Next Article in Journal
Evaluation of Latvian Power System Static Stability According to a New Development Strategy until 2025
Previous Article in Journal
Participatory Varietal Selection for Promising Rice Lines
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Analysis on the Trend and Factors of Total Factor Productivity of Agricultural Export Enterprises in China

1
Institute of Agricultural Economics and Development, Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences, Beijing 100081, China
2
School of Economics and Management, China Agricultural University, Beijing 100085, China
3
School of Economics and Management, Southwest University, Chongqing 400700, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2021, 13(12), 6855; https://doi.org/10.3390/su13126855
Submission received: 12 April 2021 / Revised: 3 June 2021 / Accepted: 14 June 2021 / Published: 17 June 2021

Abstract

:
There is an “export productivity paradox” in Chinese enterprises, which has been confirmed in agricultural enterprises. This paper attempts to explain this phenomenon from the perspective of the components of TFP. This paper uses the SFA-Malmquist method to decompose and compare the TFP of China’s agricultural export enterprises based on the data of the state-level leading agricultural enterprises from 2016 to 2017. The conclusions are as follows: firstly, China’s agricultural TFP shows a negative growth trend, and the growth rate of TFP of agricultural export enterprises is less than that of agricultural non-exported enterprises; secondly, the growth rate of TFP of grain and animal husbandry export enterprises is less than that of non-export enterprises; the growth rate of TFP of private agricultural export enterprises is lower than that of non-export enterprises of the same type; the growth rate of TFP of export enterprises in eastern and western regions is lower than that of non-export enterprises; and thirdly, technical progress is an important reason for the change of TFP of China’s agricultural enterprises. However, compared with agricultural non-exported enterprises, improving the technical efficiency of enterprises can more promote the TFP of agricultural export enterprises.

1. Introduction

Export is the main means by which agricultural enterprises participate in the international market. As a major agricultural trader, China ranks among the top agricultural exporting and importing countries in the world. China’s agricultural trade shows a continuous increasing trend, which has increased from $26.94 billion in 2000 to $201.39 billion USD in 2017, with an average annual growth rate of 12.56%, of which the agricultural export has continued to increase. Since 2004, China’s agricultural trade deficit had expanded, and it was −$50.32 billion. Agricultural enterprises, as an important trade body of China’s agricultural export, make outstanding contributions. The state-level agricultural enterprise export sector accounts for a large share of agricultural exports; the export value of these enterprises accounts for more than 80% of the total export value of China’s agricultural enterprises. Indeed, the export value of agricultural enterprises accounted for 20–25% of the total export value of China’s agricultural enterprises from 2013 to 2017.Total factor productivity (TFP) is the core of a country’s economic growth and the main factor of enterprise development. Enterprise export and productivity increase promote each other. However, there is an “export-productivity paradox” in Chinese agricultural enterprises [1], that is, the productivity of agricultural enterprises that export is lower than that of non-exporting agricultural enterprises. What is the difference in TFP between Chinese agricultural export and non-export enterprises, and what leads to this difference? In exploring these questions, this paper has important theoretical and practical significance for adjusting the export structure of China’s agricultural products, improving China’s agricultural competitiveness and promoting agricultural industrial upgrading.
TFP (Total Factor Productivity) refers to the remaining part after deducting the contribution of capital and labor to the growth rate of social output, also known as Solow residual value [2]. Compared with single factor productivity, TFP measures the ratio of output to all input factors, which can reflect the comprehensive level and change of productivity, so it has more advantages. Due to Solow’s assumption of homogeneity of capital and labor input factors, Solow’s TFP is higher. Denison (1967) further developed the “Solow residual method” and calculated that the contribution of TFP growth rate to national income growth in the United States is 54.9% [3]; Jorgenson and Griliches (1967) confirmed that 30% of the total domestic output of the private sector in the United States benefits from the growth of TFP [4]. This study was further deepened both theoretically and methodologically. TFP is more used to study national and regional macroscopic economy, for example, Klenow and Rodriguez Clare (1997), and Hall and Jones (1999) believe that the difference of TFP is the essential reason for the difference of per capita output among nations [5,6]. There are also studies on the influencing factors of TFP, such as the studies from Comin and Hobijn, (2010), Bollard et al., (2014), etc. [7,8].
The research on China’s agricultural TFP focuses on measurement, composition, and influencing factors. First, different methods of measuring TFP lead to different results; for example, in the literature on estimating TFP, the growth accounting method [9,10], the stochastic frontier production function method [11,12], the data envelopment analysis method [13,14], and semi-parametric methods, such as the OP method (Olley and Pakes’ method), the LP method(Levinsohn Petrin ’ method), and the GMM method(Generalized Method of Moments) [15,16,17], have the same data requirements and can deal with cross-sectional data and panel data. The growth accounting method can also deal with the time series data of a single economy, but the choice of agricultural input and output indicators differs. Second, in considering the composition of TFP, Si and Wang decompose the components of China’s soybean TFP and compare it to the main contributions to technological progress rate and technical efficiency change [18]; Han and Yang decompose TFP into technical efficiency and progress, comparing and analyzing the TFP of beef cattle [19]; and Chen et al. and Delpachitra confirm that technological progress promotes the growth of China’s agricultural TFP [20,21]. Many scholars have studied the influencing factors of TFP, such as agricultural human capital [22], agricultural infrastructure [23], government financial support for agriculture [24], climate change and agro-meteorological disasters [25], and other natural environments that promote changes in agricultural TFP.
The New Trade Theory holds that the export and productivity of enterprises influence each other and cause each other. Research on the relationship between export and enterprise productivity demonstrates: (1) that the direction of the impact of export on enterprise productivity is unclear, i.e., exports either have no significant impact, or no impact at all, on firm productivity [26], or they have a promoting effect at one stage and a restraining effect in another [27]; (2) that there is a significant positive correlation between export and productivity, which may be attributed to the “self-selection” and “export learning” effects of export enterprises [28,29,30,31]; (3) that in the context of China’s export-oriented strategy, exports have a negative effect on enterprise productivity [32,33,34,35], i.e., the productivity of export enterprises is lower than that of non-export enterprises and there is an “export-productivity paradox.” The existence of the “export-productivity paradox” in Chinese enterprises is related to factors such as export density [36], enterprise nature [37], industry [38], how long the enterprise has existed [39], etc. Some scholars explain the “export productivity paradox” of Chinese enterprises by that the paradox comes from two aspects; first, the heterogeneity of the terms of trade and foreign trade cost; and second, the particularity of China’s trade, that is, the comparative advantage of surplus [40].
The existing literature provides a reference point for this study, but it has some shortcomings. First, most studies on China’s agricultural TFP are focused on the agricultural industry, and most of the data used are from China’s statistical yearbooks, with few studies from the level of agricultural enterprises, only Liu et al. (2018) and Jia et al. (2018) measure and compare the TFP of agricultural enterprises [1,41], and there is a lack of the comparison of TFP to specific agricultural industries. Second, from the perspective of the relationship between export and productivity, although some studies have confirmed the existence of the “export productivity paradox” in China’s agricultural enterprises and analyze the reasons for the existence of this “export productivity paradox”, they have not undertaken this analysis from the perspective of the composition of TFP. What is the difference of TFP between agricultural export and non-export enterprises, and is there a gap between agricultural enterprises in different regions and industries?
What causes the change in TFP? This paper focuses on whether there are differences in TFP among agricultural enterprises in different industries in China, and if so, what causes these differences. It also analyzes the TFP of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises and the impact of the components of TFP on the TFP of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises.
The structure of this paper is as follows: first, we introduce the research methods and data sources; second, we measure the TFP of agricultural enterprises and compare TFP across industries, regions, and enterprise properties; third, we present the conclusions, shortcomings, and policy suggestions arising from this research.

2. Methodology and Data

2.1. Methodology

This paper decomposed the TFP into the technical efficiency change (TEC), technical change (TC), scale efficiency change, and distribution efficiency, on the basis of the research of Si and Wang [18]. The price of products is an important factor in calculating TFP, but our data does not include price statistics, so, it is difficult to calculate scale efficiency and distribution efficiency based on our data. Therefore, this paper decomposes TFP into technical progress and technical efficiency, namely the TFP index ( TFPC i t , t + 1 ) is the product of the technical progress index ( TC i t , t + 1 ) and the efficiency improvement index ( TEC i t , t + 1 ), as shown in Equation (1),
TFPC i t , t + 1 = TEC i t , t + 1 TC i t , t + 1
It can be seen from Equation (1) that measuring technical efficiency is the key. In general, technical efficiency needs to set a stochastic frontier production function, and the parameter form of the production function, the equation structure, and the setting of the error term have strict requirements, and the remaining growth except the part that can be explained by the factor contribution is regarded as the productivity. It is believed that the main reason why individual economic decision-making units cannot fall to the frontier production is the loss of technical efficiency.
According to Aigner et al. [42], and Battese and Coelli [43], the basic expression of stochastic frontier production function is as follows:
y i t = f ( X i t , t ; β ) exp ( V i t , U i t )
where i = 1, 2, I; t = 1,2,…, T; y i t is the output of the i enterprise in t period, X i t is the input vector of the i enterprise in t corresponding to y i t , t is the time trend, β is the parameter vector of stochastic frontier production function to be estimated. V i t is a random disturbance term, which is assumed to obey the normal distribution of N(0, σ v 2 ), and is independent of U i t , which represents the loss of technical efficiency caused by uncontrollable factors; U i t is the non-negative random variable of technical efficiency loss per unit t year, which is assumed to obey N( m i t , σ u 2 ), represent the influence of controllable factors on technical efficiency.
Combined with the empirical study of Coelli and Prasada [44], the stochastic frontier production function is as follows:
Ln y i t = β 0 + β j j Ln x j i t + 1 2 j j Ln x j i t Ln x j i t + β 1 j t Ln x j i t + β 13 t + 1 2 β 14 t 2 + ( v i t u i t )
where, y i t is the level of sales revenue of i enterprise in t period, x 1 i t , x 2 i t ,   x 3 i t are the capital input, labor input, and raw material input of i enterprise in t period, t is the time trend of technical progress change, β is the estimated parameter, v i t , u i t are the random error term and the technical inefficiency term respectively, v i t and u i t is independent of each other.
Stata is a kind of statistical software, scholars use the software to write the corresponding program language for the measurement and analysis of TFP. This paper use Stata15.0 software) to measure the technical efficiency, namely
TE i t = E ( y i t * | u i t ,   X i t ) E ( y i t * | u i t = 0 ,   X i t ) = exp ( u i t )  
where, TE i t represents the technical efficiency of i enterprise in the period t ; E() is the expected value of the mathematical formula in parentheses; when the logarithm of actual output is used as the dependent variable, y i t * is equal to EXP( y i t ). The technical efficiency change value is the ratio of the technical efficiency value between the t + 1 and t , as shown in Equation (5):
  TEC i t , t + 1 = TE i , t + 1 TE i t
The change of technological progress is derived from Equation (2),
TC i t = E ( y i t * | u i t ,   X i t ) E ( y i t * | u i t = 0 ,   X i t )
The technological progress index is:
TC i t , t + 1 = exp { 1 2 [ Ln y i t t + Ln y i , t + 1 ( t + 1 ) ] }
where, Formula (7)   TC i t , TC i t , t + 1 respectively represents the technological progress rate and technological progress index in t period.

2.2. Data

The relevant index data of agricultural enterprises used in this paper come from the data of 1145 state-level leading agricultural enterprises from 2016 to 2017, and a total of 2290 enterprise samples of annual data are obtained. The sample is representative for the following reasons: first, the export of sample enterprises is an important part of the export of China’s agricultural enterprises. The data showed, the number of agricultural exporting enterprises accounts for 37.5% of the total number of agricultural leading enterprises, and the export volume of 1145 agricultural enterprises accounts for 18.7% of China’s agricultural export. Second, the productivity of sample enterprises is high. Leading agricultural enterprises have become the leader in the development of agricultural enterprises. At present, there are more than 90,000 agricultural enterprises in China, including 1542 agricultural leading enterprises, the sample enterprises account for 74% of the total number of agricultural leading enterprises. We discuss agricultural leading enterprises from the regional perspective, China’s eastern region includes Beijing, Tianjin, Hebei, Liaoning, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, and Guangdong. China’s central region includes Shanxi, Jilin, Heilongjiang, Anhui, Jiangxi, Henan, Hubei, and Hunan. China’s western region includes Chongqing, Sichuan, Guizhou, Yunnan, Xizang, Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai, Ningxia and Xinjiang Guangxi, Inner Mongolia, and Hainan.According to the regional division, Hainan should belong to the eastern region. However, in the evaluation process of national leading enterprises in agricultural industrialization, Hainan is included in the western region with reference to the standards of national leading enterprises in the western region.The number of agricultural leading enterprises in the eastern, central, and western regions is 441, 348, and 356, respectively) We discuss agricultural leading enterprises from the perspective of enterprise properties, agricultural enterprises are divided into three types: collective, private, and foreign enterprises, the number of collective, private, and foreign-owned agricultural leading enterprises is 156, 940, and 49, respectively. We discuss agricultural leading enterprises from the perspective of industry distribution, agricultural enterprises include 15 categories, such as grain (including feed), eggs, milk, meat, tea, flowers, forestry, cotton, flax and silk, furriery, vegetables, aquatic products, fruits, sugar, oil and medicinal materials. Egg, milk, and meat enterprises are classified as animal husbandry enterprises. In terms of sample distribution, the number of grain and animal husbandry enterprises is large, and the number of all kinds of agricultural enterprises except grain and animal husbandry enterprises is small. They are merged into other types of enterprises. Therefore, this paper forms the sample of grain, animal husbandry, and other types of enterprises, the number of animal husbandry, grain, and other agricultural leading enterprises is 271, 274, and 600, respectively.
From the comparison of whether agricultural enterprises export or not (see Table 1), the number of grain and animal husbandry exporting enterprises account for 23.36% and 31.00% of the total number of sample enterprises, respectively, while the proportion of other exporting enterprises is higher, which is 46.83%; and the proportion of exports to sales is 2.94%, 2.75%, and 13.5%, respectively. The export of private enterprises is an important part of the export of China’s agricultural leading enterprises. There are about 339 private enterprises that export, accounting for 36% of the total number of private agricultural leading enterprises, and their export volume accounts for 73.3% of the total export of agricultural leading enterprises. The number of foreign-funded agricultural export enterprises accounts for the highest proportion of the total number of agricultural enterprises, but due to the small number of foreign-funded agricultural exporting enterprises, the proportion of their exports is the lowest. In terms of the proportion of export and domestic sales of agricultural enterprises, most of their products are sold in China’s domestic market. The export of leading agricultural enterprises accounts for only 5.61% of their sales revenue, and that of private enterprises in their sales revenue is the highest, which is 9.33%, while that of collective enterprises is relatively low. The export volume of grain and animal husbandry enterprises accounts for 2.94% and 2.75% of the sales revenue of similar enterprises, respectively.

3. Results

3.1. Index Selection and Measurement

This paper refers to the research results of Wang and Wang (2017), Gai et al. (2011), Yu (2010), Dai et al. (2016), etc. [34,45,46,47], and regards the output index as the sales income of enterprises, which reflect the production and operating conditions of enterprises and their scale. The input index includes capital, labor, and intermediate inputs, which reflect the enterprise scale and resource utilization. Capital, labor, and intermediate inputs are presented by total assets, number of employees, and raw material inputs of the enterprise, enterprise employment is divided into two parts: perennial employment and seasonal employment. This paper mainly considers perennial employment. Different from Gai et al. (2011) and Yang (2015)’s literature, the sales revenue of enterprises is not deflated by price index. The reason is that the sample time sequence used in this paper is short, and there are many kinds of agricultural industries, thus, it is not appropriate to use a unified price index of agricultural products. The statistical description of each index is shown in Table 2.
Using the maximum likelihood ratio test, the adoption of the translog production function can better reflect the input–output relationship of agricultural leading enterprises, and agricultural leading enterprises have losses of technical efficiency. Table 3 presents the estimation results of the production function model generated using Stata15.0 software.
From the estimation results of the stochastic frontier production function model, we see that capital have a positive impact on the output of agricultural leading enterprises and pass the 1% significance level test; labor input has no significant impact on the output of agricultural leading enterprises; and raw material input has a positive impact on the output of agricultural leading enterprises, passing the 5% significance level test. The maximum likelihood ratio test results show that the translog production function can better reflect the input–output relationship of agricultural leading enterprises than other types of production function. Lambda has passed the 1% significance level test, which shows that there is a loss of technical efficiency in the production process.

3.2. Measurement and Comparison of TFP

Using the estimation results of the stochastic frontier production function and Equations (1), (5), and (7), we calculate the technical efficiency index, technical progress index, and TFP index of 2290 sample enterprises from 2016 to 2017.

3.2.1. Overall Perspective Comparison

The TFP and technical progress of agricultural enterprises show a downward trend, technical efficiency shows improvement, and technical progress shows a downward trend. The degree of improvement in technical efficiency is less than the degree of technology regression; the technical progress rate of agricultural enterprises decreases by 1.9% and the rate of technical efficiency improvement increases by 0.1% (see Table 4). The root of the decline of the TFP of agricultural enterprises is the regression of enterprise technology. This is similar to Zhao et al.’s (2008) research conclusion, that is, the TFP of China’s agricultural processing industry is mainly driven by technical progress [48]. Mizobuchi (2015) also points out that technical progress is an important source of TFP growth [49].
Considering different industries, we see that the change of the TFP of agricultural enterprises is the same. The TFP index of animal husbandry enterprises is higher than that of grain and other enterprises. The technological progress rate and technical efficiency of grain and animal husbandry enterprises shows the opposite trend, while the changing direction of the technological progress rate and the technical efficiency of other types of agricultural enterprises is the same. The technological progress rate of grain, animal husbandry, and other enterprises decreased by 2.3%, 2.0%, and 1.6%, respectively, and the technological efficiency of grain, animal husbandry, and other enterprises increased by 0.3%, 0.6%, and −0.3%, respectively.
Considering different enterprise properties, the TFP is in a declining state. The TFP index of foreign-funded agricultural enterprises is higher than that of collective and private enterprises, which also shows that TFP fluctuations are more obvious for collective and private agricultural enterprises. Yang (2015) also draws a similar conclusion based on the data of industrial enterprises, which is that the technical efficiency of collective and private enterprises is relatively low [50]. As for collective agricultural enterprises, aside from the technical progress index, which is higher than the average level by 0.6 percentage points, the other indexes are below average. As for private agricultural enterprises, aside from the technical efficiency index, which is equal to the average level, the other indexes are below average. For foreign-funded agricultural enterprises, the technical efficiency index, technical progress index, and TFP index are above the average level of all agricultural leading enterprises.

3.2.2. Comparison between Agricultural Exporting Enterprises and Non-Exporting Enterprises

The TFP of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises shows a downward trend, and the TFP of exporting enterprises shows a significant downturn: the TFP of exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises decreases by 2% and 1.7%, respectively. The TFP, technical progress, and technical efficiency indices of agricultural exporting enterprises are 0.980, 0.983, and 0.997, respectively. For non-exporting enterprises, technical efficiency increases by 0.3% and the TFP and technological progress rate show a downward trend (see Table 5). According to the existing research on the relationship between the export of Chinese enterprises and TFP, export is not an important factor to promote the growth of enterprises’ TFP [51]; and even export has a negative impact on the productivity of Chinese enterprises [52,53].
From the industry point of view, the TFP of all kinds of exporting enterprises is lower than that of the same type of non-exporting enterprises. Agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises show a downward trend in technological progress, with the technological progress rate of grain, animal husbandry, and other agricultural exporting enterprises decreasing by 1.9%, 1.9%, and 1.6%, respectively, while that of grain, animal husbandry, and other agricultural non-exporting enterprises decreases by 2.5%, 2.1%, and 1.6%, respectively. The technical efficiency of grain, animal husbandry, and other agricultural exporting enterprises is deteriorating by 0.5%, 0.2%, and 0.2%, respectively. For agricultural non-exporting enterprises, aside from the deterioration of the other agricultural non-exporting enterprises, the technical efficiency of grain and animal husbandry enterprises is on the rise, with an increase of 0.6% and 1.0%, respectively.
From the perspective of enterprise properties, the TFP growth rate of collective and foreign-funded agricultural exporting enterprises is greater than that of non-exporting enterprises, and the TFP growth rate of private agricultural exporting enterprises is less than that of non-exporting enterprises. The TFP index of foreign-funded agricultural exporting enterprises is higher than that of foreign-funded agricultural non-exporting enterprises, and the TFP of foreign-funded agricultural exporting enterprises is increasing. Foreign-funded agricultural enterprise exporters show an increasing trend in technical efficiency and a decrease in technical progress. The technical efficiency of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises increases by 2.2% and 0.3%, respectively, and the technical progress rates decrease by 2.0% and 1.6%, respectively.
The overall TE of agricultural enterprises is high, and the sample size of agricultural leading enterprises with TE greater than 0.700 is 1031, accounting for 90.04% of the total sample size (see Table 6). The difference between the TFP index of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises decreases with the increase of the average TE of enterprises, and even the growth rate of the TFP of exporting enterprises is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises. The direction and degree of the effect of technical efficiency of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises on TFP change with the change of average TE levels. Bao et al. (2003) argue that the influence of export on TFP comes from the improvement of production effect of exporting sector and technology spillover to non-exporting sector, which also implies that technical efficiency is an important factor to improve TFP of exporting enterprises [54]. Finicelli et al. (2010) argue that the increase in TFP is usually associated with knowledge accumulation in technological innovation and R&D investment, from the viewpoint of innovation [55].
When the TE of enterprises is less than 0.6, the technical efficiency of both exporting and non-exporting enterprises deteriorates, and the deterioration degree of technical efficiency of agricultural exporting enterprises is greater than that of non-exporting enterprises. When the TE of enterprises ℇ[0.6,0.7), TE of agricultural exporting enterprises decreases by 0.9%. Conversely, the TE of agricultural no-exporting enterprises increases by 0.8%. When the TE of enterprises ℇ[0.7,0.8), the TE of agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises improve by 0.3% and 1.0%, respectively. When the TE of agricultural enterprises is greater than 0.8, the TE of agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises increase, but improvements in the TE of agricultural exporting enterprises is less than that of non-exporting enterprises, and the average value of the technical efficiency of agricultural exporting enterprises increase. When the TE of agricultural enterprises is greater than 0.9, the TFP growth rate of agricultural exporting enterprises is 0.1%.

3.2.3. Comparison of Agricultural Exporting and Non-Exporting Enterprises in Different Provinces

The TFP index of agricultural exporting enterprises in the eastern and western regions is less than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while the central region is the opposite. The results show that the trend of TFP of agricultural enterprises is similar to that of technical efficiency. The gap between the TFP index, the technical efficiency index, and the technical progress index of exporting and non-exporting enterprises in central China is the smallest. Therefore, the difference of TFP changes between exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises is mainly due to the change of technical efficiency. The gap between the TFP index, the technical efficiency index, and the technical progress index of exporting and non-exporting enterprises is the largest in the western region, followed by the eastern region, and the smallest in the central region.
In the eastern region, the TFP index of agricultural exporting enterprises in Shandong, Zhejiang, Guangdong, and Liaoning is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while in other provinces it is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 1). In Shandong, Zhejiang, Guangdong, and Liaoning, the technical efficiency index of agricultural exporting enterprises is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while in other provinces it is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 2). Except in Guangdong, the technological progress index of agricultural exporting enterprises is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises. In all other provinces and cities the technological progress index of exporting enterprises is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 3). The key to the comparison of the TFP index between agricultural exporting and non-exporting enterprises lies in the comparison of the technical efficiency index. Changes in technical efficiency are the main factor affecting the change of TFP of agricultural enterprises.
In the central region, the TFP index of agricultural exporting enterprises in Hubei, Anhui, Henan, Hunan, Shanxi, and Jilin is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while in other provinces it is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 1). The technical efficiency index of agricultural exporting enterprises in Anhui, Henan, Hunan, Shanxi, and Jilin is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while in other provinces and cities it is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 2). Except for Jiangxi and Jilin, the technological progress index of agricultural exporting enterprises is lower than that of non-exporting enterprises, and in other provinces and cities it is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 3).
In the western region, the TFP index of agricultural exporting enterprises in Sichuan, Chongqing, Shaanxi, Ningxia, and Gansu is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while the TFP index of other provinces is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 1). At the same time, the technical efficiency index of agricultural exporting enterprises in Sichuan, Chongqing, Shaanxi, Ningxia, and Gansu is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, while in other provinces and cities it is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 2). Except Ningxia, Gansu, and Guizhou, the technological progress index of agricultural exporting enterprises is lower than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises, and in other provinces and cities it is higher than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises (see Figure 3).

3.3. Robustness Test

A single simple additive weighting (SAW) will lead to different calculation results. Referring to Yang’s (2016) TFP calculation method [50], this paper measures the TFP index, technical efficiency index, and technical progress index of enterprises with sales income of agricultural enterprises as the weight. On the whole (see Table 7), although the value has changed, the basic conclusion remains the same. In general, the TFP of exporting enterprises is growing, and the growth rate of the TFP of exporting enterprises is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises. In different industries, the growth rate of TFP of grain and other exporting enterprises is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises, and that of animal husbandry exporting enterprises is lower than that of non-exporting enterprises. From the perspective of different enterprise properties, the TFP growth rate of collective exporting enterprises is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises, while the TFP growth rate of foreign-funded and private exporting enterprises is lower than that of non-exporting enterprises.

4. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations

Based on the data of state-level leading agricultural enterprises from 2016 to 2017, this paper uses the SFA-Malmquist method to decompose and compare the TFP of China’s agricultural exporting enterprises and obtains the following conclusions. First, China’s agricultural TFP shows a negative growth trend, and the growth rate of the TFP of agricultural exporting enterprises is less than that of agricultural non-exporting enterprises. The technical progress rate of agricultural enterprises shows a downward trend, therefore, the fundamental reason for the change of China’s agricultural TFP lies in the change of enterprise technical progress. Second, the TFP growth rates of agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in different industries and enterprise property are significantly different. The growth rate of TFP of grain and animal husbandry exporting enterprises is lower than that of non-exporting enterprises. The TFP growth rates of collective exporting enterprises is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises. The TFP growth rates of private exporting enterprises is lower than that of non-exporting enterprises. The TFP growth rate of foreign-funded enterprises is positive, which is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises. Third, the TFP growth rate of exporting enterprises in the eastern and western regions is lower than that of non-exporting enterprises, and that of exporting enterprises in the central region is higher than that of non-exporting enterprises. The gap between the TFP index, the technical efficiency index, and the technical progress index of exporting and non-exporting enterprises in the central region is the smallest, whether or not the enterprises in these three regions are exporting. However, the gap between the TFP index and technical efficiency index of exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises is the largest in the western region.
Further discussion is presented as follows. First, there are limitations to this study’s sample of agricultural enterprises. Our sample data has a short time sequence that cannot analyze the trends of TFP growth rate. With the change of economic cycle, the growth rate of productivity may accelerate [56], and it may take longer for technology to spread and develop its potential, which may have a certain impact on the research conclusions of this paper. In addition, the data on state-level leading agricultural enterprises may not represent the overall characteristics of changes in agricultural enterprises. However, our data has certain representativeness for agricultural exporting enterprises. Therefore, this paper focuses on the comparison of TFP of different industries, regions, and enterprise property of agricultural exporting enterprises, and judges the contribution of technical progress and technical efficiency to the change of TFP of agricultural enterprises. Second, many scholars have found that there is an “exporting productivity paradox” in Chinese enterprises, which still exists in agricultural enterprises. This paper focuses on the growth rate and decomposition of TFP, which is different from previous research that uses more data from the China Statistical Yearbook. This paper uses the sample of agricultural enterprises as an emphasis point sample, which allows us to analyze China’s agricultural TFP from another level and provide other evidence.
At last, policy implications are discussed in the last part of this paper. First, it is needed to increase the R&D investment of enterprises, to improve the agricultural scientific and technical level, and the technical progress rate of agricultural enterprises. In addition, agricultural enterprises should strengthen cooperation with research institutions to improve the conversion rate of agricultural scientific achievements. Second, the change of technical efficiency is an important factor in the change of TFP, especially agricultural export enterprises, so it is necessary to further optimize the allocation of enterprise factors, especially to improve the substitute elasticity of labor, capital, and raw materials. Third, private enterprises are an important part of China’s agricultural enterprises, and the export of private enterprises is also an important part of the export of agricultural products. However, the TFP of private enterprises is low. Therefore, it is needed to increase support policies and investment from government. From the regional level, the government should support the development of agricultural enterprises in the western region of China, and the central region and the western region should actively dock with the technology transfer in the eastern region. Fourth, China’s domestic market segmentation and high productivity are the important causes of the “export productivity paradox”. The government should try to take measures to eliminate the segmentation, encourage agricultural enterprises with competitive advantages and high productivity to export, especially those with high technology and high value-added products, and improve the competitiveness of China’s agricultural trade.

Author Contributions

Q.F. and W.J. were responsible for the research methods. Q.F. and W.J. are responsible for data investigation and data sorting; Q.F., T.M. and W.J. completed the first draft of the paper; Q.F. and W.J. were in charge of proofreading manuscripts. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The Agricultural Science and Technology Innovation Program (ASTIP-IAED-2021-SR-02). Central Public-interest Scientific Institution Basal Research Fund (No. Y2018ZK40).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The specific data of the survey samples cannot be made public.

Acknowledgments

Thanks to Liming Wang, Xiaolong Sun, Jieling Zou, Peifang Zhao for participating in our survey.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Jia, W.; Wang, L.M.; Mao, X.F.; Qin, F. Is there an “export productivity paradox” in Chinese agricultural enterprises? Chin. Rural Econ. 2018, 3, 45–60. [Google Scholar]
  2. Solow, R.M. Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1957, 39, 554–562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Denison, E.F. Why Growth Rates Differ: Post-War Experience in Nine Western Countries; Washington Brookings Institution: Washington, DC, USA, 1967. [Google Scholar]
  4. Jorgenson, D.W.; Griliches, Z. The Explanation of Productivity Change. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1967, 34, 249–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Klenow, P.; Rodriguez-Clare, A. The Neoclassical Revival in Growth Economics: Has It Gone Too Far? In NBER Macroeconomics Annual; Bernanke, B., Rotemberg, J., Eds.; MIT Press: Cambrige, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  6. Hall, R.; Jones, C. Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Workers than Others? Q. J. Econ. 1999, 114, 83–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Comin, D.; Hobijn, B. An Exploration of Technology Diffusion. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 2031–2059. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Bollard, A.; Klenow, P.J.; Li, H. Entry Costs Rise with Development; Working paper No. 518; Stanford University: Stanford, CA, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  9. Zhao, W.; Cheng, J. Re-examination of China’s Agricultural Total Factor Productivity—Revision of Basic Data and Comparison of Two Methods. Chin. Rural. Econ. 2011, 10, 4–15. [Google Scholar]
  10. Zhu, X.; Shi, Q.H.; Gai, Q.G. Factor allocation distortion and agricultural total factor productivity. Econ. Res. J. 2011, 46, 86–98. [Google Scholar]
  11. Li, H.; Yao, S.B.; Guo, Y.J. An Empirical Analysis on the Growth of Agricultural Total Factor Productivity of Farmers with Different Scales of Returning Farmland—Based on the Survey Data of Farmers in the Loess Plateau. Chin. Rural Econ. 2011, 10, 36–43. [Google Scholar]
  12. Zhang, L.; Cao, J. Total factor productivity growth in China’s agriculture: Introduction of changes in allocation efficiency—empirical analysis based on stochastic frontier production function. Chin. Rural Econ. 2013, 3, 4–15. [Google Scholar]
  13. Wang, J.; Song, W.F.; Han, X.F. Spatial Econometric Analysis of China’s Agricultural Total Factor Productivity and Its Influencing Factors—Based on Provincial Spatial Panel Data from 1992 to 2007. Chin. Rural Econ. 2010, 8, 24–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Fu, M.H.; Qi, C.J. Factor endowment, technological progress bias and agricultural TFP Growth: A comparative analysis based on 28 countries. Chin. Rural Econ. 2016, 12, 76–90. [Google Scholar]
  15. Lu, X.D.; Lian, Y.J. Estimation of total factor productivity of Industrial Enterprises in China: 1999–2007. China Econ. Q. 2012, 11, 541–558. [Google Scholar]
  16. Yan, Z.J.; Yu, J.P. Government subsidy and firms’ total factor productivity: A comparative analysis of emerging industry and traditional manufacturing industry. Ind. Econ. Res. 2017, 1, 1–13. [Google Scholar]
  17. Hu, C.Y.; Yu, Y.Z. Government subsidies and enterprises’ TFP—A theoretical explanation and empirical analysis of U-Curve effect. Public Financ. Res. 2019, 6, 72–85. [Google Scholar]
  18. Si, W.; Wang, J.M. Total factor productivity of soybean production and its changes in China. Chin. Rural Econ. 2011, 10, 16–25. [Google Scholar]
  19. Han, Z.; Yang, C.; Zhao, X.X. Analysis on total factor productivity of mutton sheep breeding in pastoral areas under Ecological compensation and reward mechanism. J. Agrotech. Econ. 2019, 11, 116–126. [Google Scholar]
  20. Chen, J.C.; Wang, H.M.; Zhang, J. Research on agricultural insurance development and agricultural TFP growth in China. Rural Econ. 2016, 3, 83–88. [Google Scholar]
  21. Delpachitra, S.; Van Dai, P. The determinants of TFP growth in middle income economies in ASEAN: Implication of financial crises. Int. J. Bus. Econ. 2012, 11, 63. [Google Scholar]
  22. Li, S.M.; Yin, X.W. Analysis on the impact of China’s rural labor transfer on agricultural total factor productivity. J. Agrotech. Econ. 2017, 9, 4–13. [Google Scholar]
  23. Deng, X.L.; Yan, W.B. Spillover effects of rural infrastructure on agricultural total factor productivity in China. Financ. Trade Res. 2018, 29, 36–45. [Google Scholar]
  24. Fang, F.Q.; Zhang, Y.L. Analysis of changes in China’s agricultural total factor productivity and its influencing factors—Based on the Malmquist index method from 1991 to 2008. Econ. Theory Bus. Manag. 2010, 9, 5–12. [Google Scholar]
  25. Yin, C.J.; Li, G.C.; Fan, L.X.; Gao, X. Climate change, technological stock and agricultural productivity growth. Chin. Rural Econ. 2016, 5, 16–28. [Google Scholar]
  26. Li, X.P.; Lu, X.X.; Zhu, Z.D. International trade, technological progress and productivity growth of Chinese industries. China Econ. Q. 2008, 2, 549–564. [Google Scholar]
  27. Ye, Z. Why do Chinese exporting enterprises have higher productivity? —Evidence from Jiangsu Province. Financ. Trade Econ. 2010, 5, 77–81. [Google Scholar]
  28. Qian, X.F.; Wang, J.R.; Huang, Y.H.; Wang, S. Exports and productivity of Chinese Industrial Enterprises: Self-selection effect or learning by exporting effect? J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2011, 28, 37–51. [Google Scholar]
  29. Castellani, D. Export Behavior and Productivity Growth: Evidence from Italian Manufacturing Firms. Weltwirtschaftaliches Arch. 2002, 138, 605–628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Aw, B.Y.; Hwang, A.R. Productivity and the Export Market: A Firm-level Analysis. J. Dev. Econ. 2004, 47, 313–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Greenaway, D.; Gullstrand, J.; Kneller, R. Exporting May Not Always Boost Firm Productivity. Rev. World Econ. 2005, 141, 561–582. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Li, C.D.; Yin, X.S. Chinese export firms’ “Productivity paradox” and its explanation. Financ. Trade Econ. 2009, 11, 84–90. [Google Scholar]
  33. Lu, J.Y.; Lu, Y.; Tao, Z.G. Exporting Behavior of Foreign Affiliates: Theory and Evidence. J. Int. Econ. 2010, 81, 197–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Dai, M.; Maitra, M.; Yu, M. Unexceptional Exporter Performance in China? The Role of Processing Trade. J. Dev. Econ. 2016, 121, 177–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Tang, E.Z. Chinese firms’ “export-productivity paradox”: Theory extending and testing again. Manag. World. 2017, 2, 30–42. [Google Scholar]
  36. Fan, J.Y.; Feng, M. The paradox of productivity of Chinese manufacturing export enterprises: A test based on the difference of export density. Manag. World. 2013, 8, 16–29. [Google Scholar]
  37. Sheng, D. Local administrative monopoly and the “productivity paradox” of Chinese firms. Ind. Econ. Research. 2013, 4, 70–80. [Google Scholar]
  38. Zhang, K.; Hou, W.Z.; Liu, L. Does the Chinese enterprises have “Export-Productivity Paradox”?—The comparative analysis based on different trade state. Ind. Econ. Res. 2016, 1, 30–39. [Google Scholar]
  39. Nie, W.X.; Zhu, L.X. Impact of enterprise productivity on export trade: An analysis on productivity paradox from dynamic perspective. J. Int. Trade. 2013, 12, 24–35. [Google Scholar]
  40. Wang, P.Z.; Sun, L.P.; Zhang, S.Y. The Interpretations of China’s Exports-Productivity Paradox and Policy Implications. In Proceedings of the 4th Annual International Conference on Management, Economics and Social Development (ICMESD 2018), Xi’an, China, 18–20 May 2018. [Google Scholar]
  41. Liu, N.X.; Han, Y.J.; Wang, P.P. Does FDI increase the total factor productivity of Chinese agricultural enterprises?—Evidence from panel data of 99801 agricultural enterprises. Chin. Rural Econ. 2018, 4, 90–105. [Google Scholar]
  42. Aigner, D.; Lovell, C.A.K.; Schmidt, P. Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. J. Econom. 1977, 6, 21–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Battese, G.E.; Coelli, T.J. A model for technical inefficiency effects in a stochastic frontier production function for panel data. Empir. Econ. 1995, 20, 325–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Coelli, T.J.; Prasada Rao, D.S. Total Factor Productivity Growth in Agriculture: A Malmquist Index Analysis of 93 Countries, 1980-2000. Agric. Econ. 2005, 32, 115–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  45. Wang, Y.B.; Wang, L.M. The impact of industrial clusters on the technical efficiency of agricultural enterprises-based on the data of key leading enterprises in agricultural industrialization. J. Agrotech. Econ. 2017, 3, 109–119. [Google Scholar]
  46. Gai, Q.E.; Zhu, X.; Cheng, M.W.; Shi, Q.H. Distortion of Factor Market, Monopoly Power and Total Factor Productivity. Econ. Res. J. 2015, 50, 61–75. [Google Scholar]
  47. Yu, M.J. Trade Liberalization and Productivity: Evidence from Chinese Firms. Econ. Res. J. 2010, 45, 97–110. [Google Scholar]
  48. Zhao, R.; Luo, L.; Han, P. Technical efficiency, technological progress and productivity growth of China’s agricultural product processing industry. Chin. Rural Econ. 2008, 4, 24–32. [Google Scholar]
  49. Mizobuchi, H. Multiple Directions for Measuring Biased Technical Change; CEPA Working Papers, No. WP09; School of Economics, University of Queensland: St. Lucia, Australia, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  50. Yang, R.D. Research on Total Factor Productivity of Chinese Manufacturing Enterprises. Econ. Res. J. 2015, 50, 61–74. [Google Scholar]
  51. Zhang, J.; Li, Y.; Liu, Z.B. Exports and the Productivity of Chinese Local Enterprises—Based on the Empirical Analysis of Jiangsu Manufacturing Enterprises. Manag World 2008, 11, 50–64. [Google Scholar]
  52. Li, C.D. Whether there is a “productivity paradox” in Chinese export companies: A test based on the data of Chinese manufacturing companies. J. World Econ. 2010, 33, 64–81. [Google Scholar]
  53. Liu, H.Y.; Tang, E.Z. Data verification of whether encouraging exports can promote the increase of enterprise productivity. Mod. Financ. Econ. 2011, 31, 108–119. [Google Scholar]
  54. Bao, Q.; Xu, H.L.; Lai, M.Y. How does export trade promote economic growth?—An empirical study based on total factor productivity. Shanghai J. Econ. 2003, 3, 3–10. [Google Scholar]
  55. Finicelli, A.; Pagano, P.; Sbracia, M. Trade-Revealed TFP. J. Policy Anal. Manag. 2010, 29, 267–284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Spithoven, A.H.G.M. The productivity paradox and the business cycle. Int. J. Soc. Econ. 2003, 30, 679–699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Comparison of TFPC between agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in China.
Figure 1. Comparison of TFPC between agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in China.
Sustainability 13 06855 g001
Figure 2. Comparison of TEC between agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in China.
Figure 2. Comparison of TEC between agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in China.
Sustainability 13 06855 g002
Figure 3. Comparison of TC between agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in China.
Figure 3. Comparison of TC between agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises in China.
Sustainability 13 06855 g003
Table 1. Comparison of sample distribution between agricultural export and non-export enterprises. Unit: $10 thousand.
Table 1. Comparison of sample distribution between agricultural export and non-export enterprises. Unit: $10 thousand.
Exporting EnterpriseNon-Exporting Enterprise
TotalN1P1 (%)Export valueP2 (%)N2P3 (%)
42937.473285.405.6171662.53
IndustryGrain6423.365148.332.9421076.64
Animal husbandry8431.002420.142.7518769.00
Others28146.833133.0213.5031953.17
Enterprise propertyCollective6441.034665.312.459258.97
Private33936.063049.259.3360163.94
Foreign-funded2653.062949.564.112346.94
Note: The data was compiled by the author. N1 and N2 respectively represent the number of various types of agricultural export enterprises and non-export enterprises. P1 and P3 were the ratio of the number of agricultural export and non-export enterprises to the total agricultural enterprises, respectively. P2 is the ratio of agricultural enterprise exports to sales revenue.
Table 2. Descriptive statistical analysis of input and output indicators.
Table 2. Descriptive statistical analysis of input and output indicators.
Variable NameVariable SymbolsMean ValueStandard DeviationMinimumMaximum
OutputLn y i t 11.1581.2788.50617.706
Capital Ln x 1 i t 11.2021.2588.55717.851
Labor Ln x 2 i t 6.6021.2732.70811.668
Intermediate inputs Ln x 3 i t 10.0852.693−6.91015.510
Note: The units of sales income, total assets, and purchasing-amount of raw materials of enterprises are ten thousand yuan, and the units of the number of employees of enterprises are people and have been calculated using logarithm.
Table 3. Stochastic frontier production function model estimation results.
Table 3. Stochastic frontier production function model estimation results.
Explanatory VariablesCoefficientSDP
Ln x 1 i t 0.3807 **0.14990.011
Ln x 2 i t −0.07510.12510.548
Ln x 3 i t 0.2239 **0.09150.014
( Ln x 1 i t )^20.0549 **0.02190.012
( Ln x 2 i t )^20.00850.01440.555
( Ln x 3 i t )^20.1743 ***0.01090.000
( Ln x 1 i t ) × ( Ln x 2 i t )0.1421 ***0.03300.000
( Ln x 1 i t ) × ( Ln x 3 i t )−0.2098 ***0.02200.000
( Ln x 2 i t ) × ( Ln x 3 i t )−0.1190 ***0.02030.000
t Ln x 1 i t 0.00850.02470.731
t Ln x 2 i t 0.00500.02320.830
t Ln x 3 i t −0.01000.01880.593
t −0.04320.19750.827
t ^2
_cons3.2153 ***0.75910.000
Sigma20.2428 ***0.0079
lambda0.6405 ***0.0244
Note: **, *** significance levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Table 4. The change and decomposition of TFP of leading agricultural enterprises from 2016 to 2017.
Table 4. The change and decomposition of TFP of leading agricultural enterprises from 2016 to 2017.
TECTCTFPC
Total1.0010.9810.982
IndustryGrain1.0030.9770.980
Animal husbandry1.0060.9800.986
Others0.9970.9840.981
Enterprise propertyCollective0.9950.9870.982
Private1.0010.9800.981
Foreign-funded1.0130.9820.995
Table 5. The decomposition and comparison of TFP of agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises.
Table 5. The decomposition and comparison of TFP of agricultural exporting enterprises and non-exporting enterprises.
Exporting EnterpriseNon-Exporting Enterprise
TECTCTFPCTECTCTFPC
Total0.9970.9830.9801.0030.9800.983
IndustryGrain0.9950.9810.9761.0060.9750.981
Animal husbandry0.9980.9810.9791.0100.9790.989
Others0.9980.9840.9820.9980.9840.982
Enterprise propertyCollective0.9940.9910.9850.9950.9840.979
Private0.9960.9820.9781.0040.9790.983
Foreign-funded1.0220.9801.0021.0030.9840.987
Table 6. The decomposition of TFP and exporting of agricultural leading enterprises.
Table 6. The decomposition of TFP and exporting of agricultural leading enterprises.
The Range of TEExporting EnterpriseNon-Exporting Enterprise
Enterprises QuantityATETECTCTFPCEnterprises QuantityATETECTCTFPC
(0,0.6)140.4150.8450.9930.839370.4420.9390.9900.930
[0.6,0.7)270.6590.9910.9860.977360.6611.0080.9850.993
[0.7,0.8)1470.7651.0030.9830.9862260.7661.0100.9800.990
[0.8,0.9)2310.8411.0040.9810.9853900.8411.0040.9790.983
[0.9,1.0)100.9161.0050.9961.001270.9111.0030.9860.989
Notes: ATE is Average technical efficiency of enterprise; the data in the Table 6 was based on technical efficiency in 2017.
Table 7. The decomposition of TFP and exporting of agricultural leading enterprises. Based on weighted average method.
Table 7. The decomposition of TFP and exporting of agricultural leading enterprises. Based on weighted average method.
Exporting EnterpriseNon-Exporting Enterprise
TECTCTFPCTECTCTFPC
Total0.9981.0051.0030.9990.9850.984
IndustryGrain0.9981.0191.0170.9960.9810.977
Animal husbandry0.9910.9940.9841.0070.9900.997
Others1.0070.9920.9990.9980.9870.985
Enterprise propertyCollective1.0031.0231.0261.0010.9960.997
Private0.9920.9880.9800.9990.9820.981
Foreign-funded1.0020.9850.9861.0020.9920.994
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Fan, Q.; Mu, T.; Jia, W. Analysis on the Trend and Factors of Total Factor Productivity of Agricultural Export Enterprises in China. Sustainability 2021, 13, 6855. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13126855

AMA Style

Fan Q, Mu T, Jia W. Analysis on the Trend and Factors of Total Factor Productivity of Agricultural Export Enterprises in China. Sustainability. 2021; 13(12):6855. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13126855

Chicago/Turabian Style

Fan, Qinqin, Tianyuan Mu, and Wei Jia. 2021. "Analysis on the Trend and Factors of Total Factor Productivity of Agricultural Export Enterprises in China" Sustainability 13, no. 12: 6855. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13126855

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop