3.1. CSR Disclosure Has an Incentive Effect on Corporate Exports
Corporate social responsibility (CSR) disclosure exerts a multifaceted influence on corporate export performance [
11]. First, by ensuring compliance with diverse international regulatory requirements, CSR disclosure effectively mitigates legal risks for exporting firms. This compliance serves as a strategic imperative for Chinese exporters navigating “blue” (labor-related) and “green” (environmental) trade barriers, enabling them to penetrate overseas markets, capture market share, and enhance international competitiveness. Second, CSR disclosure bolsters a firm’s reputation and credibility in international markets. By fostering consumer trust, attracting global clientele, and facilitating technical exchanges with international partners, it acts as a catalyst for market expansion [
35]. Third, transparency in CSR reporting improves supply chain management by enhancing visibility across the value chain, thereby equipping firms with greater resilience against international trade disruptions [
36]. Finally, through systematic identification and management of social and environmental risks—such as labor rights violations and environmental degradation—CSR disclosure enables firms to implement proactive risk mitigation strategies, safeguarding against potential negative impacts. In the context of heightened global economic uncertainty, CSR disclosure thus emerges as a pivotal mechanism for reducing information asymmetries, promoting social welfare objectives, and driving sustainable growth among Chinese enterprises. It not only facilitates the circumvention of trade barriers but also stimulates overseas market exploration and sustains export-led economic development [
37]. Building on these insights, this study employs a heterogeneous firm model to rigorously analyze the causal relationship between CSR disclosure and corporate export behavior.
Classical and new trade theories traditionally rely on the assumption of product homogeneity, positing that all exporting firms produce identical goods and exhibit uniform productivity levels. However, this simplifying assumption has been increasingly challenged by empirical evidence and theoretical advancements in light of evolving global trade dynamics. In response, Melitz and Redding’s (2021) heterogeneous firm model revolutionized trade theory by explicitly accounting for firm-level heterogeneity in productivity and export decisions [
38]. This model has proven particularly adept at explaining real-world trade patterns, offering a more nuanced understanding of the factors influencing firm-level export performance [
39].
This study leverages the heterogeneous firm model to investigate the impact of CSR disclosure on firms’ export strategies. The model is underpinned by several key assumptions [
40]. First, firms incur sunk costs upon industry entry and subsequently learn about their productivity during the production process. Based on this information, they make strategic decisions regarding export participation and scale, factoring in additional export-specific costs. Second, product heterogeneity is assumed, with each firm producing a differentiated good and operating at a distinct productivity level; the marginal cost of production follows a stochastic distribution [
41,
42]. Third, the model assumes symmetry in economic size between trading partners. Fourth, labor is considered the sole factor of production, with identical wage rates across countries (set as w = 1). Finally, each country’s product market is modeled as monopolistically competitive with increasing returns to scale, reflecting the characteristics of modern global markets.
Consumers in this model have equal elasticity of substitution across products [
43], and their utility function follows the CES (Constant Elasticity of Substitution) form:
where σ represents the elasticity of substitution between products and φ denotes the consumption of different products.
The income budget constraint is given by Equation (2), where y represents consumer income and p denotes the price of various products. By linking Equations (1) and (2), the optimal consumption decision under these conditions can be derived:
Let P represent the price index of the product, as determined by the following formula:
By assumption, the number of firms in the model is equal to the number of product types. Given that labor is the only input, the total cost per unit of the product q is defined as:
where firm productivity
is denoted by ϕ and fixed costs are represented by
. Under the assumption of profit maximization, the optimal price of the product sold domestically
, along with revenue
and profit
, is determined as follows:
When profits are zero, the minimum productivity required to enter the domestic market , as well as the minimum productivity needed to enter the international market , can be derived.
Upon analyzing Equation (8), it becomes evident that a firm’s actual production level is contingent upon its individual productivity. This productivity is then juxtaposed against the minimum productivity thresholds required for the domestic and international markets. In accordance with the outcomes of this comparative analysis, the firm proceeds to make a profit-maximizing decision, as meticulously illustrated in
Table 1 below:
The analytical framework reveals that firms will opt to enter the international market only when their productivity surpasses the critical threshold. Moreover, there exists a positive monotonic relationship between firm productivity and optimal export scale; specifically, higher-productivity firms must expand their export volumes more significantly to achieve profit maximization. Building on the seminal contributions of Melitz (2003) [
44], this study integrates corporate social responsibility (CSR) disclosure as a core explanatory variable in the model of firm export decisions. By adopting their theoretical approach, this research systematically investigates the transmission mechanisms through which CSR disclosure impacts export performance. The incorporation of CSR disclosure necessitates the introduction of novel assumptions into the existing theoretical framework. Specifically:
First, there are only two countries in the model: the exporter (i) and the importer (j). The unit wages of labor in both countries are denoted as and , respectively.
Second, both countries possess the same level of technology. All firms within the exporting country operate at the same rate of productivity.
Third, different products produced by different firms incur varying fixed costs.
Fourth, the elasticity of product substitution within firms is greater than the elasticity of product substitution between firms.
The demand for export products is influenced by this relationship:
where
has shown that corporate social responsibility (CSR) disclosure can effectively reduce information asymmetry and agency costs, curb surplus management behaviors, and enhance corporate reputation [
40]. Moreover, CSR disclosure has been found to lower financing costs and alleviate financing constraints [
25], as well as to reduce corporate production costs [
45]. Consequently, both fixed and variable costs (
and
) are modeled as monotonically decreasing functions of CSR disclosure
by firms when exporting.
The price of the product
in the importing country is denoted as:
Thus, the consumer’s income budget constraint is as follows:
The demand for export products can be derived from Equations (9), (12), and (13):
The nominal exchange rate
is denoted as
, while the real exchange rate is represented by P. The overall price index in the importing country is
. The price of the product in the home country is
, while the price of the product in the importing country is
. The firm’s profit function for exporting the product is given by:
Deriving the optimal solution yields the following export value and profit equation:
Deriving the optimal solution yields the following export value
and profit equation
:
This leads to the relationship between social responsibility
disclosure
and export volume:
Let
, further simplification results in the relationship between social responsibility disclosure
and export profits:
Thus, it is evident that CSR disclosure has a positive effect on both export volume and export profit. As the level of CSR disclosure increases, both export volume and export profit rise. Accordingly, Hypothesis 1 is proposed:
Hypothesis 1: CSR disclosure has a positive effect on corporate exports.
3.3. Moderating Effects of Environmental Regulation
Environmental regulation, serving as a pivotal policy instrument for fostering clean production practices and reducing environmental degradation, has the potential to moderate the relationship between corporate social responsibility (CSR) disclosure and firms’ export performance [
11]. This moderating effect can be observed in three key aspects.
First, government-mandated compliance inspections under environmental regulations prompt firms to establish and uphold robust environmental management systems, thereby enhancing the legitimacy of their operations [
59]. For example, obtaining ISO 14001 certification for environmental management systems has become a common requirement, enabling firms to systematically identify and address environmental risks. Moreover, regulatory mandates often necessitate environmental impact assessments prior to project implementation, coupled with the adoption of appropriate mitigation measures [
60]. These requirements incentivize firms to increase the frequency and quality of CSR-related disclosures, thereby cultivating a positive public image. In turn, this enhanced transparency bolsters firms’ competitiveness in international markets and contributes to improved export performance.
Second, environmental regulations serve as a corrective mechanism against selective disclosure, opacity, and “greenwashing” practices. Such unethical behaviors undermine the integrity of CSR disclosures and exacerbate information asymmetry in markets [
61]. By compelling firms to adopt environmentally friendly production processes, enhance resource efficiency, and reduce ecological footprints, environmental regulations promote sustainable development [
50]. This regulatory impetus encourages firms to proactively disclose CSR information, leveraging cleaner production technologies and eco-friendly products to penetrate international markets and ascend the global value chain [
1,
62].
Third, while environmental regulations impose immediate cost burdens on firms, they also mitigate long-term risks associated with regulatory non-compliance, reputational damage, and environmental controversies. Over time, these regulations contribute to corporate stability and sustainability, fostering confidence among consumers, investors, and other stakeholders [
63]. This trust-building process enables firms to cultivate strong brand identities in global markets, thereby enhancing their competitiveness. Additionally, CSR disclosure aligns internal operations with corporate values, boosts employee motivation and innovation, improves labor productivity, and ultimately drives export performance. By stabilizing human capital and attracting top talent, CSR disclosures help firms develop new sources of competitive advantage, providing sustained support for long-term growth [
30].
Collectively, environmental regulation may facilitate the enhancement of firms’ international competitiveness through improved CSR disclosure practices, promote upward mobility in global value chains, and ultimately strengthen export performance [
64]. We therefore propose:
Hypothesis 4: Environmental regulation positively moderates the relationship between CSR disclosure and firms’ export performance.