Next Article in Journal
Fostering Work Meaningfulness for Sustainable Human Resources: A Study of Generation Z
Previous Article in Journal
“Local Production”: What Do Consumers Think?
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Effect of Product Distribution Structures and Government Subsidy Measures on Product Quality and Consumption under Competition

1
Department of Basic & Applied Science, National Institute of Technology, Jote 791113, India
2
Department of Materials and Production, Aalborg University, 9220 Aalborg, Denmark
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
Sustainability 2022, 14(6), 3624; https://doi.org/10.3390/su14063624
Submission received: 19 February 2022 / Revised: 14 March 2022 / Accepted: 15 March 2022 / Published: 19 March 2022

Abstract

:
To improve social welfare and the sustainable development index, many governments introduce subsidies to manufacturers. Motivated by a subsidy program, we present a parsimonious analysis to determine the impact of subsidies when two competing manufacturers use different distribution structures under competition to sell their products in a three-echelon distribution setting. The objective is to understand better how distribution structures and social welfare measures affect the government’s decision to subsidize. We consider four different distribution structures where the government can provide subsidies to both the manufacturers or one of them. From the perspective of the social welfare optimization goal, we consider two well-established measures to analyze whether those measures impacted the overall dynamics. The two key areas: (i) the effect of distribution structures and (ii) decisions under different social welfare measures are not discussed comprehensively yet. We found that distribution structure significantly impacted product qualities, prices, and amount of government expenditure. The government may need to pay more subsidies in a distribution structure with a two-manufacturers-two-distributors-two-retailers distribution setting, where customers can receive a higher-quality product and pay a higher price. Our analysis reveals that the government’s social welfare goal can change the dynamics. Among four distribution structures, none can simultaneously ensure higher quality, product consumption, supply chain profits, and lower prices. The results provide insights for developing practical government subsidy program goals under competition.

1. Introduction

Intermediaries in the supply chain (e.g., dealers, wholesalers, distributors) are indispensable in many pragmatic product distribution structures [1]. In recent times, the wholesale distribution market has shown exponential growth; for example, in the U.S., it reached a record high of USD 6.01 trillion. in 2018 [2]. or in India, USD 1.1 trillion in 2021 [3]. Many academic studies [4,5] also support the notion that intermediaries are the backbone in successful product distribution. However, in the green supply chain management literature, most studies focus on exploring relationships between two-echelon supply chain settings and ignore that manufacturers might deal with intermediaries under competition and operate in different markets with different product distribution structures. For example, most manufacturers use a three-tier selling and distribution structure to ensure a local presence in a country such as India. They often rely on subsidiaries or appoint an agent, representative, or distributor. It is not unlikely that many FMCG companies operating on an all-India basis could have between 40 and 80 distributors to distribute their products to nearly 9 million retail outlets [3]. In the context of emerging markets, it is important to analyze the dependency and reciprocal actions associated with various types of distribution structures to identify under which the competing manufacturers can achieve competitive advantages.
As stated by Allaoui et al. (2019) [6], “A supply chain is a complex system with many functions, activities, and organizations”, while an empirical study by [7] supported the fact that midtier members can play a pivotal role in improving the product distribution process. Gadde (2004) [8] argued that intermediaries could bring significant benefits to eliminate the disruption in the global retail sector and contribute as a secondary resource layer. Intermediaries might have better insight into consumers’ choices and assist manufacturers in spreading their products in different areas [9]. Intermediaries can significantly influence the whole supply chain in achieving environmental sustainability goals [10].
However, studies on the influence of product distribution structure under competition beyond first-tier dyadic relationships are extremely limited. Specifically, the research has shed relatively little light on the influence of supply chain structure under a government subsidy. To the best of the authors’ knowledge, to date, a comparative analysis of different distribution structures has not been explored at a microlevel. For example, two manufacturers can use two different distributors or the same distributors under competition. To pinpoint the effect of distribution structures on the optimal decisions, this study analyzes the answer to the research question: does the distribution structure impact the sustainability goal of competing manufacturers?
During the past few decades, environmental sustainability has been highlighted as one of the key priorities for consumers. In this regard, government subsidy schemes have become an emerging topic of interest [11,12,13,14]. In the literature, researchers have explored different types of subsidy policies in a two-echelon supply chain structure; for example, government organizations can provide subsidies directly to the manufacturers [15,16], consumers [17,18] or the downstream retailer [19]. It is also reported that the government can provide subsidies both to the manufacturer and consumers [20] or manufacturer and retailer [21]. We refer to the systematic literature review by Agi et al. (2021) [22] on the green supply chain management practices for the detailed discussion. However, most studies focused on the two-level supply chain structures without competition. Note that our objective is not to analyze different subsidy policies for different members; we assume only manufacturers receive the subsidy and compare results under different distribution structures. Therefore, we ask: how does government subsidy policy (providing a single manufacturer or both manufacturers) affect green product manufacturing under competition?
Government subsidy is apparent across industries to accomplish higher supply chain performance and social welfare, e.g., the manufacturing industry [23], the automobile industry [24], the agriculture industry [25] and so on. As noted by Zhang and Wang (2017) [26], investment in innovative technology can be improved under the guidance of government policies. For example, the Nordic countries introduced incentives to manufacturers to improve emission reduction technology [27]. Accordingly, Hennes & Mauritz AB clothing company envisions it will be using 100% renewable energy by 2040 in their production model. However, if the government provides a subsidy, then there are also some conflicting issues that must be acknowledged in research. For example, a group of researchers ignored the influence of government social welfare optimization goal [17,19] and another group explored the optimal decision by considering that measure [16,21,28,29]. Moreover, the measure of social welfare from the government’s perspective is also not unique. We summarize some of the social welfare measures explored by the researchers in Table 1.
In practice, supply chain decisions under government subsidy are influenced by several key factors, e.g., quality-improvement measures, increased consumption, distribution structures. Commonly, government organizations measure/monitor the effectiveness of subsidy programs based their on social welfare optimization goals. The government can set social welfare goals by considering the influence of profits for supply chain members, consumer surplus, environmental improvement, how much subsidy they would grant. Further, modeling manufacturers’ decisions under subsidy programs without considering optimization goals of the government organizations may lead to a failure to illustrate the effect of the subsidy on profit-maximizing and pricing decisions of the overall system. However, the comparative view of the optimal decision in the presence of the social welfare optimization goal and pricing-quality decision under competition is sparse.
Subsidy schemes are sometimes necessary because, with government support, the domestic manufacturers can remain competitive with foreign manufacturers [35]. Furthermore, subsidies are relevant to those “infant” industries that make a continuous effort towards innovation, but their environmental benefits are not still properly priced by the market, or consumers are not aware of the long-term benefits of consumption of those products. However, additional expenditure might not always be worthwhile for those governments facing tight budget constraints. Moreover, such industrial policies have also been criticized in many countries, and subsidies to domestic producers sometimes face disciplinary action under World Trade Organization agreements [36].
In this study, we assume the products’ market demand is influenced by price and quality, which has been shown a growing interest in characteristics of the two-echelon supply chain [17,37,38,39]. Global manufacturers invest significantly in integrating new technologies to reduce energy consumption or natural resources usage, modify production processes, etc., and improve their products’ sustainable attributes. Similar to the present study, under competition, researchers explore how two synonymous green and non-green products influence the pricing decision and profit [40,41], but mostly in a two-echelon supply chain setting and ignoring the influence of subsidy. We explore the decision of the government to provide subsidies to single or both manufacturers under a three-echelon supply chain setting in which two manufacturers are selling their products under different distribution structures. Outcomes of optimal decisions under two social welfare optimization goals are compared to identify which distribution structures lead to higher product quality, product consumption, and lower price. Therefore, the present study contributes to the green supply chain management research by analyzing the effects of distribution structures and government subsidy under competition in achieving sustainability goals.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents all necessary assumptions and introduces four supply chain structures considered in this study. Properties of all optimal decisions are discussed in Section 4. By comparing all the decisions, we highlight the possible distribution structure choice that ensures higher benefits for supply chain members, consumers, and government organizations. Finally, we present key insights and future research directions in Section 5.

2. Model Settings

We consider four different distribution structures where two competing manufacturers sell substitutable products and compete in the end-customer market under price- and quality-level-sensitive demand. The distribution structures consist of: (1) two-manufacturers-single-distributor-single-retailer ( D 1 R 1 ); (2) two-manufacturers-single-distributor-two-retail-ers ( D 1 R 2 ); (3) two-manufacturers-two-distributors-single-retailer ( D 2 R 1 ); and (4) two-manufact-urers-two-distributors-two-retailers ( D 2 R 2 ), respectively. The overview of distribution structures is presented in Figure 1.
To characterize the demand ( q i s ) for product i, we adopt the following functional forms:
q i s ( p i s , θ i s ) = a p i s + β p j s + γ θ i s δ θ j s , i = 1 , 2 , , j = 3 i
where p i s and θ i s represents retail price and product quality for i -th product, respectively. Therefore, q i s is positively correlated with own product quality( θ i s ) and retail price of other product ( p j s ); and negatively correlated with other product quality ( θ j s ) and own retail price ( p i s ). The linear demand function is common in the literature [38,42]. Moreover, there are some studies where only quality impact is considered [43] or only retail price is considered [44].
Quadratic investment cost functions η i θ i s 2 are considered to study the impact of product quality improvement, i.e., η i represent the efficiencies of each manufacturer [45,46]. For simplicity and to keep the focus on analyzing the effect of distribution structures and government subsidy, it is assumed that both manufacturers are equally efficient, i.e., η 1 = η 2 = η ,47,48]. For parsimony, we further assume that operational costs for each supply chain are constant and normalized to zero [15].
We assume the government provides the subsidy directly to the manufacturers to improve product quality [15,49,50] and the optimal subsidy rate is determined through optimizing social welfare ( S W ) functions. Two different social welfare measures are considered in this study are as follows:
S W 1 = < Total supply chain profits > + < consumer surplus > < total subsidy > S W 2 = < Total supply chain profits > < subsidy >
Consequently, we encounter a four-stage game problem. At the first stage, retail prices are determined, prices for distributors or distributors are decided at the second stage, then two manufacturers set their respective product qualities and wholesale prices. Finally, the government chooses to whether both manufacturers or single manufacturers receive a subsidy and the proportion by optimizing the SW functions.
Note that if the manufacturers are inefficient in quality improvement investment, it is not feasible to produce products. On the other hand, if η is too small, it is also not realistic to make products without any investment. Therefore, we derive the following condition η > max ( 7 4 β ) γ ( γ ] δ ) 32 ( 2 β ) ( 1 β ) , ( ( 2 β 2 ) ( 16 14 β 6 β 2 + 5 β 3 ) ( γ δ ) 2 4 ( 2 β ) 2 ( 1 β ) ( 4 β 2 β 2 ) 2 ) , which is necessary so that an optimal solution exists in all four supply chain structures. We list notations used to distinguish optimal decisions under different scenarios in Table A1.

3. Model and Decision Making

First, we start with the benchmark single-manufacturer-single-distributor-single-retailer supply chain setting (Scenario-BM), i.e., we present results without competition. The demand function converts into q 1 ( p 1 , θ 1 ) = a p 1 + γ θ 1 , as cross-price ( β = 0 ) or cross-quality ( δ = 0 ) are irrelevant. The profit functions for the manufacturer, distributor, and retailer are obtained as follows:
π m B M = w m 1 q 1 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 1 2 ; π d B M = ( w d 1 w m 1 ) q 1 π r B M = ( p 1 w d 1 ) q 1
One can verify that optimal decision for the supply chain are as follows: w 1 m B M = 8 a ( 1 ρ s ) η 16 ( 1 ρ s ) η γ 2 ; θ B M = a γ 16 ( 1 ρ s ) η γ 2 ; p 1 B M = 14 a ( 1 ρ s ) η 16 ( 1 ρ s ) η γ 2 ; w 1 d B M = 12 a ( 1 ρ s ) η 16 ( 1 ρ s ) η γ 2 ; ρ B M 1 = 3 7 ; ρ B M 2 = 7 15 . Note that the optimal subsidy rates are independent of the parameters, even from the investment efficiency for the manufacturer. Therefore, whether the consumer is willing to buy the product ( γ ) or price sensitivity ( β ) does not impact the government decision. Later, we use these results to identify critical differences in subsidy–quality relations under monopoly and competition.

3.1. Optimal Decisions in Supply Chain Structure D 1 R 1

In this distribution structure, both manufacturers distribute their products with a single distributor; then, the retailer procures both products from the distributor to sell those to the final customers. Profit functions for the supply chain members in this distribution structure are obtained as follows:
π m 1 D 1 R 1 B v = w m 1 q 1 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 1 2 ; π m 2 D 1 R 1 B v = w m 2 q 2 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 2 2 π d D 1 R 1 B v = i = 1 2 ( w d i w m i ) q i π r D 1 R 1 B v = i = 1 2 ( p i w d i ) q i
We refer to Appendix A for the detailed derivation of the optimal decisions under four different scenarios for the supply chain structure D 1 R 1 . Note that when both manufacturers receive a subsidy, the optimal decision is symmetrical. We present the optimal decision under the supply chain structure D 1 R 1 in Propositions 1 and 2, respectively:
Proposition 1.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 1 R 1 B v is as follows:
w m i D 1 R 1 B v ( ρ s ) = 8 a ( 1 ρ s ) η 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) , θ i D 1 R 1 B v ( ρ s ) = a γ η 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) ,
w d i D 1 R 1 B v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 3 2 β ) η ( 1 β ) ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) ) , p i D 1 R 1 B v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 7 4 β ) η ( 1 β ) ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) ) ,
where ρ D 1 R 1 B 1 = 1 2 ( 2 β ) ( 1 β ) γ ( 8 5 β ) ( γ δ ) ) , ρ D 1 R 1 B 2 = 1 2 ( 2 β ) ( 1 β ) γ ( 7 4 β ) ( γ δ )
Proposition 2.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 1 R 1 S v is as follows:
w m 1 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 8 η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 , w m 2 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 8 a ( 1 ρ s ) η ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 ,
θ 1 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = a γ ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 , θ 2 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = a γ ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 ,
w d 1 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) ( 3 2 β ) η + ( 3 2 β 2 + ( 1 ρ s ) β ) γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 ,
w d 2 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) ( 3 2 β ) η + ( ( 3 2 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) + β ) γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 ,
p 1 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) ( 7 4 β ) η + ( 7 4 β 2 + 3 ( 1 ρ s ) β ) γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 ,
p 2 D 1 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) ( 7 4 β ) η + ( 7 4 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) + 3 β ) γ ( γ + δ ) ) ψ 0 ,
where ρ D 1 R 1 S 1 = 2 ( 1 + β ) ( α 2 γ + ( 8 5 β ) δ ) ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 2 ϕ 3 ,
ρ D 1 R 1 S 2 = ( 1 + β ) ( ( 3 + 2 ( 1 β ) β ) γ + ( 7 4 β ) δ ) ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 2 ϕ 4
We present all the additional notations used in this study in Appendix D. Unlike the singe-manufacturer-single-distributor-single-retailer distribution structure, one can observe that the subsidy rates are dependent on system parameters. Cross-price elasticity or efficiencies for the manufacturers are key factors affecting the consumers’ purchase decisions and government subsidy. Therefore, the expression of subsidy rate is more pragmatic under competition. Graphical representation of optimal quality levels, total supply chain profits, and the total amount of subsidy are presented in Figure 2.
Noticeably, as cross-price sensitivity increases, the total amount of subsidy also increases, i.e., in an intensive competition market, the government needs to pay more contributions. It is also observed that the product quality level is also maximum without competition. The government needs to invest less under such a distribution structure. Therefore, the government needs to decide whether to encourage competition and monitor the distribution structure before providing a subsidy. Next, suppose there are two competing manufacturers. In that case, a subsidy policy to a single manufacturer can lead to significantly lower quality products (the manufacturer who does receive subsidy) but less expenditure. Therefore, it might harm the sustainability goal. Thus, under competition, it might be preferable to subsidize both manufacturers. This is also noticeable from this study.

3.2. Optimal Decisions in Supply Chain Structures D 1 R 2 or D 2 R 1

In this distribution structure, both manufacturers distribute their products with a single distributor, and finally, the distributor sells two products through two different retailers. As mentioned earlier, cross-selling is not allowed. Therefore, profit functions for the supply chain members in this distribution structure are obtained as follows:
π m 1 D 1 R 2 B v = w m 1 q 1 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 1 2 π m 2 D 1 R 2 B v = w m 2 q 2 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 2 2 π d D 1 R 2 B v = i = 1 2 ( w d i w m i ) q i π r 1 D 1 R 2 B v = ( p 1 w d 1 ) q 1 π r 2 D 1 R 2 = ( p 2 w d 2 ) q 2
Similarly to distribution structure D 2 R 1 , both manufacturers distributes their products with their exclusive distributors, and finally, a retailer procures both products from those distributors to sell to the final customers. Therefore, profit functions for the supply chain members in this distribution structure are obtained as follows:
π m 1 D 2 R 1 B v = w m 1 q 1 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 1 2 π m 2 D 2 R 1 B v = w m 2 q 2 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 2 2 π d 1 D 2 R 1 B v = ( w d 1 w m 1 ) q 1 π d 2 D 2 R 1 B v = ( w d 2 w m 2 ) q 2 π r D 2 R 1 B v = i = 1 2 ( p i w d i ) q i
We refer to Appendix B for the detailed derivation process of the optimal decisions for the supply chain structures D 1 R 2 and D 2 R 1 , respectively. Note that when both manufacturers receive the subsidy, then optimal decisions remain the same in both distribution structures. We present optimal decisions under the supply chain structures D 1 R 2 / D 2 R 1 when both manufacturers receive subsidies in Proposition 3.
Proposition 3.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 1 R 2 B v is as follows:
w m i D 1 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 , θ m i D 1 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 γ β δ ) 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 ,
w d i D 1 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) ( 6 2 β 3 β 2 ) η ( 1 β ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 ) , p i D 1 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) η ( 1 β ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 ) ,
where ρ D 1 R 2 B 1 = ( 16 β 2 ( 34 β ( 14 + 5 ( 2 β ) β ) ) ) γ + ( 32 β ( 36 + β ( 14 β ( 21 + β 3 β 2 ) ) ) ) δ ( 2 β 2 ) ( 16 β ( 14 + β ( 6 5 β ) ) ) ( γ δ ) ;
or ρ D 1 R 2 B 2 = ( 12 + β ( 4 30 β + 10 β 2 + 9 β 3 4 β 4 ) ) γ ( 28 32 β 10 β 2 + 17 β 3 2 β 5 ) δ ( 2 β 2 ) ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) ( γ δ ) .
Note that different optimal decisions are obtained when one of the manufacturers receives a subsidy for distribution structures D 1 R 2 and D 2 R 1 , and we present optimal decision in Propositions 4 and 5, respectively:
Proposition 4.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 1 R 2 S v is as follows:
w m 1 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1 , θ 1 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 γ β δ ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 ) η α 0 ) ψ 1 ,
w m 2 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ψ 1 , θ 2 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 γ β δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1 ,
w d 1 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 1 + β ) α 2 ( 6 2 β 3 β 2 ) η ( 12 14 β 2 + 3 β 4 + β ( 2 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) ) α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
w d 2 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 1 + β ) α 2 ( 6 2 β 3 β 2 ) η ( ( 12 14 β 2 + 3 β 4 ) ( 1 ρ s ) + β ( 2 β 2 ) ) α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
p 1 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) ( 1 + β ) α 2 ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) η ( ( 14 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) + β ( 2 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) ) α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
p 2 D 1 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) ( 1 + β ) α 2 ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) η ( ( 14 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) ( 1 ρ s ) + β ( 2 β 2 ) ) α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
where ρ D 1 R 2 S 1 = 2 ( 1 + β ) [ ( ( 16 34 β 2 + 14 β 3 + 10 β 4 5 β 5 ) γ ( 32 36 β 14 β 2 + 21 β 3 + β 4 3 β 5 ) δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) 2 ] ϕ 7 ,
ρ D 1 R 2 S 2 = ( 1 β ) [ ( ( 12 + 4 β 30 β 2 + 10 β 3 + 9 β 4 4 β 5 ) γ ( 28 32 β 10 β 2 + 17 β 3 2 β 5 ) δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) 2 ] ϕ 8
Proposition 5.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 2 R 1 S v is as follows:
w m 1 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1 , θ 1 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 γ β δ ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1 ,
w m 2 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ψ 1 , θ 2 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 γ β δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1 ,
w d 1 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 8 a ( 3 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 , w d 2 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 8 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 3 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
p 1 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 4 ( 1 x ) ( 2 + β ) ( 1 + β ) α 2 ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) η ( ( 14 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) + β ( 2 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) ) α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
p 2 D 2 R 1 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) ( 1 + β ) α 2 ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) η ( ( 14 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) ( 1 ρ s ) + β ( 2 β 2 ) ) α 0 ) ( 1 β 2 ) ψ 1 ,
where ρ D 2 R 1 S 1 = 2 ( 1 + β ) [ ( ( 16 34 β 2 + 14 β 3 + 10 β 4 5 β 5 ) γ ( 32 36 β 14 β 2 + 21 β 3 + β 4 3 β 5 ) δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) 2 ] ϕ 7 ,
ρ D 2 R 1 S 2 = ( 1 β ) [ ( ( 12 + 4 β 30 β 2 + 10 β 3 + 9 β 4 4 β 5 ) γ ( 28 32 β 10 β 2 + 17 β 3 2 β 5 ) δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) 2 ] ϕ 8 .
Due to the variation of members in the lower tier, retail pricing and wholesale prices change when one of the manufacturers receives a subsidy; however, the government subsidy rate is not affected. Graphical representation of optimal quality levels, total supply chain profits, and the total amount of subsidy are in supply chain structures D 2 R 1 , and D 1 R 2 are presented in Figure 3.
Unlike distribution structure, D 1 R 1 , product quality and total supply chain profit are maximum in Scenario- D 1 R 2 S 2 , but government expenditure reduces. Therefore, distribution structures, as well as SW measures, clearly made an impact on the overall decision. Noticeably, the product quality level is maximum without competition or subsidy to a single manufacturer; therefore, the government does not necessarily encourage competition.

3.3. Optimal Decisions in Supply Chain Structure D 2 R 2

Both manufacturers distribute their products with their respective exclusive distributors and retailers in this distribution structure. Therefore, we consider two purely competing supply chains, unlike the three previously discussed structures. Profit functions for the supply chain members in this structure are obtained as follows:
π m 1 D 2 R 2 B v = w m 1 q 1 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 1 2 ; π m 2 D 2 R 2 B v = w m 2 q 2 η ( 1 ρ s ) θ 2 2 π d 1 D 2 R 2 B v = ( w d 2 w m 1 ) q 1 π d 2 D 2 R 2 B v = ( w d 1 w m 2 ) q 2 π r 1 D 2 R 2 B v = ( p 1 w d 1 ) q 1 π r 2 D 2 R 2 B v = ( p 2 w d 2 ) q 2
We refer to Appendix C for the detail derivation of the optimal decisions for the supply chain structures D 2 R 2 . We present the optimal decision under the supply chain structure D 2 R 2 in Propositions 6 and 7, respectively:
Proposition 6.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 2 R 2 B v is as follows:
w m i D 2 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 64 84 β 2 + 33 β 4 4 β 6 ) η ψ 3 , θ i D 2 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ψ 3 ,
w d i D 2 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 3 β 2 ) ( 4 3 β 2 ) η ψ 3 , p i D 2 R 2 B v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) η ψ 3 ,
where ρ D 2 R 2 B 1 = 1 ( 2 β ) α 3 α 4 α 5 4 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) ( γ δ ) ,
ρ D 2 R 2 B 2 = 1 ( 2 β ) α 3 α 4 α 5 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) ( γ δ ) .
Proposition 7.
Optimal decision in Scenarios- D 2 R 2 S v is as follows:
w m 1 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η ( 2 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ,
θ 1 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ( 2 ( 2 + β ) ( 1 ρ s ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ,
w m 2 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 4 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) α 2 α 3 η ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ,
θ 2 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ,
w d 1 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 4 β 2 ) ( 3 β 2 ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 2 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) η ψ 4 ,
w d 2 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 3 β 2 ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) η ψ 4 ,
p 1 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) η ( 2 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ,
p 2 D 2 R 2 S v ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) η ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ,
w h e r e   ρ D 2 R 2 S 1 = ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) 2 ψ 5 [ ( 1024 + 896 β 3360 β 2 1568 β 3 + 3820 β 4 + 966 β 5 1940 β 6 253 β 7 + 454 β 8 + 24 β 9 40 β 10 ) γ 2 ( 2 + β ) ( 512 448 β 904 β 2 + 786 β 3 + 562 β 4 485 β 5 148 β 6 + 127 β 7 + 14 β 8 12 β 9 ) δ ] ,
ρ D 2 R 2 S 2 = ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) 2 ψ 6 [ ( 768 + 896 β 2656 β 2 1568 β 3 + 3080 β 4 + 966 β 5 1570 β 6 253 β 7 + 366 β 8 + 24 β 9 32 β 10 ) γ 2 ( 896 384 β 1904 β 2 + 668 β 3 + 1540 β 4 408 β 5 596 β 6 + 106 β 7 + 111 β 8 10 β 9 8 β 10 ) δ ]
Graphical representation of optimal quality levels, the total supply chain profits and total amount of subsidy are presented in Figure 4.
A similar line of observation is obtained as seen in Figure 2 and Figure 3. Summarizing the optimal decision in all four distribution structures, we made the following list of observations.
  • The government needs to monitor the distribution structure for the manufacturers on which they rely. Otherwise, it can increase the expenditure without achieving the sustainability goal;
  • Under competition, it might be possible to provide a subsidy to one of the manufacturers instead of both. Because this scenario can lead to the highest product quality level and supply chain profits, the government also needs to pay less;
  • The SW measure is also critical, and it becomes more apparent when the subsidy is provided to single manufacturers.
The national manufacturer needs to compete with many international manufacturers in many countries. In this scenario, a subsidy to the national manufacturer can contribute to the government’s goal of achieving a higher sustainability development index.

4. Discussion

In the previous section, we explored optimal decisions under four distribution structures in the presence of government intervention. First, we analyze the characteristics of product qualities in the absence of a government subsidy. In the absence of a subsidy, optimal decisions are symmetrical, and the product qualities in distribution structure D 1 R 2 and D 2 R 1 remain the same. Therefore, we present graphical representation of the maximum product qualities, maximum and minimum prices among distribution structures D 2 R 2 , D 1 R 2 , and D 1 R 1 in Figure 5.
From Figure 5, one can see that the product quality can be maximized in all three distribution structures. However, the regions representing retail prices are different. It might be intuitive that maximum retail price can ensure maximum retail prices, but results do not reflect that fact. Different distribution structures can lead to different price–quality pairs. For example, in distribution structure D 2 R 2 , price, as well as product qualities, remain higher as well as lower. Hence, customers need to pay more for higher quality products if quality sensitivity is too high. However, the distribution structure D 2 R 1 can also lead to a lower price with higher quality. Therefore, we can conclude that the customers will favor the distribution structures D 2 R 1 / D 1 R 2 where they can receive lower-priced products. Overall, the distribution structures impact achieving sustainability goals in the absence of government subsidies.
Now we present the optimal product quality levels in the presence of government subsidies. Note that when the government provides a subsidy to both manufacturers, the optimal product quality remains the same, but it differs when a subsidy is offered to one manufacturer only.
Therefore, it is clear that a government subsidy and SW measures can change the whole dynamics. If both the manufacturers receive subsidies, the maximum product quality is achieved in the distribution structures D 2 R 2 , which is not the case when the subsidy is not provided. Next, the social welfare measure also made an impact. By comparing Figure 6a–f, we can see that under S W 2 , the product quality be might higher in Scenario D 2 R 2 or D 1 R 1 . Next, we explore the nature of retail prices.
It is clear that the government subsidy and its social welfare optimization objective significantly influence the customers. Product quality might be higher in D 2 R 2 . If both manufacturers try to follow the other distribution structures, then the customers never receive higher quality products, but they still need to pay more. Previously, we saw that government need to invest more under the S W 2 measures (Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4). Additionally, we found from Figure 7 that retailers can charge more for the product when the manufacturer does not receive the subsidy. Therefore, there is a need to unify social welfare measures in the supply chain literature. Next, we explore the investment ratio for each manufacturer I R = Product quality Total subsidy form the government efficiencies in different distribution structures.
Figure 8 also demonstrates the variation in effectiveness in government expenditure in various distribution structures. Note that we also explore the characteristics of supply chain profits, subsidy, and quantity (Figure A1, Figure A2 and Figure A3), and similar variations are observed.

Managerial Implications

Previously, we mainly focus on exploring whether the government encourages monopoly or competition [51]. We found that subsidy under both scenarios can lead to higher product quality. In this section, we focus mainly on exploring the variation of outcomes in different distribution structures and social welfare measures. In this direction, we also found that the outcomes are not unique. Although we conduct our analysis with respect to quality sensitivity ( γ ) and cross-quality sensitivity ( δ ), one can also observe similar variations for other parameters.
Due to increased environmental awareness among the stakeholders, establishing sustainable products is one of the main goals of contemporary organizations. In a recent review article, ref. [52] refer to the “green” concept as doing actions while integrating environmental or ecological concern and identify key barriers such as financial and cost associated with ecodesign, fear of failure, market competition and uncertainty, poor commitment from partners, and others. In this direction, refs. [53,54] also conducted a literature review to highlight current practices in several countries, product types, modeling approaches, and drew a list of factors that are the key barriers. Of those review articles, none highlight how (i) product distribution structures and (ii) social welfare measures can affect sustainability goals.
Three-level distribution under competition is not completely rare in practice [55]. This study is perhaps the first to clearly show that the distribution structures can make an enormous impact on the effectiveness of the government subsidy program and product quality. Results suggest that as a strategic decision, manufacturers use different distribution structures, or sometimes they are bound to use, which can significantly impact product quality. The government should encourage competition to ensure consumers can receive the product at the highest quality, depending on how manufacturers design their distribution channels. Regarding what is listed in the literature review, a second issue that we explore was also overlooked: how can social welfare function be set in the context of green supply chain practice? We have found that there is a need for standardization; some key insights highlighted so far, both in forward and closed-loop supply chains, might change if different social welfare measures were considered while determining the subsidy rate.

5. Conclusions and Future Research Direction

We have studied unified models to examine a situation where the government uses a subsidy program by capturing the strategic interactions under competition in a three-echelon supply chain setting. We first analyzed the base case when the subsidy program is intended to improve social welfare for a supply chain consisting of a single-manufacturer-single-distributor-single-retailer. We then examine four possible distribution structures of the base model: (1) when the subsidy program involves two competing manufacturers; and (2) when the subsidy program is intended for one of the manufacturers. Throughout the study, we have considered two social welfare optimization goals.
This study mainly focuses on exploring the effect of two relatively unexplored issues in the green supply chain literature: (i) the impact of distribution structures in a three-echelon supply chain under competition and (ii) social welfare measures while the government decides subsidy. Our study reveals that when the government’s goal is to optimize social welfare, the performance differs significantly. Out of four distribution structures, it is difficult to identify one particular structure that ensures optimal product quality, lower retail prices, and higher product consumption under competition. The efficiency of subsidy in improving product quality and total supply chain profit might not be concurrent in a particular structure. The relative emphasis that the government places on defining social welfare also comes into play. No definite one ensures lower subsidies and the highest product quality among the four distribution structures. Whether government should invite multiple competing manufacturers to participate in the subsidy to ensure higher product quality levels is also responsible for the variation. Therefore, the government must enhance the supervision of manufacturers’ distribution structures before introducing a subsidy program. In the literature, several empirical research has been conducted under a multicriteria decision-making framework by incorporating several factors affecting sustainability [53]; however, the two factors highlighted in this study are not explored yet. Our research can provide a guideline for the government to design an effective subsidy program that depends on its relative emphasis placed on product distribution structures and social welfare optimization goals.
Our study reveals that when the government’s goal is to optimize social welfare, it is difficult to achieve optimal product quality that ensures lower prices and higher product consumption under competition. The efficiency of subsidy expenditure and total supply chain profit optimization goal might not be concurrent. The relative emphasis that the government places on defining social welfare comes into play. Among the four distribution structures, there is no definite one in which the government cares a lot about social welfare that ensures lower subsidies and the highest product quality. Therefore, the government should enhance the manufacturers’ distribution structures before introducing a subsidy program. The government should invite multiple competing manufacturers to participate in the subsidy to ensure higher product quality levels, but not always. However, several empirical research has been conducted under a multicriteria decision-making framework [53], two factors highlighted in this study are not explored yet. Our research has provided a guideline for the government to design an effective subsidy program that depends on its relative emphasis placed on product distribution structures and social welfare optimization goals.
This study assumes that both manufacturers offer green products; therefore, one can compare four different outcomes by taking one manufacturer offers green products and the other offers nongreen products. We consider the influence of two social warfare measures. However, it will also be a crucial work to compare the result for different social welfare measures to construct a generalized measure (Table 1). We highlight the variation of social welfare measures on the forward supply chain. Therefore, it will also be interesting to study various social welfare measures on the closed-loop or dual-channel supply chain [56].

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, S.M. (Sani Majumder) and S.S.; methodology, S.S.; software, S.M. (Sani Majumder); validation, I.N. and S.M. (Susanta Maity); formal analysis, S.S.; investigation, S.M. (Sani Majumder); resources, I.N.; writing—original draft preparation, S.S. and S.M. (Sani Majumder); writing—review and editing, I.N. and S.M. (Susanta Maity); visualization, S.M. (Sani Majumder) and S.M. (Susanta Maity); supervision, S.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Derivation of Optimal Decision for Supply Chain Structure D1R1

First, we derive optimal decision in Scenarios D 1 R 1 . Solving first-order conditions for the retailer’s profit function, π r p 1 = 0 and π r p 2 = 0 simultaneously, one can obtain the quantities as follows:
p i = a ( 1 + β ) + ( 1 β 2 ) w d i + ( γ β δ ) θ i + ( β γ δ ) θ j 2 ( 1 β 2 ) , i = 1 , 2 , , j = 3 i
Because 2 π r p 1 2 · 2 π r p 2 2 2 π r p 1 p 2 2 = 4 ( 1 β 2 ) > 0 and 2 π r p 1 2 = 2 π r p 2 2 = 2 < 0 ; π r is jointly concave in p i s’. Substituting retailer’s response in Equation (4), profit function for the distributor is obtained as follows:
π d ( w d i ) = i = 1 2 ( w d i w m i ) ( a w d i + β w d j + γ θ i δ θ j ) 2 ; i = 1 , 2 , , j = 3 i
Solving first order conditions for the distributor’s profit function given in Equation (A2), π d w d 1 = 0 a n d π d w d 2 = 0 simultaneously, one can obtain the response for the distributor as follows:
w d i = a ( 1 + β ) + ( 1 β 2 ) w m i + ( γ β δ ) θ i + ( β γ δ ) θ j 2 ( 1 β 2 )
π d is jointly concave in w d i , because 2 π d w d 1 2 · 2 π d w d 2 2 2 π d w d 1 w d 2 2 = 1 β 2 > 0 and 2 π d w d i 2 = 1 < 0 . Using distributor’s response, profit function for two manufacturers are obtained as follows:
π m i ( w m i , θ i ) = ( a w m i ) w m i 2 + w m i ( β w m j + γ θ i δ θ j ) 4 ( 1 ρ s ) η θ i 2 4 , i = 1 , 2 , , j = 3 i
Profit function in Equation (A4) for each manufacturer is concave because, 2 π m i w m i 2 · 2 π m i θ i 2 2 π m i w m i θ i 2 = 16 ( 1 ρ s ) η γ 2 16 > 0 ; 2 π m i w m i 2 = 1 2 < 0 , a n d 2 π m i θ i 2 = 2 ( 1 ρ s ) η < 0 . Solving the first order conditions of Equation (A4) π m i w m i = 0 a n d π m i θ i = 0 for each manufacturer simultaneously, the responses for each manufacturer is obtained as follows:
w m i = 8 a ( 1 ρ s ) η 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) θ i = a γ η 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ )
Using the responses for the supply chain members, social welfare functions are obtained as follows:
S W 1 ( ρ s ) = T S + C S ρ s η ( θ 1 2 + θ 2 2 ) = 2 a 2 η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 8 5 β ) η ( 1 β ) γ 2 ) ( 1 β ) ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) ) 2
S W 2 ( ρ s ) = T S ρ s η ( θ 1 2 + θ 2 2 ) = 2 a 2 η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 7 4 β ) η ( 1 β ) γ 2 ) ( 1 β ) ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) η γ ( γ δ ) ) 2
Therefore, optimal subsidies are obtained by solving d S W i d ρ s = 0 as follows:
ρ D 1 R 1 B 1 = 1 2 ( 2 β ) ( 1 β ) γ ( 8 5 β ) ( γ δ ) )
ρ D 1 R 1 B 2 = 1 2 ( 2 β ) ( 1 β ) γ ( 7 4 β ) ( γ δ )
Note that each S W i ( ρ s ) is concave as d 2 S W 1 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 1 R 1 B 1 = 16 a 2 ( 8 5 β ) 4 ( γ δ ) 4 η 2 ( 1 β ) γ 2 ϕ 2 3 < 0 , and d 2 S W 2 d ρ s 2
| ρ D 1 R 1 B 2 = 16 a 2 ( 7 4 β ) 4 ( γ δ ) 4 η 2 ( 1 β ) γ 2 ϕ 1 3 < 0 , respectively, Substituting the response of Equation (A8) and Equation (A9), we can obtain the product qualities, wholesale prices for the manufacturers and distributor, and retail prices of products are as presented in Proposition 1.

Appendix A.1. Derivation of Optimal Decision for Supply Chain Structure D 1 R 1 S j

This subsection presents an optimal decision where one of the manufacturers receives a subsidy. In this scenario, the response of the retailer and the distributor are remain the same as given in Equations (A1) and (A3), respectively. Therefore, the profit functions for the manufacturers based on the responses of the retailer and distributor are obtained as follows:
π m 1 ( w m 1 , θ 1 ) = w m 1 ( a w m 1 + w m 2 β + γ θ 1 δ θ 2 ) 4 η θ 1 2 4
π m 2 ( w m 2 , θ 2 ) = w m 2 ( a w m 2 + w m 1 β δ θ 1 + γ θ 2 ) 4 ( 1 ρ s ) η θ 2 2 4
As we assume, the second manufacturer receives a subsidy; therefore, the profit function for the first manufacturer is independent of the subsidy rate. By solving first-order conditions of Equations (A10) and (A11) with respect to w m i & θ i , we obtain the responses for the manufacturers as follows:
w m 1 = 8 η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 ) θ 1 = a γ ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 )
w m 2 = 8 a ( 1 ρ s ) η ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 ) θ 2 = a γ ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 )
Finally, substituting response for the supply chain members, social welfare functions are obtained as follows:
S W 1 ( ρ s ) = T S + C S ρ s η θ 2 2 = 2 a 2 η ( 1 β 2 ) ( 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 ) ) [ ( ( 1 β 2 ) γ 4 ( γ + δ ) 2 + γ 2 ( γ + δ ) ( ( ρ s 2 ( 15 9 β 2 ) 4 ρ s ( 1 + β ) ( 12 β ( 7 + 2 β ) ) + 4 ( 1 + β ) ( 16 β ( 9 + 4 β ) ) ) γ + ( 32 + 4 ( 3 5 β ) β + 4 ρ s ( 1 + β ) ( 8 5 β ) + ρ s 2 ( 15 9 β 2 ) ) δ ) η 32 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) γ ( ( 20 2 β ( 6 + β ) + ρ s 2 ( 10 β ( 6 + β ) ) + ρ s ( 28 β ( 17 + 2 β ) ) ) γ ( 2 ρ s ) ( 1 ρ s ) ( 8 5 β ) δ ) η 2 256 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) 2 ( 8 5 β ) η 3 ) ]
S W 2 ( ρ s ) = T S ρ s η θ 2 2 2 a 2 η ( 1 β 2 ) ( 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 ) ) 2 [ 32 ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) η ( 2 ρ s ) γ δ ) ( 1 ρ s ) ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) ( 7 4 β ) η 2 + 4 ( 22 + 10 β 4 β 2 ( 4 + β ) + ρ s 2 ( 7 4 β 2 ) 2 ρ s ( 1 + β ) ( 9 5 β β 2 ) ) γ 3 δ η + 2 γ 2 η ( ( 14 7 ( 2 ρ s ) ρ s + 6 ( 1 ρ s ) β 4 ( 2 2 ρ s + ρ s 2 ) β 2 ) δ 2 + 16 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) ( ρ s ( 25 2 β ( 7 + β ) ) ( 2 + ρ s 2 ) ( 9 β ( 5 + β ) ) ) η ) + γ 4 ( 2 ( 30 22 ρ s + 7 ρ s 2 ) η + 4 β ( 7 2 ρ s 2 β 4 β ( 3 + β ) ρ s ( 5 2 β ( 4 + β ) ) ) η ( 1 β 2 ) δ 2 ) ( 1 β 2 ) γ 5 ( γ + 2 δ ) ]
Solving first-order condition of Equations (A14) and (A15) with respect to ρ s , we obtain subsidy rate as follows:
ρ D 1 R 1 S 1 = 2 ( 1 + β ) ( α 2 γ + ( 8 5 β ) δ ) ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 2 ϕ 3
ρ D 1 R 1 S 2 = ( 1 + β ) ( ( 3 + 2 ( 1 β ) β ) γ + ( 7 4 β ) δ ) ( 8 ( 2 + β ) η γ ( γ + δ ) ) 2 ϕ 4
Similar to the previous section, one can find that d 2 S W 1 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 1 R 1 S 1 < 0 , and d 2 S W 2 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 1 R 1 S 2 < 0 and therefore each S W i ( ρ s ) is concave in ρ s . Upon simplification, we present the optimal decision in Proposition 2.

Appendix B. Derivation of Optimal Decision for Supply Chain Structures D1R2

First, we derive optimal decision for Scenario D 1 R 2 . Solving first order conditions for the retailer’s profit function ( π r i = ( p i w d i ) q i i = 1 , 2 ), d π r i d p i = 0 i = 1 , 2 simultaneously, one can obtain retail prices as follows:
p i = 2 w d i + w d j β + a ( 2 + β ) + ( 2 γ β δ ) θ i + ( β γ 2 δ ) θ j 4 β 2 i = 1 , 2 ; j = 3 i
Because d 2 π r i d p i 2 = 2 < 0 ; i.e., π r i are concave functions in p i . Substituting responses for two retailers, profit function for the distributor is obtained as follows:
π d ( w d i , w d j ) = i = 1 2 ( w d i w m i ) ( a ( 2 + β ) + w d j β w d i ( 2 β 2 ) + ( 2 γ β δ ) θ i + ( β γ 2 δ ) θ j ) 4 β 2 j = 3 i
The profit function of the distributor given in Equation (A19) is jointly concave in w d i , because 2 π d w d 1 2 · 2 π d w d 2 2 2 π d w d 1 w d 2 2 = 4 ( 1 β 2 ) 4 β 2 > 0 and 2 π d w d i 2 = 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 4 β 2 < 0 . Solving the first-order conditions of Equation (A19) with respect to w d i , the response for the distributor is obtained as follows:
w d i = a ( 1 + β ) + w m i ( 1 β 2 ) + ( γ β δ ) θ i + ( β γ δ ) θ j 2 ( 1 β 2 ) i = 1 , 2 ; j = 3 i
Based on the responses, profit functions for two manufacturers are obtained as follows:
π m i ( w m i , θ i ) = w m i ( a ( 2 + β ) ( 2 β 2 ) w m i + β w m j + ( 2 γ β δ ) θ i + ( β γ 2 δ ) θ j ) 2 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η θ i 2 2 ( 4 β 2 )
The profit function for each manufacturers ( π m i ) given in Equation (A21) are jointly concave in w m i and θ i because 2 π m i w m i 2 · 2 π m i θ i 2 2 π m i w m i θ i 2 = 8 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β 2 ) ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 2 γ β δ ) 2 4 ( 4 β 2 ) 2 > 0 and 2 π m i w m i 2 = 2 β 2 4 β 2 < 0 , and 2 π m i θ i 2 = 2 ( 1 ρ s ) η < 0 . Solving first-order conditions, product qualities, and wholesale prices for two manufacturers are obtained as follows:
w m i = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 θ m i = a ( 2 γ β δ ) 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1
Finally, we compute the social welfare measures as given below:
S W 1 ( ρ s ) = T S + C S ρ s η i = 1 2 θ i 2 = 2 a 2 η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 2 β 2 ) ( 16 14 β 6 β 2 + 5 β 3 ) η ( 1 β ) ( 2 γ β δ ) 2 ) ( 1 β ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 ) 2
S W 2 ( ρ s ) = T S ρ s η i = 1 2 θ i 2 = 2 a 2 η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 2 β 2 ) ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) η ( 1 β ) ( 2 γ β δ ) 2 ) ( 1 β ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 3 η α 1 ) 2
Solving firstorder conditions of Equations (A23) and (A24) with respect to ρ s , we obtain subsidy rate as follows:
ρ D 1 R 2 B 1 = ( 16 β 2 ( 34 β ( 14 + 5 ( 2 β ) β ) ) ) γ + ( 32 β ( 36 + β ( 14 β ( 21 + β 3 β 2 ) ) ) ) δ ( 2 β 2 ) ( 16 β ( 14 + β ( 6 5 β ) ) ) ( γ δ )
ρ D 1 R 2 B 2 = ( 12 + β ( 4 30 β + 10 β 2 + 9 β 3 4 β 4 ) ) γ ( 28 32 β 10 β 2 + 17 β 3 2 β 5 ) δ ( 2 β 2 ) ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) ( γ δ )
Because d 2 S W 1 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 1 R 2 B 1 = 16 a 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 4 ( 16 14 β 6 β 2 + 5 β 3 ) 4 ( γ δ ) 4 η 2 ( 1 β ) ( 2 γ β δ ) 2 ϕ 5 3 < 0 and d 2 S W 2 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 1 R 2 B 1 = 16 a 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 4 ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) 4 ( γ δ ) 4 η 2 ( 1 β ) ( 2 γ β δ ) 2 ϕ 6 3 < 0 , the SW function given in Equations (A23) and (A24) are concave in ρ s . We present optimal decision in this distribution structure in Proposition 3.

Derivation of Optimal Decision for Supply Chain Structure D 1 R 2 S j

This subsection presents the detailed derivation of an optimal decision where one manufacturer receives a subsidy. In this scenario, the responses of the retailers and the distributor are the same as given in Equations (A18) and (A20). Therefore, the profit functions for the manufacturers based on the responses of the retailers and distributor are obtained as follows:
π m 1 ( w m 1 , θ 1 ) = w m 1 ( a ( 2 + β ) w m 1 ( 2 β 2 ) + w m 2 β + ( 2 γ β δ ) θ 1 + ( β γ 2 δ ) θ 2 ) 2 ( 4 β 2 ) η θ 1 2 2 ( 4 β 2 )
π m 2 ( w m 2 , θ 2 ) = w m 2 ( a ( 2 + β ) w m 2 ( 2 β 2 ) + w m 1 β + ( 2 γ β δ ) θ 2 + ( β γ 2 δ ) θ 1 ) 2 ( 4 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) η θ 2 2 2 ( 4 β 2 )
As we assume, the second manufacturers receives subsidy, therefore profit function for first manufacturers independent for the subsidy rate. By solving first order conditions of Equation (A27) with respect to w m 1 & θ 1 and Equation (A28) with respect to w m 2 & θ 2 , we obtain the responses for the manufacturers as follows:
w m 1 = 4 a ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1 θ 1 = a ( 2 γ β δ ) ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1
w m 2 = 4 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ψ 1 θ 2 = a ( 2 γ β δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) ψ 1
where ψ 1 = 16 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η 2 4 ( 2 ρ s ) ( 2 γ β δ ) α 4 η + ( γ 2 δ 2 ) ( 2 γ β δ ) 2 .
Finally, similar to the previous Section (Appendix A.1), substituting, response for the supply chain members, one can obtain the social welfare functions, and by solving first-order conditions with respect to ρ s , we obtain subsidy rate as follows:
ρ D 1 R 2 S 1 = 2 ( 1 + β ) [ ( ( 16 34 β 2 + 14 β 3 + 10 β 4 5 β 5 ) γ ( 32 36 β 14 β 2 + 21 β 3 + β 4 3 β 5 ) δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) 2 ] ϕ 7
ρ D 1 R 2 S 2 = ( 1 β ) [ ( ( 12 + 4 β 30 β 2 + 10 β 3 + 9 β 4 4 β 5 ) γ ( 28 32 β 10 β 2 + 17 β 3 2 β 5 ) δ ) ( 4 ( 2 + β ) α 2 η α 0 ) 2 ] ϕ 8
One can verify that SW functions are concave also. We present optimal decision in this distribution structure in Proposition 4. Note that the derivation of optimal decision in distribution structure D 2 R 1 is similar with D 1 R 2 , we omitted the proof.

Appendix C. Derivation of Optimal Decision for Supply Chain Structure D2R2

The optimal responses of the retailers remain the same as Equation (A18), for this scenario. Therefore, substituting retailer’s response, profit function for each distributor are obtained as follows:
π d i ( w d i ) = ( w d i w m i ) ( a w d i + β w d j + γ θ i δ θ j ) 2 ; i = 1 , 2 ; j = 3 i
Solving first-order conditions for the profit functions of each distributors given in Equation (A33), ( π d i w d i = 0 i = 1 , 2 ) simultaneously, one can obtain the responses of each distributor as follows:
w d i = ( a + γ θ j δ θ i ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 + ( 2 w m i ( 2 β 2 ) + w m j β ) ( 2 β 2 ) + ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) ( θ i θ j ) 16 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ;
Each π d i is concave in w d i , because 2 π d i w d i 2 = 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 4 + β 2 < 0 . Substituting distributor’s response, profit function for two manufacturers are obtained as follows:
π m i ( w m i , θ i ) = 1 ( 4 β 2 ) ( 16 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) [ ( 2 β 2 ) w m i ( a ( 2 + β ) α 2 + w m j β ( 2 β 2 ) w m i ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) + ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( γ θ i δ θ j ) 2 β ( 3 β 2 ) ( δ θ i γ θ j ) ) ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η θ i 2 ]
Profit function for each manufacturer is concave given in Equation (A35) because, 2 π m i w m i 2 · 2 π m i θ i 2 2 π m i w m i θ i 2 = ( 2 β 2 ) ψ 2 ( 64 84 β 2 + 33 β 4 4 β 6 ) 2 > 0 ; if ψ 2 = 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 )
α 2 α 3 η ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 2 > 0 and 2 π m i w m i 2 = 2 ( 2 β 2 ) ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 < 0 , a n d 2 π m i θ i 2 = 2 ( 1 x ) η < 0 . Solving the first-order conditions of Equation (A35) ( π m i w m i = 0 a n d π m i θ i = 0 ) for each manufacturer simultaneously, the responses for each manufacturer is obtained as follows:
w m i = 2 a ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η ψ 3 θ i = a ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ψ 3
where ψ 3 = 2 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 β ) α 5 α 3 η ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ( γ δ ) . Finally, we obtain the social welfare functions for this distribution structures as follows:
S W 1 ( ρ s ) = T S + C S ρ s η ( θ 1 2 + θ 2 2 ) = 1 ψ 3 2 [ 2 a 2 ( 2 β 2 ) η ( 8 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) η ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 2 ]
S W 2 ( ρ s ) = T S ρ s η ( θ 1 2 + θ 2 2 ) = 1 ψ 3 2 [ 2 a 2 ( 2 β 2 ) η ( 4 ( 1 ρ s ) 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) η ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 2 ) ]
Therefore, solving the first-order condition of Equations (A37) and (A38) w.r.t. ρ s , the optimal subsidies are obtained as follows:
ρ D 2 R 2 B 1 = 1 ( 2 β ) α 3 α 4 α 5 4 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) ( γ δ )
ρ D 2 R 2 B 2 = 1 ( 2 β ) α 3 α 4 α 5 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) ( γ δ )
Note that S W i ’s are concave in ρ s because:
d 2 S W 1 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 2 R 2 B 1 = 256 a 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) 4 ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) 4 ( γ δ ) 4 η 2 α 4 2 ϕ 9 3 < 0 , and d 2 S W 2 d ρ s 2 | ρ D 2 R 2 B 2 = 16 a 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) 4 ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) 4 ( γ δ ) 4 η 2 α 4 2 ϕ 10 3 < 0 . We present optimal decision in this distribution structure in Proposition 6.

Derivation of Optimal Decision for Supply Chain Structure D 2 R 2 S j

This subsection presents an optimal decision where one of the manufacturers receives a subsidy. In this scenario, the response of the retailer and the distributor are same as given in Equations (A18) and (A34). Therefore, the profit functions for each manufacturer based on the responses of the retailers and distributors are obtained as follows:
π m 1 = 1 ( 4 β 2 ) ( 16 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) [ w m 1 ( 2 β 2 ) ( a ( 2 + β ) α 2 w m 1 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) + w m 2 β ( 2 β 2 ) + ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( γ θ 1 δ θ 2 ) 2 ( 3 β 2 ) β ( δ θ 1 γ θ 2 ) ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η θ 1 2 ]
π m 2 = w m 2 ( a w m 2 + w m 1 β δ θ 1 + γ θ 2 ) 4 ( 1 x ) η θ 2 2 ) 4 [ w m 2 ( 2 β 2 ) ( a ( 2 + β ) α 2 w m 2 ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) + w m 1 β ( 2 β 2 ) + ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( γ θ 2 δ θ 1 ) 2 ( 3 β 2 ) β ( δ θ 2 γ θ 1 ) ) ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η θ 2 2 ]
As we assume, the second manufacturers receive a subsidy, therefore profit function for the first manufacturers is independent for the subsidy rate. By solving first-order conditions of Equation (A41) with respect to w m 1 & θ 1 and Equation (A42) with respect to w m 2 & θ 2 , we obtain the responses for the manufacturers as follows:
w m 1 = 2 a ( 4 β 2 ) α 2 α 3 η ( 2 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 ; θ 1 = a ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ( 2 ( 2 + β ) ( 1 ρ s ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4
w m 2 ( ρ s ) = 2 a ( 4 β 2 ) ( 1 ρ s ) α 2 α 3 η ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4 θ 2 ( ρ s ) = a ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) ψ 4
where ψ 4 = 4 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) α 6 α 5 α 2 α 3 η 2 ( 2 β 2 ) α 4 ( 2 ( 2 ρ s ) ( 2 ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) γ β ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) δ ) η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ 2 δ 2 ) α 4 ) . Finally, similar to the previous sections, by substituting responses for the supply chain members, one can obtain the social welfare functions, and by solving the first-order condition of S W i ’s with respect to ρ s , we obtain subsidy rate as follows:
ρ D 2 R 2 S 1 = ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) 2 ψ 5 [ ( 1024 + 896 β 3360 β 2 1568 β 3 + 3820 β 4 + 966 β 5 1940 β 6 253 β 7 + 454 β 8 + 24 β 9 40 β 10 ) γ 2 ( 2 + β ) ( 512 448 β 904 β 2 + 786 β 3 + 562 β 4 485 β 5 148 β 6 + 127 β 7 + 14 β 8 12 β 9 ) δ ]
ρ D 2 R 2 S 2 = ( 2 ( 2 + β ) α 2 α 6 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( γ + δ ) α 4 ) 2 ψ 6 [ ( 768 + 896 β 2656 β 2 1568 β 3 + 3080 β 4 + 966 β 5 1570 β 6 253 β 7 + 366 β 8 + 24 β 9 32 β 10 ) γ 2 ( 896 384 β 1904 β 2 + 668 β 3 + 1540 β 4 408 β 5 596 β 6 + 106 β 7 + 111 β 8 10 β 9 8 β 10 ) δ ]
where
ψ 5 = α 7 α 8 ( ( 16 14 β 2 + 3 β 4 ) 2 γ 5 + ( 2 β 2 ) 2 ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( 8 12 β 3 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) γ 4 δ 4 ( 6 β 5 β 3 + β 5 ) 2 δ 5 ) 4 β ( 3 β 2 ) ( 2 β 2 ) ( 278528 + 346112 β 1186304 β 2 1423616 β 3 + 2113024 β 4 + 2460544 β 5 2060280 β 6 2335516 β 7 + 1206292 β 8 + 1334072 β 9 435944 β 10 471057 β 11 + 95342 β 12 + 100764 β 13 11580 β 14 11980 β 15 + 600 β 16 + 608 β 17 ) δ 3 η 16 ( 2 + β ) 2 α 7 ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) α 2 2 α 6 2 δ η 2 ( 2 β 2 ) γ 3 ( ( 2 β 2 ) α 7 α 8 ( 64 + 96 β 84 β 2 68 β 3 + 33 β 4 + 12 β 5 4 β 6 ) δ 2 + 2 ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( 507904 + 358400 β 1895936 β 2 1317120 β 3 + 3015296 β 4 + 2061472 β 5 2668472 β 6 1795116 β 7 + 1438376 β 8 + 952108 β 9 484292 β 10 315431 β 11 + 99651 β 12 + 63858 β 13 11480 β 14 7236 β 15 + 568 β 16 + 352 β 17 ) η ) ( 2 β 2 ) γ 2 δ ( ( 2 β 2 ) α 7 α 8 ( 64 96 β 84 β 2 + 68 β 3 + 33 β 4 12 β 5 4 β 6 ) δ 2 + 4 ( 2 β ) ( 196608 1294336 β 2386944 β 2 + 4269824 β 3 + 7110144 β 4 5750720 β 5 10145904 β 6 + 3969020 β 7 + 8350348 β 8 1355256 β 9 4259864 β 10 + 81525 β 11 + 1372253 β 12 + 107131 β 13 272213 β 14 40258 β 15 + 30400 β 16 + 6084 β 17 1464 β 18 352 β 19 ) η ) + 2 γ ( 2 β ( 3 β 2 ) ( 2 β 2 ) 2 α 7 α 8 ( 8 3 β 3 β 2 + β 3 ) δ 4 + ( 2 β 2 ) ( 2228224 + 3358720 β 12218368 β 2 16009216 β 3 + 27480576 β 4 + 32275200 β 5 34059840 β 6 36325440 β 7 + 26046456 β 8 + 25278804 β 9 12923204 β 10 11332768 β 11 + 4225400 β 12 + 3286883 β 13 898554 β 14 596900 β 15 + 118364 β 16 + 61780 β 17 8616 β 18 2784 β 19 + 256 β 20 ) δ 2 η + 8 ( 2 + β ) 2 α 7 ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) ( α 2 ) 2 ( α 6 ) 2 η 2 )
ψ 6 = ( 8 3 β 2 ) 2 ( 2 β 2 ) 2 α 7 α 9 γ 5 + ( 2 β 2 ) 2 ( 8 3 β 2 ) α 7 α 9 ( 8 12 β 3 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) γ 4 δ 4 α 7 ( 6 β 5 β 3 + β 5 ) 2 α 9 δ 5 8 β ( 3 β 2 ) ( 2 β 2 ) ( 57344 + 75776 β 245504 β 2 311552 β 3 + 437920 β 4 + 537352 β 5 426336 β 6 508204 β 7 + 248644 β 8 + 288860 β 9 89342 β 10 101385 β 11 + 19400 β 12 + 21540 β 13 2337 β 14 2542 β 15 + 120 β 16 + 128 β 17 ) δ 3 η 4 ( 2 + β ) 2 α 2 2 α 6 2 α 7 α 9 δ η 2 ( 2 β 2 ) α 9 γ 3 ( ( 2 β 2 ) α 7 ( 64 + 96 β 84 β 2 68 β 3 + 33 β 4 + 12 β 5 4 β 6 ) δ 2 + ( 8 3 β 2 ) ( 4096 + 2816 β 9472 β 2 6304 β 3 + 8368 β 4 + 5376 β 5 3530 β 6 2186 β 7 + 715 β 8 + 426 β 9 56 β 10 32 β 11 ) η ) ( 2 β 2 ) γ 2 δ ( ( 2 β 2 ) α 7 α 9 ( 64 96 β 84 β 2 + 68 β 3 + 33 β 4 12 β 5 4 β 6 ) δ 2 + 2 ( 393216 2637824 β 3350528 β 2 + 10264576 β 3 + 9375232 β 4 17323264 β 5 13430272 β 6 + 16657792 β 7 + 11512440 β 8 10070776 β 9 6325876 β 10 + 3975470 β 11 + 2287798 β 12 1026189 β 13 542228 β 14 + 167259 β 15 + 81018 β 16 15640 β 17 6912 β 18 + 640 β 19 + 256 β 20 ) η ) + 4 γ ( β ( 3 β 2 ) ( 2 β 2 ) 2 α 7 α 9 ( 8 3 β 3 β 2 + β 3 ) δ 4 + ( 2 β 2 ) ( 458752 + 753664 β 2609152 β 2 3615232 β 3 + 5994240 β 4 + 7313472 β 5 7534080 β 6 8242608 β 7 + 5821980 β 8 + 5735412 β 9 2914862 β 10 2568184 β 11 + 961934 β 12 + 743375 β 13 206868 β 14 134648 β 15 + 27677 β 16 + 13894 β 17 2064 β 18 624 β 19 + 64 β 20 ) δ 2 η + ( 2 + β ) 2 α 2 2 α 6 2 α 7 α 9 η 2 ) .
We present optimal decision in this distribution structure in Proposition 7.
Figure A1. Maximum supply chain profit when (a) both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (d) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure A1. Maximum supply chain profit when (a) both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (d) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g0a1
Figure A2. Minimum subsidy when (a) both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (d) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different supply chain structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure A2. Minimum subsidy when (a) both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (d) second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different supply chain structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g0a2
Figure A3. Maximum selling quantity of (a) each product when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (d) each product when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (e) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; (f) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different supply chain structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure A3. Maximum selling quantity of (a) each product when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (d) each product when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (e) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; (f) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different supply chain structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g0a3

Appendix D. List of Symbols

Table A1. Notations.
Table A1. Notations.
Descriptions
Indices
usubsidy provided to single manufacturer (S) or both manufacturers (B), u { S , B }
vsocial welfare measures, v { 1 , 2 }
sindex for scenario, s { D 1 R 1 u v , D 1 R 2 u v , D 2 R 1 u v , D 2 R 2 u v }
Parameters
amarket potential for each product
β the cross-price sensitivity between two products, β [ 0 , 1 )
γ product quality level sensitivity with own product, γ > δ
δ cross-quality sensitivity between two products, 0 δ < γ
η investment efficiency for each manufacturer, η > 0
Variables
p i s market price per unit of i t h product
w d i s wholesale price per unit for distributor of i t h product
w m i s wholesale price per unit for manufacturer of i t h product
θ i s quality level of i t h product
ρ s subsidy rate in Scenarion s
π r i s retailer’s profit while selling i t h product
π d i s distributor’s profit while selling i t h product
π m i s manufacturer’s profit while selling i t h product
π c s total supply chain profits
S W s social welfare
T S s total government subsidy
q i s sales volume of i t h product

Appendix E. List of Additional Symbol

  • α 0 = ( 2 γ β δ ) ( γ + δ )
  • α 1 = ( 2 γ β δ ) ( γ δ )
  • α 2 = 4 + β 2 β 2
  • α 3 = 4 β 2 β 2
  • α 4 = ( 8 3 β 2 ) γ 2 β ( 3 β 2 ) δ
  • α 5 = 16 2 β 18 β 2 + β 3 + 4 β 4
  • α 6 = 16 + 2 β 18 β 2 β 3 + 4 β 4
  • α 7 = ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 )
  • α 8 = ( 240 334 β 2 + 139 β 4 18 β 6 )
  • α 9 = 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6
  • ψ 0 = 64 ( 1 ρ s ) ( 4 β 2 ) η 2 8 ( 2 ρ s ) γ ( 2 γ β δ ) η + γ 2 ( γ 2 δ 2 )
  • ϕ 1 = 16 ( 2 β ) 2 ( 1 β ) η ( 8 5 β ) ( γ δ ) 2
  • ϕ 2 = 16 ( 2 β ) 2 ( 1 β ) η ( 7 4 β ) ( γ δ ) 2
  • ϕ 3 = 3 ( 5 3 β 2 ) γ 2 ( γ δ ) ( γ + δ ) 2 8 γ ( ( 62 + β ( 37 β ( 2 + β ) ( 11 + 4 β ) ) ) γ 2 + 2 ( 1 β ) ( 6 β ( 11 + 8 β ) ) γ δ + ( 34 + β ( 55 β ( 16 + 19 β ) ) ) δ 2 ) η + 128 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) 2 ( 8 5 β ) ( γ δ ) η 2 ) )
  • ϕ 4 = 64 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) 2 ( 7 4 β ) ( γ δ ) η 2 8 γ ( ( 28 + β ( 17 2 β ( 2 + β ) 2 ) ) γ 2 + ( 1 β ) ( 6 β ( 11 + 8 β ) ) γ δ ( 14 + β ( 26 β ( 5 + 8 β ) ) ) δ 2 ) η + ( 7 4 β 2 ) γ 2 ( γ δ ) ( γ + δ ) 2
  • ϕ 5 = 4 ( 2 β ) 2 ( 1 β ) α 3 2 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( 16 14 β 6 β 2 + 5 β 3 ) ( γ δ ) 2
  • ϕ 6 = 4 ( 2 β ) 2 ( 1 β ) α 3 2 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) ( γ δ ) 2
  • ϕ 7 = 32 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) 2 ( 2 β 2 ) α 2 2 ( 16 14 β 6 β 2 + 5 β 3 ) ( γ δ ) η 2 4 ( 2 γ β δ ) ( ( 992 + 664 β 1860 β 2 1272 β 3 + 1200 β 4 + 830 β 5 329 β 6 226 β 7 + 33 β 8 + 22 β 9 ) γ 2 + 2 ( 1 β ) ( 96
    200 β 468 β 2 + 48 β 3 + 328 β 4 + 42 β 5 73 β 6 12 β 7 + 4 β 8 ) γ δ ( 544 + 744 β 1212 β 2 1496 β 3 + 980 β 4 + 1088 β 5 335 β 6 338 β 7 + 41 β 8 + 38 β 9 ) δ 2 ) η + ( 3 β 2 ) ( 2 β 2 ) ( 10 9 β 2 ) ( γ δ ) α 0 2
  • ϕ 8 = 16 ( 1 + β ) ( 2 + β ) 2 ( 2 β 2 ) α 2 2 ( 14 12 β 5 β 2 + 4 β 3 ) ( γ δ ) η 2 4 ( 2 γ β δ ) ( ( 448 + 296 β 816 β 2 552 β 3 + 504 β 4 + 346 β 5 130 β 6 89 β 7 + 12 β 8 + 8 β 9 ) γ 2 + ( 1 β ) ( 96 200 β 468 β 2 + 48 β 3 + 328 β 4 + 42 β 5 73 β 6 12 β 7 + 4 β 8 ) γ δ ( 224 + 336 β 492 β 2 664 β 3 + 394 β 4 + 475 β 5 133 β 6 145 β 7 + 16 β 8 + 16 β 9 ) δ 2 ) η + ( 2 β 2 ) ( 14 17 β 2 + 4 β 4 ) ( γ
    δ ) α 0 2
  • ϕ 9 = ( 2 β ) 2 α 3 2 α 5 2 η 2 ( 2 β 2 ) ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 64 90 β 2 + 38 β 4 5 β 6 ) ( γ δ ) 2 ;
  • ϕ 10 = ( 2 β ) 2 α 3 2 α 5 2 η ( 2 β 2 ) ( 8 9 β 2 + 2 β 4 ) ( 112 154 β 2 + 63 β 4 8 β 6 ) ( γ δ ) 2

References

  1. Krafft, M.; Goetz, O.; Mantrala, M.; Sotgiu, F.; Tillmanns, S. The evolution of marketing channel research domains and methodologies: An integrative review and future directions. J. Retail. 2015, 91, 569–585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Beaulieu, A. State of the Wholesale Distribution Industry. 2021. Available online: www.naw.org/state-of-the-industry/ (accessed on 25 January 2022).
  3. India-Country Commercial Guide. 2021. Available online: www.trade.gov/country-commercial-guides/india-distribution-and-sales-channels-0 (accessed on 21 January 2022).
  4. Sharma, A.; Cosguner, K.; Sharma, T.K.; Motiani, M. Channel intermediaries and manufacturer performance: An exploratory investigation in an emerging market. J. Retail. 2021, 97, 639–657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Watson, G.F.; Worm, S.; Palmatier, R.W.; Ganesan, S. The evolution of marketing channels: Trends and research directions. J. Retail. 2015, 91, 546–568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Allaoui, H.; Guo, Y.; Sarkis, J. Decision support for collaboration planning in sustainable supply chains. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 229, 761–774. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Gómez-Luciano, C.A.; Domínguez, F.R.R.; González-Andrés, F.; De Meneses, B.U.L. Sustainable supply chain management: Contributions of supplies markets. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 184, 311–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gadde, L.E. Activity coordination and resource combining in distribution networks-Implications for relationship involvement and the relationship atmosphere. J. Mark. Manag. 2004, 20, 157–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Wilson, H.; Daniel, E. The multi-channel challenge: A dynamic capability approach. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2007, 36, 10–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Leigh, M.; Li, X. Industrial ecology, industrial symbiosis and supply chain environmental sustainability: A case study of a large UK distributor. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 106, 632–643. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Wang, X.; Li, Z.; Shaikh, R.; Ranjha, A.R.; Batala, L.K. Do government subsidies promote financial performance? Fresh evidence from China’s new energy vehicle industry. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2021, 28, 142–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Nielsen, I.; Majumder, S.; Szwarc, E.; Saha, S. Impact of strategic cooperation under competition on green product manufacturing. Sustainability 2020, 12, 10248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Goel, P.; Sharma, N.; Mathiyazhagan, K.; Vimal, K.E.K. Government is trying but consumers are not buying: A barrier analysis for electric vehicle sales in India. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2021, 28, 71–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Zhong, Z.; Peng, B. Can environmental regulation promote green innovation in heavily polluting enterprises? Empirical evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2022, 30, 815–828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Hafezalkotob, A. Modelling intervention policies of government in price-energy saving competition of green supply chains. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2018, 119, 247–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Guo, D.; He, Y.; Wu, Y.; Xu, Q. Analysis of supply chain under different subsidy policies of the government. Sustainability 2016, 8, 1290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Madani, S.R.; Rasti-Barzoki, M. Sustainable supply chain management with pricing, greening and governmental tariffs determining strategies: A game-theoretic approach. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2017, 105, 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Zhang, Y.H.; Wang, Y. The impact of government incentive on the two competing supply chains under the perspective of Corporation Social Responsibility: A case study of Photovoltaic industry. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 154, 102–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Liu, Y.; Quan, B.T.; Xu, Q.; Forrest, J.Y.L. Corporate social responsibility and decision analysis in a supply chain through government subsidy. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 208, 436–447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Fu, J.; Chen, X.; Hu, Q. Subsidizing strategies in a sustainable supply chain. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2017, 69, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Chen, J.Y.; Dimitrov, S.; Pun, H. The impact of government subsidy on supply Chains’ sustainability innovation. Omega 2019, 86, 42–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Agi, M.A.; Faramarzi-Oghani, S.; Hazır, Ö. Game theory-based models in green supply chain management: A review of the literature. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2021, 59, 4736–4755. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Yu, J.J.; Tang, C.S.; Shen, Z.J.M. Improving consumer welfare and manufacturer profit via government subsidy programs: Subsidizing consumers or manufacturers? Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2018, 20, 752–766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Fremeth, A.R.; Holburn, G.L.; Richter, B.K. Bridging qualitative and quantitative methods in organizational research: Applications of synthetic control methodology in the US automobile industry. Organ. Sci. 2016, 27, 462–482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Alizamir, S.; Iravani, F.; Mamani, H. An analysis of price vs. revenue protection: Government subsidies in the agriculture industry. Manag. Sci. 2019, 65, 32–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Zhang, H.; Zheng, Y.; Cao, J.; Qiu, Y. Has government intervention effectively encouraged the use of waste cooking oil as an energy source? Comparison of two Chinese biofuel companies. Energy 2017, 140, 708–715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Yu, M.; Cruz, J.M.; Li, D.; Masoumi, A.H. A multiperiod competitive supply chain framework with environmental policies and investments in sustainable operations. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2021, 300, 112–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Saha, S. Game-theoretic analysis to examine how government subsidy policies affect a closed-loop supply chain decision. Appl. Sci. 2020, 10, 145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Saha, S.; Nielsen, I.; Sana, S.S. Effect of optimal subsidy rate and strategic behaviour of supply chain members under competition on green product retailing. Math. Probl. Eng. 2021, 2021, 6661103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Hua, Z.; Chen, W.; Zhang, Z.G. Competition and coordination in two-tier public service systems under government fiscal policy. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2016, 25, 1430–1448. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Niu, B.; Chen, L.; Zhang, J. Punishing or subsidizing? Regulation analysis of sustainable fashion procurement strategies. Transp. Res. Part Logist. Transp. Rev. 2017, 107, 81–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Xiao, L.; Wang, X.; Chin, K.S.; Qin, Y. Competitive strategy in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidy. J. Syst. Sci. Syst. Eng. 2017, 26, 417–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Zhou, Y.; Hu, F.; Zhou, Z. Pricing decisions and social welfare in a supply chain with multiple competing retailers and carbon tax policy. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 190, 752–777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Hong, Z.; Guo, X. Green product supply chain contracts considering environmental responsibilities. Omega 2019, 83, 155–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. McGillivray, F. Privileging Industry; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  36. Fischer, C.; Greaker, M.; Rosendahl, K.E. Strategic technology policy as a supplement to renewable energy standards. Resour. Energy Econ. 2018, 51, 84–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Dey, K.; Roy, S.; Saha, S. The impact of strategic inventory and procurement strategies on green product design in a two-period supply chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2019, 57, 1915–1948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Meng, Q.; Li, M.; Liu, W.; Li, Z.; Zhang, J. Pricing policies of dual-channel green supply chain: Considering government subsidies and consumers’ dual preferences. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2021, 26, 1021–1030. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Dey, K.; Saha, S. Influence of procurement decisions in two-period green supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 190, 388–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Zhang, C.T.; Wang, H.X.; Ren, M.L. Research on pricing and coordination strategy of green supply chain under hybrid production mode. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2014, 72, 24–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Shen, B.; Cao, Y.; Xu, X. Product line design and quality differentiation for green and non-green products in a supply chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2020, 58, 148–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Saha, S.; Banaszak, Z.; Bocewicz, G.; Nielsen, I.E. Pricing and quality competition for substitutable green products with a common retailer. Oper. Res. 2021, 1–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Li, X.; Li, Y. Chain-to-chain competition on product sustainability. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 112, 2058–2065. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Bian, J.; Zhao, X.; Liu, Y. Single vs. cross distribution channels with manufacturers’ dynamic tacit collusion. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2020, 220, 107456. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Sana, S.S.; Saha, S. Comparative analysis of government incentives and game structures on single and two-period green supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 235, 1371–1398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Saha, S.; Majumder, S.; Nielsen, I.E. Is it a strategic move to subsidized consumers instead of the manufacturer? IEEE Access 2019, 7, 169807–169824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Zhou, Y. The role of green customers under competition: A mixed blessing? J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 170, 857–866. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Li, T.; Zhang, R.; Zhao, S.; Liu, B. Low carbon strategy analysis under revenue-sharing and cost-sharing contracts. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 212, 1462–1477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Sinayi, M.; Rasti-Barzoki, M. A game theoretic approach for pricing, greening, and social welfare policies in a supply chain with government intervention. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 196, 1443–1458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Yuyin, Y.; Jinxi, L. The effect of governmental policies of carbon taxes and energy-saving subsidies on enterprise decisions in a two-echelon supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 181, 675–691. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Barman, A.; Das, R.; De, P.K.; Sana, S.S. Optimal pricing and greening strategy in a competitive green supply chain: Impact of government subsidy and tax policy. Sustainability 2021, 13, 9178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Tseng, M.L.; Islam, M.S.; Karia, N.; Fauzi, F.A.; Afrin, S. A literature review on green supply chain management: Trends and future challenges. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 141, 145–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Bhatia, M.S.; Gangwani, K.K. Green supply chain management: Scientometric review and analysis of empirical research. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 284, 124722. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Junaid, M.; Zhang, Q.; Syed, M.W. Effects of sustainable supply chain integration on green innovation and firm performance. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2022, 30, 145–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Saha, S. Exploring the intervention of intermediary in a green supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 233, 1525–1544. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Saha, S.; Sarmah, S.P.; Moon, I. Dual channel closed-loop supply chain coordination with a reward-driven remanufacturing policy. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016, 54, 1503–1517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Different distribution structures.
Figure 1. Different distribution structures.
Sustainability 14 03624 g001
Figure 2. (a) Product quality, (b) total subsidy, and (c) total supply chain profits in distribution structure D 1 R 1 : a = 100 ; δ = 0.3 ; η = 0.5 , β ( 0 , 0.8 ) , γ = 0.5 .
Figure 2. (a) Product quality, (b) total subsidy, and (c) total supply chain profits in distribution structure D 1 R 1 : a = 100 ; δ = 0.3 ; η = 0.5 , β ( 0 , 0.8 ) , γ = 0.5 .
Sustainability 14 03624 g002
Figure 3. (a) Product quality, (b) total subsidy, and (c) total supply chain profits in distribution structures D 1 R 2 / D 1 R 2 : a = 100 ; δ = 0.3 ; η = 0.5 , β ( 0 , 0.8 ) , γ = 0.5 .
Figure 3. (a) Product quality, (b) total subsidy, and (c) total supply chain profits in distribution structures D 1 R 2 / D 1 R 2 : a = 100 ; δ = 0.3 ; η = 0.5 , β ( 0 , 0.8 ) , γ = 0.5 .
Sustainability 14 03624 g003
Figure 4. (a) Product quality, (b) total subsidy, and (c) total supply chain profits in distribution structure D 2 R 2 : a = 100 ; δ = 0.3 ; η = 0.5 , β ( 0 , 0.8 ) , γ = 0.5 .
Figure 4. (a) Product quality, (b) total subsidy, and (c) total supply chain profits in distribution structure D 2 R 2 : a = 100 ; δ = 0.3 ; η = 0.5 , β ( 0 , 0.8 ) , γ = 0.5 .
Sustainability 14 03624 g004
Figure 5. (a) Maximum product qualities; (b) Maximum retail prices; (c) Minimum retail prices in the absence of subsidy: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure 5. (a) Maximum product qualities; (b) Maximum retail prices; (c) Minimum retail prices in the absence of subsidy: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g005
Figure 6. Maximum product qualities of (a) both products when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (d) both products when both when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (e) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; (f) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 . in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure 6. Maximum product qualities of (a) both products when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (d) both products when both when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (e) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; (f) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 . in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g006
Figure 7. Minimum retail prices of (a) each products when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (d) each products when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (e) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; (f) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure 7. Minimum retail prices of (a) each products when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (d) each products when both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (e) first product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; (f) second product when the second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g007
Figure 8. Maximum investment efficiencies of (a) Both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) Second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) Both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (d) Second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Figure 8. Maximum investment efficiencies of (a) Both the manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 1 ; (b) Second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 1 ; (c) Both manufacturers receive a subsidy under S W 2 ; (d) Second manufacturer receives a subsidy under S W 2 ; in different distribution structures: a = 100 ; δ ( 0.1 , 0.6 ) ; η = 0.5 , β = 0.4 , γ ( 0 , 0.8 ) .
Sustainability 14 03624 g008
Table 1. Social welfare measures to determine optimal subsidy rate.
Table 1. Social welfare measures to determine optimal subsidy rate.
AuthorsSocial Welfare FunctionGovernment SubsidySupply Chain Structure
Hua et al. (2016) [30] π c + C S YESFSC
Niu et al. (2017) [31] YESFSC
Xiao et al. (2017) [32] π c + C S T S E I YESFSC
Zhou et al. (2018) [33] π c T S YESFSC
Liu et al. (2019) [19] π c + C S T S YESCLSC
Alizamir et al. (2019) [25] YESCLSC
Hong et al. (2019) [34] π c + C S + E I YESFSC
πc—total supply chain profit; EI—environment improvement; CI—consumer surplus; TS—total subsidy.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Majumder, S.; Nielsen, I.; Maity, S.; Saha, S. Effect of Product Distribution Structures and Government Subsidy Measures on Product Quality and Consumption under Competition. Sustainability 2022, 14, 3624. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14063624

AMA Style

Majumder S, Nielsen I, Maity S, Saha S. Effect of Product Distribution Structures and Government Subsidy Measures on Product Quality and Consumption under Competition. Sustainability. 2022; 14(6):3624. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14063624

Chicago/Turabian Style

Majumder, Sani, Izabela Nielsen, Susanta Maity, and Subrata Saha. 2022. "Effect of Product Distribution Structures and Government Subsidy Measures on Product Quality and Consumption under Competition" Sustainability 14, no. 6: 3624. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14063624

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop