality, force firms in the GVCs or GPNs to focus on innovation [52,53].
In fact, upgrading is a complicated process. Global technology forerunners tend to delimitate against the chances of being caught up by their suppliers in developing countries [26]. Therefore, it is much easier for the latter to make process and upgrade their products than to carry out functional and chain upgrades [26]. Another line of literature demonstrates that cross-regional production networks (CRPNs) within a nation provide more possibilities for firms in less developed countries to move up to higher value-added activities by embedding into national or regional value chains than into a GVC or GPN [55]. The reason for this is because tacit knowledge is often embedded in the relationships between related firms with a common cultural background and is transmitted easily between firms in value chains within a country or region [55]. However, later studies do not deny the feasibility of using the analytical framework of GPN theory to explore industrial upgrading and regional development.
It supposes that CRPNs make it possible for SAs to gain knowledge and skills for production from their suppliers. Moreover, the dynamics of inter-relationships between SAs and their suppliers across the region may have an impact on the extension of value chain to manufacturing. On the one hand, as more and more suppliers incorporate into the GPNs of global companies, or depend more on e-commerce services, their connections with SAs loosen; on the other hand, as SAs enter into manufacturing, in their suppliers’ eyes, the competition between them outweighs the benefits of cooperation. That means SAs would further expand the production scale to depend more on internal manufacturing, given their bargaining power and learning opportunities from their upstream suppliers decrease. Therefore, the authors put forward the following hypotheses.
H5: SAs’ setting foot in manufacturing is positively affected by the accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic relationships with cross-regional suppliers.
H6: SAs’ manufacturing scale is negatively affected by the accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic relationships with cross-regional suppliers.

3. Research Area and Data Source

3.1. Case Selection and Overview

Linyi, a city located in Shandong Province, China (Figure 1), was once an isolated area with underdeveloped manufacturing and business services. However, since the establishment of the Linyi Western Suburbs Wholesale Market in the mid-1980s, the city has become a large distribution hub for the area north of the Yangtze River, and well-known for trade and logistics throughout China. This paper selects Linyi, the city on the border of Shandong Province and Jiangsu Province, as the study area for the following reasons. First, there are 101 SMs in the downtown of Linyi, including 57,000 shops and stalls, employing 233,000 staff and catering to 300,000 customers per day [56]. The products in Linyi cover the major categories of daily consumer goods, so we have chosen the so-called “The Northern China Yiwu” (Yiwu is a county-level city in Zhejiang Province known as “China’s Commodity City”). Second, there is much literature based on the experiences of Zhejiang Province in China that emphasizes the co-evolution between SMs and their neighboring manufacturing clusters, while little is concerned about regions such as Linyi where local economies rely on SMs but have no related manufacturing sectors nearby. Third, recent evidence shows that local SAs no longer focus on sales, but have begun to invest in related product manufacturing, resulting in the development of local manufacturing clusters. This change means that the development of SMs is not only accelerating the urbanization, but also contributing to the development of local manufacturing. Therefore, a case study of Linyi has general meaning and reference value.
Linyi is the largest toy SM in Shandong Province and the second major location for warehouses for toy manufacturers in China (Chinese toy industry markets are characterized as export-oriented, and mainly depend on original equipment manufacturers, with few self-owned brands. In 2013, about 70% of the world's toys were made in China [57]. External demand contraction and reduced export orders caused by the economic crisis, Chinese toy exporters suffered terribly and had to turn to domestic markets or create its own brand. In 2007, the number of Chinese toy exporters was 8610, but by 2008, the number had plummeted to 4388 [58].). Besides this, Linyi has been listed as one of the top ten distribution centers of toys in China since 2011 [59]. The first group of toy SAs set up shop in the 1990s in the wholesale market of Linyi downtown, which was known as the “Mainland Business Village”. As the sale of toys and the number of toy SAs rapidly increased, Linyi Yongxing International Toy Wholesale Market (“Yongxing Market” for short), a unique SM for toys in Shandong Province, was established in 2007 to improve the business environment for toy SAs. Since Yongxing Market’s establishment, many SAs for toys have gradually moved in, and the sales of toys have risen rapidly. In 2014, the market was home to more than 600 SAs and 1,200 operating booths. The success of Yongxing Market can be attributed to its geographical proximity to the inter-city bus station of Linyi and the entrance to the Beijing-Shanghai Highway. Moreover, many other SMs and logistics distribution centers are located around the market (Figure 2). Today, only a small percentage of toy SAs are still located in the toy retail market in Linyi’s People’s Square and Linyi Small Commodities Market, with the majority of these conglomerates belong in Yongxing Market. Toys in Yongxing Market are sold throughout the country, but mainly to the neighboring provinces of Shandong, such as Henan, Anhui, Hebei and Jiangsu (Figure 1).
Initially, the toys in Linyi were mainly manufactured in Guangdong, Jiangsu and a couple of other cities of Shandong. Recently, the market share of toys made in Linyi has risen. According to this survey on local toy SAs, local products account for 40% of all sales in Yongxing Market. Linyi is the second largest source of toys, after Guangdong Province. More than half of toy SAs in the market have already invested in manufacturing, and especially in plush-toy manufacturing, whereby 80% of the SAs manufacture products of their own. Following those SAs’ lead, new entrants emerged, and manufacturing villages in the surrounding suburban areas of Linyi burgeoned. Most of these factories are family-owned and small in size.

3.2. Data Collection

Based on interviews with members of staff and SAs in Yongxing Market carried out in August 2011, the authors learned about the history, competition and transition to manufacturing of the market, and also confirmed toy SMs as the object of study. Subsequently, the authors created a structured questionnaire to collect relevant data.
The second on-site questionnaire survey was conducted between December 2011 and January 2012. A total of 486 questionnaires were distributed, accounting for approximately 80% of the total number of existing SAs in the market; 126 questionnaires were returned (the return rate was 25.9%), and 117 questionnaires were valid (the validity rate was 92.9%). Among the 117 valid questionnaires, 54 SAs have invested in manufacturing activities, which is roughly the same as the proportion of the whole market. The basic information for the 117 sample SAs is illustrated in Table 1. Some of the SAs took part in semi-structural interviews during the second survey. In June 2012 and July 2015, the authors re-interviewed several SAs online.
According to the questionnaire, the surviving SAs under the influence of commerce modality changes in China’s wholesale market have three directions of business transition: (1) establishing SMs in other cities (not very popular in Linyi); (2) making extension to e-commerce services by establishing an e-commerce platform or co-operating with internet service companies (33.3% of all the samples provide e-commerce services); and (3) moving into toy manufacture (46.2% of all the samples).

4. Data Analysis and Results

This paper discusses the factors that exert influence on the expansion of SAs from wholesale to manufacturing and on the scale of internal production. Based on the literature reviewed in Section 2, the authors selected three kinds of determinants, namely, individual motivations of entrepreneurial innovation, local agglomeration effects of SMs, and dynamic relationships within CRVCs, as independent variables, and defined “whether or not SAs set foot in related product manufacturing” and “the production scale of SAs” as the dependent variables, respectively.

4.1. Factors Affecting SAs to Investing in Manufacturing

According to the literature analysis in the second section, eight variables were selected as independent variables presenting individual motivations of intra-firm coordination, local inter-firm relationships for facilitation to get SMBC-specific benefits, and dynamic cross-regional inter-firm relationships for accessibility to crucial resources. “Sales duration”, “Size of SAs” and “Industry specialization” were the control variables, and “whether or not SAs set foot in related product manufacturing” as the dependent variable. All variables and their meanings, and their scores quantitative criteria are shown in Table 2.
Based on the related data of 117 valid samples, the authors used the “Backward: LR” method of Binary Logistic Regression, which first starts with all variables in the regression equation, and then removes the independent variables that have no significant effect on the dependent variable according to the probability value of statistic derived from the Maximum Likelihood Estimation. The judgment probability is set as 0.05, so that the performance of the model is more optimized. The logistic regression model estimation results are shown in Table 3 and Table 4.
According to Table 4, the overall fitting degree is good (X2 = 83.509, P = 0.000), which shows that the independent variables on the whole have a significant effect on the dependent variable (P < 0.05). Only one independent variable, namely lr2, had a significant effect on the dependent variables (P < 0.05), while the other independent variables did not have significant effect. According to the probability value of statistics derived from the Maximum Likelihood Estimation, the irrelevant independent variables were removed and the optimized results are shown in Table 4.
The optimized model result shows that the effect of im2, lr2, and dcrr2 on the dependent variable is clear, and the corresponding regression coefficients are 0.704, 1.358, and 0.839 respectively. It indicates that the three factors, “reducing transaction costs of innovative products”, accessibility to “local resources”, and “skill acquisition from suppliers” drive SAs to invest in related manufacturing. They, respectively, represent “individual motivations of intra-firm coordination” (related to the firm-specific efficiency), “accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationships” and “accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic cross-regional inter-firm relationships”, which verify hypotheses 1, 3 and 5. The coefficient of lr2 is higher than dcrr2 and im2, which means that accessibility to “local resources” is the most significant, and “accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationships” play a much more important role than “accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic cross-regional inter-firm relationships” and “individual motivations of intra-firm coordination” in driving SAs to invest in the manufacturing sector. In fact, due to a variety of different SMs nearby, toy SAs can easily get access to raw materials at a low cost of transportation and transaction. The external economies of scope in the agglomeration of SMs provide an important precondition or advantage for SAs in making an expansion into manufacturing.
Long-term business collaborations with trans-local toys manufacturers are an important learning channel for SAs to acquire indispensable technical support in the initial stages of entering into manufacturing. Despite the fact that more than half have their own ideas of product design in general as mentioned below, 23 SAs setting foot in manufacturing (making up 42.6% of the similar SAs) claimed in the questionnaire survey that they remained the business cooperation with their previous trans-local suppliers for access to new information about product development and design The subsequent interviews further indicated that local toy SAs were not bold when making investment in manufacturing without acquiring knowledge about it first. There is little evidence to indicate that those suppliers have turned to depend more on other sales channels than traditional SMs.
No matter whether they invested in manufacturing or not, almost all the SAs surveyed claimed that there is very little profit in toy manufacturing. This is the reason why the variable, “gaining profit”, is not significant to the dependent variable, and it can also explain the reason why the dependent variable “peer’s demonstration” has no significant relationship with the business expansion of SAs. Meanwhile, due to intensive contact sub-level distributors all over the country, some toy SAs are sensitive to the market changes and often figure out innovative ideas about the new product development. 35 SAs setting foot in manufacturing (making up 64.8% of the similar SAs) claimed in the questionnaire survey that they often created some good ideas of product design by virtue of their marketing experiences for years. Those SAs prefer to adopt internal production rather than outsource production in case their innovations are leaked out.
Interestingly, although the two variables concerning individual motivations, “prompt response to the market change” and “gaining profit”, have no significance on SAs setting foot in manufacturing in the model, the questionnaire result indicates that internal production does improve the competitiveness and the profit levels for SAs. Table 5 shows that the majority of SAs in the questionnaire survey claimed that their competitiveness had improved to some extent after moving to internal production, sales and profits had increased, and accordingly external purchase of toys had decreased. Furthermore, during the subsequent interview, a couple of SAs mentioned that increasing uncertainty in the toy market requires a prompt response from SAs to the rapid changes in demands. As a consequence, SAs adopt low-volume production for the initial stage of launching new products and then promptly move to organize mass production once those new products are successful. Otherwise, SAs would not be able get much economic return as their creative ideas would be widely copied in a short time. That situation requires geographical proximity of sales to toy production, which helps improve their competitiveness.

4.2. Factors Affecting the Production Scale of SAs

The 54 SAs setting foot in manufacturing showed a big difference in production scales. In terms of the percentage of internal production to the total sales volume, nearly half of these SAs (25) reached more than 30%, and a couple of SAs even amounted to more than 90%, while some SAs account for less than 10%. In this section, the authors explore which factors affect the production scale of SAs after moving into manufacturing. Nine variables have been selected as independent variables, which respectively present individual motivations, local agglomerations and dynamic trans-local relationships as mentioned before, with “technical change” and “financial capital” added as two control variables; “the scale of internal production” is the dependent variable. All variables and their meanings are explained in Table 6.
The estimated results of the logistic regression model are shown in Table 7 and Table 8. Table 7 shows that the overall fitting degree is not good (X2 =17.499, P = 0.095), which indicates that the whole independent variables do not have a significant effect on the dependent variable (P > 0.05). Independent variables LR1and LR4 have a significant effect on the dependent variables (P < 0.05). According to the probability value of statistics derived from the Maximum Likelihood Estimation, the irrelevant independent variables are removed and the optimized results are shown in Table 8.
Table 8 shows as a whole, the independent variables have a significant effect on the dependent variable (P < 0.05). The optimized model result shows that only LR1, LR3 and LR4 are significant at the 5% level, and their corresponding regression coefficients are 1.416, 0.878 and 1.115, respectively. That is to say, accessibility to “local resources”, “local learning”, and “local labor resources” encourage SAs to expand the scale of manufacturing. These three factors are part of the local cluster effects, which verifies hypothesis 4 that accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationships positively impacts on the scale of SAs’ internal production. The authors made a further comparison between the two groups of samples. The results show that for SAs whose production percentage is more than 30%, the means of LR1, LR3 and LR4 are, respectively, 4.7, 3.8, and 3.4, which is much higher than those of SAs with less than 30% (the means of the three variables are 4.1, 3.3, and 2.6, respectively).
The variable “(accessibility to) local resources” is closely related to the external economies of scope in agglomeration of SMs. Local related SMs not only provide raw materials and components for SAs to set foot in toy manufacturing, but also have a positive effect on the expansion of the production scale. Local learning between SAs does not have a significant bearing on the decision about whether or not SAs set foot in manufacturing, but local mutual learning between SAs setting foot in manufacturing can promote the expansion of the production scale. Although the variable “local lower logistics costs” is not significant in the model, subsequent interviews show that fast local logistics services and its lower costs make it convenient for SAs to purchase some raw materials and toys from outside.
Individual motivations of intra-firm coordination can inspire SAs to set foot into related manufacturing; however, their subsequent impact on the expansion of production scale is not significant. That probably implies that SAs’ administration capabilities are more important than their motivations in realizing an expansion of production. Despite the fact that accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic inter-firm relationships across regions have no significance on the production scale, a couple of the SAs interviewed responded by saying that they still paid attention to business cooperation with trans-local suppliers as it helps them get access to the updated information about new products. SAs often purchase toys in small quantities and promptly organize internal production once those products are welcomed in the market. In fact, local manufacturers often encounter problems concerning complicated skills, product design, and crucial technologies, and have difficulties in learning those from their suppliers across regions. This is particularly true in the manufacturing of electronic toys.

5. Conclusions and Discussion

Western cluster literature mentions little about SMs and the geographical location of SAs. Chinese scholars have noted the role of SMs in the burgeoning of industrial clusters and have placed an emphasis on the interdependent and co-evolutionary relationships between prosperous SMs and mature industrial clusters nearby, but ignored the response of SAs in the SMs to the changing circumstances and their importance in regional development. One contribution of this paper is to fill in the gap between the existing research on cluster upgrading and Chinese practice through providing the case of Linyi where SMBCs incorporate manufacturing into local value chains. Another contribution is to use the updated GPN theory to set up the analytical framework, and to explain how competitive dynamics and risk management shape the four types of relationship, and then have an effect on local development. The empirical results show that individual motivations of intra-firm coordination, regional inter-firm relationships and cross-regional inter-firm relationships have a significant and positive impact on the upgrading of local industrial clusters so as to sustain local competitiveness. Moreover, it also demonstrates that SAs could trigger the burgeoning of industrial clusters and speed up the process of industrialization through their investments in manufacturing in less-developed industrialized areas. The SAs in SMs actually act as the intermediate agents or the gatekeepers between local production networks and global flows in the cluster learning literature, whose role is neglected in GPN 2.0 theory. In addition, there is a group of small- and medium-sized business trade cities in China, especially for those newly burgeoning e-commercial towns without strong economies and those with emerging economies. The case of Linyi provides experiences for those places to reshape regional competitiveness on the basis of adding advantages through trade.
In the case of Linyi, three important points are worth being highlighted. First, in terms of such kind of traditional products as toys, due to shrinking profit margins, intensifying competition and rapid changes in consumer tastes, it is preferable for the increase in efficiencies or firm competitiveness rather than simple pursuit of economic profit that encourages SAs to move into manufacturing. Therefore, innovation-based internal production could sustain SAs’ competitiveness through the improvement of product quality and instantly responding to changing situations. Second, agglomeration of various kinds of SMs in the same place and the local inter-firm relationships within SM-based clusters facilitate access to material and human resources with lower manufacturing costs, and production knowledge and technologies for an expansion of manufacturing scale, which is beneficial to reshaping local competitiveness, whereas an isolated SM cannot easily benefit from these advantages. Mutual learning between toy SAs setting foot in manufacturing and new entrants as manufacturers are an important channel for the sharing of knowledge, and so it is helpful for SAs to make expansions in terms of production scales. That implies it is necessary to improve local innovation networks. Third, a dynamic relationship with cross-regional suppliers is an important channel of knowledge transmission; however, it cannot guarantee efficient access to core technologies and crucial knowledge for SAs without knowledge-oriented cooperation. That probably means it is indispensible to establish cross-regional learning channels to further strengthen the competitiveness of SAs and SMBCs.
Some issues worthy of further discussion remain. First, although this paper uses an analytical framework on the basis of GPN 2.0 theory, there is no direct linkage between local SAs in Linyi and foreign multinational companies. The result is probably different if such international linkages exist. Second, extra-firm partners mentioned in GPN2.0 theory are not taken into consideration in this paper. The authors focused on the CRCV but have not covered external learning channels with knowledge institutions as the preliminary survey evidence, which showed that local SAs have little interest in establishing external technology-based cooperation. The emergence and dynamics of such relationships for access to external knowledge deserves concern. Additionally, local authorities and other institutions are not integrated into the analytical framework. Although almost all SAs in the survey claimed that local governments made little effort in promoting the development of toy manufacturing, it has been reported that the Linyi municipal government has proposed industrial policies and established industrial parks to “stimulate prosperity in manufacturing sectors by taking advantage of local SMs strategy”. Finally, the relationships between SAs and local toy factories in the suburban areas are worth investigation in order to gain a better understanding of the role of SAs in local development.

Acknowledgments

This research is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (projectcode: 41171098). The authors would also wish to extend their thanks to two anonymous referees, and Wang Maojun at Capital Normal University, and Wang He at Hong Kong City University, and Pan Fenghua at Beijing Normal University for their valuable comments.

Author Contributions

Huasheng Zhu contributed to the analytical framework and the methodology design and wrote the article. Xue Huang and Qingcan He contributed to the data analysis. Jie Li and Lingzhi Ren sent out questionnaires and collected data.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Rabellotti, R. External Economies and Cooperation in Industrial Districts: A Comparison of Italy and Mexico; Macmillan Press Ltd.: London, UK, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  2. Plambeck, E.L.; Taylor, T.A. Sell the plant? The impact of contract manufacturing on innovation, capacity, and profitability. Manag. Sci. 2005, 51, 133–150. [Google Scholar]
  3. Scott, A.J. The changing global geography of low-technology, labor-intensive industry: Clothing, footwear, and furniture. World Dev. 2006, 34, 1517–1536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Kaplinsky, R.; Morris, M.; Readman, J. The globalization of product markets and immiserizing growth: Lessons from the South African furniture industry. World Dev. 2002, 30, 1159–1177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Nassimbeni, G.; Sartor, M. The internationalization of local manufacturing systems: Evidence from the Italian chair district. Prod. Plan. Control 2005, 16, 470–478. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Grandinetti, R.; Nassimbeni, G.; Sartor, M. Foreign direct investments in manufacturing by district firms: Evidence from the Italian chair district. Prod. Plan. Control 2009, 20, 403–419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Pietrobelli, C.; Rabellotti, R. Global value chains meet innovation systems: Are there learning opportunities for developing countries? World Dev. 2011, 39, 1261–1269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Pipkin, S. Local means in value chain ends: Dynamics of product and social upgrading in apparel manufacturing in Guatemala and Colombia. World Dev. 2011, 39, 2119–2131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Lu, L.J. Yiwu mode of China commodity city and rural economic development. Bus. Econ. Manag. 1997, 6, 4–9. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  10. Lu, L.J.; Yu, H.D.; Lu, Y. Specialized Market and Industrial Cluster: Linkage and Influential Factors. China Ind. Econ. 2011, 1, 151–160. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  11. Ding, K. Market Platforms, Industrial Clusters and Small Business Dynamics: Specialized Markets in China; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  12. Statistical Yearbook of China Commodity Exchange Market in 2014. Available online: http://tongji.cnki.net/kns55/Navi/YearBook.aspx?id=N2014110013&floor=1 (accessed on 25 December 2015).
  13. Cai, J.J.; Wang, S.H. Analysis of the development of the specialized market based on industry cluster—A case study of Taizhou, Zhejiang. Contemp. Financ. Econ. 2005, 8, 88–91+96. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  14. Xie, S.H.; Zhou, J.Y. The temporal and spatial dynamics patterns and its causes of specialized markets development in China. Econ. Geogr. 2013, 11, 77–83. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  15. Yang, Y.; Qu, H.J.; Xu, Z.B. Effect of textile & garment specialized market on regional industrial clusters. Shanghai Text. Sci. Technol. 2013, 10, 53–57. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  16. Bellandia, M.; Lombardib, S. Specialized markets and Chinese industrial clusters: The experience of Zhejiang Province. China Econ. Rev. 2012, 23, 626–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Zhu, H.S. The Industrial Clusters of Zhejiang: Industrial Network, Growth Trajectory and Development Momentum; Zhejiang University Press: Hangzhou, China, 2003. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  18. Fang, X.S.; Xiao, D.W. Research of specialized markets development and planning. City Plan. Rev. 2002, 10, 61–63. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  19. Liu, S.A. The development and evolution of Zhejiang specialized market in e-commerce era of. Commer. Res. 2006, 03, 187–189. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  20. Du, L.L. The opportunity and challenge of the traditional specialized market in the era of e-commerce. China Logist. Purch. 2014, 12, 68–69. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  21. Lu, L.J.; Yu, H.D. On the professional market, driven by industrial cluster and upgrade—Yiwu City, Zhejiang Province-based survey and analysis. East China Econ. Manag. 2009, 23, 50–54. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  22. Zhou, C.S.; Li, Y.F.; Zhang, G.J. Research on Upgrading of the Traditional Manufacturing Industry Based on Global Value Chains: A Case of Shantou. Areal Res. Dev. 2014, 01, 28–33. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  23. Bathelt, H.; Malmberg, A.; Maskell, P. Clusters and knowledge: Local buzz, global pipelines and the process of knowledge creation. Prog. Hum. Geogr. 2004, 28, 31–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Henderson, J.; Dicken, P.; Hess, M.; Coe, N.M.; Yeung, H.W.C. Global production networks and the analysis of economic development. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 2002, 9, 436–464. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Coe, N.M.; Hess, M.; Yeung, H.W.C.; Dicken, P.; Henderson, J. “Globalizing” regional development: A global production networks perspective. Trans. Inst. Br. Geogr. 2004, 29, 468–484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Humphrey, J.; Schmitz, H. How does insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters? Reg. Stud. 2002, 36, 1017–1027. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Yeung, H.W.C.; Coe, M.N. Toward a dynamic theory of global production networks. Econ. Geogr. 2015, 91, 29–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Yeung, H.W.C. Regional development and the competitive dynamics of global production networks: An East Asian perspective. Reg. Stud. 2009, 43, 325–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. MacKinnon, D. Beyond strategic coupling: Reassessing the firm-region nexus in global production networks. J. Econ. Geogr. 2012, 12, 227–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Gereffi, G.; Humphrey, J.; Sturgeon, T. The governance of global value chains. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 2005, 12, 78–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Dicken, P.; Kelly, P.; Olds, K.; Yeung, H.W.C. Chains and networks, territories and scales: Towards an analytical framework for the global economy. Glob. Netw. 2001, 1, 89–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Parrilli, M.D.; Nadvi, K.; Yeung, H.W.C. Local and regional development in global value chains, production networks and innovation networks: A comparative review and the challenges for future research. Eur. Plan. Stud. 2013, 21, 967–988. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Guiliani, E. Role of technological gatekeepers in the growth of industrial clusters: Evidence from Chile. Reg. Stud. 2011, 45, 1329–1348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Wang, J. Derived cluster: The formation mechanism of industrial cluster in the west bank of Pearl River Delta. Manag. World 2005, 8, 80–86. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  35. Chang, P.Y. Optimizing Supply Chain Collaboration Based on Negotiation and Bargain Power for Single Retailer And Single Supplier. Lect. Notes Eng. Comput. Sci. 2013, 2, 1. [Google Scholar]
  36. Wise, R.; Baumgartner, P. Go Downstream: The New Profit Imperative in Manufacturing. Harv. Bus. Rev. 1999, 77, 133–141. [Google Scholar]
  37. Gooroochurn, N.; Hanley, A. A tale of two literatures: Transaction costs and property rights in innovation outsourcing. Res. Policy 2007, 36, 1483–1495. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Danneels, E. The dynamics of product innovation and firm competences. Strateg. Manag. J. 2002, 12, 1095–1121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Volpe, L.; Biferali, D. Edith Tilton Penrose, the Theory of the Growth of the Firm. J. Manag. Gov. 2008, 12, 119–125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Bai, X.H. Economies of scope and economies of scale of specialized wholesale market: An empirical analysis of Yiwu. Financ. Trade Econ. 2004, 2, 55–59. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  41. Sheng, K.R.; Fan, J. Economies of scope and concentration of differentiated stores. Econ. Geogr. 2010, 30, 531–536. [Google Scholar]
  42. Porter, M.E. Clusters and the new economics of competition. Harv. Bus. Rev. 1998, 76, 77–90. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
  43. Wei, J.F. Toward the effect of commerce clusters—Analysis based on informatics. Modern Econ. Sci. 2006, 28, 93–96. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  44. Rocha, H.O.; Sternberg, R. Entrepreneurship: The Role of Clusters Theoretical Perspectives and Empirical Evidence from Germany. Small Bus. Econ. 2005, 24, 267–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Keeble, D.; Wilkinson, F. Collective Learning and Knowledge Development in the Evolution of Regional Clusters of High Technology Smes in Europe. Reg. Stud. 1999, 33, 295–303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Scott, A.J. Entrepreneurship, innovation and industrial development: Geography and the creative field revisited. Small Bus. Econ. 2006, 26, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Riordan, M.H.; Williamson, O.E. Asset Specificity and Economic Organization. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 1985, 3, 365–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Delgado, M.; Porter, M.E.; Stern, S. Clusters and Entrepreneurship. J. Econ. Geogr. 2010, 10, 495–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Farsani, J.J.; Bidmeshgipour, M.; Habibi, M.; Rashidi, M.M. Intellectual Capital and Organizational Learning Capability in Iranian Active Companies of Petrochemical Industry. Procedia Soc. Behav. Sci. 2012, 62, 1297–1302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Huggins, R.; Thompson, P. A Network-based view of regional growth. J. Econ. Geogr. 2014, 14, 511–545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Hansen, M.W.; Kuada, J. Transnational Corporations and Local Firms in Developing Countries: Linkages and Upgrading; Copenhagen Business School Press: Copenhagen, Danmark, 2006; p. 29. [Google Scholar]
  52. Humphrey, J.; Schmitz, H. Governance and Upgrading: Linking Industrial Cluster and Global Value Chain Research; IDS Working Paper 120; IDS: Brighton, UK, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  53. Ernst, D. Global production networks, knowledge diffusion, and local capability formation. Res. Policy 2002, 31, 1417–1429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Singh, J. Distributed R & D, Cross-Regional Knowledge Integration and Quality of Innovative Output. Res. Policy 2008, 37, 77–96. [Google Scholar]
  55. Navas-Alemán, L. The impact of operating in multiple value chains for upgrading: The case of the Brazilian furniture and footwear industries. World Dev. 2011, 39, 1386–1397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Introduction to the Market. Available online: http://www.linyi.gov.cn/lysc/scjj.htm (accessed on 20 July 2014).
  57. Chinese Toy Industry, from “Manufacturing” to “Create”. Available online: http://news.xinhuanet.com/world/2015-02/03/c_127450678.htm (accessed on 20 December 2015).
  58. Toy Industry Need to Speed up Product Innovation. Available online: http://lib.cet.com.cn/paper/szb_con/36957.html (accessed on 20 December 2015).
  59. ChinaToyTrade.com Picked Out the Top Ten Toy Distribution Centers in China. Available online: http://news.ctoy.com.cn/show-11697.html (accessed on 15 March 2015).
Figure 1. Primary source locations and distribution destinations of toys in Yongxing Market.
Figure 1. Primary source locations and distribution destinations of toys in Yongxing Market.
Sustainability 08 00176 g001
Figure 2. Sketch Location Map of Yongxing Market in Linyi, Shandong.
Figure 2. Sketch Location Map of Yongxing Market in Linyi, Shandong.
Sustainability 08 00176 g002
Table 1. Basic information from 117 valid questionnaires on Yongxing Market in Linyi China.
Table 1. Basic information from 117 valid questionnaires on Yongxing Market in Linyi China.
AttributesNumber of SamplesAttributesNumber of Samples
Toy category The number of sales people
Plush toy37 (Accounting for 31.6%;31 are involved in the manufacturing sector)<3 persons33 (28.2%)
Plastic and electronic toys80 (Accounting for 68.4%;23 are involved in the manufacturing sector)3–6 persons81 (69.2%)
Total117>6 persons3 (2.6%)
Business scope of SAs Top three sources of toys
Sales63 (53.8%)Guangdong66 (56.4%)
Sales + Manufacturing54 (46.2%)Linyi49 (41.9%)
Sales duration Hebei9 (7.7%)
Manufacturing duration
<5 years64 (54.7%)
5–10 years46 (39.3%)<3 years29 (53.7%)
>10 years7 (6.0%)3–6 years22 (40.7%)
Area of shops >6 years3 (5.6%)
The number of production workers
<75 m262 (53.0%)
75–150 m249 (41.9%)<20 persons40 (74.1%)
>150 m26 (5.1%)20–50 persons14 (25.9%)
>50 persons0 (0.0%)
Note: the number of valid questionnaires related to “Manufacturing duration” and “The number of production workers” is 54 from a total of 117, and the remainder is 117.
Table 2. Factors that affect toy SAs in Linyi setting foot in manufacturing and their quantitative criteria.
Table 2. Factors that affect toy SAs in Linyi setting foot in manufacturing and their quantitative criteria.
FactorVariableNameMeaningQuantitative Criteria
1. Dependent variable
Whether or not set foot in manufacturingY If yes,1; otherwise, 0
2. Independent variables
(1) Individual motivations of intra-firm coordinationim1Gaining profit [34]Manufacturing gives more profits than product sales Take five scale method, give a score to each variable according to the degree of compliance with each variable's expression: “strongly agree”, 5; “ agree”, 4; “slightly agree”, 3; “disagree”, 2; “strongly disagree”, 1
im2Reducing transaction costs of innovative products [27,37]Turning their own design ideas into new products in case of being copied and improving quality control,
im3Prompt response to market change [27,38]Prompt response to the market change and improving market share
(2) Accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationshipslr1Effects of Competition among local SAs on intra-firm innovation [42]With increasingly intense competition in the local market, intra-firm innovation increases
lr2Local resources [40,41]Other SMs in Linyi can provide raw materials and intermediate products for producing toys
lr3Peers' demonstrations/local learning [45,46]Following local peers’ experiences to set foot in producing toys
(3) Accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic cross-regional inter-firm relationshipsdcrr1Change in suppliers’ sales channels [17]External suppliers have more diversified sales channels which strengthens their bargaining power with local SAs
dcrr2Skill acquisition from suppliers [53,54]Local SAs obtain knowledge concerning manufacturing skills, technology, and product design from external suppliers
3. Control variable
Sales durationSDSales durationDuration of SAs’ investment in sales5 or less than 5 years, 1; otherwise, 2
The size of SASIZEThe size of SAThe number of the clerks in SAless than 5 people, 1; otherwise, 2
Industry specializationISIndustry specializationDifferent kinds of toys have different technological basesplush toys, 1; plastic, 2; electronics, 3
Table 3. Model estimation result of toy SAs involving into production in Linyi.
Table 3. Model estimation result of toy SAs involving into production in Linyi.
Uim1im2im3lr1lr2lr3dcrr1dcrr2SDSIZEIS
B−11.321−0.4620.6440.268−0.2571.6160.3610.6180.616−0.4922.002−0.555
S.E3.5630.3240.3330.3270.3340.4050.3440.4090.3240.8231.3190.705
wald10.0952.0303.7380.6740.59115.9381.1012.2843.6070.3572.3060.671
Sig.0.0010.1540.0530.4120.4420.0000.2940.1310.0580.5500.1290.413
X2 = 83.509, P = 0.000; RCS = 0.510, Rn = 0.682
Note: Constant; S.E: standard deviation; Wald: Chi square value; Sig: Significant probability; RCS: Cox and Snell R2; Rn: Nagelkerke R2.
Table 4. Optimized model result of toy SAs setting foot in production in Linyi.
Table 4. Optimized model result of toy SAs setting foot in production in Linyi.
OptimizedUim2lr2dcrr2
B−9.4450.7041.3580.839
S.E1.7490.2880.3060.247
Wald29.1705.98419.73211.525
Sig.0.0000.0140.0000.001
X2 = 75.212, P = 0.000; RCS = 0.474, Rn = 0.634
Table 5. The effects of setting foot in manufacturing on the business operation of SAs.
Table 5. The effects of setting foot in manufacturing on the business operation of SAs.
Extent of Agree or DisagreeIncrease in SalesCompetitiveness ImprovementIncrease in ProfitDecrease in External Purchasing
Strongly agree2016811
agree1410289
Slightly agree1827830
disagree0052
Strongly disagree2152
Table 6. Factors that affect production scale of toy SAs in Linyi and quantitative criteria.
Table 6. Factors that affect production scale of toy SAs in Linyi and quantitative criteria.
FactorVariableNameMeaning or DefinitionQuantitative Criteria
1. Dependent variable
Production scaleYProduction scaleThe relative size of production can reflect the degree to which sales companies have invested in manufacturingIf the percentage of internal proportion reaches 30%, 1; otherwise, 0
2. Independent variables
(1) Individual motivation of intra-firm coordinationIM1Gaining profit [34]Gaining more profits on basis of economies of scaleTake five scale method, and give a score to each variable according to its degree of compliance with each variable's expression: “strongly agree”,5; ”agree”, 4; “slightly agree”, 3; ”disagree”, 2; ”strongly disagree”, 1
IM2Reducing transaction costs of innovative products [27,37]Turning more design ideas of their own into new products in case of being copied, and improving quality control
IM3Prompt response to the market change [27,38]Prompt response to the market change and improving market share
(2) Accessibility to SMBC-specific benefits from local inter-firm relationshipsLR1Local resources [40,41]Other wholesale markets in Linyi can provide the required raw materials and intermediate products for producing toys
LR2Local lower logistics costs [40]Local lower logistics costs are beneficial for purchasing the required raw materials from other locations
LR3Local learning [45,46]There are various channels for mutual learning among local SAs setting foot in manufacturing.
LR4Local labor resources [40]Local skilled labors are abundant.
(3) Accessibility to knowledge/technology based on dynamic cross-regional inter-firm relationshipsDCRR1Change in suppliers’ sales channels [17]External Toy suppliers have more diversified sales channels, which strengthens their bargaining power with local SAs.
DCRR2Skill acquisition from suppliers [53,54]Local SAs obtain knowledge concerning manufacturing skills, technology, and product design from external suppliers.
3. Control variable
Changes in technologyTC Toy manufacturing technology tends to be mature, easy to obtain or learn
Financial capitalFC Having enough money to manufacture toys
Table 7. Model estimation result of production scale of toy SAs in Linyi.
Table 7. Model estimation result of production scale of toy SAs in Linyi.
UIM1IM2IM3LR1LR2LR3LR4DCRR1DCRR2TCFC
B−0.354−0.767−0.074−0.5531.2900.3390.7770.9670.085−1.009−1.0290.135
S.E4.2410.4480.4300.5590.5740.4600.4200.4690.5210.5350.6260.384
wald0.0072.9240.0300.9795.0520.5433.4134.2580.0273.5562.7030.123
Sig.0.9330.0870.8630.3220.0250.4610.0650.0390.8700.0590.1000.726
X2 = 17.499, P = 0.094; RCS = 0.277, Rn = 0.370
Note: Constant; S.E: standard deviation; Wald: Chi square value; Sig: Significant probability; RCS: Cox and Snell R2; Rn: Nagelkerke R2.
Table 8. Optimized model result of production scale of toy SAs in Linyi.
Table 8. Optimized model result of production scale of toy SAs in Linyi.
UIM1LR1LR3LR4DCRR2TC
B−3.496−0.6351.4160.8781.115−0.753-0.916
S.E1.9920.3850.5620.4140.4320.4150.559
wald3.0802.7206.3524.5116.6713.2972.691
Sig.0.0790.0990.0120.0340.0100.0690.101
X2 = 16.034, P = 0.014; RCS = 0.257,Rn = 0.343

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhu, H.; Huang, X.; He, Q.; Li, J.; Ren, L. Sustaining Competitiveness: Moving Towards Upstream Manufacturing in Specialized-Market-Based Clusters in the Chinese Toy Industry. Sustainability 2016, 8, 176. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8020176

AMA Style

Zhu H, Huang X, He Q, Li J, Ren L. Sustaining Competitiveness: Moving Towards Upstream Manufacturing in Specialized-Market-Based Clusters in the Chinese Toy Industry. Sustainability. 2016; 8(2):176. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8020176

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhu, Huasheng, Xue Huang, Qingcan He, Jie Li, and Lingzhi Ren. 2016. "Sustaining Competitiveness: Moving Towards Upstream Manufacturing in Specialized-Market-Based Clusters in the Chinese Toy Industry" Sustainability 8, no. 2: 176. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8020176

APA Style

Zhu, H., Huang, X., He, Q., Li, J., & Ren, L. (2016). Sustaining Competitiveness: Moving Towards Upstream Manufacturing in Specialized-Market-Based Clusters in the Chinese Toy Industry. Sustainability, 8(2), 176. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8020176

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop