Next Article in Journal
Safety Contributions, Events and Operating Context as Criteria in Safety Awards: A Case Study from a Large Organisation
Previous Article in Journal
Visitors’ Perception of the Overcrowding of a Protected Natural Area: A Case Applied to the Natural Reserve “Garganta de los Infiernos” (Caceres, Spain)
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Policy Analyses on Promoting the Recycling of Express Packages

1
School of Management, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang 212013, China
2
School of Mathematical Science, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang 212013, China
3
Institute of Applied System Analysis, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang 212013, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2020, 12(22), 9504; https://doi.org/10.3390/su12229504
Submission received: 23 September 2020 / Revised: 8 November 2020 / Accepted: 9 November 2020 / Published: 15 November 2020

Abstract

:
With the development of e-commerce industry, the express enterprises are growing up rapidly. At the same time, they produce a large amount of express packaging garbage. The recycling of express packages has become an important issue for environment protection. In this paper, three types of possible policies are discussed for consideration: subsidy, penalty, and tax reduction. We analyze the efficiency of each policy and find the conditions under which the express packaging manufacturers prefer to recycle and reprocess the used products. A two-stage model is established from the perspective of manufacturers to discuss the production and recycling strategies under the three policies. Besides, we suggest an optimal choice between subsidy and tax reduction for the government when the budget is fixed. This paper provides guidelines for the government to improve related policies on promoting the recycling of express packages.

1. Introduction

In recent years, the express industry grows up rapidly with the development of e-commerce. Grace [1] predicted that the number of global cross-border online consumers will reaching 1 billion by 2020, which is triple that that in 2014. The global e-commerce market is expected to grow at a compound annual growth rate of 19.4 % . E-commerce brings great convenience to customers, while it also produces a large amount of express packaging waste [2,3]. Packaging materials generally include paper boxes, foam cotton, woven bags, tapes, and so on [4]. Europe produces 73 million tons of packaging each year, including packaging paper, cardboard, plastics, and others [5]. Chueamuangphan et al. [6] provided reports and cases of e-commerce in Thailand, showing that the growth of e-commerce will cause the increase in solid waste and environmental issues such as global warming. In China, the express industry took more than 40 billion express orders in 2017, and only about 10% of express packages are recycled and reused [7]. These disposable materials lead to serious solid wastes and white pollution.
The environmental problems caused by express packaging garbage have attracted wide attention from scholars. Zhang et al. [8] discussed the current mainstream approaches for waste treatments, including landfill, incineration, and compost. The environmental impact of landfill for solid wastes was investigated by El-Fadel et al. [3]. They pointed out that landfill not only brings potential health threats, but also incurs fire and explosion, vegetation damage, and air pollution. For plastic packing which is known as white pollution, Liu et al. [9] showed large amounts of residual plastic film have detrimental effects on soil structure, water and nutrient transport, and crop growth, which will cause the damage of the agricultural environment and the reduction of crop yield.
How to deal with this issue is a pressing concern. Laws and regulations are necessary because of the externality of environmental behaviors. In 1991, the German government passed a packaging law that required manufacturers to recycle or dispose any packaging materials they sold. As a result, the German industry set up a “dual system” of waste collection, which picked up household packaging in parallel to the existed municipal waste-collection systems. This system greatly facilitates the recycling of packaging materials produced by manufacturers [10]. Besides, South Korea implemented the “Volume-based Waste Fee (VWF) System” in 1995 [11,12]. The “Producer Responsibility Obligations Packaging Waste Regulations” was passed by UK legislation in 1997 [13,14]. Many potential policies for the government have been explored by scholars, including subsidies [15,16], incentive strategies [17,18], punishments [19], and carbon emission tax (or “green tax”) [20,21]. Furthermore, Dong and Hua [22], Cao and Liu [23] investigated the willingness of consumers to recycle express packages. Pazoki and Zaccour [24] discussed the mechanism to promote product recovery and the impact on the environments.
In general, subsidy, penalty, and tax reduction are three main policies that the government may take to control the express packaging garbage. However, most current research focuses on the qualitative analysis. Duan et al. [7] suggested that the government should consider to establish producer responsibilities to encourage express service providers to recycle packaging waste. Express service providers, especially large companies, should take on more social responsibilities. Consumers should raise awareness of environmental protection, and do a good job of garbage classification to facilitate the recycling of waste packaging. Chueamuangphan et al. [6] believed that both consumers and sellers are responsible for solving the problem of packaging waste. Companies need to set up a reverse logistics system to promote reuse and recycling, so that consumers can make sustainable consumption. Escursell et al. [25] reviewed the development status of e-commerce packaging technology and pointed out the current problems of express packaging, such as excessive packaging and the use of non-renewable materials. They suggested to use degradable materials and new technologies such as 3D printing to design new express packaging. In this paper, we quantitatively consider the effects of three policies on express packaging recycling. A two-stage model is established from the perspective of manufacturers to discuss the production and recycling strategies under the three policies. Besides, we suggest an optimal choice between subsidy and tax reduction for the government when the budget is fixed. This paper provides guidelines for the government to improve related policies on promoting the recycling of express packages.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces a two-stage model and the objective function of the manufacturer. Section 3 studies the optimal strategies of manufacturers under the three policies. Section 4 summarizes the paper and provides some suggestions for the government to make decisions.

2. Models

Traditionally, the government may take three types of policies to guide the market: subsidy, penalty, and tax reduction [24]. The subsidy policy supports the enterprises who participate in recovering and reprocessing the express packages. The penalty policy means the enterprises who fail to meet the regulations of the recovery level set by the government will be punished. Here, the tax reduction policy is to reduce the consumption of new packaging materials for express packages. Specifically, the tax for reprocessed packaging is less than that for new packaging.
Once the policy made by the government, the enterprises will determine their optimal strategies for production. In the first stage, we assume that the enterprises can only produce recyclable packaging and non-recyclable packaging without consideration of the recycling process. The recovery and reprocessing for old packaging is considered in the second stage. The enterprises may recycle old packaging and reprocess it into recovered products. Manufacturers determine the optimal quantity for each type of productions to maximize their profits.
Table 1 presents the notations for variables and parameters as follows. Here, j { 1 , 2 , 3 } (including j 1 and j 2 ) denotes non-recyclable packaging, recyclable packaging, and reprocessed packaging, respectively.

2.1. The First Stage

In the first stage, we only consider the production of non-recyclable packaging and recyclable packaging. The inverse demand functions [26,27] are defined as follows:
p 1 = α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 + ϵ 1 , p 2 = α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 + ϵ 2 .
Here, α means the maximum willingness to pay of consumers [28,29]. η 1 , η 2 > 0 denotes a negative relationship between quantities and prices. The prices of products decrease with the increasing of quantities produced by manufacturers. δ 1 , 2 , δ 2 , 1 > 0 characterize the competitive intensity between two types of products. The price of one type decreases when the quantity of the other type increases. The impacts are assumed to be symmetric between two types of products. The white noises in the real market are also considered by ϵ 1 and ϵ 2 with zero means and finite variances [30,31].
Considering the production cost c 1 , c 2 , the object of manufacturers is to maximize their expected profits by determining the quantity of two types of products q 1 , q 2 [30]. The optimization problem in the first stage can be written as
max q 1 , q 2 E [ Π ] = max q 1 , q 2 E [ q 1 ( p 1 c 1 ) + q 2 ( p 2 c 2 ) ] = max q 1 , q 2 E [ q 1 ( α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 + ϵ 1 c 1 ) + q 2 ( α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 + ϵ 2 c 2 ) ] = max q 1 , q 2 q 1 ( α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 c 1 ) + q 2 ( α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 c 2 ) .
where Π denotes the profits of manufacturers.
By taking the derivative of Equation (2), let
E [ Π ] q 1 = α 2 η 1 q 1 2 δ 1 , 2 q 2 c 1 = 0 , E [ Π ] q 2 = α 2 η 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 c 2 = 0 .
Then, the optimal quantities q 1 , q 2 are obtained as follows:
q 1 * = α η 2 δ 1 , 2 α + δ 1 , 2 c 2 c 1 η 2 2 ( η 2 η 1 δ 1 , 2 2 ) , q 2 * = α η 1 δ 1 , 2 α + δ 1 , 2 c 1 c 2 η 1 2 ( η 2 η 1 δ 1 , 2 2 ) .

2.2. The Second Stage

In the second stage, in addition recyclable and non-recyclable packaging, reprocessed packaging is considered in our model. There are competitive relationships among these three types of packaging. Thus, the inverse demand functions can be defined as
p 1 = α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 + ϵ 1 , p 2 = α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 3 + ϵ 2 , p 3 = α η 3 q 3 δ 1 , 3 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 2 + ϵ 3 .
The interpretation of parameters are similar to those in Equation (1). The only difference is that there are three types of packaging competing with each other now. The price of one type will be affected by the quantity of the other two types.
Here, we consider the three common policies for the government to guide the market: subsidy, penalty, and tax reduction. Under the subsidy policy, manufacturers will get subsidies for each reprocessed packaging. It is a direct motivation to encourage manufacturers to recycle the used packaging. The regulation function is defined as f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) = ρ q 3 , where ρ is the per-unit subsidy. On the contrary, the penalty policy forces manufacturers to reprocess old packaging by imposing penalty. The regulation function is defined as f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) = β ( Q q 3 ) , where β is the per-unit penalty for remaining recyclable packaging. Here, Q is the maximal quantity of returnable used packages, which is viewed as a given constant. Tax reduction is another form of subsidy policy. It provides a discount rate of tax for reprocessed packaging compared with new packaging. The regulation function is defined as f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) = ξ ( q 1 + q 2 + ϕ q 3 ) , where ξ is the per-unit tax for new package and ϕ is the discount rate.
In general, considering the production cost c 1 , c 2 and the cost of acquiring and reprocessing the used packaging c 3 , the objective function of manufacturers under the government’s policies is
E [ Π ] = E [ q 1 ( p 1 c 1 ) + q 2 ( p 2 c 2 ) + q 3 ( p 3 c 3 ) + f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) ] .
Note that the quantity of reprocessed packaging q 3 must be less than the maximal quantity Q. Thus, the optimization problem can be written as
max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ Π ] = max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ q 1 ( p 1 c 1 ) + q 2 ( p 2 c 2 ) + q 3 ( p 3 c 3 ) + f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) ] = max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 q 1 ( α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 c 1 ) + q 2 ( α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 3 c 2 ) + q 3 ( α η 3 q 3 δ 1 , 3 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 2 c 3 ) + f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) , s . t . q 3 Q .

3. Analysis of Policies

In this section, we discuss the optimal strategies of manufactures under the three policies.

3.1. Subsidy

Under this policy, the government subsidizes ρ to per-unit reprocessed packaging. The regulation function is f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) = ρ q 3 . Then, the optimal strategy of manufacturers is to optimize Equation (5) as follows:
max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ Π ] = max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 q 1 ( α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 c 1 ) + q 2 ( α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 3 c 2 ) + q 3 ( α η 3 q 3 δ 1 , 3 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 2 c 3 ) + ρ q 3 , s . t . q 3 Q .
By taking the derivatives of Equation (6), let
E [ Π ] q 1 = α 2 η 1 q 1 2 δ 1 , 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 c 1 = 0 , E [ Π ] q 2 = α 2 η 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 2 δ 2 , 3 q 3 c 2 = 0 , E [ Π ] q 3 = α 2 η 3 q 3 2 δ 1 , 3 q 1 2 δ 2 , 3 q 2 c 3 + ρ = 0 .
Then, the optimal quantity q 1 , q 2 , q 3 are obtained as follows:
q 1 * = ( ( α c 1 ) δ 2 , 3 ( α c 2 ) δ 1 , 3 ) m n ( η 3 ( α c 1 ) δ 1 , 3 ( α c 3 + ρ ) ) δ 1 , 3 u , q 2 * = ( α c 3 + ρ ) l ( α c 1 ) m ( α c 2 ) ( η 1 η 3 δ 1 , 3 2 ) u , q 3 * = ( α c 3 + ρ ) ( δ 1 , 2 2 η 1 η 2 ) + ( α c 1 ) n + ( α c 2 ) l u .
where
l = δ 2 , 3 η 1 δ 1 , 2 δ 1 , 3 , m = δ 2 , 3 δ 1 , 3 δ 1 , 2 η 3 , n = δ 1 , 3 η 2 δ 1 , 2 δ 2 , 3 , u = 2 ( 2 δ 1 , 2 δ 2 , 3 δ 1 , 3 + δ 2 , 3 2 η 1 + δ 1 , 3 2 η 2 + δ 1 , 2 2 η 3 η 1 η 2 η 3 ) .
Here, l , m , n , u are symbols for convenience and are used in the following solutions.
Considering the inequality constraint q 3 Q , q 3 * in Equation (8) is the optimal reprocessed quantity when q 3 * Q . Otherwise, the optimal quantity should be Q, which means all the recyclable packagings have been recycled. Intuitively, manufacturers prefer to recycle more reprocessed packaging with higher subsidies.
A numerical simulation is presented to demonstrate this result. The parameters are set by referring to the ideas in [32]. Here, we focus on the ordinal relation of different parameters, rather than specific values. Among the three kinds of packaging, the non-recyclable packaging is one-off and thus has the lowest cost. The second is the recyclable packaging, which has higher technology. The reprocessed packaging has the highest cost when considering the costs of acquiring and reprocessing. Thus, we set c 1 = 0.25 , c 2 = 0.35 , and c 3 = 0.45 , respectively, to characterize the ordinal relation. The parameter η j is the conversion coefficient for quantity and price of the jth packaging. The packaging with lower cost should have the lower conversion coefficient since most of costs are rigid and inevitable. The quantity has lower effects on the price of product. Thus, η 1 = 0.4 , η 2 = 0.5 , and η 3 = 0.6 are set, respectively, which also characterize their ordinal relation. Note that both non-recyclable and recyclable packaging are new packaging, while the reprocessed packaging is reused. The competitive intensity between new packaging should be higher than they are with reused packaging. Thus, we set δ 1 , 2 = 0.6 and δ 1 , 3 = δ 2 , 3 = 0.5 in the numerical simulation. Besides, we assume that maximum willingness of consumers to pay α = 5 and the maximal quantity of returnable used packages Q = 4 . These parameters are summarized in Table 2.
Given the parameters in Table 2, the optimal quantities q 1 , q 2 , q 3 and profit Π are solved under different ρ in Table 3.
According to Table 3, there is a significant negative trend in q 1 and q 2 and a positive trend in q 3 with the increasing of ρ . It demonstrates that manufacturers prefer to recycle more reprocessed packaging rather than produce new packaging with higher subsidies. In addition, manufacturers gain more profits with higher subsidies from the government. The corresponding graph is shown in Figure 1.

3.2. Penalty

Under this policy, the government imposes penalty for failing to meet the recycling requirements. The regulation function is f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) = β ( Q q 3 ) . It is a cost for manufacturers to avoid it, and thus they are forced to recycle used packaging. The optimal strategy of manufacturers is to optimize Equation (5) as follows:
max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ Π ] = max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ q 1 ( α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 + ϵ 1 c 1 ) + q 2 ( α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 3 + ϵ 2 c 2 ) + q 3 ( α η 3 q 3 δ 1 , 3 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 2 + ϵ 3 c 3 ) β ( Q q 3 ) ] , s . t . q 3 Q .
By taking the derivatives of Equation (10), let
E [ Π ] q 1 = α 2 η 1 q 1 2 δ 1 , 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 c 1 = 0 , E [ Π ] q 2 = α 2 η 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 2 δ 2 , 3 q 3 c 2 = 0 , E [ Π ] q 3 = α 2 η 3 q 3 2 δ 1 , 3 q 1 2 δ 2 , 3 q 2 c 3 + β = 0 .
Then, the optimal quantity q 1 , q 2 , q 3 are obtained as follows:
q 1 * = ( ( α c 1 ) δ 2 , 3 ( α c 2 ) δ 1 , 3 ) m n ( η 3 ( α c 1 ) δ 1 , 3 ( α c 3 + β ) ) δ 1 , 3 u , q 2 * = ( α c 3 + β ) l ( α c 1 ) m ( α c 2 ) ( η 1 η 3 δ 1 , 3 2 ) u , q 3 * = ( α c 3 + β ) ( δ 1 , 2 2 η 1 η 2 ) + ( α c 1 ) n + ( α c 2 ) l u ,
where l , m , n , u are defined in Equation (9).
Considering the inequality constraint q 3 Q , q 3 * in Equation (12) is the optimal reprocessed quantity when q 3 * Q . Otherwise, the optimal quantity should be Q, which means all the recyclable packagings have been recycled and manufacturers receive no penalty from the government. Using common sense, higher penalty forces manufacturers to produce more reprocessed packaging to satisfy the government’s requirement. A numerical simulation is presented to demonstrate this result. We use the same parameters in Table 2. The optimal quantities q 1 , q 2 , q 3 and profit Π are solved under different β in Table 4.
According to Table 4, there is a significant negative trend in q 1 and q 2 and a positive trend in q 3 with the increasing of β . It demonstrates that manufacturers are forced to recycle more reprocessed packaging rather than produce new packaging under higher penalty. The profits of manufacturers also decrease with higher penalty. The corresponding graph is shown in Figure 2.

3.3. Tax Reduction

Tax reduction is another type of subsidy policies. The government may provide a discount of tax for reprocessed packaging. The regulation function is f ( q 1 , q 2 , q 3 ) = ξ ( q 1 + q 2 + ϕ q 3 ) , where ξ is the normal tax for new packaging and ϕ is the discount rate. The optimal strategy of manufacturers is to optimize Equation (5) as follows:
max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ Π ] = max q 1 , q 2 , q 3 E [ q 1 ( α η 1 q 1 δ 1 , 2 q 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 + ϵ 1 c 1 ) + q 2 ( α η 2 q 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 3 + ϵ 2 c 2 ) + q 3 ( α η 3 q 3 δ 1 , 3 q 1 δ 2 , 3 q 2 + ϵ 3 c 3 ) ξ ( q 1 + q 2 + ϕ q 3 ) ] , s . t . q 3 Q .
By taking the derivatives of Equation (13), let
E [ Π ] q 1 = α 2 η 1 q 1 2 δ 1 , 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 3 q 3 c 1 ξ = 0 , E [ Π ] q 2 = α 2 η 2 q 2 2 δ 1 , 2 q 1 2 δ 2 , 3 q 3 c 2 ξ = 0 , E [ Π ] q 3 = α 2 η 3 q 3 2 δ 1 , 3 q 1 2 δ 2 , 3 q 2 c 3 ξ ϕ = 0 .
Then, the optimal quantity q 1 , q 2 , q 3 are obtained as follows:
q 1 * = ( ( α c 1 ξ ) δ 2 , 3 ( α c 2 ξ ) δ 1 , 3 ) m n ( η 3 ( α c 1 ξ ) δ 1 , 3 ( α c 3 ξ ϕ ) ) δ 1 , 3 u , q 2 * = ( α c 3 ξ ϕ ) l ( α c 1 ξ ) m ( α c 2 ξ ) ( η 1 η 3 δ 1 , 3 2 ) u , q 3 * = ( α c 3 ξ ϕ ) ( δ 1 , 2 2 η 1 η 2 ) + ( α c 1 ξ ) n + ( α c 2 ξ ) l u ,
where l , m , n , u are defined in Equation (9).
Considering the inequality constraint q 3 Q , q 3 * in Equation (12) is the optimal reprocessed quantity when q 3 * Q . Otherwise, the optimal quantity should be Q. The government imposing less tax for reprocessed packaging may encourage the motivation of manufacturers to recycle the used packaging. Intuitively, the lower is the tax discount, the higher should be the optimal quantity of reprocessed packaging q 3 . A numerical simulation is presented to demonstrate this result. We use the same parameters in Table 2. The optimal quantities q 1 , q 2 , q 3 and profit Π are solved under different ϕ with a fixed tax rate ξ = 0.5 in Table 5.
According to Table 5, there is a significant positive trend in q 1 and q 2 and a negative trend in q 3 with the increasing of ϕ . It demonstrates that manufacturers are willing to produce more reprocessed packaging when the discount of tax is lower.
In addition, we also consider the influence of parameter ξ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π when ϕ is fixed, which is set as an intermediate value ϕ = 0.5 . Since the discount rate ϕ is fixed, the higher tax rate ξ brings more tax advantages to reprocessed packaging compared with new packaging. The optimal quantity of reprocessed packaging q 3 is expected to increase with the tax rate ξ . Table 6 demonstrates this result numerically.
According to Table 6, given a fixed ϕ , there is a significant negative trend in q 1 and q 2 and a positive trend in q 3 with the increasing of ξ . This demonstrates that manufacturers are more willing to recycle old packaging when the tax advantage is higher. Figure 3 and Figure 4 present the impacts of ϕ and ξ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π , respectively.
We perform the sensitivity analysis of main policy parameters ρ , β , ϕ and x ß . The impact of these policy parameters on the decision variables q 1 , q 2 , and q 3 and target profit Π is summarized in Table 7, where + denotes the positive impact and denotes the negative impact.

3.4. Comparison of Three Policies

We continue to explore the conditions when these policies will work, i.e., q 3 > 0 . That means that manufacturers will reprocess the used products.
  • For the subsidy policy, the condition can be solved by q 3 * > 0 in Equation (8) as follows:
    ρ ( α c 1 ) n + ( α c 2 ) l η 1 η 2 δ 1 , 2 2 α + c 3 .
    It shows that the subsidy from the government should be larger than the threshold value. Otherwise, the subsidy cannot cover the costs of manufacturers and they may not produce the reprocessed packaging.
  • For the penalty policy, the condition can be solved by q 3 * > 0 in Equation (12) as follows:
    β ( α c 1 ) n + ( α c 2 ) l η 1 η 2 δ 1 , 2 2 α + c 3 .
    The threshold value for penalty is equal to that in the subsidy policy. It demonstrates a symmetric effect between penalty and subsidy. The government may provide subsidy to manufacturers in the positive direction or impose penalty in the negative direction. The profits of manufacturers will be influenced by the policy greatly.
  • For the tax reduction policy, the condition can be solved by q 3 * > 0 in Equation (15) as follows:
    ϕ ( α c 1 ξ ) n + ( α c 2 ξ ) l ξ ( δ 1 , 2 2 η 1 η 2 ) + α c 3 ξ .
    The policy works when the discount rate of tax is less than the threshold value. Tax reduction is another type of subsidy policies. The lower discount rate is corresponding to higher subsidy from the government.
Among the three policies, the subsidy policy is a direct expense for the government. It encourages manufacturers to recycle the used packaging and produce reprocessed packaging. Manufacturers are happy since they gain more profits. It is a win–win result that the market becomes prosperous and the environment is protected. The disadvantage is this policy causes much financial pressure on the government when the budget is finite. The government may not have enough funds to afford this subsidy policy.
On the contrary, the penalty policy does not need to consider the constraint of budgets. It means this policy is a good choice when the budgets of the government are limited. The consequence is that it will reduce the profits and enthusiasm of manufacturers and thus may lead the market into recession.
The tax reduction policy is a combination of subsidy and penalty. It encourages manufacturers by using different tax rates for different products. It will not add financial burden for the government since it actually imposes the extra tax incomes. The goals of environment protection and prosperous markets can be attained with suitable parameters of the tax rate ξ and the discount rate ϕ .
To sum up, every policy will take its price. There is no such thing as a free lunch. Some prices are explicit, such as direct financial expenditure. However, some prices are implicit, which will appear in the following years, such as recession of the industry. The government policy should balance the short- and long-term interests, and consider both market prosperity and budget constraints. In practice, we believe the tax reduction policy is the most promising to attain these targets.

4. Conclusions

In this paper, we consider three types of policies applied to the express packaging industry, including subsidy, penalty, and tax reduction. A two-stage model is established to characterize the decision process of manufacturers. The optimal quantities of manufacturers are solved under different policies.
In general, all three policies could guide manufacturers to produce reprocessed packaging. The subsidy policy brings manufacturers more profits and makes the market more prosperous, but it causes heavy burden for the government’s budgets. In the Chinese market, the express industry takes more than 40 billion packages each year and the number is still increasing rapidly. Even if the subsidy coefficient is small, the government will face excessive fiscal expenditures. Thus, the subsidy policy may be the best for the market and enterprises, but it may not be practical in China. The penalty policy could guide the market without extra financial investment from the government. The negative effect is that the penalty may frustrate the enthusiasm of manufacturers and thus lead the market into recession. It goes against China’s policy of developing new industries such as e-commerce. The tax reduction policy combines the properties of subsidy and penalty. The goals of environment protection and prosperous markets can be attained with suitable parameters of the tax rate ξ and the discount rate ϕ . Thus, the tax reduction may be the most suitable policy in China. It can achieve a good balance between the development of new industries and environmental protection.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization and literature review, J.W. and L.X.; methodology, J.W. and C.W.; calculation and writing, R.F.; writing—original draft, R.F.; and writing—review and editing, L.X. and C.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by Six Talent Peaks Project in Jiangsu Province [JY-095] and the National Natural Science Foundation of China [71704066].

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Grace, R. E-commerce drives package design, market strategy changes: Brands need to adopt more of a holistic, systems approach to e-commerce packaging, to reduce waste and improve customer experience. Plast. Eng. 2017, 73, 8–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Brisson, I. Packaging waste and the environment: Economics and policy. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 1993, 8, 183–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. El-Fadel, M.; Findikakis, A.N.; Leckie, J.O. Environmental impacts of solid waste landfilling. J. Environ. Manag. 1997, 50, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Wang, F.; Hu, Y. Research on green express packaging design under the electronic commerce. Open J. Bus. Manag. 2016, 4, 621–628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Tallentire, C.; Steubing, B. The environmental benefits of improving packaging waste collection in Europe. Waste Manag. 2020, 103, 426–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  6. Chueamuangphan, K.; Kashyap, P.; Visvanathan, C. Packaging waste from e-commerce: Consumers’ awareness and concern. In Sustainable Waste Management: Policies and Case Studies; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2020; pp. 27–41. [Google Scholar]
  7. Duan, H.; Song, G.; Qu, S.; Dong, X.; Xu, M. Post-consumer packaging waste from express delivery in China. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 144, 137–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Zhang, D.Q.; Tan, S.K.; Gersberg, R.M. Municipal solid waste management in China: Status, problems and challenges. J. Environ. Manag. 2010, 91, 1623–1633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Liu, E.; He, W.; Yan, C. ‘White revolution’ to ‘white pollution’—agricultural plastic film mulch in China. Environ. Res. Lett. 2014, 9, 091001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Neumayer, E. German packaging waste management: A successful voluntary agreement with less successful environmental effects. Eur. Environ. 2000, 10, 152–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Park, J.H.; Tohno, S.; Kasahara, M.; Yi, P. A study on the volume-based waste charging system in South Korea. Waste Manag. Res. 2003, 14, 51–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Park, S.; Lah, T.J. Analyzing the success of the volume-based waste fee system in South Korea. Waste Manag. 2015, 43, 533–538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Anderson, S.; Allen, J.; Browne, M. Logistics implications of the UK packaging waste regulations. Int. J. Logist. Res. Appl. 1999, 2, 129–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Cruz, N.; Ferreira, S.; Cabral, M.; Simoes, P.; Marques, R.C. Packaging waste recycling in Europe: Is the industry paying for it? Waste Manag. 2014, 34, 298–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  15. Mitra, S.; Webster, S. Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidies. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2008, 111, 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Wang, Y.; Chang, X.; Chen, Z.; Zhong, Y.; Fan, T. Impact of subsidy policies on recycling and remanufacturing using system dynamics methodology: A case of auto parts in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 74, 161–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. De Giovanni, P.; Reddy, P.V.; Zaccour, G. Incentive strategies for an optimal recovery program in a closed-loop supply chain. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 249, 605–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. De Giovanni, P. A joint maximization incentive in closed-loop supply chains with competing retailers: The case of spent-battery recycling. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2018, 268, 128–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Esenduran, G.; Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya, E.; Swaminathan, J.M. Impact of take-back regulation on the remanufacturing industry. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2017, 26, 924–944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Yenipazarli, A. Managing new and remanufactured products to mitigate environmental damage under emissions regulation. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 249, 117–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Liu, B.; Holmbom, M.; Segerstedt, A.; Chen, W. Effects of carbon emission regulations on remanufacturing decisions with limited information of demand distribution. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2015, 53, 532–548. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Dong, F.; Hua, Y. Are Chinese residents willing to recycle express packaging waste? Evidence from a Bayesian regularized neural network model. Sustainability 2018, 10, 4152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Cao, X.; Liu, C. Research on customers’ willingness to participate in express package recycling. In IOP Conference Series: Earth and Environmental Science; IOP Publishing: Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia, 2019; Volume 295, p. 032030. [Google Scholar]
  24. Pazoki, M.; Zaccour, G. A mechanism to promote product recovery and environmental performance. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 274, 601–614. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Escursell, S.; Llorach, P.; Roncero, M.B. Sustainability in e-commerce packaging: A review. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 280, 124314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Fuchs-Seliger, S. Modelling consumer behaviour by inverse demand functions. Theor. Econ. Lett. 2013, 3, 229–232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Fuchsseliger, S. A note on duality in consumer theory. Econ. Theory 1999, 13, 239–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Zhang, Q.; Tang, W.; Zaccour, G.; Zhang, J. Should a manufacturer give up pricing power in a vertical information-sharing channel? Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 276, 910–928. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Pazoki, M.; Zaccour, G. Extended producer responsibility: Regulation design and responsibility sharing policies for a supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 236, 117516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Chemama, J.; Cohen, M.C.; Lobel, R.; Perakis, G. Consumer Subsidies with a Strategic Supplier: Commitment vs. Flexibility. Manag. Sci. 2019, 65, 681–713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Sunklodas, J. Approximation of distributions of sums of weakly dependent random variables by the normal distribution. Lith. Math. J. 1988, 27, 113–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Farshbaf-Geranmayeh, A.; Zaccour, G. Pricing and advertising in a supply chain in the presence of strategic consumers. Omega 2020, 102239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Sample Availability: Samples of the compounds ...... are available from the authors.
Figure 1. The impacts of ρ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Figure 1. The impacts of ρ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Sustainability 12 09504 g001
Figure 2. The impacts of β on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Figure 2. The impacts of β on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Sustainability 12 09504 g002
Figure 3. The impacts of ϕ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Figure 3. The impacts of ϕ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Sustainability 12 09504 g003
Figure 4. The impacts of ξ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Figure 4. The impacts of ξ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Sustainability 12 09504 g004
Table 1. Notations for variables and parameters.
Table 1. Notations for variables and parameters.
NotationDescription
p j price of the jth packaging
q j quantity of the jth packaging
α maximum willingness of consumers to pay
δ j 1 , j 2 competitive intensity between the j 1 th packaging and j 2 th packaging
η j conversion coefficient for quantity and price of the jth packaging
c j production cost of the jth packaging ( j = 1 , 2 )
c 3 costs of acquiring and reprocessing the used packaging
ρ per-unit subsidy
β per-unit penalty
ξ per-unit tax for new package
ϕ discount of the tax for reprocessed packaging
Table 2. Input data of parameters.
Table 2. Input data of parameters.
Parameter α η 1 η 2 η 3 c 1 c 2 c 3 δ 1 , 2 δ 2 , 3 δ 1 , 3 Q
Value50.40.50.60.250.350.450.60.50.54
Table 3. The impacts of ρ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Table 3. The impacts of ρ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
ρ = 0.1 ρ = 0.2 ρ = 0.3 ρ = 0.4 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0.6 ρ = 0.7 ρ = 0.8 ρ = 0.9
q 1 0.98810.86900.75000.63100.51190.39290.27380.15480.0357
q 2 2.47622.23812.00001.76191.52381.28571.04760.80950.5714
q 3 0.98811.36901.75002.13102.51192.89293.27383.65484.0357
Π 10.401210.519010.675010.869011.101211.371411.679812.026212.4107
Table 4. The impacts of β on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Table 4. The impacts of β on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
β = 0.1 β = 0.2 β = 0.3 β = 0.4 β = 0.5 β = 0.6 β = 0.7 β = 0.8 β = 0.9
q 1 0.98810.86900.75000.63100.51190.39290.27380.15480.0357
q 2 2.47622.23812.00001.76191.52381.28571.04760.80950.5714
q 3 0.98811.36901.75002.13102.51192.89293.27383.65484.0357
Π 10.00129.71909.47509.26909.10128.97148.87988.82628.8107
Table 5. The impacts of ϕ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Table 5. The impacts of ϕ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
ϕ = 0.1 ϕ = 0.2 ϕ = 0.3 ϕ = 0.4 ϕ = 0.5 ϕ = 0.6 ϕ = 0.7 ϕ = 0.8 ϕ = 0.9
q 1 0.45240.51190.57140.63100.69050.75000.80950.86900.9286
q 2 1.40481.52381.64291.76191.88102.00002.11902.23812.3571
q 3 2.20242.01191.82141.63101.44051.25001.05950.86900.6786
Π 8.83158.72628.63048.54408.46738.40008.34238.29408.2554
Table 6. The impacts of ξ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
Table 6. The impacts of ξ on q 1 , q 2 , q 3 , and Π .
ξ = 0.1 ξ = 0.2 ξ = 0.3 ξ = 0.4 ξ = 0.5 ξ = 0.6 ξ = 0.7 ξ = 0.8 ξ = 0.9
q 1 1.02380.94050.85710.77380.69050.60710.52380.44050.3571
q 2 2.54762.38102.21432.04761.88101.71431.54761.38101.2143
q 3 0.77380.94051.10711.27381.44051.60711.77381.94052.1071
Π 9.91739.52989.15898.80488.46738.14647.84237.55487.2839
Table 7. Sensitivity analysis of policy parameters to results.
Table 7. Sensitivity analysis of policy parameters to results.
Parameter ρ β ϕ ξ
q 1 +
q 2 +
q 3 +++
Π +
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Xiao, L.; Fan, R.; Wang, C.; Wang, J. Policy Analyses on Promoting the Recycling of Express Packages. Sustainability 2020, 12, 9504. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12229504

AMA Style

Xiao L, Fan R, Wang C, Wang J. Policy Analyses on Promoting the Recycling of Express Packages. Sustainability. 2020; 12(22):9504. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12229504

Chicago/Turabian Style

Xiao, Lu, Rongrong Fan, Chaojie Wang, and Jun Wang. 2020. "Policy Analyses on Promoting the Recycling of Express Packages" Sustainability 12, no. 22: 9504. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12229504

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop