Next Article in Journal
Formula Derivation and Analysis of the Seismic Lateral Pressure of Squat Silos
Next Article in Special Issue
What Can We Expect for the Development of Rural Areas in Europe?—Trends of the Last Decade and Their Opportunities for Rural Regeneration
Previous Article in Journal
Collaborative Governance and Environmental Regulation Measures for Pollution Reduction and Carbon Reduction in the Yangtze River Basin under the “Double Carbon” Goal
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Access to Land: Markets, Policies and Initiatives

by
Willem K. Korthals Altes
Faculty of Architecture and the Built Environment, Delft University of Technology, Julianalaan 134, 2628 BL Delft, The Netherlands
Sustainability 2023, 15(6), 5097; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065097
Submission received: 16 February 2023 / Revised: 7 March 2023 / Accepted: 11 March 2023 / Published: 13 March 2023

Abstract

:
Acquiring access to land is an important issue for new entrants into farming. Traditionally, the succession of farms is within the family; market transactions are geared towards the enlargement of running farms. Policies and institutions have been built to facilitate this process. Current challenges of climate change, resource scarcity, biodiversity and equity, as are analysed by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), the International Resource Panel (IRP), the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services (IPBES) and the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) reporting activities, make it so that there is a need to find alternatives for the current developments in farming, which is a process of up (scale enlargement) or out (stop farming). For these alternatives, new types of farmers who face the issue of access to land are needed. Based on FADN data and EUROSTAT data, current developments in the European farming sector were analysed to understand the impact of the process of modernisation on farmland markets and the complexities of access to land for new entrants. Whether these data may point to opportunities for alternative farming methods and the role of the direct payments of the European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy were analysed. Policies and consequences are discussed. It is concluded that, whereas alternative farming models are promoted at the level of policy aims, this is not performed at the policy guidance level of land markets. Alternatives outside traditional institutions face the issue of scaling up to create impact. The Common Agricultural Policy is, in many ways, more of an obstacle than it is a promoter of providing access to land for new farmers. New policies are needed.

1. Introduction

Current agriculture is in crisis. Agriculture is facing not only issues with its impact on the natural environment, such as on soil health and biodiversity [1], but also with the loss of the function of farming as the backbone of rural communities [2]. For decades, the logic of agricultural innovation has been about mechanisation, specialisation and scale enlargement. Cochrane [3] has analysed this development as an ‘agricultural treadmill’ [4,5] in which farmers must innovate and grow at the expense of farmers who step out, which results in a concentration of landholdings in fewer farms.
For as long as this treadmill has been defined, there have been authors [6,7,8,9] that looked for alternatives. Currently, these alternatives are on the agenda more and more to address challenges such as climate change [10], resource scarcity [11], biodiversity decline [12] and global equity [13], for which policies are being formulated as part of, e.g., the European Green Deal [14], its Farm to Fork Strategy [15] or, more generally, the Sustainable Development Goals [16]. This may also involve new entrants stepping into farming, which is at odds with the logic of the treadmill.
The mechanism of the treadmill [3,4] is that farmers are considered to be small firms that produce exchangeable commodities against a price they cannot individually influence. Farmers that come with innovations have a competitive advantage over their colleagues and receive a windfall profit. Other farmers soon follow this uptake, and in this way, innovations are internalised by the market. This internalisation does not only happen through lower prices for the commodities they produce, but also through the land market as farmers ‘…try to expand in an effort to realize these benefits. The resulting competition for land drives up rents, and profits go back to zero’ [17]. Farmers who do not expand or innovate step out and are overtaken by their innovative competitors [4]. For landowning farmers, it may be attractive to stop farming and rent out the land to the most competitive bidder, the process of which harms the ‘number of new entrants into farming’ [17] and contributes to a ‘oneway transfer of people and money out of rural communities’ [17]. Therefore, the issue is of relevance for a wider rural development agenda.
This paper considers, from a land market perspective, whether there is potential for rural regeneration by new farmers who operate outside this treadmill. Many of the critics, including Van der Ploeg [8], indicate that farmers must not be seen as entrepreneurs operating firms. Rather, there is a need for a revaluation of peasant farmers who are combining a range of activities and who do not depend on specialisation to produce a few market commodities. Farmers may redirect from producing exchangeable commodities towards producing unique products and services for a specific client base.
Critics, furthermore, show that coordinated efforts have constructed the treadmill and its appreciation of the farmer as an entrepreneur. Innovation was ‘not the work of a few lonesome inventors in attics or old barns; rather it resulted from organized and well-financed research several levels’ [3]. This has been channelled in public-financed infrastructure, such as ‘publicly funded access to research, information and training’ [4], as well as government-funded land consolidation programmes that allowed for large-scale mechanised farming practices [18].
The European Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) fits this infrastructure [19]. Since the 1957 Treaty of Rome, the CAP has as its first objective ‘to increase agricultural productivity by promoting technical progress and by ensuring the rational development of agricultural production and the optimum utilisation of the factors of production, in particular labour’ [20] (article 39-1a) as its first objective, which is still the first objective of the CAP in the treaties of today [21].
There is also a long tradition of analysing this treadmill concerning access to land, in which well-intended support to farmers to keep up in this land race is captured in higher land prices [22]. Cochrane [3] has characterised the ‘agricultural treadmill’ as a race.
‘No generalization can be made with respect to this race except to say that it probably operates to increase income disparities within agriculture: the labor income of the efficient producer, farming more land with more capital, holds constant or rises, and the labor income of average and poor farmers declines.’
[3]
So decades ago already, this development was criticized because of the promotion of disparities between farmers that step into the treadmill and farmers stepping out, as well as between renters and owners [17]. The outcome is not only that there are fewer farms, but also that farm holders have become older, resulting in the issue of a lack of rejuvenation [23].
Currently, policy agendas for farming have been changed from modernisation towards greener production methods [14,15]. Greener production methods involve more than a few updates, which can be performed as a simple fix by a farmer who is a few years before retirement but needs a different practice of farming. Therefore, the issue of rejuvenating farming is more than just a change of generations; it is also a change of practices.
Generational renewal can take place in various ways. It can be performed in the modernist ways by farmers that invest in entrepreneurial farming practises to work on a larger scale (more land, novel technologies) than previous generations, or it can be performed by farmers that ground themselves in a localised context of nature and society. In this latter practice, there is, from an economic perspective, less emphasis on external resources, mechanisation and specialisation, but more on enlarging the ratio between the added value of the farm and the gross value of the production [9]. From the perspective of a farmer, it may look like a revolutionary change—a strong breach with past practices and the ‘path dependency’ [8] of its technologies—which is easier to accomplish for a new farmer than for a farmer who has already worked for decades on a farm.
It is likely, based on the analysis by Zagata and Sutherland [23], that this younger farming issue works towards both making the next step into the modernist ‘agricultural treadmill’ (young farmers that take the next step in innovative entrepreneurial investments) and breaching out of this treadmill towards green farming alternatives. Here, it may be that alternative forms of farming may provide ‘non-monetary benefits’ to new generations needed to keep them ‘satisfied with their profession’ [24], which may mean that farmers breach out of a single purpose of basic food production to a range of products and services. In this way, it may bend the outflow of labour and capital from rural areas.
Access to land is, according to several studies, the main issue for new entrants into farming [25,26]. In a report commissioned by the European Commission, access to land was considered to be ‘the most important barrier for young farmers to enter into the agricultural sector’ [27]. Central to this paper is the issue of whether, in the context of current developments in the land market, there is potential for access to land by alternative farmers operating outside this treadmill, but focusing on more diverse product portfolios and the embedding of farming in their communities and natural environments. The study was conducted in the context of the European Union and its CAP, but is of wider relevance, as both the modernisation of agricultural practices and the current challenges of climate change, resource scarcity, biodiversity and equity are of global relevance.
This issue will be discussed in this paper in the following way. After a short introduction to some economic principles, the paper will use FADN data and Eurostat data to study whether the current land markets are still reflecting the logic of the treadmill. This is important because if land markets still do so, then there is not much of an incentive for alternative pathways through the market. To put it in another way, the market as it is has been constructed based on current policy programmes, such as the CAP, but also on national programmes. National legislation may provide a lock-in to allocate land to farmers running in this treadmill. Furthermore, the paper investigates whether the FADN data show potential for alternative developments. This is followed by a discussion on how such an alternative may be developed.

2. Markets and Market Trends

Land is a specific good; there is a distinction between the values of ‘a land component and an improvement component’ [28]. The land component, the pure land value, is not based on the costs of producing it, as it is given by nature, which stands in contrast to the values of land improvements, such as irrigation works and buildings that people have added to the land. Specific to land is that these improvements are often bound to the land in such a way that they cannot be cost effectively separated from the land, making it so that ‘investments are locational fixed’ [29]. The following special features of land are distinguished by Alexander [30]. Firstly, land has limited substitutability; the specific location of land makes it so that it cannot be replaced easily by other lands. The land of a direct neighbour may have more value than land a little further away. Second is that land is a limited resource, not only globally, but also locally. Third is that land is an important investment asset. Fourth, and different from many other investment assets [30], is that there are considerable public interests involved in land. Fifthly, trading land has large transaction costs. Selling property takes time. It is the interplay of these characteristics that makes it so that land is very different from economic commodities [31]; that is, land market developments can be better explained if the institutional context is taken into account [32].
A specific feature of the land market is that local land supply is finite. Supply curves (Figure 1) become very steep close to the full use of this finite supply, which may enlarge this issue of accessibility towards properties. This well-known representation of supply and demand curves shows that even when the quantity of demand in a market is high, this may not result in a transaction, as the price is too high. Furthermore, the quantity of demand may exceed the fixed area of land that is available. Due to urbanisation pressure, available farmland is in decline [33]. Moreover, farmland is often transferred within the family, making it so that only a very small percentage of available farmland is transacted through the market [34,35].
In many rural contexts, existing farms that enlarge their properties may be able to pay a higher price than new entrants to farming can afford. There are marginal costs to the benefits of a running farm acquiring some extra land, resulting in an improvement of benefits versus costs for the existing lands of the farm as well [36]. Furthermore, studies have revealed that it is ‘easier for larger farms to expand’ [37] and that large farms expand more than smaller farms, especially in a context of unequal farm sizes [37]. Rasva and Jürgenson [38] indicate that for many farms, it is a matter of ‘to grow or go’ [38].
Luijt and Voskuilen [36] analysed data in the Netherlands, showing that field crop farmers with a higher standard output not only hold more hectares, but also achieve higher standard outputs per hectare. Between 2005 and 2009, the average income per hectare for smaller farmers was EUR 554 standard output per hectare; for mid-sized farms it was EUR 706 per hectare, and for large farms, it was EUR 1171 per hectare. According to their insights, a mid-sized farm growing to a large farm could, if the costs per hectare stayed the same, pay more than twice as much for land per hectare than a small farm aiming to achieve a mid-sized farm [36]. Figures are different for different crops. This method shows what farms potentially can afford to pay. It does not reveal what they are paying for land and other costs that fit farming on a larger scale. An analysis of the net incomes of farms can show us what remains below the line.
In this paper, we will analyse two types of data to study the relationship between farm enlargement, farm concentration and farm development, that is, data from the FADN relating to the economic features of scale enlargement and EUROSTAT data relating to regional concentration of farmland holdings. The analysis focuses on data of relevance for new entrants into farming that aim for an alternative practice.

3. The Logic of Farm Enlargement and Its Impact on the Farmland Market

Statistical data provide insight into current developments. The statistical survey of the FADN allows for analysing farm developments throughout the EU. However, at the scale of the EU, there are many different contexts, including climate, price levels of labour and land and path dependency; there is diversity underlying the averages presented by the data.
The figures of the Farm Accountancy Data Network [39,40] underwrite the logic of farm enlargement (based on the treadmill idea), as they show that farms with higher standard outputs are larger (Table 1) and that generally, the standard output per hectare is higher the larger the farm is (Table 2).
The higher standard output per hectare (Table 2) for larger farms is not only for the extra hectares they use, but for all hectares. Therefore, the statistical data suggest that in current farms, there is a large incentive towards scale enlargement. If, as Luijt and Voskuilen [36] have suggested for the Netherlands’ context, the idea is that these extra outputs can be unlocked by buying extra land, the result is that the extra output can be allocated to the extra land acquired to achieve higher production, especially for larger farms (Table 3 and Table 4). The results presented are only an assumption. It is about different farms that are in different size classes. Differences in context between the farms may dictate these differences. Therefore, it is a potential increase that may not reflect the situation of a specific farm. However, it is also a step that many farms take as they grow.
For farms with animals, that is, Milk, Other grazing livestock, Granivores (pig and poultry farms) and Mixed (Table 4), the tables suggest that there is no incentive for smaller farms to grow incrementally, but this incentive only comes above a certain threshold. For all crops, it seems to be profitable for large farms to grow, at least taking into consideration how current farm practices have developed. These differences in a potential increase in output between small farms and big farms may contribute to the explanation of the unequal division of land holdings in many European regions. It at least adds to the explanation of why big farms aim to get even bigger, as there are economies of scale involved in current practices, and it also explains why certain types of farms do not make the step towards growth, as this cannot be reached incrementally. It also suggests why it is difficult for new entrants into farming to start a small farm, as they cannot pay the same price for the land as large farms that can unlock more extra output by growing larger.
Based on the potential increase in output, the expectation is that farms grow, which is reflected by statistical data (Figure 2).
In the EU, there is a tendency towards fewer small farm holdings and more large farm holdings (Figure 2). Kay et al. [42] have analysed the inequality of farm holdings in Europe based on EUROSTAT data and revealed that the GINI index at the level of the EU was very high, equalling 0.81 in 2016 [42,43]. Note that a GINI of zero means that all land holdings are the same, and that with a GINI of one, all land is concentrated. Korthals Altes [29] has, using this same method, analysed the GINI at (NUTS 2) a regional level (Table 5, Figure 3). After all, it is at the level of the region that this inequality counts. Differences in landholdings between different regions may be a reflection of other differences in farming practices, including differences in climate, rather than in access to land.
In 2020, there were 26 NUTS2 regions with a GINI of 0.81 or higher; 22 of these regions were located in Bulgaria, Hungary, Romania and Slovakia (see Appendix A). In Bulgaria, Romania and Slovakia, land restitution to heirs of original owners resulted in a splintering of ownership rights. Large companies have stepped in by acquiring lease rights to obtain reverse tenure situations [44]. In Hungary, the land has not been returned to the original owners, but a voucher system has been in place, resulting in a mix of large farms and smaller ones [45]. The others include two cities (Vienna and Lisbon) which have a limited area of farmland, such as a few relatively small vineyards in the hills close to the Vienna forest and some large farms in the flat areas on the east side of the Danube (and a city-owned farm of 2000 hectares) [46], a mountain area with large differences in size between vineyards in the valleys and mountain pastures (Aosta in Italy) [29,47] and a region (Jihovychod) in Czechia, which shares a border with Slovakia. Other regions with a large inequality (GINI above 0.67) include other regions in the CEE (from Latvia to Croatia and including the east of Germany), city areas, the well-known rural regions of inequality in the Iberian Peninsula (Andalucía, Alentejo, Extremadura and many others), some other mountain regions with both intensive valley agriculture and extensive mountain pastures (Trento), some other regions in the Mediterranean area (including in Greece and Italy) and some of the outermost regions of the EU (Guyane, Canarias). Two other outermost regions (Madeira and Mayotte) have the most equal division of farmland holdings in the EU (See Appendix A for the complete list).
Korthals Altes [29] indicates that many of the unequal farmland-holdings areas have a low score on the quality of government indicators as studied by Charron et al. [48,49]. This means that many people answer in questionnaires that they, e.g., do not feel that all people have equal access to public services or have equal access to get their interests promoted by the government. An in-depth analysis of the context of some of these regions, such as the NUTS 3 region of Teleorman in the NUTS 2 region Sud-Muntenia (GINI 0.86 see Appendix A) in Romania, shows that the large landholders have a powerful position in the economy outside the farming sector and tight relationships with people in office [29].
In short, the outcomes of the analysis show that there is a tendency for scale enlargement. Furthermore, it shows that in some regions, this is a more equitable development than in others. The question remains whether the data show that this development is inevitable or whether they also suggest that there are alternatives for the treadmill.

4. Analysing the Data from Alternative Development Perspectives about Land

The question is whether there are alternatives for the developments analysed above. The most obvious alternative pathway to enlarging farm income without enlarging the farm is to step outside the silo of current crops towards another crop. A switch from a farm with animals, for example (see Table 2), milk production, to another type of crop may result in a higher standard output. Although in the past many farms have been multifunctional [50], currently, the process of scale enlargement largely takes place within the pillars of a given production method. Stepping outside these pillars may result in even more added value than that provided by scale enlargement in the current way of production. One such new way of farming is a process of farm restructuring which may be as large in its impact as the current trajectory towards mechanisation and scale enlargement has been. Here, an ‘ever increasing lock-in makes paths more difficult to break over time’ [51] (page 147) within a specific trajectory of farm organisation. From the perspective of a ‘farm manager’, such a process of restructuring may feel like terminating the current farm and starting anew. After all, farms are so specialised that past investments may not be re-used in the case of such a change. It is more a step taken as part of a process of generational renewal, with a new generation on the farm finding a new way of farming, than a step taken as part of natural development by a given farm. It is also complex, as not all local contexts allow for all kinds of transitions, i.e., not all land is fit for vineyards. Moreover, other matters, including public policies, may limit these possibilities. New types of farming may involve matters that are relevant for planning and environmental regulations, such as new types of buildings, new uses of existing buildings and a different impact on the environment. It may also be that the current specialisation of the farm is the ‘highest and best use’ [52] of the land in the current context. This means that changes in the context are needed to nudge farmers towards a different way of farming. After all, it is the context which has been important in structuring current agricultural development pathways [4].
However, as indicated in the introduction, going back to the basics of farming is not all about enlarging gross income. Alternative farming models are less focused on the total output of the farm than on receiving more added value [9]. Here the FADN indicator ‘Farm Net Income’ provides some insight, as this variable excludes the finances for external factors (such as rent, wages and interest) and subsidies and taxes on investments [53]. The share of farm net income relative to total output becomes smaller as the farm gets larger (Table 6). As decoupled payments in the CAP are per-hectare payments, the importance of these payments relative to net income is, in many cases, higher for big farms than for small farms (Table 7). However, most striking here are not the differences within a certain type of crop, but the differences between different crop types. For farms practising horticulture, the decoupled payments play a marginal role (2% to 3% of farm net income), but for farms active in field crops, they are often more than 50% of the net income. Labour-intensive crops seem to be less well subsidised than land-intensive crops, which has an impact that goes beyond the land market. It may be discussed whether this low contribution to labour-intensive farming meets the CAP objective ‘to ensure a fair standard of living for the agricultural community, in particular by increasing the individual earnings of persons engaged in agriculture’ [21] (article 29-1(b)). Individual earnings of persons active in horticulture (Table 7) seem to be less supported than those for people active in other forms of farming, and it is precisely this horticulture where many new entrants into farming find their way [26,54,55].
Larger farms lease a larger percentage of their farms (Table 8) and pay more rent per rented hectare in most cases (Table 9). This suggests that large farms are leading the demand for rented land (as they pay more), which implies that access to land is difficult for smaller farms that need a better ratio between net income and total income of the farm.
The larger share of farm net income to total income for smaller farms (Table 6) underwrites the conclusions that Oostindie et al. [56] drew for dairy farming, which they based on individual farm accounts. Farms that focus on reducing costs are more resilient during a crisis. The impact, both positive and negative, of changes in gross income (if these changes are independent of changes in costs) on net income is larger the smaller the ratio is between net income and gross income. This suggests that larger farms are riskier than smaller farms. This illustrates the importance that agricultural policies have in scale enlargements of farms, as these policies contribute to a stable environment that reduces the risks of farming big. The outcome is that for many types of crops, the growth of the farm does not transfer into a high net income per hectare. A considerable amount of this growth is captured by the extra costs of managing a large farm, including higher costs for renting land, which fits the treadmill theory.
Renting extra land involves not only making extra costs, but also getting extra decoupled payments of the CAP, as these are based on the area of farmland. In a way, the higher rent paid by larger farms can be seen as a capturing of decoupled payments by land markets [57,58,59,60,61]. Moreover, the CAP likely has an impact on farm sizes [62]. This makes it have, relative to existing farmers, a negative impact on new entrants into farming. In addition, the CAP is not likely to support other green development aims [63].

5. Discussion: Towards an Alternative Infrastructure

What does the previous analysis of existing farms say on the issue of access to land for new farmers? As indicated in the introduction, access to land for new farmers is a big issue in the European context of ageing farmers [23]. The fact that the highest rents are paid by large farms and that the added value is larger for bigger farms contributes to the fact that many new entrants have a large issue in getting access to land. Therefore, many new entrants go for crops that promise a high output per hectare of land, such as horticulture [26].
In this context, the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) may be less of a support and more of a hindrance to these new entrants. The average share of CAP decoupled payments is, for farmers in horticulture, marginal to the farm net income (Table 7). Therefore, it does not support them considerably. Furthermore, the decoupled payments are captured by the land market, resulting in high land prices and making the land market very difficult to access for new entrants [60]. Existing landholders keep the land to harvest the grants, which are higher than the rent in most member states [64]. It seems that many new entrants into farming would be better off without the decoupled payments of the CAP (as it forms a barrier to access to land) than with the CAP (as the contributions from the CAP to horticulture are marginal). This is quite a disappointment, as the CAP aims to foster generational renewal [65]. Furthermore, the EU suggests that farming should transform into a practice contributing to a green deal. It suggests that the modernisation programme of the CAP, as has been carved in the Treaty of Rome [20] and upheld by a coalition of interested parties ever since, needs an update, which is very difficult. Treaties [21] are quite difficult to change, as they need consent from all member states and their parliaments. Opening this box of Pandora may also result in unforeseen outcomes, making continuation a part of a pragmatic political approach.
In addition, many national policies and legal structures aim to facilitate farmers running in the treadmill by supporting them to be one step ahead of the competition. An analysis of government legal tools and policies in the European Union shows that access to land for new farmers was not an established policy aim anywhere [66].
‘Unlike for the agenda for modernisation of farmland, for which most of the EU Member States have had land consolidation instrument, there is no successfully dispersed legal and policy arrangement to provide access to land for new generations.’
[66].
It is therefore the case that new entrants may find the best options for the issue of access to land outside markets and policy. Although several initiatives and organisations acquire land to make it available to new entrants into farming, many more are active in supporting other stakeholders to take action. These organisations exchange knowledge, such as in the Erasmus-Plus-funded projects ‘Fostering access to land for a new generation of agroecological farmers’ [67], ‘Learning towards access to land’ [68] and ‘Setting up a Learning Platform for Farmers’ Access to Land’ [69]. One of the leading actors in the access-to-land movement is Terre de Liens, whose foundation was founded in 2003 [70], and which has a range of legal entities, such as a national association, several regional associations to ensure local embeddedness, a charity foundation to allow for using gifts and bequests [70,71] and an investment fund, the ‘Foncière Solidaire’, [71] to allow for acquisition and use of low-interest funding to acquire farmland to be leased to new farmers. Macombe [71] evaluates this structure as ‘… a potential for durable collective alternatives to individual ownership of agricultural land, the future extent of which depends on future policy decisions.’ [71] Some older organisations, such as BD Grondbeheer in the Netherlands (founded in 1978), have not been directly involved in these Erasmus programmes, but have been inspired towards taking a more active role in obtaining new sources of finance to broaden their scope by this new access-to-land movement [55].
Loveluck, Martin-Prével, Rioufol, Farrell, Murtagh, Graham, Swade and Blasco [55] have provided an overview of 64 innovative actions, which have been categorised based on an ‘access to land pathway’ [55]. This pathway has the following stages. First, there are innovative practices that support people in their development towards professional farmers before they have access to land. Examples are schools that teach people to become farmers or traineeships. Secondly, there are practices that aim to ensure that land in general will be available for farm use. This can be initiatives and organisations that fight against land take, organisations that favour sustainable or more specifically agroecological use of farmland or organisations that support the use of local lands for local food provision [55]. Thirdly, there are initiatives that aim for land to be controlled by organisations that favour ‘more sustainable practices’ [55]. So, land acquisitions by Terre de Liens or other organisations on the access-to-land network fit under this heading. Fourthly, there are the actual disposes of land towards new entrants by these organisations. Usually, this happens in the form of a lease. The price and conditions of the leases fit the proposed use of the land, which is different from many market leases that aim for high prices and a short turnover, which is not fostering sustainable land use. Fifthly, there are actions that support new farmers if they already have the land. Being a farmer only starts after having access to land to be able to use it for farming. The overview of the 64 practices shows that different initiatives have different focuses, but that the whole realm of this pathway is covered by the set of initiatives selected [55].
This access-to-land pathway can be seen as an alternative to the pathway of the agricultural treadmill. The main difference is that the organisation of this pathway lacks many of the government resources that the mainstream has, as government resources have not been set up to support this. Alternatively, access-to-land institutions are searching for support from local authorities and other stakeholders [72].
Many of these initiatives happen on a relatively small scale. Terre des Liens has acquired 5750 hectares of land for 219 farms [55]. Although a notable share of the other 390,000 farms [73] in France consult Terre de Lines to improve agroecological practices, it is still outside mainstream farming. Notably, organisations such as Terre de Liens provide an alternative to the current market-based allocation of land based on the idea that land should not be a commodity, but a common good [74]. Therefore, it is an alternative to the practices of markets and public policies. Building such an alternative, a parallel to land market allocations, is something that is not easy to deliver. This is an emerging movement. Although certain local governments participate in it well based on supporting initiatives [75], it is mostly not based on mainstream land policies, but is about specific actions outside policies which aim to stay outside the logic of the treadmill. Therefore, it is a different context that is being created outside the dominant logic, for which new allies are sought and found at local government levels. If the government is willing to support this development as well, it is necessary to support every stage of this pathway and to change financial support to farmers in a way that there is an incentive for big farms to transfer a part of their land to new farmers in a way that supports a sustainable way of farming. The current direct payment programme, in which farmers will get fewer grants if they do so, is a measure that puts the cart before the horse.
Although this study is focused on the EU, it has a wider relevance both in the global North [76] and in the global South. Although ‘secure and equal access to land’ for ‘small-scale food producers’ is one of the targets of the SDG, there is no official indicator to measure access to land [77]. Furthermore, next to farming, there is a wider competition for land. This competition is not reserved for traditional forms of urban sprawl for housing, economic sites and infrastructure [78], but also for clean energy production, which may result in ‘a klondike-like landrush’ [79] for sites designated for energy harvesting or ‘energy injustice’ [80] concerning the planning of hydropower plants, biodiversity offsets [81] and water management [82]. There is a hunger for land for which issues of fair governance are on the table.
Consequently, there is a policy gap between the aims and targets of providing farmers access to land, with the policies in action on one side resulting in a displacement of these farmers on the other side.

6. Conclusions

The question in this paper is why markets and policies do not cater to provide new farmers access to land; farmers who are aiming for new farming practices that support addressing the current challenges of rural areas. The short answer is that current institutions are built to guide the process of farm modernisation. This process has been analysed as an agricultural treadmill [3], which is upheld with an infrastructure of policies and other institutions. It has an impact on the land market. Large farms that grow can pay higher prices than new entrants into farming. Moreover, many of the incentives and farm grants are captured by the land market, resulting in higher prices. Large, growing farms enlarge their landholdings primarily via rent. Due to the growing dominance of rent as a way to assemble more farmland, incentives and grants flow through the accounts of active farmers towards non-farming landowners, who are the final recipients of public funding to support farmers.
There is some scope in the market for other ways of farming, such as farming different crops and finding a better ratio between farm net income and the gross turnover of a farm, but whether these are indeed feasible strategies depends on the local context.
There are many policy initiatives that, in response to challenges of climate change, resource scarcity, biodiversity loss and global equity, promote other ways of farming at a high level of abstraction, such as the Farm to Fork Strategy [15], but these have not resulted in changes in the conditions on land markets, nor have they developed operational programmes that make a difference to the topic of access to land for new farmers. For many new farmers, the capturing of agricultural subsidies by the land markets and the consequent high costs of entering farming outweigh the potential benefits of direct payments from the EU Common Agricultural Policy.
For new entrants into farming, neither market conditions nor policies provide a way to access land. However, there is a network of access-to-land organisations that aim to fill this gap by providing support to potential new farmers, addressing land taken from farming to other sectors, promoting sustainable use of farmland, providing land to new farmers and supporting farmers that farm outside the treadmill. New policies may learn from these practices and support new farmers through these ways rather than by financing landowners through the purses of farmers.

Funding

This research has received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under grant agreement No 817642.

Institutional Review Board Statement

The research has been approved by the Human Research Ethics Committee TU Delft.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Inequality of Farmland Holdings by NUTS2 Region in the European Union in 2020 Based on EUROSTAT [41]

CodeRegionGINI2020
RO22Sud-Est0.88
RO32Bucuresti-Ilfov0.88
SK01Bratislavský kraj0.88
HU23Dél-Dunántúl0.87
BG33Severoiztochen0.87
HU22Nyugat-Dunántúl0.86
HU12Pest0.86
RO31Sud-Muntenia0.86
HU21Közép-Dunántúl0.86
BG32Severen tsentralen0.86
HU31Észak-Magyarország0.85
BG42Yuzhen tsentralen0.85
BG31Severozapaden0.85
AT13Wien0.84
CZ06Jihovýchod0.84
BG34Yugoiztochen0.84
HU32Észak-Alföld0.84
HU33Dél-Alföld0.83
SK03Stredné Slovensko0.83
RO42Vest0.82
SK02Západné Slovensko0.82
ITC2Valle d’Aosta/Vallée d’Aoste0.82
HU11Budapest0.82
BG41Yugozapaden0.82
PT17Área Metropolitana de Lisboa0.81
LV00Latvija0.79
SK04Východné Slovensko0.79
ES43Extremadura0.79
ITH2Provincia Autonoma di Trento0.78
ES61Andalucía0.78
CZ07Strední Morava0.78
ES70Canarias0.78
PT18Alentejo0.78
ES23La Rioja0.77
LT01Sostines regionas0.77
ES62Región de Murcia0.77
CZ01Praha0.77
LT02Vidurio ir vakaru Lietuvos regionas0.76
ES30Comunidad de Madrid0.76
FRY3Guyane0.76
RO12Centru0.76
RO21Nord-Est0.75
CZ08Moravskoslezsko0.75
DE60Hamburg0.75
HR03Jadranska Hrvatska0.74
ES42Castilla-la Mancha0.73
ITI1Toscana0.73
CZ05Severovýchod0.73
CY00Kypros0.73
ITI4Lazio0.73
RO41Sud-Vest Oltenia0.73
PT16Centro (PT)0.73
ITC4Lombardia0.73
HR02Panonska Hrvatska0.73
PL43Lubuskie0.73
FRL0Provence-Alpes-Côte d’Azur0.73
PL52Opolskie0.72
PL51Dolnoslaskie0.72
PL42Zachodniopomorskie0.72
ITF4Puglia0.72
ITC1Piemonte0.72
EE00Eesti0.71
DED4Chemnitz0.71
PT20Região Autónoma dos Açores (PT)0.71
CZ02Strední Cechy0.70
ITH3Veneto0.70
ES52Comunitat Valenciana0.70
ITI2Umbria0.70
ITH4Friuli-Venezia Giulia0.70
CZ03Jihozápad0.70
ITF6Calabria0.70
ITI3Marche0.70
PT15Algarve0.70
ITG1Sicilia0.70
EL42Notio Aigaio0.70
DED2Dresden0.70
ITF5Basilicata0.69
FRY2Martinique0.69
ES51Cataluña0.69
DK01Hovedstaden0.69
ES11Galicia0.69
RO11Nord-Vest0.69
ES22Comunidad Foral de Navarra0.69
ES21País Vasco0.69
ITC3Liguria0.69
EL41Voreio Aigaio0.69
FRJ1Languedoc-Roussillon0.69
ITF1Abruzzo0.68
AT11Burgenland (AT)0.68
ITG2Sardegna0.68
ES53Illes Balears0.68
ITH5Emilia-Romagna0.68
EL43Kriti0.67
PL63Pomorskie0.67
DK05Nordjylland0.67
DK02Sjælland0.67
DK04Midtjylland0.66
SE32Mellersta Norrland0.66
PT11Norte0.66
PL62Warminsko-Mazurskie0.66
ITF3Campania0.66
ES24Aragón0.66
SE22Sydsverige0.66
SE11Stockholm0.65
DEG0Thüringen0.65
SE23Västsverige0.65
SE31Norra Mellansverige0.65
HR05Grad Zagreb0.65
ES41Castilla y León0.64
PL22Slaskie0.64
DK03Syddanmark0.64
ITH1Provincia Autonoma di Bolzano/Bozen0.64
SE33Övre Norrland0.64
CZ04Severozápad0.64
EL64Sterea Ellada0.64
HR06Sjeverna Hrvatska0.64
PL41Wielkopolskie0.63
DEB3Rheinhessen-Pfalz0.63
DED5Leipzig0.63
NL33Zuid-Holland0.62
DEB2Trier0.62
ITF2Molise0.62
ES13Cantabria0.62
SE21Småland med öarna0.62
SE12Östra Mellansverige0.62
FRF2Champagne-Ardenne0.62
EL54Ipeiros0.61
PL61Kujawsko-Pomorskie0.61
EL51Anatoliki Makedonia, Thraki0.61
EL53Dytiki Makedonia0.61
EL30Attiki0.61
DE13Freiburg0.61
EL52Kentriki Makedonia0.61
ES12Principado de Asturias0.61
EL61Thessalia0.60
FRF1Alsace0.60
DEB1Koblenz0.60
EL62Ionia Nisia0.60
EL63Dytiki Ellada0.59
FRY4La Réunion0.59
DE26Unterfranken0.59
DE12Karlsruhe0.58
NL42Limburg (NL)0.58
SI03Vzhodna Slovenija0.58
DE11Stuttgart0.57
PL91Warszawski stoleczny0.56
SI04Zahodna Slovenija0.56
FRK2Rhône-Alpes0.56
DE40Brandenburg0.56
DEA4Detmold0.55
FRI1Aquitaine0.55
NL22Gelderland0.55
DEA1Düsseldorf0.55
NL41Noord-Brabant0.55
BE21Prov. Antwerpen0.54
NL32Noord-Holland0.54
DE71Darmstadt0.54
DE72Gießen0.54
PL81Lubelskie0.54
PL82Podkarpackie0.54
DE24Oberfranken0.53
FRY1Guadeloupe0.53
DE73Kassel0.53
AT12Niederösterreich0.53
DEA5Arnsberg0.53
DEF0Schleswig-Holstein0.52
DEA2Köln0.52
DE14Tübingen0.52
DE30Berlin0.52
BE10Région de Bruxelles-Capitale/Brussels Hoofdstedelijk Gewest0.52
DE93Lüneburg0.51
DE25Mittelfranken0.51
AT34Vorarlberg0.51
EL65Peloponnisos0.51
FRM0Corse0.51
AT22Steiermark0.51
DEC0Saarland0.51
BE24Prov. Vlaams-Brabant0.51
DEA3Münster0.51
PL92Mazowiecki regionalny0.51
NL13Drenthe0.51
PL84Podlaskie0.50
FI1DPohjois- ja Itä-Suomi0.50
DE92Hannover0.50
DE91Braunschweig0.50
DE94Weser-Ems0.50
FI19Länsi-Suomi0.50
PL71Lódzkie0.50
AT21Kärnten0.50
BE22Prov. Limburg (BE)0.50
DEE0Sachsen-Anhalt0.49
FI1BHelsinki-Uusimaa0.49
FRJ2Midi-Pyrénées0.49
NL34Zeeland0.49
DE80Mecklenburg-Vorpommern0.49
AT33Tirol0.49
BE23Prov. Oost-Vlaanderen0.49
DE22Niederbayern0.49
BE25Prov. West-Vlaanderen0.48
LU00Luxembourg0.48
FI1CEtelä-Suomi0.48
NL21Overijssel0.48
PL72Swietokrzyskie0.48
AT32Salzburg0.48
PL21Malopolskie0.48
IE06Eastern and Midland0.47
DE23Oberpfalz0.47
FRD1Basse-Normandie0.47
NL31Utrecht0.47
FI20Åland0.47
DE27Schwaben0.46
DE50Bremen0.45
FRI2Limousin0.45
BE33Prov. Liège0.45
DE21Oberbayern0.45
BE31Prov. Brabant wallon0.45
NL23Flevoland0.45
FRC1Bourgogne0.44
NL11Groningen0.44
IE05Southern0.43
BE32Prov. Hainaut0.43
FRI3Poitou-Charentes0.43
BE35Prov. Namur0.42
AT31Oberösterreich0.42
FRH0Bretagne0.42
IE04Northern and Western0.42
FRK1Auvergne0.42
FRE1Nord-Pas-de-Calais0.42
NL12Friesland (NL)0.42
FRG0Pays-de-la-Loire0.42
BE34Prov. Luxembourg (BE)0.41
FRD2Haute-Normandie0.41
MT00Malta0.41
FRC2Franche-Comté0.38
FRE2Picardie0.36
FRF3Lorraine0.35
FRB0Centre-Val de Loire0.35
FR10Île de France0.31
FRY5Mayotte0.30
PT30Região Autónoma da Madeira (PT)0.16

References

  1. Giller, K.E.; Hijbeek, R.; Andersson, J.A.; Sumberg, J. Regenerative Agriculture: An agronomic perspective. Outlook Agric. 2021, 50, 13–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Park, S.; Deller, S. Effect of farm structure on rural community well-being. J. Rural. Stud. 2021, 87, 300–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Cochrane, W.W. (Ed.) The Agricultural Treadmill. In The Curse of American Agricultural Abundance: A Sustainable Solution, 1st ed.; 1958; University of Nebraska Press: Lincoln, NE, USA, 2003; pp. 19–44. [Google Scholar]
  4. Röling, N. Pathways for impact: Scientists’ different perspectives on agricultural innovation. Int. J. Agric. Sustain. 2009, 7, 83–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ward, N. The Agricultural Treadmill and the Rural Environment in the Post-Productivist Era. Sociol. Rural. 1993, 33, 348–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Marsden, T. Agriculture beyond the treadmill? Issues for policy, theory and research practice. Prog. Hum. Geogr. 1998, 22, 265–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Marsden, T. Denial or diversity? creating new spaces for sustainable development. J. Environ. Policy Plan. 2006, 8, 183–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Van der Ploeg, J.D. From de-to repeasantization: The modernization of agriculture revisited. J. Rural. Stud. 2018, 61, 236–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. van der Ploeg, J.D.; Barjolle, D.; Bruil, J.; Brunori, G.; Madureira, L.M.C.; Dessein, J.; Drąg, Z.; Fink-Kessler, A.; Gasselin, P.; de Molina, M.G.; et al. The economic potential of agroecology: Empirical evidence from Europe. J. Rural. Stud. 2019, 71, 46–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Climate Change and Land; IPCC: Cambridge, UK, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  11. Working Group on Land and Soils of the International Resource Panel. Unlocking the Sustainable Potential of Land Resources: Evaluation Systems, Strategies and Tools; UNEP: Nairobi, Kenya, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  12. IPBES. Global Assessment Report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services; IPBES: Bonn, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  13. United Nations. The Sustainable Development Goals Report 2022; United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  14. EC. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the European Council, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions the European Green Deal (Com/2019/640 Final); European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  15. EC. Commincation from the Commission to the European Parliament the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions: A Farm to Fork Strategy for a Fair, Healthy and Environmentally-Friendly Food System; European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  16. Terlau, W.; Hirsch, D.; Blanke, M. Smallholder farmers as a backbone for the implementation of the Sustainable Development Goals. Sustain. Dev. 2019, 27, 523–529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Levins, R.A.; Cochrane, W.W. The Treadmill Revisited. Land Econ. 1996, 72, 550–553. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Brink, A.V.D.; Molema, M. The origins of Dutch rural planning: A study of the early history of land consolidation in the Netherlands. Plan. Perspect. 2008, 23, 427–453. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Pe’er, G.; Bonn, A.; Bruelheide, H.; Dieker, P.; Eisenhauer, N.; Feindt, P.H.; Hagedorn, G.; Hansjürgens, B.; Herzon, I.; Lomba, Â.; et al. Action needed for the EU Common Agricultural Policy to address sustainability challenges. People Nat. 2020, 2, 305–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. EEC. Treaty Establishing the European Economic Community; Kingdom of Belgium, Federal Republic of Germany, French Republic, Italian Republic, Grand Duchy of Luxembourg, Kingdom of the Netherlands: Rome, Italy, 1957; Available online: https://www.europarl.europa.eu/about-parliament/en/in-the-past/the-parliament-and-the-treaties/treaty-of-rome (accessed on 17 November 2022).
  21. EU. Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. Off. J. Eur. Union 2010, 53, 47–200. [Google Scholar]
  22. Salter, L.A. Farm Property and Agricultural Policy. J. Political Econ. 1943, 51, 13–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Zagata, L.; Sutherland, L.-A. Deconstructing the ‘young farmer problem in Europe’: Towards a research agenda. J. Rural. Stud. 2015, 38, 39–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Jansuwan, P.; Zander, K.K. Multifunctional farming as successful pathway for the next generation of Thai farmers. PLoS ONE 2022, 17, e0267351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Zagata, L.; Hrabák, J.; Lošťák, M.; Bavorová, M.; Ratinger, T.; Sutherland, L.-A.; McKee, A. Research for AGRI Committee—Young Farmers—Policy Implementation after the 2013 CAP Reform; European Parliament: Brussels, Belgium, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  26. Dwyer, J.; Micha, E.; Kubinakova, K.; van Bunnen, P.; Schuh, B.; Maucorps, A.; Mantino, F. Evaluation of the Impact of the CAP on Generational Renewal, Local Development and Jobs in Rural Areas; European Commission: Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural Development: Brussels, Belgium, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  27. Zondag, M.-J.; de Lauwere, C.; Sloot, P.; Pauer, A. Pilot Project: Exchange Programmes for Young Farmers; Executive Summary; European Commission: Directorate-General for Agriculture and Rural Development: Brussels, Belgium, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  28. Krause, A.L.; Bitter, C. Spatial econometrics, land values and sustainability: Trends in real estate valuation research. Cities 2012, 29, S19–S25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Korthals Altes, W.K. Technical Report on Quantitative Analysis of Land Holdings and Land Market Trends; Community Research and Development Information Service: Luxembourg, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  30. Alexander, E. Land-property markets and planning: A special case. Land Use Policy 2014, 41, 533–540. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Woestenburg, A.; van der Krabben, E.; Spit, T. Institutions in rural land transactions Evidence from The Netherlands. J. Eur. Real Estate Res. 2014, 7, 216–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Gorgan, M.; Hartvigsen, M. Development of agricultural land markets in countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. Land Use Policy 2022, 120, 106257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Hüttel, S.; Wildermann, L.; Croonenbroeck, C. How do institutional market players matter in farmland pricing? Land Use Policy 2016, 59, 154–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Kionka, M.; Odening, M.; Plogmann, J.; Ritter, M. Measuring liquidity in agricultural land markets. Agric. Financ. Rev. 2022, 82, 690–713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Bradfield, T.; Butler, R.; Dillon, E.J.; Hennessy, T.; Loughrey, J. Attachment to land and its downfalls: Can policy encourage land mobility? J. Rural. Stud. 2023, 97, 192–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Luijt, J.; Voskuilen, M.J. Grond Voor Schaalvergroting: Achtergronddocument; LEI, Onderdeel van Wageningen UR: Den Haag, The Netherlands, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  37. Plogmann, J.; Mußhoff, O.; Odening, M.; Ritter, M. Farm growth and land concentration. Land Use Policy 2022, 115, 106036. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Rasva, M.; Jürgenson, E. Agricultural Land Concentration in Estonia and Its Containment Possibilities. Land 2022, 11, 2270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. FADN. FADN Public Database; European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  40. EC. Consolidated Text: Commission Implementing Regulation (EU) 2015/220 of 3 February 2015 Laying down Rules for the Application of Council Regulation (EC) No 1217/2009 Setting up a Network for the Collection of Accountancy Data on the Incomes and Business Operation of Agricultural Holdings in the European Union; EC: Brussels, Belgium, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  41. EUROSTAT. Farm Indicators by Agricultural Area, Type of Farm, Standard Output, Sex and Age of the Manager and NUTS 2 Regions [ef_m_farmang]; EUROSTAT: Luxembourg, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  42. Kay, S.; Peuch, J.; Franco, J. Extent of Farmland Grabbing in the EU; Policy Department B: Structural and Cohesion Policies European Parliament: Brussels, Belgium, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  43. EP. European Parliament Resolution of 27 April 2017 on the State of Play of Farmland Concentration in the EU: How to Facilitate the Access to Land for Farmers (2016/2141(INI); European Parliament: Brussels, Belgium, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  44. Amblard, L.; Colin, J.-P. Reverse tenancy in Romania: Actors’ rationales and equity outcomes. Land Use Policy 2009, 26, 828–836. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Hartvigsen, M. Land reform and land fragmentation in Central and Eastern Europe. Land Use Policy 2014, 36, 330–341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Weidinger, H. Organic Production in Vienna. In Organic Cities—Wien is(s)t nachhaltig (Vienna Is Sustainable/Vienna Eats Sustainably); Stadt Wien: Vienna, Austria, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  47. Bagnod, G.; Chenal, G.; Corsi, A.; Letey, M.; Mazzarino, S. The ‘Pergola Valdostana’ and heroic viticulture in Aosta Valley (Italy): A case study on a traditional wine-growing system. Ann. Ser. Hist. Et Sociol. 2020, 30, 99–112. [Google Scholar]
  48. Charron, N.; Lapuente, V.; Annoni, P. Measuring quality of government in EU regions across space and time. Pap. Reg. Sci. 2019, 98, 1925–1953. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Charron, N.; Dijkstra, L.; Lapuente, V. Mapping the Regional Divide in Europe: A Measure for Assessing Quality of Government in 206 European Regions. Soc. Indic. Res. 2015, 122, 315–346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Marquardt, K.; Eriksson, C.; Kuns, B. Towards a Deeper Understanding of Agricultural Production Systems in Sweden—Linking Farmer’s Logics with Environmental Consequences and the Landscape. Rural. Landsc. Soc. Environ. Hist. 2022, 9, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Sutherland, L.-A.; Burton, R.J.; Ingram, J.; Blackstock, K.; Slee, B.; Gotts, N. Triggering change: Towards a conceptualisation of major change processes in farm decision-making. J. Environ. Manag. 2012, 104, 142–151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. McCarthy, I. Impact of Sustainable Agriculture Practices on Farmland Value; The Property Foundation: Wellington, New Zealand, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  53. FADN. Farm Accounting Data Network: An A to Z of Methodology; European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  54. Farrell, M.; Murtagh, A.; Weir, L.; Conway, S.F.; McDonagh, J.; Mahon, M. Irish Organics, Innovation and Farm Collaboration: A Pathway to Farm Viability and Generational Renewal. Sustainability 2022, 14, 93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Loveluck, W.; Martin-Prével, A.; Rioufol, V.; Farrell, M.; Murtagh, A.; Graham, K.; Swade, K.; Blasco, C. D6.1—Typology of Actions Based on an Analysis of Current Innovative Actions and Discussion with Stakeholders; Community Research and Development Information Service: Luxembourg, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  56. Oostindie, H.; Van der Ploeg, J.D.; Van Broekhuizen, R. Buffercapaciteit: Bedrijfsstijlen in de Melkveehouderij, Volatiele Markten en Kengetallen; Wageningen UR: Wageningen, The Netherlands, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  57. Ciaian, P.; Kancs, D.; Espinosa, M. The Impact of the 2013 CAP Reform on the Decoupled Payments’ Capitalisation into Land Values. J. Agric. Econ. 2018, 69, 306–337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Ciaian, P.; Kancs, D.; Swinnen, J. The Impact of the 2013 Reform of the Common Agricultural Policy on Land Capitalization in the European Union. Appl. Econ. Perspect. Policy 2014, 36, 643–673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Latruffe, L.; Le Mouël, C. Capitalization of government support in agricultural land prices: What do we know? J. Econ. Surv. 2009, 23, 659–691. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Ciaian, P.; Baldoni, E.; Kancs, D.A.; Drabik, D. The Capitalization of Agricultural Subsidies into Land Prices. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2021, 13, 17–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Hennig, S.; Breustedt, G. The Incidence of Agricultural Subsidies on Rental Rates for Grassland. Jahrbücher Für Natl. Und Stat. 2018, 238, 125–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Bartolini, F.; Viaggi, D. The common agricultural policy and the determinants of changes in EU farm size. Land Use Policy 2013, 31, 126–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Scown, M.W.; Brady, M.V.; Nicholas, K.A. Billions in Misspent EU Agricultural Subsidies Could Support the Sustainable Development Goals. One Earth 2020, 3, 237–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Altes, W.K.K. Land Policy for Rural Development in the European Union and its Impact on Access to Land. Eur. Countrys. 2022, 14, 658–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. EP. CEU, Regulation (EU) 2021/2115 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 2 December 2021 establishing rules on support for strategic plans to be drawn up by Member States under the common agricultural policy (CAP Strategic Plans) and financed by the European Agricultural Guarantee Fund (EAGF) and by the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development (EAFRD) and repealing Regulations (EU) No 1305/2013 and (EU) No 1307/2013. Off. J. Eur. Union 2021, 64, 1–186. [Google Scholar]
  66. Korthals Altes, W.K.; de Wolff, H.W. D6.2 Report on Legal and Policy Arrangements in 28 Member States Report; Community Research and Development Information Service: Luxembourg, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  67. Erasmus + Fostering Access to Land for a New Generation of Agroecological Farmers. Available online: https://erasmus-plus.ec.europa.eu/projects/search/details/2014-1-FR01-KA204-008763 (accessed on 17 November 2022).
  68. Erasmus + Learning towards Access to Land. Available online: https://erasmus-plus.ec.europa.eu/projects/search/details/2016-1-CZ01-KA204-024020 (accessed on 17 November 2022).
  69. Erasmus + Setting up a Learning Platform for Farmers’ Access to Land. Available online: https://erasmus-plus.ec.europa.eu/projects/search/details/2018-1-FR01-KA204-047852 (accessed on 17 November 2022).
  70. Le Monnier, J. Terre de Liens: Histoire de convergences. Pour 2013, 220, 289–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Macombe, C. Is an alternative to private property durable in agriculture? In Food Economy; Franco Angeli: Milano, Italy, 2021; Volume 23, pp. 127–137. [Google Scholar]
  72. Rodrigo, J.; Rioufol, V. Supporting Access to Land for Farmers in Europe: Experiences and Potential of Local Authorities; Xarxa de Custòdia del Territori: Vic, Spain; Terre de Liens: Crest, France, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  73. Sovran, C.; Crola, J.-D.; Blin, N.; Desriers, M.; Martin, T.; Rioufol, V.; Wagner, H. Etat des Terre Agricoles en France; Terre de Liens: Crest, France, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  74. Lombard, P.; Baysse-Lainé, A. Terre de Liens, un levier foncier militant au service d’un projet politique pour l’agriculture. Économie Rural. 2019, 369, 83–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Perrin, C.; Baysse-Lainé, A. Governing the coexistence of agricultural models: French cities allocating farmlands to support agroecology and short food chains on urban fringes. Rev. Agric. Food Environ. Stud. 2020, 101, 261–286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Magnan, A.; Davidson, M.; Desmarais, A.A. ‘They call it progress, but we don’t see it as progress’: Farm consolidation and land concentration in Saskatchewan, Canada. Agric. Hum. Values 2022, 40, 277–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. United Nations. Resolution adopted by the General Assembly on 6 July 2017 (71/313). Work of the Statistical Commission Pertaining to the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development; Official Document System of the United Nations: New York, NY, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  78. Abu Abdulai, I.; Enu-Kwesi, F.; Boateng, J.A. Landowners’ willingness to supply agricultural land for conversion into urban uses in peri-urban Ghana. Local Environ. 2022, 27, 145–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Kirkegaard, J.K.; Rudolph, D.; Nyborg, S.; Cronin, T. The landrush of wind energy, its socio-material workings, and its political consequences: On the entanglement of land and wind assemblages in Denmark. Environ. Plan. C Politics Space 2022, 23996544221143657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Zhao, X.; Wu, L.; Qi, Y. The energy injustice of hydropower: Development, resettlement, and social exclusion at the Hongjiang and Wanmipo hydropower stations in China. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2020, 62, 101366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Barral, S.; Guillet, F. Preserving peri-urban land through biodiversity offsets: Between market transactions and planning regulations. Land Use Policy 2023, 127, 106545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Almeida, B.; Jacobs, C. Land expropriation—The hidden danger of climate change response in Mozambique. Land Use Policy 2022, 123, 106408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Supply and demand curves [29].
Figure 1. Supply and demand curves [29].
Sustainability 15 05097 g001
Figure 2. Number of farms by landholding in the EU27 (based on [41]).
Figure 2. Number of farms by landholding in the EU27 (based on [41]).
Sustainability 15 05097 g002
Figure 3. Number of EU27 NUTS2 regions by GINI index of land holdings in 2020 (this paper, based on [41]).
Figure 3. Number of EU27 NUTS2 regions by GINI index of land holdings in 2020 (this paper, based on [41]).
Sustainability 15 05097 g003
Table 1. Size of farms in hectares of utilised agricultural area depending on economic size in Euro (€).
Table 1. Size of farms in hectares of utilised agricultural area depending on economic size in Euro (€).
Economic Size (Standard Output)Utilised Agricultural Area (ha, Average)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
€2000–€8000 [A]8.41.135.34.64.46.12.65.0
€8000–€25,000 [B]20.12.48.29.113.521.28.413.8
€25,000–€50,000 [C]42.43.510.514.123.047.915.532.1
€50,000–€100,000 [D]74.95.516.622.136.992.520.260.6
€100,000–€500,000 [E]167.610.528.847.276.8160.737.4126.4
Over €500,000 [F]685.931.170.5121.7268.4301.586.3657.9
Source: FADN [39].
Table 2. Standard output per hectare by economic size in Euro (€).
Table 2. Standard output per hectare by economic size in Euro (€).
Economic Size (Standard Output)Average Standard Output per Hectare
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
€2000–€8000 [A]€951€11,969€2068€2120€1385€1263€3016€1235
€8000–€25,000 [B]€968€11,487€2471€2277€1230€950€2499€1104
€25,000–€50,000 [C]€1069€15,793€3832€2912€1741€856€3651€1217
€50,000–€100,000 [D]€1138€18,683€4477€3346€2173€782€4279€1258
€100,000–€500,000 [E]€1354€25,076€7421€4144€3068€1049€6455€1795
Over €500,000 [F]€1536€41,393€11,125€7938€3826€2635€11,485€2085
Source: FADN [39].
Table 3. Potential increase in standard output per hectare for farm growing in size (authors based on FADN [39]).
Table 3. Potential increase in standard output per hectare for farm growing in size (authors based on FADN [39]).
Growth in Economic Size (Standard Output)Average Increase in Standard Output per Hectare of New Land in Euro (€)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
▪ From [A] to [B]€981€11,058€3204€2438€1154€823€2263€1031
▪ From [B] to [C]€1159€25,451€8591€4078€2468€782€5001€1303
▪ From [C] to [D]€1228€23,697€5585€4106€2891€702€6382€1303
▪ From [D] to [E]€1528€32,014€11,442€4846€3896€1412€8998€2289
▪ From [E] to [F]€1595€49,731€13,690€10,343€4129€4445€15,339€2154
Standard Output A (€2000–€8000), B (€8000–€25,000), C (€25,000–€50,000), D (€50,000–€100,000), E (€100,000–€500,000) and F (Over €500,000). Increase in standard output per hectare of new land, from [x] to [y] = ((Standard output per hectare [y] * Utilised agricultural area [y]) − (Standard output per hectare [x] * Utilised agricultural area [x]))/(Utilised agricultural area [y] − Utilised agricultural area [x]).
Table 4. Potential increase in standard output per hectare for farm growing in size relative to current output per hectare (authors based on FADN [39]).
Table 4. Potential increase in standard output per hectare for farm growing in size relative to current output per hectare (authors based on FADN [39]).
Growth in Economic Size (Standard Output)Increase in Standard Output per Hectare of New Land Relative to Current Standard Output per Hectare (Based on Averages)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
▪ From [A] to [B]103%92%155%115%83%65%75%83%
▪ From [B] to [C]120%222%348%179%201%82%200%118%
▪ From [C] to [D]115%150%146%141%166%82%175%107%
▪ From [D] to [E]134%171%256%145%179%181%210%182%
▪ From [E] to [F]118%198%184%250%135%424%238%120%
Standard Output A (EUR 2000–EUR 8000), B (EUR 8000–EUR 25,000), C (EUR 25,000–EUR 50,000), D (EUR 50,000–EUR 100,000), E (EUR 100,000–EUR 500,000) and F (Over EUR 500,000). Increase in standard output per hectare land new land, from [x] to [y] = ((Standard output per hectare [y] * Utilised agricultural area [y]) − (Standard output per hectare [x] * Utilised agricultural area [x]))/(Utilised agricultural area [y] − Utilised agricultural area [x]).
Table 5. Farm size inequality in the European Union based on the GINI index of land holdings by farm.
Table 5. Farm size inequality in the European Union based on the GINI index of land holdings by farm.
GINI EU as a WholeAverage GINI NUTS 2 RegionNumber of Farms (Million)
20050.810.6414.2
20070.810.6313.6
20100.820.6212.0
20130.820.6210.7
20160.810.6210.2
20200.810.629.1
Note: 2020 is without the UK (112 thousand farms in 2016). Source author for 2020: Korthals Altes [29] for other years, both based on EUROSTAT [41] and earlier publications of ef_m_farmang data.
Table 6. Farm net income as a percentage of total output (source FADN [39]).
Table 6. Farm net income as a percentage of total output (source FADN [39]).
Economic Size (Standard Output)Farm Net Income as a Percentage of Total Output (Based on Averages)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
€2000–€8000 [A]41%40%39%57%46%39%23%35%
€8000–€25,000 [B]46%38%50%57%44%48%17%41%
€25,000–€50,000 [C]38%33%42%52%42%38%23%35%
€50,000–€100,000 [D]34%31%40%46%36%35%21%29%
€100,000–€500,000 [E]27%23%32%35%25%29%18%21%
Over €500,000 [F]20%13%29%25%15%27%15%8%
Table 7. Decoupled payments of CAP relative to farm net income (source FADN [39]).
Table 7. Decoupled payments of CAP relative to farm net income (source FADN [39]).
Economic Size (Standard Output)CAP Decoupled Payments Relative to Farm Net Income(Based on Averages)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
€2000–€8000 [A]48%2%14%23%16%30%12%26%
€8000–€25,000 [B]47%3%10%21%23%43%24%33%
€25,000–€50,000 [C]51%3%7%17%23%57%15%43%
€50,000–€100,000 [D]54%3%6%15%27%59%18%53%
€100,000–€500,000 [E]59%2%5%17%35%58%19%58%
Over €500,000 [F]68%3%3%11%48%40%14%126%
Table 8. Share of rented utilised agricultural area by economic size (source FADN [39]).
Table 8. Share of rented utilised agricultural area by economic size (source FADN [39]).
Economic Size (Standard Output)Rented Utilised Agricultural Area (%) of Total Utilised Agricultural Area (Based on Averages)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
€2000–€8000 [A]22%22%6%10%18%27%12%14%
€8000–€25,000 [B]31%18%11%16%27%30%17%26%
€25,000–€50,000 [C]43%24%21%19%32%45%24%38%
€50,000–€100,000 [D]55%32%31%25%47%54%32%51%
€100,000–€500,000 [E]69%43%59%35%64%62%52%70%
Over €500,000 [F]75%62%68%49%67%72%58%82%
Table 9. Rent paid per ha rented utilised agricultural area (source FADN [39]).
Table 9. Rent paid per ha rented utilised agricultural area (source FADN [39]).
Economic Size (Standard Output)Rent Paid in Euro (€) per ha Rented Utilised Agricultural Area (based on Averages)
Field CropsHorticultureWineOther Permanent CropsMilkOther Grazing LivestockGranivoresMixed
€2000–€8000 [A]€113.51€168.00€158.82€173.91€53.75€85.80€80.65€60.56
€8000–€25,000 [B]€134.82€388.64€179.55€177.62€48.38€74.61€61.43€61.30
€25,000–€50,000 [C]€151.67€555.95€377.31€214.13€85.41€85.18€122.55€100.65
€50,000–€100,000 [D]€153.80€651.70€510.49€259.39€129.11€80.18€164.82€123.60
€100,000–€500,000 [E]€180.07€822.49€853.46€325.23€203.95€102.77€283.13€161.61
Over €500,000 [F]€211.28€1190.52€1286.18€430.44€225.13€140.94€418.68€140.60
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Korthals Altes, W.K. Access to Land: Markets, Policies and Initiatives. Sustainability 2023, 15, 5097. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065097

AMA Style

Korthals Altes WK. Access to Land: Markets, Policies and Initiatives. Sustainability. 2023; 15(6):5097. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065097

Chicago/Turabian Style

Korthals Altes, Willem K. 2023. "Access to Land: Markets, Policies and Initiatives" Sustainability 15, no. 6: 5097. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065097

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop