1. Introduction
Science and technology innovation (S&T innovation), as the first driving force for the formation of new productive forces and the promotion of high-quality development, is related to the overall situation of the country’s modernization [
1]. Jin systematically explained this concept in the Economic Research on “High-Quality Development”, pointing out that high-quality development is the organic unity of the quality of economic development, efficiency power, social benefits and ecological benefits, with multidimensional characteristics such as innovation, coordination, greenness, openness and sharing [
2]. Chen et al. further emphasized that high-quality development needs to break through the traditional GDP orientation and build a comprehensive evaluation system that includes dimensions such as optimization of economic structure, innovation-driven development, and sustainability of resources and environment [
3].
From the realistic dimension, high-quality development is reflected in the practical deepening of the five development concepts: at the economic level, it calls for the establishment of a modernized economic system [
4], whereas at the innovation level, it emphasizes scientific and technological self-reliance and self-improvement [
5], at the coordination level, it focuses on balanced regional development [
6], at the green level, it highlights the goal of carbon peaking and carbon neutrality [
7], and promotes a high level of institutionalized openness at the openness level [
8]. This multidimensional character is further strengthened in the report of the 20th Party Congress, which calls for the construction of an economic system with “effective market mechanisms, dynamic micro-entrepreneurs, and moderate macro-control”. City clusters centered on large cities play a very important role as innovation growth poles due to their strong scientific and technological resource advantages. At the city cluster level, China implemented the Yangtze River Delta (YRD) Regional Integration Development Strategy and the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei (BTH) Synergistic Development Strategy in 2012 and 2014, respectively. The policy emphasizes the need for the Yangtze River Delta region to strengthen cross-regional synergies in science and technology innovation and industrial innovation, linking the Yangtze River Economic Belt and radiating across the country. This reflects the strategic deployment of the city clusters to jointly promote high-quality development with science and technology innovation as the leader and collaborative innovation as the booster. Such a development model not only helps to realize the optimal allocation and efficient use of scientific and technological resources, but also accelerates the transformation and application of scientific and technological innovation achievements through the model of collaborative innovation, thus further enhancing the role of scientific and technological innovation in promoting high-quality development.
From a practical point of view, on the one hand, scientific and technological talents, equipment and other innovation factors are constantly gathering in large cities, forming a strong innovation capacity and power; with the depth of scientific and technological innovation activities, the innovative technology formed spills over to the surrounding cities through a variety of channels and mechanisms, improving the overall innovation capacity of the entire city cluster. On the other hand, the introduction of city cluster planning helps to improve inter-city collaboration and exchanges, and promotes collaborative innovation; through resource sharing and complementary advantages between cities, the formation of science and technology innovation networks further improves the efficiency of innovation [
9].
Figure 1 shows that the average S&T innovation capacity, degree of collaborative innovation and high-quality development level of the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei and Yangtze River Delta city clusters all show growth. However, what still needs to be further explored in depth behind this is what kind of correlation exists among the three. What is the impact of S&T innovation and technology spillover on Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei and the Yangtze River Delta as the two city clusters with the strongest S&T innovation strength? What is the role of collaborative innovation in technology spillover and high-quality development? The two most representative city clusters in China will be empirically and comparatively analyzed.
Existing studies have formed an important consensus on collaborative innovation and innovation performance, innovation and high-quality development: most scholars confirm that collaborative innovation can promote innovation performance [
10], and at the same time, innovation also has a significant role in promoting high-quality development [
11,
12]. At the level of metrics, the existing literature mainly presents two paths: for the measurement of high-quality development, some scholars use a single indicator such as total factor productivity (TFP) or GDP per capita [
3,
13]; while for the assessment of collaborative innovation, it generally relies on a multi-indicator evaluation system or questionnaire data [
10,
14]. However, there are still significant shortcomings in existing studies: firstly, in terms of research perspectives, there is little literature on innovation, collaborative innovation and high-quality development into a unified analytical framework, and cities are generally regarded as independent “black box” [
13], ignoring inter-city interactions, which is fundamentally conflicting with the first theorem of geography and the reality; secondly, in terms of high-quality development metrics, it is difficult to comprehensively reflect the multidimensional characteristics of high-quality development by relying on a single proxy; and finally, regarding the measurement of collaborative innovation, existing evaluation systems either lack theoretical support or have subjective bias, while questionnaire methods face problems of limited sample size and selection bias. Characteristics [
2]; and finally, regarding collaborative innovation measurement, the established evaluation system either lacks theoretical support or has a subjective bias, while the questionnaire method faces the problems of limited sample size and selection bias.
The rest of this study is formed as follows.
Section 2 provides a literature review.
Section 3 develops a theoretical model.
Section 4 establishes the econometric model and explains the calculation method of each indicator.
Section 5 analyzes the current situation of high-quality development and collaborative innovation in the two city clusters and shows the regression results of the econometric model.
Section 6 discusses the reasons for the different results for the two city clusters. Finally,
Section 7 summarizes the research conclusions and provides policy recommendations.
2. Literature Review
S&T innovation is an effective way to address the negative externalities generated by vicious competition and crowding effects when industries are over-aggregated [
15]. In regional economics, Marshall first proposed that industrial agglomeration externalities are important for economic development. Currently, research has concluded that S&T innovation has a “core-edge” distribution [
16], and the spillover effect of innovation has been confirmed by scholars from many countries [
17,
18,
19]. In addition, in terms of research methodology, the current research on S&T innovation is mainly divided into two main categories: one is research based on the gravity model and the breaking point formula [
20], and the other one is studies using the panel model and spatial econometrics model [
21,
22]. Regarding the relationship between S&T innovation and high-quality development, Yang et al. [
23] confirmed that S&T innovation factors are the main driving force for high-quality development. However, their study did not consider the role of cooperative innovation.
Many scholars have also carried out relevant studies on the measurement and role mechanism of collaborative innovation. In terms of measurement, existing studies, respectively, started from the multi-indicator evaluation system [
10], questionnaire data [
14], and network analysis of collaborative papers or collaborative patents [
24]. Most studies on collaborative innovation have focused on its influencing factors [
25,
26], the trend of temporal and spatial evolution [
27,
28] and the impact of collaborative innovation on other things [
10,
29]. In terms of the effects of collaborative innovation on innovation, studies by Bai et al. and Fan et al. use spatial econometric modeling to confirm the facilitating effect of collaborative innovation on regional innovation performance [
10,
28]. Fan et al. also formalize that this facilitating effect has a lag [
29]. In terms of the impact of collaborative innovation on high-quality development, Deng et al. used a spatial Durbin model to confirm the facilitating effect of collaborative innovation on high-quality development [
21]. Dai et al.’s study uses the spatial panel model with Chinese city clusters as an example and confirms that both the depth and the width of collaborative innovation can promote high-quality development [
30]. In summary, the contribution of innovation and collaborative innovation to high-quality development has been proved, but whether there is a complementary relationship between innovation and collaborative innovation has not yet been explored.
High-quality development is a development approach that balances the quality and quantity of economic development. Green and sustainable development are important elements of high-quality development. Many studies have used different data and methods to measure the degree of high-quality development from different dimensions. Some scholars directly use a single indicator to measure high-quality development, e.g., Jahanger directly uses total factor productivity to measure high-quality development [
13], and Chen et al. use per capita GDP to measure high-quality development [
3]. Other scholars use the evaluation system approach to measure. For example, Deng et al. established a high-quality development evaluation system from five aspects [
31], and Dai et al. measured it from six aspects [
30]. Li et al.’s study assessed the extent of high-quality development in Chinese prefecture-level cities from the perspective of five dimensions and 15 indicators [
32]. Overall, as it is recognized that high-quality development is multidimensional [
33], high-quality development has gradually developed into a comprehensive indicator system. In general, in studies on the national, city cluster, and province levels, the evaluation system usually contains at least five dimensions and 20 indicators; while in studies on the measurement of prefecture-level cities, the number of years, indicators, or cities in the relevant empirical research samples is relatively small due to the difficulty of data collection. Such limitations may affect the accuracy of regional comparative analysis.
In summary, a large number of studies have examined S&T innovation and its spillovers, collaborative innovation and high-quality development, but few studies have included all three in the same analytical framework. Yang et al.’s study confirms that the flow of innovation factors can lead to the improvement of the level of high-quality development of neighboring regions through the spatial spillover effect of high-quality development of the economy [
25]. Deng et al.’s study confirms the role of collaborative innovation in high-quality development using a city cluster as an example [
21]. Based on these, this study further deepens the understanding of the mechanism of how collaborative innovation in city clusters affects S&T innovation, and in turn, promotes high-quality development.
Based on existing studies, the marginal contribution of this study is mainly reflected in the following aspects: First, it innovatively constructs a three-dimensional linkage framework of “scientific and technological innovation-collaborative innovation-high-quality development” and uses spatial econometric models to capture the spillover phenomenon of scientific and technological innovation. Second, it improves the measurement system for high-quality development through six dimensions, breaking the one-dimensional limitation of TFP. Third, this study uses crawler technology to obtain all cooperative invention patents and combines social network analysis methods to more accurately quantify collaborative innovation. Empirical results show that scientific and technological innovation has a direct promotional and spatial spillover effect on high-quality development (positive in the Yangtze River Delta city cluster and negative in the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei city cluster), and that collaborative innovation has a direct driving effect but does not produce significant spatial spillover.
3. Theoretical Model
From the perspective of new economic geography, the phenomenon of spatial overflow of technological level between regions is common in the process of S&T innovation and development of city clusters. Increasing research and development investment and encouraging city innovation can greatly enhance the spread of S&T innovation among neighboring cities. This will further promote rapid economic growth. This model builds upon the spatial economic framework proposed by Fujita and Thisse [
34] and integrates Romer’s [
35] knowledge-driven growth mechanism to explore the mechanism by which the technological progress growth rate of urban agglomerations influences economic growth through the spatial spillover effects of technological innovation.
The significance of this model lies in two aspects of expansion: (1) incorporating the intensity of technological spillovers into the growth rate of R&D, and (2) quantifying the marginal effect of innovation spillovers on total output (), thereby addressing the shortcomings of the original model in analyzing the relationship between spillovers and economic performance. The specific analysis is as follows:
It is assumed that there are only two regions in the whole economy, A and B, with three types of production sectors: the traditional product sector (T), the modern product sector (M) and the research and development sector (R).
Both T and M sectors use unskilled personnel (L) and R&D sector (R) uses skilled personnel (H) for scientific and technological research, development and innovation. The T sector produces homogeneous products and the modern product sector (M) produces differentiated products using diversified R&D and innovations from the R&D sector (R). Here, the total number of technicians (H) is constant and normalized to 1, and they are free to move between A and B but with migration costs; non-technicians (L) are not mobile.
3.1. Household Department
Assume that any consumer
in the economy as a whole makes the following behavioral decisions in time and space: for time
,
will choose a consumption path
and a location path
. Then, the indirect utility of
at time
is
where,
is the price index of commodity
in region
at time
, and then:
is the total number of
modern products available in the entire economy at time
,
is the expenditure of
at a given moment
,
is the price of product
,
.
is the constant elasticity of substitution between different types of final products. If
, then the product relocates its geographic position at time
. Denote the sequence of such movements by
. Here, the price index for differentiated products is described using an integral form, following the Dixit-Stiglitz monopolistic competition framework [
36]. When the number of product types M is large enough, the discrete sum can converge to a continuous integral and can more clearly characterize the elasticity of substitution between products. In order to focus on the role of innovation spillovers in economic growth, the model assumes that consumer utility comes only from differentiated modern products (M). Traditional products (T) are homogeneous commodities, and their consumption does not generate additional utility differences, so they are not included in the utility function.
Assuming that the migration cost of moving between regions A and B of type
people at time
is
, the lifetime utility function of consumer
at time 0 can be defined as
where
is the subjective discount rate common to all consumers, and:
Equation (4) represents the total lifetime utility of the migration cost. Where
is the interest rate on bonds in the aggregate economy at moment
, and the interest rates in regions A and B are equal. Let
be the wage rate when the consumer lives in region
at moment
. Thus, the present value of wage income is
where
is the average interest rate between 0~
. Then, according to the study of Barro and Sala-i-Martin [
37], the intertemporal budget constraint for consumer
can be written as the present value of expenditures being equal to the wealth owned:
where
is the value of the consumer’s initial asset.
In summary, the first-order condition on the optimal expenditure path
after maximizing Equation (3) on any location path
from constraint Equation (6) is
where
. If the above equation holds for every consumer, and denote the total economic expenditure at the moment
by
, we have:
3.2. Production Department
Suppose that sector T, which produces a traditional product, produces a homogeneous good at a fixed return. This product is produced in both regions A and B, and the wage rate of unskilled workers (L) is equal in both regions, being normalized to 1.
The modern product sector (M) produces differentiated modern products using proprietary technology specific to product
. Each unit of production of
requires the investment of one unit of technicians (H). Each unit of product
has no transportation costs within the same region but incurs trade friction costs of
when it is moved from one region to another for sale. That is, only
units of each unit of product
can reach its destination when it is transferred for sale from region
to another region
. This assumption follows the iceberg transportation cost theory [
38], which states that a certain percentage of products are lost during transportation. Thus, product
is produced in region
and is sold at price
. However, the price paid by the consumer changes when the product is transported to region
:
Assume that the consumer demand function for product
is
. Where
is the product share of the modern product sector (M) in consumer expenditure
. Then, set
to be the total expenditure of region
at a given moment and
to be the price index of the products of the modern product sector (M) of the region. Combined with Equation (9), it can be seen that the total demand for the production of the product
in the region
is
The corresponding profit is
For simplicity, set
. Define
as the subjective discount rate, which represents consumers’ time preference (i.e., the trade-off between current consumption and future consumption). This parameter is exogenous and its value is determined by social consumption habits [
39]. Combining Equations (10) and (11) show that the common equilibrium price
for all types of products, the equilibrium product
for any type of product, and the equilibrium profit
for the modern product sector (M) in region
during the time window under study are, respectively:
From Equation (13), in a region is directly proportional to total expenditures in each region and inversely proportional to the quantity of heterogeneous products in that individual region. The higher the equilibrium product output of the modern product sector (M) in a region, the higher the equilibrium profit, and the higher the constant elasticity of substitution among final products with heterogeneity, the lower the equilibrium profit.
3.3. R&D Department
Based on the R&D growth theory [
35], the productivity of technicians (H) grows with the accumulation of their own intellectual capital (experience and work methods). The productivity of each technician (H) in the region is also given by
if the intellectual capital of the region r is
. The total number of technicians (H) in the region is normalized to 1, and the total number of technicians (H) in the region r is normalized to 1. The total number of technicians (H) in region r is normalized to 1. Therefore, the number of patents developed per unit of time in region r when the share of technicians (H) in that region is
is
Let the amount of personal knowledge possessed by technician (H)
be
and the total amount of intellectual capital available to region
be
where
measures the degree of complementarity between technicians (H) in R&D and innovation, and
denotes the intensity of technological spillovers between the two regions.
Finally, assuming that j’s personal knowledge
is proportional to the number of existing patents
in the economy as a whole:
, normalizing a to 1, and combining with Equation (16), we get
Substituting (17) into (15), we get
It is assumed that patents have an infinite duration, so that the firm producing a particular product will always be a monopoly. In summary, the equation of motion for the number of categories (or number of patents) in the economy is obtained:
where
and
. For simplicity, set
and
Thus, the above equation of motion becomes
where
is the growth rate of the number of patents/categories in the economy as a whole when the distribution of technicians (H) is
. It is easy to obtain that
is symmetric about 1/2 such that
. The partial derivative of
with respect to the intensity of technology spillovers
between the two regions is obtained:
This implies spatial spillovers of technology between city clusters that can contribute to R&D growth rates.
To analyze the equilibrium wage
of technicians (H) in this sector: combining Equation (18), the intellectual capital
acquired by each research and development(R)-based firm in region
can be taken as given, so that the marginal productivity of the labor of the technicians (H) is also
and the unit cost of a new patent is
. Firms are free to enter the research and development (R), and the zero-profit condition is
, where
denotes the market price of a particular patent in the market price of a patent developed in region
.
The profit for each type of personnel can be defined:
The initial endowment of technicians is
3.4. Market Equilibrium
Since firms in each modern product sector (M) in the economy as a whole are free to choose locations in both regions to produce any new product. Therefore, given any moment, the profits of firms in each region must be the same when the market reaches equilibrium. Combining Equation (14), we have
. Again, from Equation (13) and
and
, we have:
When
, there is
, from Equations (26) and (13), we have:
Similarly, the equilibrium results can be obtained when , , and .
The equilibrium profits for all firms in the modern product sector (M) in all three of these cases are
3.5. Spatial Innovation Spillovers from R&D Growth Rates on a Steady-State Path to Economic Growth
For any given case of
, the steady-state growth path of the regional economy is analyzed as follows. Based on Equation (21), the number of patents (the number of modern product sector-type enterprises) at moment
is as follows:
where
is the number of initial product types. Combined with Equation (29), the value of the firm’s assets at moment
is
In summary, the asset value of all firms in the modern product sector (M) sector at moment
is
where
, so the above equation can be written as
Obviously, since Equation (32) does not vary over time, substituting
in Equation (23) into
leads to the equilibrium wage rate for technicians (H) in each region as
For Equation (25), there are
and
for each technician (H) living in region
. And Equation (24) implies that at any given time, the total expenditure for all personnel in region
is
Therefore, the total return to the economy as a whole on the equilibrium path is
Substituting Equation (19) into Equation (36) leads to the effect of spatial S&T innovation spillovers on total returns is
, that is, space S&T innovation spillovers favor the growth of the economy.
From Equation (20), the R&D growth rate can be written as
Combining Equations (19) and (39), the effect of R&D growth rate on spatial S&T innovation spillovers can be obtained as
Based on Equations (38) and (40), and according to the chain rule, the marginal contribution of the growth rate of R&D innovation
, to the total return
is found to be
From the above theoretical model, it can be seen that an increase in the R&D growth rate of each region in the city cluster will accelerate the spatial spillover of S&T innovation among regions, which in turn will promote the economic growth of the city cluster.
6. Discussion
Knowledge diffusion generates spillover effects between cities. S&T innovation mainly relies on the diffusion of explicit knowledge and tacit knowledge, the former can be learned and reapplied by research subjects through record carriers, while the latter needs to be realized through human capital flows. According to the theoretical model (Equation (38)) and the push-pull theory, the innovation spillover effect is jointly determined by push
, pull
, and resistance
:
. According to the theoretical model (Equation (38)) and the push-pull theory, the innovation spillover effect is jointly determined by push
, pull
, and resistance
: where push refers to the level of investment and output in scientific and technological innovation in a city, pull refers to the capacity of other cities to absorb scientific and technological innovation, and resistance
refers to the smoothness of elements that hinder the flow of knowledge and its reapplication. Only when the innovation externality is greater than 0 can a city’s scientific and technological innovation have a positive spillover effect [
45]. Focusing on the Yangtze River Delta and Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei city clusters, push, pull, and resistance are measured based on human capital and other innovation inputs, scientific and technological innovation outputs, innovation gaps, and the smooth flow of factors in the indicator system.
Investment in S&T innovation in this study is measured by the ratio of full-time teachers in general higher education institutions, the ratio of people employed in scientific research and technical services, and the share of local financial expenditure on S&T in local financial expenditure. Beijing ranks first with a score of 3.83, which is 4.7 times higher than the lowest score. Although the difference in the ratio score is not large, the difference in the specific amount is huge. Taking the number of full-time teachers in the city’s higher education institutions as an example, within the BTH city cluster, Beijing has 70,645, while Handan has only 4471; within the YRD city cluster, Nanjing has 55,134, followed by Shanghai with 47,668, while Xuancheng, the city with the least, has only 342.
From the number of invention patents authorized and the city innovation index published by Kou et al. [
48], S&T innovation shows a huge gap, and the degree of innovation output gap within BTH is significantly larger than the degree of gap within the YRD. Within the BTH city cluster, S&T innovation shows a precipitous fall. Beijing is far ahead, with the number of invention patents authorized and its innovation index in 2020, for example, more than 10 times that of second-place Tianjin and nearly 200 times that of last-place Anyang. The wide gap in S&T innovation is one of the key reasons why the surrounding areas are unable to take up Beijing’s S&T innovation overflow. Within the YRD city cluster, Shanghai is at the top of the list in terms of the number of invention patents authorized, which is 1.4 times that of Hangzhou in the second place, although there is a certain gap, the magnitude is not large compared with Beijing, Tianjin and Hebei. In terms of the innovation index, the gap between Shanghai and the top few cities in the cluster is also significantly smaller than that in the BTH city cluster.
In terms of transportation, the average road mileage of the BTH city cluster is 1.47 times that of the YRD city cluster, while the YRD has an even better shipping network, and the two form both good transportation channels. However, the degree of marketization of the two city clusters shows a clear gap, with the average marketization of the YRD city cluster nearly four times that of the BTH city cluster. Some cities within the YRD city cluster have formed an open market-oriented exchange environment, which has 8 cities with high scores. On the other hand, there are only 2 cities with high scores in the BTH city cluster, indicating that there is still a large gap between the degree of marketization of the neighboring cities and that of Beijing, which to a certain extent hinders the collaboration innovation and development of BTH.
Compared with international cases, the multi-center structure of the Yangtze River Delta city cluster is similar to that of the Rhine-Ruhr city cluster [
19], while the single-core model of the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei city cluster is similar to that of the Seoul metropolitan area in its early stages. After Seoul adopted the “Innovation Diffusion Corridor” policy in 2010, it increased its innovation spillover effect by 37%, which provides a reference for the development of the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei city cluster.
7. Conclusions and Further Research
This study mainly obtains the following conclusions:
First, from the perspective of the degree of high-quality development, the performance of high-quality development in the YRD city cluster is significantly better than that of the BTH city cluster. This is reflected in the following three aspects: (1) The average score of high-quality development and the average scores of most dimensions in the YRD city cluster are significantly higher than those in the BTH city cluster. (2) More cities within the YRD city cluster have top quality development scores. (3) The degree of high-quality development in the BTH city cluster decreased rather than increased over the study period, while the degree of high-quality development in the YRD city cluster was more stable.
Second, from the perspective of the network structure of collaborative innovation, the node cities within the two city clusters are increasingly connected and the degree of collaborative innovation is gradually increasing, but there is some heterogeneity: (1) The network density of the BTH city cluster is higher than that of the YRD city cluster during the observation period. And the density increase in the YRD city cluster is significantly higher than that of the BTH city cluster. (2) The S&T innovation network of the BTH city cluster always shows a cooperative network with Beijing as the core and Tianjin and Shijiazhuang as the sub-core. On the other hand, the S&T innovation network of the YRD city cluster has gradually evolved from the perspective of Shanghai and Hangzhou as the core and Nanjing as the sub-core to a pattern with Shanghai, Nanjing and Hangzhou as the core and Suzhou, Wuxi and Hefei as the sub-core. (3) The network structure of the YRD city cluster is relatively more stable. There are no more isolated cities in the YRD city cluster after 2012. And in 2020, all cities have established multi-line connections with the city cluster innovation network.
Thirdly, from the perspective of spatial Durbin analysis: (1) the S&T innovation of all cities in the BTH and YRD city cluster has a certain positive contribution to high-quality development, but it mainly comes from the local S&T innovation; the S&T innovation of the neighboring cities also has a certain positive impact on the high-quality development of the city, but this indirect effect is far less than the direct effect. (2) From the perspective of the spillover effect of collaborative innovation, collaborative innovation has a significant driving effect on local high-quality development, but its spillover effect is not yet obvious; and collaborative innovation has not yet strengthened the spillover effect of S&T innovation on high-quality development. (3) Comparing the BTH city cluster and the YRD city cluster, S&T innovation in the two city clusters has a significant role in promoting the high-quality development of both the local area and the city cluster. However, the BTH city cluster shows a significant negative indirect effect, while the YRD city cluster shows a positive indirect effect.
Fourth, from the perspective of the conduction path of S&T innovation, the spillover effect is influenced by three factors: push, pull and resistance. The study finds that the BTH and YRD city clusters are clearly differentiated internally, and the degree of marketization shows obvious differences. In the BTH city cluster, Beijing is far ahead in the level of input and output of S&T innovation, but the degree of marketization and S&T innovation receiving capacity of neighboring cities have not yet been able to match, resulting in a low degree of factor fluency in the circulation and reapplication of knowledge, and the spillover effect of innovation has not been brought into full play. Within the YRD city cluster, Shanghai is also at the forefront of S&T innovation, but it has formed a close cooperation network with other cities and has a relatively high degree of marketization, which is conducive to the dissemination and undertaking of S&T innovation.
Based on the empirical analysis conclusions of this study on the relationship between technological innovation spillovers, collaborative innovation networks, and high-quality development in the Yangtze River Delta and Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei metropolitan areas, especially the findings of significant regional heterogeneity, this study proposes the following policy recommendations, ranked by urgency:
The primary task is to address the negative spillover challenges faced by the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei urban agglomeration, with the core focus on removing administrative barriers that hinder the flow of innovative elements. Empirical results clearly indicate that the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region exhibits significant negative spatial spillover effects, which are closely linked to its single-core radiation model, the weak innovation absorption capacity of peripheral cities, and low institutional coordination across regions. Therefore, the urgent priority for the coordinated development of the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region is to establish a robust cross-regional coordination mechanism. Specifically, it is necessary to mandate the establishment of a unified science and technology resource-sharing platform covering Beijing, Tianjin, and Hebei, requiring national key laboratories, large-scale scientific research instruments, and other core innovation resources to be open and shared among all cities within the region, and to establish a cross-administrative region mutual recognition system for innovation qualification certification. Additionally, a pilot program should be implemented to introduce a cross-regional settlement system for innovation vouchers in the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region, prioritizing support for small and medium-sized enterprises in Hebei and Tianjin to conveniently purchase technical services from universities and research institutions in Beijing, thereby effectively reducing technology transaction costs and activating knowledge spillover channels. These measures aim to directly address the core issue of “negative spillover caused by the single-core radiation model”, enhancing the marketization level and innovation absorption capacity of peripheral cities.
The Yangtze River Delta urban agglomeration should shift its focus to strengthening the radiating and driving role of secondary innovation centers and optimizing the multi-center network structure. Although the Yangtze River Delta exhibits a positive spatial spillover trend, it has not yet passed the significance test. Social network analysis shows that the betweenness centrality of secondary centers (such as Nanjing and Hefei) still lags significantly behind that of the core city Shanghai, and the hierarchical radiating potential of its multi-center structure has not yet been fully realized. Therefore, the Yangtze River Delta needs to build on its existing good collaboration and take it a step further. A key measure is for the governments of Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, and Anhui to jointly establish a special “industrial chain collaborative innovation fund”, focusing on supporting cross-provincial industrial chain key core technology joint research and development projects led by secondary center cities such as Nanjing (integrated circuits, etc.) and Hefei (quantum technology, etc.), to strengthen the hub role of secondary centers in the innovation network. Concurrently, a three-tier technology transfer network comprising “core (Shanghai)—secondary centers (Nanjing, Hangzhou, Hefei)—node cities” should be established. Policy incentive mechanisms should be explored to encourage high-tech enterprises to prioritize the low-cost transfer and licensing of non-core patents or technology usage rights to enterprises in peripheral cities such as Zhoushan, Xuancheng, and Chizhou, thereby accelerating the hierarchical diffusion of innovation outcomes within the cluster. These measures aim to optimize the multi-center network structure, significantly enhance the radiation efficiency of secondary core cities like Nanjing and Hefei, address the issue of insufficient positive spillover effects, and enable the top-ranked secondary core cities in
Table 4 to better drive the development of the entire region.
As a universal basic measure applicable to all city clusters, the “innovation voucher” system should be fully implemented and optimized to accurately support small and medium-sized enterprises in improving their R&D capabilities and technology adoption levels. Research has found that peripheral cities generally have low marketization levels and weak innovation foundations, and that collaborative innovation has not significantly enhanced the spillover effects of scientific and technological innovation on high-quality development as expected, with possible problems such as resource dispersion or dependence on innovation. As an inclusive policy tool, innovation vouchers need to be designed to be more targeted. The issuance of innovation vouchers should prioritize technology buyers (especially small and medium-sized enterprises in peripheral cities) rather than simply subsidizing R&D suppliers, to directly incentivize technology adoption and application, addressing the challenges of “supply without adoption” or “high adoption costs.” At the same time, the effectiveness of innovation vouchers should be linked to multidimensional indicators of high-quality development, requiring subsidized enterprises to commit to and actually improve their performance in areas such as green development (e.g., carbon emission intensity per unit of patent output) and regional coordination (e.g., the proportion of raw materials or services procured across cities) while upgrading their technological level, to ensure that innovation investment is truly transformed into comprehensive efficiency improvements in line with the connotation of high-quality development. This foundational measure aims to systematically enhance the marketization level, technological absorption capacity, and innovative vitality of all cities, particularly peripheral and low-scoring cities, addressing the current shortcomings of collaborative innovation models in reinforcing spillover effects.
This study has the following limitations: (1) The sample is limited to two major city clusters, and future research should expand to other city clusters such as the Guangdong-Hong Kong-Macao Greater Bay Area and the Chengdu-Chongqing Metropolitan Area to validate the generalizability of the conclusions; (2) Collaborative innovation is quantified solely through the number of cooperative patents, failing to encompass non-patent forms such as technology transfer and industry-academia-research alliances; (3) The spatial econometric model identifies spillover effects but lacks sufficient analysis of micro-level transmission mechanisms (e.g., talent mobility and technology diffusion channels). It is recommended that future research combine enterprise microdata and technology transaction data to deepen the analysis of these mechanisms.