Next Article in Journal
Climate-Adaptive Passive Design Strategies for Near-Zero-Energy Office Buildings in Central and Southern Anhui, China
Previous Article in Journal
Sustainable Entrepreneurship in Emerging Economies: The Role of Financial Planning, Environmental Consciousness, and Artificial Intelligence in Ecuador—A Cross-Sectional Study
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Do Economic Growth Targets Aggravate Environmental Pollution? Evidence from China

1
School of Artificial Intelligence, Xiamen Institute of Technology, Xiamen 361021, China
2
School of Mathematics and Statistics, Fujian Normal University, Fuzhou 350117, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2025, 17(14), 6534; https://doi.org/10.3390/su17146534
Submission received: 14 June 2025 / Revised: 10 July 2025 / Accepted: 14 July 2025 / Published: 17 July 2025

Abstract

How to balance the relationship between economic development and environmental protection is a common challenge faced by developing countries. Based on panel data from 30 Chinese provinces between 2008 to 2021, we analyze the impact of economic growth targets (EGTs) on environmental pollution (EP) using a spatial autoregressive threshold panel (SARTP) model. The empirical findings are as follows. (1) A 1% increase in the EP index in adjacent provinces leads to a 0.5870% increase in the observing province. (2) For provinces with EGTs above 7.5%, a 1% increase in the EGT results in a 0.3799% increase in the EP index. Conversely, its impact on EP is not significant. (3) As EGTs increase, the EP effect intensifies in central provinces, weakens in western provinces, and remains insignificant in eastern provinces; the EP effect of EGTs is significantly greater in provinces with a large population size and a low proportion of tertiary industry. (4) When the provincial EGT exceeds the central target by 0.5%, a 1% increase in the EGT results in a 0.4469% increase in the EP index. Our paper offers theoretical and empirical insights for alleviating EP and promoting sustainable economic development.

1. Introduction

Since the reform and opening up, China’s economy has maintained a high growth rate and achieved remarkable accomplishments. These achievements have been accompanied by significant adjustments in economic structure and the gradual improvement of the industrial system. However, rapid industrialization, urbanization, and continuous population growth have significantly exacerbated environmental pollution (EP). Severe environmental pollution has become a major obstacle to sustainable economic development and social well-being [1]. In response to increasingly severe EP, the Chinese government has implemented a series of proactive reforms in pollution control. In 1998, the government established sulfur dioxide pollution control zones. In 2006, it incorporated environmental protection into the performance evaluation system for government officials. In 2013, the government launched the air pollution prevention and control action plan. This series of measures marks a gradual shift in China’s environmental regulations from lenient to strict, achieving significant pollution control results while maintaining rapid economic growth. However, China ranked 118th out of 178 countries and regions in the 2014 Global Environmental Performance Index, indicating the severity of its environmental pollution. Balancing economic development with environmental protection remains a major challenge for the Chinese government.
In regional economic development, local governments play a crucial role as key policymakers and executors in promoting economic growth [2]. Local governments accelerate local economic growth by implementing economic policies and investment strategies and promoting infrastructure development. However, while dedicated to economic development, local governments must navigate the complex challenges of balancing economic growth with environmental protection [3]. In response to the urgent need for rapid economic growth, local governments often prioritize resource allocation to sectors that promise quick returns, such as heavy industry and real estate. Certainly, these sectors contribute to GDP growth and fiscal revenues, but they also pose serious environmental challenges. For example, air and water pollution from industrial emissions, along with ecological degradation due to land over-exploitation, pose serious threats to the natural environment.
In China, the central government influences local government decisions by formulating regional development targets [4,5]. Economic growth targets (EGTs) and environmental policies set by the central government provide a decision-making framework for local governments, requiring them to balance economic growth and environmental protection within this framework [6]. The central government’s regulatory mechanism requires local governments to adhere to national strategic objectives; otherwise, they risk reduced resources or failing assessment standards [7]. To mitigate these risks, local governments often prioritize economic growth over environmental protection due to various factors [8]. On one hand, the traditional performance evaluation system centered on the GDP leads local government officials to prioritize short-term economic growth over long-term environmental protection benefits [9]. On the other hand, environmental protection often demands significant capital investment and technical support. Local governments with limited financial resources may struggle to balance economic growth with environmental protection. Thus, protecting the environment while sustaining economic growth is a difficult challenge for local governments. When setting EGTs, local governments are often given clear phased targets. These targets are carefully planned and decomposed into a series of concrete, feasible, and hard-bound quantitative indicators. To achieve EGTs, the central government has motivated local governments through incentives and assessment systems. It is noteworthy that the official selection mechanism based on rankings of economic development performance serves as the intrinsic motivation driving local officials to pursue economic growth. While this mechanism encourages local governments to boost the economy, it may also cause them to overlook environmental protection. Therefore, when discussing economic growth, it is essential to fully consider the EGTs, particularly their potential impact on EP, and implement effective mitigation measures to reduce the negative effects.
Existing research on EGTs primarily focuses on the motivations for target setting, governmental behavioral responses, and macroeconomic performance [10,11,12] while largely neglecting their specific impact on EP. Although the literature has examined the influencing factors, regional heterogeneity, and dynamic characteristics of EP [13,14,15], the direct linkage between EGTs set by local governments and EP has not yet been systematically explored. In addition, traditional linear regression methods fall short in simultaneously capturing the spatial spillover effects of EP and the potential nonlinear threshold effects under the influence of EGTs [16,17], which may result in biased estimates and conflicting conclusions. Meanwhile, some scholars have noted the incentive effect of local governments setting EGTs higher than those set by the central government [18,19], but they have not yet precisely quantified the relationship between the extent to which local governments set EGTs above those set by the central government and EP. This study addresses these gaps by employing a spatial autoregressive threshold panel (SARTP) model to quantify the impact of EGTs on EP.
This study aims to address following questions. (1) Is there a significant spillover effect of EP? (2) Is there a significant threshold effect of EGTs on EP under varying EGT settings? (3) Does the top–down amplification of EGTs exacerbate the EP effects of these targets? To investigate these questions, we employ a SARTP model to explore the nonlinear impact of EGTs on EP and the spatial spillover effect of EP. Meanwhile, we use this model to identify the relationship between top–down amplification of EGTs and the EP effects of these targets. Furthermore, we assess the nonlinear impacts of EGTs on EP in provinces with varying geographies, population sizes, and industrial structures.
This study makes following contributions. (1) Enrichment of research on the socioeconomic causes of EP. Existing research on EP primarily examines its influencing factors, regional differences, and dynamic characteristics. Unlike previous studies, we adopt a unique perspective of EGTs, focusing on the nonlinear impact of EGTs set by local governments on EP. (2) Methodological advancement. Traditional linear regression methods are inadequate for effectively addressing spatial effects and nonlinear relationships. Unlike previous methods, we are the first to employ the SARTP model to capture both the spatial spillover effects of EP and the nonlinear threshold effects of EGTs on EP, significantly enhancing estimation accuracy and explanatory power. (3) Heterogeneous analysis. We explore the heterogeneous effects of EGTs on EP from three perspectives, geographical location, population size, and industrial structure, providing references for designing targeted environmental protection policies and economic growth strategies. (4) Quantitative analysis. Most existing research emphasizes qualitative analysis, examining the relationship between local and central government EGTs. For the first time, we quantify the specific relationship between the magnitude by which provincial EGTs exceed central government targets and the EP index, providing a quantitative basis for setting reasonable EGTs to protect the environment.
The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 covers the literature review. Section 3 delves into theoretical mechanisms and research hypotheses. Section 4 introduces the theoretical model. Section 5 focuses on variable selection and empirical model construction. Section 6 presents the empirical analysis. Conclusions, policy implications, and limitations are given in Section 7.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Related Research on EGTs

An EGT typically influences the allocation and utilization of resources, thereby impacting economic growth [20]. While an EGT can drive resource investment and economic expansion in the short term, it may not effectively enhance the quality and sustainability of long-term economic development [21]. On the one hand, EGTs set by local governments are often shaped by both horizontal and vertical competition. Horizontal competition occurs among governments at the same level. For instance, local governments set competitive EGTs to attract production factors and enhance their advantages. While this competition can improve governance efficiency and optimize resource allocation, it may also result in excessive rivalry and resource waste [22]. Vertical competition exists between local and central governments, with local governments actively seeking preferential policies and resource support from the central government to meet their economic growth targets. On the other hand, a performance-based promotion system aims to motivate local officials by linking rewards and punishments to their fiscal revenue growth and target achievements [23]. However, this mechanism poses a risk, as it may lead local officials to set excessive or unrealistic EGTs for short-term personal gain [24,25]. Faced with unrealistic targets, local governments often prioritize short-term economic growth over environmental protection and long-term sustainability [26].
The setting of EGTs is influenced by two main constraints: external and internal. External constraints primarily arise from the central government, which uses the GDP’s growth rate as a key indicator to assess local development effectiveness and officials’ promotion prospects. Consequently, motivated by career advancement, local officials often set ambitious EGTs to demonstrate their governance capabilities to higher-level governments, resulting in the top–down amplification of EGTs [27]. Meanwhile, local governments adopt stricter, rigid measures in terms of internal constraints. Specifically, local governments impose significant pressure on themselves by setting hard EGTs. This rigid constraint mechanism forces local governments to go all out, even striving to exceed EGTs. However, this high-intensity pressure to meet targets leads to distortions in resource allocation by local governments, thereby triggering negative consequences, such as environmental degradation and excessive resource exploitation [28].

2.2. Related Research on EP

In recent years, research on EP has focused on how factors like economic and population agglomeration impact the environment [29,30]. Based on panel data from 74 cities within China’s Yellow River Basin between 2005 and 2016, Wang et al. (2022) [31] identified the relationship between economic agglomeration and haze pollution using a spatial Durbin model. Their findings indicated that haze pollution rises during the early stage of economic agglomeration and declines as it matures. As economic agglomeration deepens, its demand for and attraction to the population will increase [32]. Excessive population concentration can lead to heightened pollution emissions, significantly worsening environmental issues. However, some scholars have argued that population agglomeration can lower resource consumption and reduce EP [33].
In addition to economic and demographic factors influencing EP, the role of the government is crucial. An inefficient government can exacerbate EP issues due to its limited capacity for effective environmental protection [34]. Conversely, a stable and knowledgeable government is essential for mitigating environmental degradation, as it can better plan and implement environmental policies while effectively addressing environmental challenges [35]. It is important to note that some scholars highlight the government’s crucial role in regulation and policymaking for EP control [36]. Zheng (2023) [37] found that multi-party cooperation, interactive monitoring, and benefit compensation can enhance local government collaboration in haze control. When environmental preferences are high, government regulation effectively reduces pollution emissions [38]. Additionally, based on panel data from 223 Chinese cities between 2005 and 2014, Shen et al. (2024) [28] explored the impact of EGTs on haze pollution using spatial autoregressions and other models. Their findings suggested that EGTs can significantly increase haze pollution.

2.3. Related Research on the EGT–EP Relationship

An EGT is related to EP in complex ways. Existing studies found that local governments often prioritize high-energy-consuming and high-emission industries to achieve economic growth, which worsens EP [16,39]. Moreover, the official promotion mechanism linked to GDP strengthens the short-term economic growth orientation, neglecting the environmental costs [2,40]. However, some studies have pointed out that including environmental protection in performance evaluations can shift EGTs towards a green orientation [41]. Currently, there are still few studies on the impact of EGTs on EP. Chai et al. (2021) [42] noted that the constraint of EGTs on air pollution has a significant threshold effect, with the inhibitory effect strengthened by industrial structure adjustments. Ren et al. (2023) [43] suggested that environmental decentralization can mitigate the adverse effects of EGT constraints on pollution. While these studies have shown results, systematic research on the impact of provincial EGTs on EP remains limited and needs further investigation.
In summary, existing research has mainly focused on the impact of factors like economic agglomeration, population agglomeration, and government regulation on EP and pollution control. However, few scholars have examined how EGTs affect EP. Additionally, existing methods have failed to effectively capture the spatial characteristics of EP and the potential nonlinear effects of related factors simultaneously, leading to biased estimates and contradictory conclusions. This paper aims to explore whether EGTs influence EP using a SARTP model. Moreover, the study identifies heterogeneous characteristics of the impact of EGTs on EP.

3. Theoretical Mechanisms and Research Hypotheses

3.1. EGTs and EP

Recently, the link between economic growth and environmental protection has gained renewed attention. Nations increasingly recognize that pursuing economic progress at the expense of environmental conservation is unsustainable. On one hand, economic growth is a vital goal for governments worldwide, closely tied to national development, social progress, and people’s well-being. On the other hand, EP, as a byproduct of economic growth, has significant and irreversible effects. If not effectively managed, EP will severely hinder sustainable economic development [44,45]. Due to relaxed environmental regulations and hindered industrial upgrades, along with suppressed technological innovation, EGTs have risen across all levels of organizations [16]. However, this persistent growth worsens regional EP and poses serious challenges for environmental protection [46]. While government-set EGTs promote economic expansion, they can also lead to the diversion of funds away from environmental protection and green technology investment, exacerbating EP [47]. Absolute EGTs significantly raise carbon emissions in horizontal competition, whereas relative targets do so in vertical competition [48].
It is important to note that local governments often prioritize high economic growth for political gains at the expense of environmental protection and balanced regional development. Specifically, government-set EGTs frequently exceed the local economy’s actual capacity. These ambitious goals are typically influenced by political pressure, performance evaluations, or rivalry with other regions [49,50]. When under high growth pressures, local governments may favor economic measures that yield short-term results. These short-term measures often neglect their long-term effects on the environment, resources, and social well-being [51]. For instance, to achieve high EGTs, local governments prioritize land quotas for traditional industrial sectors. This resource tilt exacerbates EP [28]. Meanwhile, the upgrading and substitution process of traditional polluting industries may be delayed, resulting in the continued existence of EP. Additionally, local governments compete to lower environmental standards and relax regulations to attract investment and boost economic growth. This behavior not only degrades environmental quality but also heightens unfair regional competition [52]. Regions with strict environmental standards may face higher costs and lose competitive advantages, while those that relax such standards might achieve short-term economic growth. Guo et al. (2024) [17] found that higher EGTs primarily lead to increased pollution emissions by reducing investments in pollution control. Therefore, we put forth the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1. 
EGTs have a nonlinear impact on EP. Specifically, setting high EGTs significantly increases EP.

3.2. EGT Constraint and EP

The constraint strength of EGTs indicates the reasonableness of their setting. The internal constraints of EGTs emphasize the limitations that local governments themselves face in terms of resources and capabilities [53], which restrict the ways local governments act to achieve EGTs. If an EGT is set too high, exceeding the existing resources and capabilities of local governments, it may lead to difficulties in policy implementation, an increase in short-term behavior, and, ultimately, environmental problems.
External constraints emphasize the influence and pressure exerted by the central government on EGTs set by local governments. These targets are usually directly linked to the performance evaluations of local officials. Local governments need to achieve these targets to gain political recognition and ensure that their leadership positions are not affected [54]. To demonstrate their capability and determination to the central government, local governments tend to establish elevated EGTs. Consequently, EGTs from the central government down to local governments exhibit a trend of gradual expansion [55]. Additionally, local governments set EGTs higher than those of their peers primarily to stand out in the competition among local governments [56]. This tendency to establish excessively high EGTs reflects not only fierce competition among local governments but also a strong drive for performance and promotion. Under pressure to achieve EGTs, local governments may adopt measures that are detrimental to long-term sustainable development [16]. A common practice is to distort resource allocation by directing more resources towards sectors that can rapidly stimulate economic growth, prioritizing EGTs over environmental costs [18]. For instance, local governments may prioritize land needs for high-profit, quick-return projects, such as industrial production, while neglecting the land needs of environmental protection industries or green technologies, thereby exacerbating EP. Additionally, to focus funds on achieving EGTs, local governments often invest in areas that yield immediate benefits but conflict with green development principles. Meanwhile, local governments may cut budgets for environmental protection infrastructure. This approach results in ineffective pollution control measures and exacerbates EP [43]. Therefore, we put forth the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 2. 
Top–down amplification of EGTs aggravates their EP effect.

4. Theoretical Methodology

4.1. SARTP Model

When analyzing the relationship between EGTs and EP, traditional spatial regression models and panel data methods struggle to handle both spatial autocorrelation and potential nonlinear effects simultaneously. For example, Chai et al. (2021) [42] used a spatial Durbin model to analyze the spillover effects of air pollution and a threshold panel model to assess the nonlinear impact of EGTs on air pollution. Shen et al. (2024) [28] constructed a fixed effects model to assess the average impact of EGTs on haze pollution and then applied a spatial econometric framework to examine the spatial spillover characteristics of haze pollution. In contrast, the SARTP model simultaneously captures both the spatial spillover effect of EP and the nonlinear influence of EGTs on EP by incorporating a spatial lag term and a threshold effect. Thus, it offers a more accurate and comprehensive analytical framework for this study, addressing the shortcomings of existing methods.
The threshold panel model divides data into different intervals by setting thresholds, with each interval having distinct regression coefficients. This model reveals the nonlinear relationships between variables. Hansen (1999) [57] first introduced the single-threshold panel model as follows:
y i t = β 1 x i t I q i t γ + β 2 x i t I q i t > γ + μ i + ε i t ,   i = 1 , , N ,   t = 1 , , T
where the subscript i represents the i - th individual, t denotes the t - th year, y i t is the observations of the dependent variable, x i t is the observations of the explanatory variable, q i t signifies a threshold variable, β 1 and β 2 denote the regression coefficients of the different regimes, I ( ) is an indicator function, u i stands for individual fixed effects, and ε i t i i d 0 , σ 2 is the random error term. Equation (1) considers the single-threshold case, which can be extended to the multi-threshold case according to the steps of the measurement test of sample data.
Adding a spatial autoregressive term to the single-threshold panel model results in the single-threshold SARTP model [58]:
y i t = ρ j = 1 N W i j y j t + β 1 x i t I q i t γ + β 2 x i t I q i t > γ + μ i + ε i t
where ρ stands for the spatial correlation coefficient, W i j is the spatial weight, and other variables are the same as Equation (1).

4.2. Test of Threshold Effect and Threshold Number

It is essential to verify the threshold effect and determine the number of regimes before conducting empirical analysis with the SARTP model. The hypothesis of no threshold effect is H 10 : β 1 = β 2 , and the alternative hypothesis is H 11 : β 1 β 2 . We construct the F statistic defined as F 1 = S 0 S 1 ( γ ^ ) σ ^ 2 to test whether the SARTP model has a threshold. S 0 and S 1 ( γ ^ ) represent the residual sum of squares (RSS) under H 10 and H 11 , respectively. σ ^ 2 = 1 N ( T 1 ) S 1 ( γ ^ ) serves as the consistent estimator of σ 2 . We obtain the asymptotic distribution and P value of F 1 using the bootstrap method.
When a threshold effect exists, the number of thresholds must be determined. The null hypothesis is H 20 : Only one threshold exists, and the alternative hypothesis is H 21 : Two thresholds exist. We construct the LR statistic defined as L R 1 = S 1 ( γ ^ 1 ) S 1 ( γ ^ 2 ) σ ^ * 2 to verify whether H 20 holds. S 1 ( γ ^ 1 ) and S 1 ( γ ^ 2 ) signify the RSS under H 20 and H 21 , respectively. σ ^ * 2 = 1 N ( T 1 ) S 1 ( γ ^ 2 ) is the consistent estimator of σ 2 . When there are more than two regimes, the corresponding test method can be performed similarly.

5. Variable Selection, Empirical Model Construction, and Data Description

5.1. Variable Selection

Environmental pollution (EP) is the dependent variable. We create an EP index system composed of wastewater discharge, SO2 discharge, and general industrial solid waste production [59,60]. In this paper, the entropy method calculates the EP index for 30 Chinese provinces from 2008 to 2021. The detailed description of the EP index’s construction can be found in Appendix A.
An economic growth target (EGT) serves as the core explanatory variable. An EGT refers to the GDP growth rate a country or region aims to achieve over time [61]. An EGT includes not just the concept of speed but the unity of quantity and quality. It emphasizes the coordination of economic proportions, structural optimization, and sustainable development while maintaining a moderate economic growth rate. We collected data on EGTs from Chinese provincial government reports.
Top–down amplification of economic growth targets (PNGAP) is the threshold variable. We measure this variable according to the difference between provincial and central EGTs [27].
EP is influenced not only by EGTs but also by various internal and external factors. To accurately assess the impact of these factors on EP, we select the following control variables based on the existing literature.
Openness (OPEN). While opening up can drive rapid economic growth, it also leads to increased resource consumption. This excessive consumption not only worsens resource scarcity but may also cause environmental damage [62]. Openness is measured by the ratio of total import and export trade to regional GDP.
Environmental regulation (ER). Environmental regulation encompasses laws, regulations, policies, and technical standards established by the government or relevant agencies to protect the environment and mitigate pollution. These measures aim to reduce EP by limiting industrial activities, raising emission standards, and promoting cleaner production and technological innovation [63]. The investment ratio in pollution control to industrial added value reflects environmental regulation.
Foreign direct investment (FDI). FDI can enhance economic scale but may also lead to increased resource consumption and pollution. Neglecting environmental protection while attracting foreign investment could exacerbate pollution issues [64]. Foreign direct investment is indicated by its proportion in regional GDP.
Technological investment (TECH). Technological investment drives innovation, leading to greener production technologies. Advanced environmental protection technologies can effectively treat and restore polluted environments [65]. Technological investment is defined as the ratio of fiscal expenditure on science and technology to general budget expenditure in each region.
Industrial agglomeration (IA). During the early stages of industrial agglomeration, underdeveloped infrastructure leads to enterprise competitiveness relying heavily on production factor inputs. This may prompt governments to relax environmental regulations to boost economic growth, worsening pollution [66]. To measure industrial agglomeration, we use the proportion of employed individuals to the area of the regional administrative division.
R&D intensity (RD). With increased R&D intensity, enterprises can create more environmentally friendly and energy-efficient production technologies and products. The use of these technologies significantly reduces pollutant emissions during production, thereby lessening EP [67]. R&D intensity is expressed as the ratio of internal R&D expenditure to gross regional product.
Informationization level (IL). The enhancement of informationization promotes rapid technological advancements in clean energy and pollution control technologies. These technologies help reduce pollutant emissions during production, improve resource utilization efficiency, and lower EP [68]. We chose the proportion of total postal and telecommunications businesses within the regional GDP to represent IL.
Energy consumption (EC). The widespread use of fossil fuels results in significant emissions of harmful gases, worsening the greenhouse effect and air pollution and contributing to environmental issues like acid rain [69]. Energy consumption is assessed by per capita energy consumption.
In conclusion, while EGTs can drive local governments to promote economic growth, they may also exacerbate EP. Meanwhile, factors like OPEN, ER, FDI, TECH, IA, RD, IL, and EC can influence EP in the process through which EGTs affect EP. For instance, overly high EGTs and EC may exacerbate EP. In this process, factors like TECH and RD can help mitigate EP by fostering technological advancements.

5.2. Empirical Model Construction

EP can spread pollutants to nearby areas via air, water, or soil. Thus, we explore the spatial spillover effect of EP using an SAR model. The model is as follows:
E P i t = ρ j = 1 N W i j E P j t + β 1 E G T i t + β 2 C o n t r o l i t + μ i + ε i t
where i = 1 , , 30 ,   t = 1 , , 14 , E P i t and E G T i t are, respectively, the environmental pollution index and economic growth targets for the i - th province in the t - th year, C o n t r o l i t = O P E N i t , E R i t , F D I i t , T E C H i t , I A i t , R D i t , I L i t , E C i t comprises a vector of control factors, β 1 and β 2 stand for parameters to be estimated, ρ is the spatial correlation coefficient, j = 1 n W i j E P i t signifies the spatial lag term of the EP index, W i j stands for the spatial weight of the geographical distance at the i - th and j - th provinces, u i denotes the individual fixed effect, and ε i t i i d 0 , σ 2 represents the random error term.
Based on Equation (3), we introduce a threshold effect to examine the nonlinear impact of EGTs on EP. Among them, EGT is included in the SARTP model as a threshold variable. The details are as follows:
E P i t = ρ j = 1 N W i j E P j t + β 1 X i t I E G T i t γ 1 + k = 2 K 1 β k X i t I γ k 1 < E G T i t γ k   + β K X i t I E G T i t > γ K 1 + μ i + ε i t
where X i t = E G T i t , O P E N i t , E R i t , F D I i t , T E C H i t , I A i t , R D i t , I L i t , E C i t serves as the core explanatory variable and all control variables; β k = β k 1 , β k 2 , , β k 9 denotes the regression coefficient vector for the core explanatory variable and control variables within the k - th regime; and γ k signifies the threshold value. In discussing research hypothesis H2, simply replace the threshold variable in Equation (4) with PNGAP.

5.3. Data Source and Description

Excluded due to incomplete data in Tibet. Thus, we will analyze a panel dataset of 30 Chinese provinces between 2008 and 2021. The original data are sourced from the China Statistical Yearbook, the China Labor Statistics Yearbook, and the National Bureau of Statistics. The related variables and their descriptive statistical results are shown in Table 1, where missing values are filled using linear interpolation and logarithmic transformation is applied to certain variables with excessively large values.
To describe the spatial distribution of EP in China, we analyze sample data from each province for 2008 and 2021. Figure 1 illustrates this distribution for both years. Overall, the EP index decreased in 2021 compared to 2006. Notably, the eastern and central regions exhibit higher pollution indices than the western regions, indicating more severe environmental issues in the former during the sample period, while western areas experience relatively minor pollution.
EP varies significantly across different regions of China, influenced by factors like economic development, industrial agglomeration, and energy use. Firstly, the eastern and central regions are economically developed, experiencing rapid industrialization and urbanization that lead to significant resource consumption and pollutant emissions. In contrast, while the western region is also developing quickly, its weaker economic foundation and lower level of industrialization result in relatively less EP. Secondly, the eastern and central regions attract many enterprises due to their favorable geographical locations and traffic conditions. While this agglomeration boosts regional economic development, it also leads to concentrated EP. In contrast, the western region experiences lower industrial concentration and less environmental pressure due to natural conditions and traffic limitations. Finally, the eastern and central regions have high energy demands and traditionally rely on polluting sources like coal, resulting in significant pollutant discharge. In contrast, while the western region has abundant energy resources, it has recently focused more on clean and efficient energy use, leading to relatively lower EP.

6. Empirical Results

6.1. Panel Unit Root Test and Panel Cointegration Test

Before using the SARTP model, it is crucial to verify the stationarity of each variable to prevent pseudo-regression resulting from non-stationary series. To achieve this, we utilize unit root tests, specifically IPS, LLC, Fisher–ADF, and Fisher–PP. According to Table 2, only ER, TECH, and IL satisfy all tests, whereas the remaining variables are determined to be non-stationary. To test for a long-term, stable relationship between variables, we employ the panel cointegration test. Common methods include the Pedroni, Kao, and Westerlund tests. Notably, Panel–ADF and Group–ADF in the Pedroni tests are more accurate for testing short-term data [70]. Thus, we utilize the Pedroni test method for our analysis. As shown in Table 3, there is a long-term co-integration relationship among the variables, allowing them to be used for subsequent modeling and estimation.

6.2. Spatial Correlation Test

Before using the SARTP model, it is essential to test the spatial correlation of EP. We assess this by calculating the global Moran’s I [71], with the results shown in Table 4. Moran’s I values for EP during the sample period are all positive and mostly significant. This indicates that EP is significantly spatially correlated. Although the correlation pattern has changed, a spatial effect analysis can be carried out in general.

6.3. Estimation Results

Before using the SARTP model, we conduct two key tests. Firstly, we perform the threshold existence test using EGT as the threshold variable. The results show F1 = 142.3784 and p = 0.000, indicating a significant threshold effect between EGTs and EP. Secondly, the threshold number test indicates F2 = 0.000 and p = 1, confirming a single threshold. Thus, the model is identified as a two-regime SARTP model. Column (3) of Table 5 presents the estimation results for this model. For comparison, we include the estimated results from the fixed effect (FE) and spatial autoregressive (SAR) models. Notably, the SARTP model has the highest R ¯ 2 among the three models. This indicates that the SARTP model is superior in capturing both spatial spillover and nonlinear threshold effects compared to the other models. Therefore, we will focus on analyzing the results from the SARTP model. It can be seen from Table 5 that the EGT threshold is 0.0750. The regression coefficient vectors β 1 and β 2 indicate the impact of EGTs and control variables on EP in regime I (EGT ≤ 0.0750) and regime II (EGT > 0.0750), respectively.
Table 6 displays the mean values of all variables for both regime I and regime II. The EP index in regime II is significantly higher than in regime I, indicating that EP worsens as EGTs rise. Several factors contribute to this issue. First, increasing EGTs often push companies to adopt energy-intensive and high-emission production methods in pursuit of higher output and profits. This approach typically results in significant pollutant emissions, worsening EP. Secondly, while pursuing economic growth, governments and enterprises tend to prioritize economic development over environmental protection and sustainable practices, leading to greater resource consumption and environmental damage. Additionally, achieving these growth targets significantly raises the demand for resources, further intensifying environmental pressure.
As shown in column (3) of Table 5, when the EGT exceeds 0.0750, the regression coefficient for the EGT rises from 0.1416 to 0.3799, shifting its impact on EP from insignificant to significant. This suggests that higher EGTs notably worsen EP, confirming Hypothesis 1. This may be due to high EGTs leading to excessive resource consumption and environmental damage. Meanwhile, weak government oversight allows enterprises to illegally emit pollutants for profit. Enterprises prioritize short-term economic gains over long-term environmental impact, exacerbating environmental issues.
Furthermore, as EGTs increase, while OPEN can mitigate EP, EC further exacerbates it. Additionally, the mitigating effect of RD on EP diminishes. In regions with lower EGTs, TECH significantly reduces EP. The enhancement of EGTs often accelerates opening up, attracting more foreign investment. The high environmental standards set by foreign-funded enterprises further motivate domestic companies to upgrade their environmental practices and boost market competitiveness. However, economic growth pressures lead to biased resource allocation towards short-term projects, constraining long-term investments like green technology R&D. The conflict between short-term economic interests and long-term sustainable development has led companies and governments to prioritize rapid economic growth over the development of eco-friendly technologies. In contrast, regions with lower EGTs experience less economic pressure, allowing for more rational resource allocation and greater investment in environmental protection infrastructure, effectively reducing EP. It is important to note that the increased EGTs come with a broad expansion of economic activity, leading to a surge in energy demand. To meet the needs of industry, transportation, construction, and other sectors, fossil fuel exploitation has risen significantly, resulting in substantial harmful pollutant emissions during combustion and serious EP.
To evaluate the reliability of these findings, we re-estimate the SARTP model using the adjacency matrix and the economic distance matrix instead of the previously used geographical distance matrix. Table 7 indicates that the model remains divided into two regimes based on the two matrices above using EGT as the threshold variable. The coefficient’s magnitude and direction for EGT are very close to the results in column (3) of Table 5. This indicates that changes in the spatial weight matrix do not alter the interpretation of the research findings. Furthermore, the spatial autocorrelation coefficient ρ is significantly positive under various spatial weight matrices. These findings highlight the robustness of the SARTP model. It is worth noting that educational level (EDU) may influence EP by strengthening environmental awareness and promoting the adoption of green technologies. Therefore, we include EDU as a control variable in the SARTP model, where EDU is defined as the average years of education. Column (3) of Table 7 shows that even after controlling for educational level, high EGTs still significantly worsen EP, confirming the robustness of our findings. Additionally, the impact of educational level on EP is found to be insignificant.
The logical starting point of this paper is that in provinces where economic growth targets are set higher, government-led economic development has significantly exacerbated environmental pollution. However, a potential concern is that environmental pollution may not be the result of government intervention but rather driven by market forces. Given that economic growth targets are primarily set by the government, the difference between the actual economic growth rate and the growth target is mainly influenced by market factors. Therefore, this paper constructs two core explanatory variables for a placebo test: the difference between the actual economic growth rate and the economic growth target (TARGET1) and the ratio of the actual economic growth rate to the economic growth target (TARGET2). As shown in columns (1) and (2) of Table 8, when the economic growth target (EGT) exceeds 0.0800, the coefficients of TARGET1 and TARGET2 are both significantly negative at the 1% level. This indicates that in provinces with higher economic growth targets, market-driven economic development significantly reduces environmental pollution. This conclusion is in stark contrast to the baseline regression results, thereby confirming the robustness of the baseline findings.
Notably, the results of the placebo test have important policy implications. On the one hand, properly managing the relationship between the government and the market is a key prerequisite for achieving high-quality development. On the other hand, market-oriented resource allocation is regarded as an effective way to guide various production factors towards green and low-carbon development. Therefore, the government should reduce its intervention in market operations and rely more on market-driven economic mechanisms to promote sustainable green development.

6.4. Heterogeneity Tests

6.4.1. Heterogeneity Based on Geographical Location

Geographical location influences the EP effect of EGTs, as different regions experience varying levels of EP due to disparities in resource distribution, climate conditions, transportation, and policy support. Therefore, we categorize 30 provinces into eastern, central, and western regions based on their geographical locations [72]. The results in Table 9 indicate that as EGTs increase, the EP effect intensifies in the central region, is somewhat alleviated in the western region, and remains insignificant in the eastern region. This indicates that EGTs affect EP differently across regions.
The impact of EGTs on EP varies across different geographical locations, primarily due to the disparities in regional economic development levels and industrial structures. The central region has a high proportion of heavy industry, which generates significant pollutants during production. When EGTs are raised, investment in heavy industry may increase to meet economic goals quickly, leading to greater EP. The economic structure of the western provinces is relatively simple, and, in recent years, more proactive ecological protection measures have been implemented. Even though EGTs have been raised, the lower levels of industrialization have led to a reduction in pollution’s impacts. Conversely, the eastern region’s early economic development has led to a more optimized industrial structure with complete industrial chains. Industries in the eastern region typically have higher technical content and added value while causing relatively less environmental harm. The geographical differences reflect the imbalance among provinces in terms of economic development and industrial structure adjustment. These factors collectively influence the varying responses of different regions to the relationship between EGTs and EP.

6.4.2. Heterogeneity Based on Population Size

The EP effect of EGTs may relate to regional population size. A larger population exacerbates these effects, as densely populated areas generate more waste and emissions, leading to greater environmental issues. Therefore, we divide the 30 provinces into two groups based on median population. As shown in Table 10, regardless of population size, the EP effect of EGTs diminishes as they increase. However, overall, the EP effect of EGTs is relatively greater in provinces with a large population size.
The difference in population size leads to varying impacts of EGTs on EP, primarily due to the higher resource demand and pollution emission pressures faced by provinces with larger populations. Provinces with larger populations are generally more industrialized and have concentrated production activities. These activities consume significant resources and emit higher levels of pollutants. Additionally, resource allocation in populous provinces may be distorted by excessive demand for resources. To drive economic growth, governments and enterprises in these provinces often prioritize resources for energy-intensive, high-emission industries at the expense of environmental protection, worsening pollution. In provinces with smaller populations, the industrial structure is more simplified, with lower resource demand and pollution emissions. Additionally, environmental protection measures in these provinces may be easier to implement, resulting in a smaller impact of EGTs on EP.

6.4.3. Heterogeneity Based on Industrial Structure

The EP effect of EGTs may be linked to regional industrial structure. In areas at early or mid-industrialization stages, the tertiary industry has a low share, with the secondary industry driving economic growth, leading to a more pronounced EP effect. Conversely, in regions with developed economies and a strong tertiary sector, economic growth relies more on technological and service innovation, thereby reducing EP risk. Based on the relationship between the proportion of tertiary industry output value and the sample average from each province during the study period, we categorize the samples into regions with low and high tertiary industry proportions for testing. The results in Table 11 show that the EP effect of EGTs is significantly greater in provinces with a low proportion of tertiary industry, while it is not significant in those with a high proportion.
The difference in industrial structure leads to varying impacts of EGTs on EP, primarily due to the resource consumption characteristics and pollution emission levels of different industries. Manufacturing and heavy industry rely heavily on energy and raw materials. Their production processes involve high energy consumption and significant pollutant emissions. In provinces with a low proportion of the tertiary industry, traditional industries have a more pronounced pollution effect when driving economic growth. In contrast, provinces with a higher proportion of the tertiary industry depend more on the service sector and high-tech industries for economic growth. These sectors use fewer resources and lower pollution emissions through technological innovation and efficiency. In addition, the tertiary industry typically has mature environmental policies and governance systems, allowing for more effective pollution control.

6.5. Further Discussion

When local governments set easily achievable EGTs, they are less likely to distort resource allocation. However, to showcase governance capabilities to the central government, local governments often set ambitious growth targets, resulting in top–down amplification of these economic goals. This behavior can distort resource allocation further and worsen EP caused by economic growth. Based on the analysis above, PNGAP is incorporated into the SARTP model as a threshold variable. First, the threshold existence test yields F1 = 115.7785, p = 0.000, indicating a threshold effect between EGTs and EP. Next, the threshold number test results in F2 = −2.3066, p = 1, confirming a single threshold. Thus, the model is identified as a two-regime SARTP model.
In Table 12, column (1) employs the geographical distance matrix to estimate the SARTP model. The findings suggest that when PNGAP exceeds 0.0050, the regression coefficient for the EGT rises from 0.3611 to 0.4469, shifting their impact on EP from insignificant to significant. This indicates that the top–down amplification of EGTs exacerbates EP caused by pursuing these targets, confirming Hypothesis 2. Column (2) of Table 12 re-estimates the SARTP model using an adjacency matrix instead of the geographical distance matrix. EGT coefficients are similar in magnitude and direction to those in column (1), further validating the robustness of the research’s conclusions.
This can be attributed to several factors. First, higher-level governments view economic growth as a key performance indicator, pressuring local governments to set excessively high EGTs. Second, to meet high EGTs, local governments often pursue short-term, profit-driven strategies that favor resource-intensive and polluting industries. Additionally, local governments lack effective environmental supervision, leading to insufficient investment in environmental protection and difficulty in curbing violations. These combined factors result in local governments overlooking environmental costs and sustainability, exacerbating EP.

7. Conclusions, Policy Implications, and Limitations

7.1. Conclusions

Using panel data from 30 Chinese provinces, we utilize a SARTP model to explore the EP problem from the perspective of EGTs. The research findings indicate the following. (1) EP has a significant positive spatial spillover effect. A 1% increase in the EP index in adjacent provinces results in a 0.5870% increase in the observing province. (2) For provinces with EGTs above 7.5%, a 1% increase in an EGT results in a 0.3799% increase in the EP index. For provinces with EGTs below 7.5%, the impact of EGTs on EP is not significant. (3) As EGTs increase, openness reduces EP, but the mitigating effect of R&D intensity on EP weakens, and energy consumption exacerbates it. In provinces with low EGTs, technological investment significantly lowers EP. The impact of other control variables on EP is not significant. (4) As EGTs increase, the EP effect intensifies in central provinces, weakens in western provinces, and remains insignificant in eastern provinces. Provinces with larger populations experience greater EP effects from EGTs compared to those with smaller populations. Compared to provinces where the tertiary industry leads, those with a low proportion of it experience significantly greater EP effects from EGTs. (5) The top–down amplification of EGTs exacerbates EP caused by pursuing these targets. When the provincial EGT exceeds the central target by 0.5%, a 1% increase in the EGT results in a 0.4469% increase in the EP index.

7.2. Policy Implications

The policy implications derived from the aforementioned research findings are as follows.

7.2.1. Create a Joint Mechanism for Inter-Provincial EP Prevention and Control and Improve the Dynamic Monitoring Network for Border Pollution

Given the significant trans-regional spillover effects of EP, local governments should establish inter-provincial joint prevention and control mechanisms to foster inter-provincial pollution management communities. Specific measures include the following. First, implement ecological compensation mechanisms and tax differentiation policies to encourage environmentally friendly practices and reduce pollution emissions. Second, create a regional emission trading market to facilitate trading among enterprises, achieving economic and environmental benefits simultaneously. Additionally, local governments must enhance the dynamic monitoring network for border pollution to understand real-time pollution conditions and respond promptly with appropriate measures.

7.2.2. Set Realistic EGTs, Boost Environmental Protection Investment, and Minimize EP

In response to the notable aggravation of EP in provinces where EGTs exceed 7.5%, here are some policy recommendations. On one hand, policymakers should set realistic EGTs and recognize the environmental pressures associated with high economic growth. Local governments must incorporate environmental protection into their economic development plans to avoid prioritizing economic expansion at the expense of the environment. On the other hand, local governments need to boost investment in environmental protection in high-growth provinces and enhance their governance capabilities. This includes improving environmental infrastructure and monitoring systems for timely and accurate assessments of environmental conditions.

7.2.3. Promote Opening Up, Optimize R&D Allocation, Upgrade Energy Structure, and Boost Technological Investment to Reduce EP

Considering the need to weigh the effect of openness, R&D intensity, energy consumption, and technology investment on EP when setting EGTs, local governments and relevant enterprises should implement the following measures. (1) Given that openness significantly reduces EP, local governments should steadfastly promote high-level opening up, expand the scale of imports and exports, and effectively reduce EP. (2) Given the diminishing impact of R&D intensity on reducing EP, relevant enterprises should optimize their R&D resource allocation. They should encourage technological innovation towards green and low-carbon fields to ensure that R&D activities effectively enhance environmental quality. (3) Given that energy consumption significantly aggravates EP, high-energy-consuming enterprises should strictly limit total energy use, accelerate the transformation of their energy structure, promote clean energy adoption, and fundamentally reduce sources of pollution. (4) Given that technology investment significantly reduces EP, local governments should enhance their support for such investments to leverage their role in minimizing pollution.

7.2.4. Differentiated EGTs Should Be Based on Each Province’s Geographical Location, Population Size, and Industrial Structure

Given the significant differences in geographical location, population size, and industrial structure across provinces, each province should establish tailored EGTs. (1) Central provinces must enhance environmental supervision, promote green technologies, and optimize industrial structures to minimize EP. (2) Western provinces should enhance ecological protection, promote coordinated regional development, and cultivate characteristic industries to balance economic development with environmental protection. (3) Provinces with larger populations should boost public understanding of environmental conservation efforts, strengthen environmental regulations, and promote eco-friendly living practices. (4) Provinces with a smaller share of the tertiary industry should adjust their industrial structure, actively develop the tertiary sector, and receive policy support and vocational training.

7.2.5. The Central Government Should Incorporate Environmental Protection into Local Government Performance Assessments and Guide Them to Optimize EGTs

Provincial governments often set overly ambitious EGTs to showcase their governance to the central government, which can result in heightened EP. The central government should set realistic EGTs, considering each province’s actual situation and the capacity of resources and the environment. Simultaneously, the central government should incorporate environmental protection into local government performance assessments and reasonably reduce the weight of EGTs. Furthermore, the central government should enhance environmental supervision of local governments, establish an environmental accountability mechanism, promote the green economy, optimize industrial structure, and strengthen resource conservation and recycling. To summarize, the central and local governments should enhance policy coordination to promote the balanced development of the economy and environment, achieve sustainable development goals, and ensure a win–win outcome for economic growth and environmental conservation.

7.3. Limitations

Indeed, this study has certain limitations and requires further exploration in future research. (1) We select wastewater, SO2, and solid waste as the three pollutants to construct the EP index. Future research can include other pollutants, like PM2.5 or CO2, within the scope of the EP index. (2) The conclusions of this study may have limitations in other countries. Future research can apply the model and analysis methods of this study to other countries. (3) Although the SARTP model and placebo tests are adopted in this paper to alleviate the endogeneity problem, there may still be unobservable confounding factors due to the limitations of the data and the model. On the basis of the SARTP model, future research can consider the spatial error term and serial correlation or add variables like political dynamics and informal governance practices to strengthen the identification and control of unobservable confounding factors so as to further improve the accuracy of the results.

Author Contributions

J.C., conceptualization, formal analysis, funding acquisition, project administration, methodology, writing—review and edit; C.W., visualization, software, data curation, formal analysis, investigation, writing—original draft. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Social Science Fund of China, grant number 22BTJ024.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data used in the study are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Appendix A

To measure EP effectively, we select wastewater discharge, SO2 discharge, and general industrial solid waste production as key indicators. These metrics effectively reflect the impact of different pollution forms on the environment and provide a scientific basis for assessing EP levels.
Criteria for indicator selection: On one hand, wastewater discharge, SO2 discharge, and general industrial solid waste production are the primary sources of water, air, and solid waste pollution. On the other hand, these three pollutants are prevalent during China’s industrialization and significantly impact the environment. Local governments focus their pollution control efforts on these three pollutants. Therefore, these three pollutants are appropriate indicators for measuring the EP index.
Weight calculation method: We employ the entropy method to objectively determine the weights of each indicator based on data variability. Indicators with greater variability are deemed more important, resulting in higher weights. The process involves first calculating the entropy of each indicator to reflect the distribution of information, then standardizing the entropy values to eliminate dimensional differences, and, finally, calculating the weights of each indicator based on the standardized entropy values to obtain the final composite EP index.
Rationale for the method: The entropy method avoids subjective bias, ensuring that weight allocation is based on the inherent variability of the data, thereby guaranteeing the objectivity and scientific rigor of EP assessment.

References

  1. Zhang, G.; Jia, Y.; Su, B.; Xiu, J. Environmental regulation, economic development and air pollution in the cities of China: Spatial econometric analysis based on policy scoring and satellite data. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 328, 129496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Li, H.; Zhou, L.A. Political turnover and economic performance: The incentive role of personnel control in China. J. Public Econ. 2005, 89, 1743–1762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Rafei, M.; Esmaeili, P.; Balsalobre-Lorente, D. A step towards environmental mitigation: How do economic complexity and natural resources matter? Focusing on different institutional quality level countries. Resour. Policy 2022, 78, 102848. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Yu, H.; Wang, J.; Hou, J.; Yu, B.; Pan, Y. The effect of economic growth pressure on green technology innovation: Do environmental regulation, government support, and financial development matter? J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 330, 117172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Chu, T.; Wang, S. Environmental tax-for-fee reform and China’s urban green innovation: A local government behavior perspective. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2025, 114, 107950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ding, X.; Ren, J.; Lu, H.; Hussain, J.; Zhou, R. Strategic dynamics of local governments in regional collaborative governance: An evolutionary game theory analysis of haze pollution response in the Fen-Wei Plain, China. Heliyon 2024, 10, e39242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Yang, Z.; Ding, H. Turning a blind eye: How local government fiscal distress affects the entry of energy-intensive enterprises. Energy Econ. 2024, 138, 107828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Yang, X.; Zhang, P.; Hu, X.; Qamri, G.M. Environmental pollution and officials’ promotion: How China’s green attention matters. J. Environ. Manag. 2024, 365, 121590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  9. Lorente, D.B.; Mohammed, K.S.; Cifuentes-Faura, J.; Shahzad, U. Dynamic connectedness among climate change index, green financial assets and renewable energy markets: Novel evidence from sustainable development perspective. Renew. Energy 2023, 204, 94–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Ren, M.; Ke, K.; Yu, X.; Zhao, J. Local governments’ economic growth target pressure and bank loan loss provision: Evidence from China. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2023, 87, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Li, S.; Li, G. Rethinking government behavior: Local government self-interest and economic development quality. Econ. Anal. Policy 2025, 86, 1645–1659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Ren, S.; Zhou, P.; Wu, B.; Wang, P. Welfare public service expenditure, financing platform debt, and economic growth: Evidence from China. Econ. Anal. Policy 2025, 87, 649–664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Liu, K.; Lin, B. Research on influencing factors of environmental pollution in China: A spatial econometric analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 206, 356–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Chang, Y.; Hu, P.; Huang, Y.; Duan, Z. Effectiveness and heterogeneity evaluation of regional collaborative governance on haze pollution control: Evidence from 284 prefecture-level cities in China. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2022, 86, 104120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Xiang, S.; Huang, X.; Lin, N.; Yi, Z. Synergistic reduction of air pollutants and carbon emissions in Chengdu-Chongqing urban agglomeration, China: Spatial-temporal characteristics, regional differences, and dynamic evolution. J. Clean. Prod. 2025, 493, 144929. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Yu, Y.; Li, K.; Duan, S.; Song, C. Economic growth and environmental pollution in China: New evidence from government work reports. Energy Econ. 2023, 124, 106803. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Guo, L.; Yang, M.; Su, M.; Li, H. Hidden environmental costs of economic ambitions: An empirical study of pollution emissions in the wake of growth targets. J. Clean. Prod. 2024, 450, 141925. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Chen, Y.; Tang, J. The impact of economic growth targets on the level of green development—A perspective on officials’ promotion incentives and environmental regulations. J. Environ. Manag. 2024, 368, 122056. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  19. Chen, B.; Zhang, Y.; Bell, C.M. Economic growth target setting under environmental constraints: A spatial autoregressive model analysis of Chinese prefectures. J. Environ. Manag. 2025, 376, 124473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. Zhang, J.; Tian, G.L.; Yuan, S.; Tu, Y. Exploring the nexus between mineral policies, natural resource utilization, and green reforms for driving economic growth in China. Resour. Policy 2024, 89, 104619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wu, T.; Yi, M.; Zhang, Y. Towards cities’ green growth: The combined influence of economic growth targets and environmental regulations. Cities 2024, 146, 104759. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Zhai, Y.; Wang, W.; Zhou, L. Green efficiency loss caused by economic growth goals: Evidence from an emerging economy. Econ. Anal. Policy 2024, 81, 983–995. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Wu, H.; Yang, J.; Yang, Q. The pressure of economic growth and the issuance of Urban Investment Bonds: Based on panel data from 2005 to 2011 in China. J. Asian Econ. 2021, 76, 101341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Chen, J.; Chen, X.; Hou, Q.; Hu, M. Haste doesn’t bring success: Top-down amplification of economic growth targets and enterprise overcapacity. J. Corp. Financ. 2021, 70, 102059. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Zhang, Z.; Xu, Z.; Ding, Y. Do economic growth target constraints affect firm innovation? Econ. Anal. Policy 2023, 78, 373–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Liang, Q.; Huang, J.; Liang, M.; Li, J. Economic growth targets and bank risk exposure: Evidence from China. Econ. Model. 2024, 135, 106702. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Yu, Y.; Pan, Y. The mysterious coexistence of rapid economic growth and a lag in the service industry’s upgrade in China: An interpretation based on the economic growth target constraints perspective. Econ. Res. J. 2019, 54, 150–165. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  28. Shen, L.; Liu, H.; Wang, Y. Does the Mobilization of Economic Growth Targets Aggravate Haze Pollution?—Research Based on Prefecture-level Cities in China. Chin. J. Econom. 2024, 4, 1149–1171. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  29. Zhou, M.; Shao, W.; Jiang, K.; Huang, L. How does economic agglomeration affect carbon emissions at the county level in Liaoning China? Ecol. Indic. 2024, 158, 111507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Wei, Y.; Lemoy, R.; Caruso, G. The effect of population size on urban heat island and NO2 air pollution: Review and meta-analysis. City Environ. Interact. 2024, 24, 100161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Wang, X.; Zhang, Q.; Chang, W.Y. Does economic agglomeration affect haze pollution? Evidence from China’s Yellow River basin. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 335, 130271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Liu, S.; Li, Y.; Shen, Z.; Yu, J.; Xu, Z. The impact of population agglomeration on economic resilience: Evidence from 280 cities in China. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2024, 94, 103429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Erdogan, S. Linking green fiscal policy, energy, economic growth, population dynamics, and environmental degradation: Empirical evidence from Germany. Energy Policy 2024, 189, 114110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Feng, S.; Li, J.; Nawi, H.M.; Alhamdi, F.M.; Shamansurova, Z. Assessing the nexus between fintech, natural resources, government effectiveness, and environmental pollution in China: A QARDL study. Resour. Policy 2024, 88, 104433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Deng, Q.S.; Cuesta, L.; Alvarado, R.; Murshed, M.; Tillaguango, B.; Işık, C.; Rehman, A. Nexus between government stability and environmental pollution. J. Clean. Prod. 2024, 434, 140061. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Hossain, B. Do government spending on pollution abatement and targeted environmental policies promote green growth in Canada? J. Clean. Prod. 2024, 434, 140391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Zheng, L. Collaborative governance of haze pollution between local governments. Alex. Eng. J. 2023, 65, 119–129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Liu, Z.; Kong, L.; Xu, K. The impact of public environmental preferences and government environmental regulations on corporate pollution emissions. J. Environ. Manag. 2024, 351, 119766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  39. Jiang, S.; Tan, X.; Hu, P.; Wang, Y.; Shi, L.; Ma, Z.; Lu, G. Air pollution and economic growth under local government competition: Evidence from China, 2007–2016. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 334, 130231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Zheng, S.; Kahn, M.E.; Sun, W.; Luo, D. Incentives for China’s urban mayors to mitigate pollution externalities: The role of the central government and public environmentalism. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2014, 47, 61–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Fan, L.; Yao, S.; Zhou, C.; Richardson-Barlow, C. Environmental regulatory policies and local air quality: Evidence from a comparison of environmental policy effects in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2025, 518, 145906. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Chai, J.; Hao, Y.; Wu, H.; Yang, Y. Do constraints created by economic growth targets benefit sustainable development? Evidence from China. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2021, 30, 4188–4205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Ren, S.; Du, M.; Bu, W.; Lin, T. Assessing the impact of economic growth target constraints on environmental pollution: Does environmental decentralization matter? J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 336, 117618. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  44. Sueyoshi, T.; Yuan, Y. Social sustainability measured by intermediate approach for DEA environmental assessment: Chinese regional planning for economic development and pollution prevention. Energy Econ. 2017, 66, 154–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Zheng, Y.; Tarczyński, W.; Jamróz, P.; Ali Raza, S.; Tiwari, S. Impacts of mineral resources, economic growth and energy consumption on environmental sustainability: Novel findings from global south region. Resour. Policy 2024, 92, 105019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Addis, A.K.; Cheng, S. The nexus between renewable energy, environmental pollution, and economic growth across BRICS and OECD countries: A comparative empirical study. Energy Rep. 2023, 10, 3800–3813. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Wang, X.; Su, Z.; Mao, J. How does haze pollution affect green technology innovation? A tale of the government economic and environmental target constraints. J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 334, 117473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  48. Shi, B.; Zhu, G.; Li, N. Does economic growth targets setting lead to carbon emissions? An empirical study from China. J. Environ. Manag. 2024, 368, 122084. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  49. Shao, W.C.; Chou, L.C. Political influence and air pollution: Evidence from Chinese cities. Heliyon 2023, 9, e17781. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  50. Li, J.; Ma, X. Government-to-government peer pressure and air pollution: Causal evidence from an environmental ranking policy in China. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2024, 222, 123–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Jiang, S.S.; Li, J.M. Do political promotion incentive and fiscal incentive of local governments matter for the marine environmental pollution? Evidence from China’s coastal areas. Mar. Policy 2021, 128, 104505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Zhang, C.; Tao, R.; Yue, Z.; Su, F. Regional competition, rural pollution haven and environmental injustice in China. Ecol. Econ. 2023, 204, 107669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Wu, T.; Wen, L.; Yi, M. Balancing growth targets and environmental regulations: An empirical analysis of dual policy impact on corporate environmental responsibility–insights from China. J. Environ. Manag. 2024, 355, 120500. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  54. Chen, B.; Wang, H.; Wang, X. Innovation Like China: Evidence from Chinese Local Officials’ Promotions. China Econ. Rev. 2024, 86, 102203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Zhang, Y.; Mao, W.; Zhang, B. Distortion of government behaviour under target constraints: Economic growth target and urban sprawl in China. Cities 2022, 131, 104009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Zhou, D.; Wang, H.; Wang, M. Does local government competition affect the dependence on polluting industries? Evidence from China’s land market. J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 325, 116518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  57. Hansen, B.E. Threshold effect in non-dynamic panels: Estimation, testing and inference. J. Econom. 1999, 93, 346–368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Li, F.; Chen, J.; Chen, H.; Zhuo, Z. How to reduce PM2.5? Perspective from a spatial autoregressive threshold panel model. Ecol. Indic. 2022, 143, 109353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Shi, D.; Ding, H.; Wei, P.; Liu, J. Can smart city construction reduce environmental pollution? China Ind. Econ. 2018, 6, 117–135. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  60. Deng, R.; Zhang, A. Research on the impact of urban digital economy development on environmental pollution and its mechanism. South China J. Econ. 2022, 2, 18–37. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  61. Xu, X.; Liu, Y. Economic growth target management. Econ. Res. J. 2017, 52, 18–33. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  62. Dong, W.Y.; Zhang, Z.B. Is China’s international trade exacerbating urban environmental pollution?—A quasi-natural experiment based on the opening of the China railway express. J. Clean. Prod. 2023, 406, 137159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. You, Z.; Hou, G.; Wang, M. Heterogeneous relations among environmental regulation, technological innovation, and environmental pollution. Heliyon 2024, 10, e28196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  64. Chen, X.; Liang, X. Foreign direct investment and environmental pollution: A fiscal decentralization perspective. Chin. J. Popul. Resour. Environ. 2021, 19, 34–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Zhang, L.; Mu, R.; Hu, S.; Yu, J.; Zhang, J. Industrial coagglomeration, technological innovation, and environmental pollution in China: Life-cycle perspective of coagglomeration. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 362, 132280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Hong, Y.; Lyu, X.; Chen, Y.; Li, W. Industrial agglomeration externalities, local governments’ competition and environmental pollution: Evidence from Chinese prefecture-level cities. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 277, 123455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Wang, Y.; Shi, M.; Liu, J.; Huang, H.; Yu, K. Environmental pollution management effects of technological convergence between digital and real economy industries: A perspective of tripartite co-governance by company, government, and public. J. Clean. Prod. 2025, 501, 145201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Xia, Q.; Zhou, Z. Research on the impact of manufacturing servitization on environmental pollution: Spatial econometric analysis of sulfur dioxide based on 284 prefecture-level cities. Chin. J. Popul. Resour. Environ. 2024, 22, 258–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Sultana, M.; Rahman, M.H. Investigating the impact of GDP, energy mix, energy intensity, and the service sector on environmental pollution in MENA countries: An application of Driscoll-Kraay standard error approach. Soc. Sci. Humanit. Open 2024, 10, 101087. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Tao, C.; Peng, Y.; Ju, Z. An empirical study on economic growth, industrial structure and the carbon emissions—Based on PVAR model. Econ. Surv. 2015, 32, 126–131. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  71. Ke, N.; Chen, J.; Cheng, T. The drivers of carbon intensity and emission reduction strategies in heavy industry: Evidence from nonlinear and spatial perspectives. Ecol. Indic. 2024, 160, 111764. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Shen, X.; Chen, Y.; Lin, B. The impacts of technological progress and industrial structure distortion on China’s energy intensity. Econ. Res. J. 2021, 56, 157–173. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Spatial features of EP in China in 2008 and 2021.
Figure 1. Spatial features of EP in China in 2008 and 2021.
Sustainability 17 06534 g001
Table 1. Descriptive statistical results for each variable.
Table 1. Descriptive statistical results for each variable.
VariableDefinitionObs.MeanSDMinMax
EPEnvironmental pollution4200.23730.14320.01550.6722
EGTEconomic growth target4200.08840.02120.04500.1500
PNGAPTop–down amplification of EGTs4200.01620.0171−0.02000.0700
OPENOpenness4200.27750.31760.00761.6977
EREnvironmental regulation4200.00360.00340.00010.0310
FDIForeign direct investment4200.02140.01950.00010.1210
TECHTechnological investment4200.02080.01470.00390.0720
IAIndustrial agglomeration4200.02560.03710.00030.2171
RDR&D intensity4200.02000.01480.00180.0704
ILInformationization level4200.06700.05000.01700.2900
ECEnergy consumption4203.66381.85941.223411.9128
Table 2. Panel unit root test results.
Table 2. Panel unit root test results.
SeriesIPSLLCFisher−PPFisher−ADF
EP−2.4897 ***−6.7213 ***24.834019.4746
EGT−3.7948 ***−7.8952 ***21.345132.9327
PNGAP−3.7948 ***−7.8952 ***60.250285.3873 **
OPEN−4.0569 ***−5.0363 ***54.6920161.4783 ***
ER−6.0527 ***−3.3491 ***77.1289 *151.1276 ***
FDI−3.1249 ***−7.3726 ***72.065159.0311
TECH−2.2745 **−4.1507 ***87.0748 **80.4882 **
IA4.68512.5495349.4668 ***200.6194 ***
RD−3.6852 ***−4.9511 ***38.942480.9641 **
IL−5.6146 ***−4.9847 ***157.2554 ***80.9527 **
EC−2.4551 ***−7.5397 ***83.9425 **64.5758
Notes: * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (the same below).
Table 3. Panel cointegration test results.
Table 3. Panel cointegration test results.
SeriesPedroni TestSeriesPedroni Test
Panel−ADFGroup−ADFPanel−ADFGroup−ADF
EGT−3.5518 ***−3.9369 ***TECH−0.1785 *4.1312 ***
PNGAP−1.8422 **−2.2668 **IA−1.5611 *−1.7165 **
OPEN2.0412 **1.5860 *RD−3.1633 ***−2.1991 **
ER2.1070 **2.2756 **IL4.6818 ***5.6718 ***
FDI−1.7291 **−1.9644 **EC3.2084 ***2.7938 ***
Table 4. Moran’s I of EP in China from 2008 to 2021.
Table 4. Moran’s I of EP in China from 2008 to 2021.
YearMoran’s IYearMoran’s I
20080.08920150.121 *
20090.09020160.136 *
20100.09420170.125 *
20110.133 *20180.137 *
20120.135 *20190.123 *
20130.139 *20200.095
20140.128 *20210.137 *
Table 5. Estimation results of three models.
Table 5. Estimation results of three models.
Variables(1) FE(2) SAR(3) SARTP
EGT1.3795 ***0.5954 ***0.14160.3799 **
OPEN−0.0201−0.0376−0.1112 **−0.1124 ***
ER1.53440.87850.45750.6750
FDI0.39580.26110.54750.0504
TECH−1.8343 **−0.7280 *−1.4904 ***−0.3956
IA0.07280.16370.1414−0.0101
RD−2.4532−1.6037 **−2.0811 **−1.7855 **
IL−0.1831 **−0.06550.0137−0.0497
EC0.0094 **0.0123 ***0.0139 ***0.0157 ***
Threshold value//EGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750
ρ /0.6214 ***0.5870 ***
R ¯ 2 0.42730.51220.9266
Table 6. The average of each variable for regime I and regime II.
Table 6. The average of each variable for regime I and regime II.
VariablesRegime I (EGT ≤ 0.0750)Regime II (EGT > 0.0750)
EP0.19520.2607
EGT0.06610.1007
OPEN0.29350.2685
ER0.00280.0040
FDI0.01630.0242
TECH0.02410.0190
IA0.03260.0216
RD0.02310.0184
IL0.09000.0542
EC4.29713.3119
Table 7. Robustness test results.
Table 7. Robustness test results.
VariablesSARTP Model
(1) Adjacency Matrix(2) Economic Distance Matrix(3) Add a Control Variable
EGT−0.46630.3892 **0.15500.3786 **−2.36610.4894 ***
EDU 0.0092−0.0085
Control variablesYESYESYESYESYESYES
Threshold valueEGT ≤ 0.0700EGT > 0.0700EGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750EGT ≤ 0.0700EGT > 0.0700
ρ 0.1427 ***0.5022 ***0.1418 ***
R ¯ 2 0.94230.91850.9436
Table 8. Placebo test results.
Table 8. Placebo test results.
Variables(1) EP(2) EP
TARGET1−0.0419−0.1107 ***
TARGET2 −0.0099−0.1107 ***
OPEN1.29470.15131.17710.0817
ER−0.46221.7376 ***−0.40351.7195 ***
FDI−2.8788 ***−0.0543−2.7858 ***−0.0721
TECH0.0122 ***−0.05640.0133 ***−0.0007
IA−0.0739 **0.7798−0.0739 **0.9253
RD0.0647−0.95810.0967−1.0086 *
IL2.0887 ***−2.3464 ***2.0712 ***−2.2706 ***
EC−0.02260.018 4 ***−0.02750.0192 ***
ρ 0.5680 ***0.5631 ***
Threshold valueEGT ≤ 0.0800EGT > 0.0800EGT ≤ 0.0800EGT > 0.0800
R ¯ 2 0.92670.9268
Table 9. Heterogeneity test results based on geographical location.
Table 9. Heterogeneity test results based on geographical location.
Variables(1) Eastern Provinces(2) Central Provinces(3) Western Provinces
EGT0.3956−0.08421.25261.3261 ***1.5494 ***1.2072 ***
OPEN−0.12090.0077−0.1669−0.4276 **−0.6315 ***−0.1884 **
ER−3.4331−1.61662.35390.20460.79872.5483 **
FDI−0.1557−1.2242 ***0.24562.4822 **−0.69860.4684
TECH−0.2298−1.5409−4.2167 ***0.8194−2.4712−5.6431 ***
IA1.23840.21520.64112.987624.4554 **20.6378 **
RD−5.0075 **−7.1868 ***5.3784−4.2059 *0.79141.4032
IL−0.1904−0.5974 ***−0.0524−0.20000.05020.0917
EC−0.0301 **0.0345 **0.01330.01830.0107 **0.0146 ***
Threshold
value
EGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750EGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750EGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750
ρ 0.5316 ***0.9386 ***0.3719 ***
R ¯ 2 0.94840.93250.8859
Table 10. Heterogeneity test results based on population size.
Table 10. Heterogeneity test results based on population size.
Variables(1) High Population Size Region(2) Low Population Size Region
EGT3.0918 ***1.3576 ***0.7741 **0.6147 ***
OPEN−0.0649−0.0257−0.0252−0.0547 *
ER4.94685.8122 **1.63091.0971
FDI−0.3111−0.8204 **0.2375−0.1215
TECH1.6095 *0.3024−0.5585−1.1045
IA5.4967 *7.5185 **−1.2439 **−1.0145
RD−6.1329 ***−4.7946 **−1.02940.1112
IL−0.12410.1023−0.0173−0.1841 *
EC0.0341 **0.0729 ***0.0073 **0.0142 ***
Threshold valueEGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750EGT ≤ 0.0850EGT > 0.0850
ρ 0.6155 ***0.4217 ***
R ¯ 2 0.89930.9452
Table 11. Heterogeneity test results based on industrial structure.
Table 11. Heterogeneity test results based on industrial structure.
Variables(1) High Tertiary Industry Proportion Region(2) Low Tertiary Industry Proportion Region
EGT0.25900.10941.2461 **0.8021 ***
OPEN−0.0074−0.0464−0.3104 **−0.1363 *
ER2.9485−0.15692.3694 *0.8729
FDI0.65750.1163−0.24580.0161
TECH−2.1883 ***−1.34853.4490 ***−0.4193
IA−0.4926−0.94853.13258.9193 ***
RD−3.6105 ***−3.3600 ***−0.1097−0.0544
IL−0.0759−0.3080 **0.0576−0.0175
EC−0.00800.01560.0076 *0.0158 ***
Threshold valueEGT ≤ 0.0850EGT > 0.0850EGT ≤ 0.0750EGT > 0.0750
ρ 0.4364 ***0.9900 ***
R ¯ 2 0.94230.9350
Table 12. Estimation results of the SARTP model using PNGAP as a threshold variable.
Table 12. Estimation results of the SARTP model using PNGAP as a threshold variable.
VariablesSARTP Model
(1) Geography Distance Matrix(2) Adjacency Matrix
EGT0.36110.4469 **0.04430.3942 **
Control variablesYesYesYesYes
Threshold valuePNGAP ≤ 0.0050PNGAP > 0.0050PNGAP ≤ 0.0050PNGAP > 0.0050
ρ 0.6220 ***0.1447 ***
R ¯ 2 0.92310.9420
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Chen, J.; Wu, C. Do Economic Growth Targets Aggravate Environmental Pollution? Evidence from China. Sustainability 2025, 17, 6534. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17146534

AMA Style

Chen J, Wu C. Do Economic Growth Targets Aggravate Environmental Pollution? Evidence from China. Sustainability. 2025; 17(14):6534. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17146534

Chicago/Turabian Style

Chen, Jianbao, and Chenwei Wu. 2025. "Do Economic Growth Targets Aggravate Environmental Pollution? Evidence from China" Sustainability 17, no. 14: 6534. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17146534

APA Style

Chen, J., & Wu, C. (2025). Do Economic Growth Targets Aggravate Environmental Pollution? Evidence from China. Sustainability, 17(14), 6534. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17146534

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop