Next Article in Journal
The Effectiveness of Marketing Communication and Importance of Its Evaluation in an Online Environment
Previous Article in Journal
Intelligent Prediction of Minimum Miscibility Pressure (MMP) During CO2 Flooding Using Artificial Intelligence Techniques
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

What Affects Participation in the Farmland Rental Market in Rural China? Evidence from CHARLS

1
School of Geographical Sciences, Southwest University, Chongqing 400715, China
2
State Cultivation Base of Eco-Agriculture for Southwest Mountainous Land, Southwest University, Chongqing 400715, China
3
Research Base of Karst Eco-environments at Nanchuan in Chongqing, Ministry of Nature Resources, Chongqing 400715, China
Sustainability 2019, 11(24), 7021; https://doi.org/10.3390/su11247021
Submission received: 31 October 2019 / Revised: 27 November 2019 / Accepted: 4 December 2019 / Published: 9 December 2019
(This article belongs to the Section Sustainability in Geographic Science)

Abstract

:
Land fragmentation and the small size of land parcels are still the major bottlenecks for agriculture sustainable development in rural China, and an efficient land rental market could consolidate land plots and realize agricultural management at a moderate scale. However, transaction cost is still the main obstacle of land transfer. It is, therefore, essential to reduce the excessive transaction costs in the process of transfer; the primary task is to identify the roots of transaction costs. In order to accurately identify the sources of transaction costs, a generalized ordered Logit model with thresholds that allowed transaction costs to affect different directions of land transfer was developed using the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Survey in 2015. The results suggested that the roots of transaction costs presented significant differences regarding the supply and demand of cropland. For the supply of land, the land titling program, land transfer intermediaries, and well-planned roads were the three most important factors that reduced transaction costs. For the demand of land, the three critical measures for reducing the transaction costs were well-planned roads, land consolidation, and the land titling program. The government should continue to push forward the land titling program and land consolidation projects in rural China, especially in hilly and mountainous areas. The infrastructure that greatly restricted agricultural development should be improved at a moderate level and the system of land circulating intermediary services at the township level should be established.

1. Introduction

In the last 30 years, although China has achieved substantial economic growth, a proportion of the rural population remains in poverty. According to the World Bank, China’s urban residents’ per capita disposable income was estimated at $4385.23 in 2014, which is classified as a high-income level (i.e., above $4086). In contrast, rural residents’ per capita disposable income was $1476.42, which is just across the low-income level (i.e., below $1035). In the 21st century, as non-agricultural wages continue to rise, large-scale rural labor forces were transferred to the cities for non-agricultural employment and it led to agricultural recession [1,2], which urgently improved the productivity of agricultural labor and expanded the scale of agricultural management [3]. In reality, China’s per capita arable land area is 0.08 hm2 (1 hm2 = 15 mu), which is less than half of the global average of 0.197 hm2. Land fragmentation and small scale of land parcels are problematic for the agriculture development in China [3,4]. In order to raise peasants’ income, the government has implemented a variety of stimulus programs that cultivate the land rental market and encourage peasants to participate in cropland transfer, with the aim of realizing effective large-scale management.
Related policies to develop the land rental market have been put forward in recent years. Land transfer was encouraged by both in 1998 and 2002. In 2008, related documents stated that peasants should have a fully guaranteed right to contract cropland, with these land contracts remaining stable for a long period. In the same year, the government began to implement land registration and certification, i.e., the land titling program. In 2011, the land titling program was implemented nationwide [5]. It is clear that the adoption of these policies has created favorable conditions to foster an effective land rental market.
However, with the exception of some individual regions, the ratio of land transfer to total land area is still very low in most areas and less than 10% in 20% of provinces in China [6]. The high transaction costs are the root of the inefficient operation of the land rental market [7,8,9], together with the uncertainty of tenure [10,11] and the unwillingness of small-scale peasants to enter into contracts [12]. The existence of these transaction costs has severely dampened the enthusiasm to take part in the land rental market, particularly in Ethiopia, Vietnam, China, Europe, America, and other regions [7,13,14,15]. There is no doubt that such high transaction costs are the roots of inefficiency of the land rental market [16,17].
Unfortunately, the question about transaction costs leading to the low efficiency of the land rental market in China did not receive enough attention both from theoretical and empirical aspects [5,18], let alone identity and mine the sources of transaction costs owing to the limitations of technology, methods, and data [7,19]. There is an urgent need to identify the roots of the failure in the land rental market and to take effective measures to reduce unnecessary transaction costs. Therefore, a theoretical model was built and a generalized ordered Logit model with shifting thresholds was developed using the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Study (CHARLS) in 2015. Our findings will help to improve the understanding of the inefficiency of the cropland rental market, and will also help to improve the vitality of the cropland rental market in order to promote the efficient use of cropland in rural China.

2. Land Tenure Reform in China

The formation of China’s rural land system has occurred in two stages: the establishment of the Household Contract Responsibility System (HCRS) from 1978 to 1993; and the improvement of the stability of the market-oriented land property and cropland rental market since 1993.

2.1. Establishment of the HCRS

In 1979, village collective land was assigned to the individuals in Xiaogang village, Anhui province, China. Afterwards, HCRS, in two main forms, began to be implemented in China. The core of the HCRS is that the village collective retains the land ownership and peasants have the right to the contracted management of land that has been reallocated based on family sizes and labor forces. By the end of 1984, the HCRS had been implemented in more than 99% of village collectives. Land productivity rapidly improved due to the HCRS, which greatly improved peasants’ production enthusiasm [20].
With the improvement in land productivity, however, three problems associated with the HCRS appeared. First, peasants’ contracts for the management of land were not defined clearly in a legal format. Second, the HCRS allowed the village collective to reallocate land due to an increase or decrease in the village population, but it could not guarantee the long-term stability of land rights. Third, the HCRS was only applicable to village residents; thus, peasants who were engaged in non-agricultural employment faced the risk of losing their rights to the contracted management of land [21]. Frankly speaking, the HCRS faced many challenges and the development of agriculture has entered a bottleneck, which did not materialize as an increase in peasants’ income.

2.2. Improvement of the Tenure Security

Document No. 1 in 1984 stated that the period of contracted management of land should be not less than 15 years, and the earliest implementation of the HCRS occurred in Xiaogang village [22]. In 1993, the first 15-year land contract period for Xiaogang village had arrived. Therefore, Document No. 1 in 1993 introduced a further regulation in which the period of contracted management of land was extended for 30 additional years once the original land contract expired. The aim was to stabilize land contract relations and improve cropland productivity. In 2002, the Rural Land Contracting Law was introduced, and it aimed to maintain the long-term stability of land contracting rights. The Property Law was passed in 2007 and it defined the right of land contract as usufruct right. This further strengthened the legal status of the right to land contracted management, thus ensuring the stability of the cropland rental market and system in rural China [22].
As massive labor forces in villages flow from rural to urban areas, a series of changes have taken place in rural land use such as the extensive operation of cropland [23]. What is more, the phenomena of abandoned cropland or idle cropland occurred in some areas and this objectively requires to expand the rural land management scale [24]. Therefore, land transfer was encouraged in Document No. 1 in 1993 and Rural Land Contracting Law in 2002. In reality, peasants were still reluctant to undertake land circulation owing to land adjustment issues, as well as the existence of phenomena such as the infringement of contracted management. In 2008, the government established that the existing land contract system should remain stable for a long period, which gave peasants a fully guaranteed right to contract land. Meanwhile, the pilot work on the land titling program was carried out nationwide since 2008. Since the implementation of HCRS in rural areas of China in the 1980s, the ownership of cropland has been owned by the village collective and the contracted management right is owned by each farm household. The reform of the three rights separation in 2014 makes the management right of cropland separated from the farm household, and the management right can be transferred in the land rental market and the peasants can obtain the rent [25].
It is worth noting that a series of beneficial conditions have been created for the development of the rental market, especially since 2008 when the land titling program greatly improved tenure security and the land rental market subsequently boomed. The total proportion of cropland in circulation was close to 30% in 2015, but the proportion was still less than 10% in ten provinces. Approximately 70% of peasants did not take part in the cropland rental market. The proportion of non-participation remained high, such as 37% in Bangladesh and 54% in India [26,27]. Furthermore, in recent years, the phenomenon about cropland being left idle or seasonally abandoned became more prominent, for example, the ratio of idle cropland was 13.5% in 2011 and 15% in 2013 in China, indicating that transaction costs were high [28,29]. Therefore, the priority in improving the situation is to accurately identify the roots of transaction costs and to make efforts to reduce them in the cropland rental market.

3. Materials and Methods

3.1. Data

The CHARLS was used for empirical analysis and CHARLS was conducted in 30 provinces of Chinese Mainland by the China Center for Economic Research at the Institute of National Development of Peking University from October 2017 to November 2017, and the data included 17,708 individuals in 10,257 households distributed in 450 villages, which was distributed in 150 prefecture-level cities, with 52.67% and 47.33% in rural and urban areas, respectively. In order to ensure that the sample is highly representative, there were four stages in the sampling process, i.e., the prefecture-level city, village, household, and personal levels. In the city-level sampling stage, the probability proportional to size was used based on the number of population and gross domestic product in cities in 2013 and about 150 prefecture-level cities were extracted from the 30 provinces in mainland China. At the village-level sampling stage, according to the Participatory Rural Evaluation (PRE) method, three villages or communities in every city were randomly selected, and finally obtained 450 villages or communities.
The data applied in this study mainly came from the rural samples and included 6026 farm households in 237 villages distributed in 101 prefecture-level cities in the CHARLS (Figure 1). In addition, the data contained village, household, and population databases. The village database contained land use, agricultural operation, village collective, and other related information. The household database included land transfer, agricultural input–output and household income. The population database contained details of education, work history, health history, and other demographic information. More importantly, the details about land circulation were included in these databases, which enabled the study to be successfully implemented.
To prevent the influence of noises in the samples on the empirical analysis, sample cleaning was conducted. First, the individual and household databases were combined, to produce a total of 5952 samples. Second, households in which the number of effective laborers was more than the total population were eliminated (17 samples; 0.28% of the total). Third, peasants who both rented-in and rented-out land were eliminated (25 samples, 0.41% of the total). Fourth, samples in which important indexes were missing were also eliminated. Finally, there were 5792 valid farm households in this study, accounting for 96.12% of the total samples.

3.2. Model Specification

In the presence of transaction costs associated with land transfer, the rent paid due to renting-in cropland does not equal the rent received due to renting-out cropland. There is a significant difference between the rent to be paid due to renting-in land and the rent earned due to renting-out land, and it creates a price band. There are two thresholds in the land rental market [7]. When the marginal product value (πfA) of cropland is greater than the rent ( R h i ) paid due to renting-in land, households are inclined to rent-in cropland. When the rent ( R h o ) received due to renting-out land is greater than the marginal product value (πfA) of cropland, households tend to rent-out cropland [7,14,30,31]. Otherwise, households are not involved in land transfer. It is worth noting that whether a household is involved in the rental market is influenced by cropland marginal production and transaction costs, although the two latent variables cannot be accurately measured. Fortunately, the household choices involved in the cropland rental have been examined so as to further identify the root of transaction costs in the rental market.
The theoretical model showed that there were three mutually exclusive choices (i.e., renting-out, autarkic referring to peasants who neither rent out nor rent in cropland, and renting-in) of the land rental market, and they could be ranked in order of πfA for farm household h. These choices could be tied to πfA by a nonlinear probability model for ordinal outcomes [16]. The choices equation of rental market was as follows:
S h = { 1 ,   π f A < R h o 2 , R h o π f A R h i 3 , π f A > R h i
where Sh is an index function with values of 1, 2, 3 in order and R h o and R h i are two thresholds. It is noteworthy that the differences between two levels of ordering scale (i.e., the renting-out versus the autarkic; the autarkic versus renting-in) is not the same on the scale of πfA. The factors that affect the potential cropland marginal production value (fA) are complex. fA can be regarded as the linear expression based on a series of factors according to the above theory. The formula is as follows:
f A v h = α + β 1 X 1 v h + β 2 X 2 v h + β 3 X 3 v + D + ε v h
where fAvh is the dependent variable of farm household h in village v; X1vh denotes the householders’ characteristics such as age, education level, marital status, and health status of the head of the household; X2vh denotes the family characteristics, including the family effective workforce, the dependency ratio, cropland area, productive assets, and occupation; X3v refers to village characteristics such as terrain, infrastructure, population information, and rural endowment insurance. In addition, D, which denotes regional dummy variable and represents the provincial factors such as climate, culture, and other invisible factors are included in the model. The parameter ͛h denotes the level of disturbance. The definition and description of the variables are given in Table 1.
According to Table 1, about 8.72% of households rented out cropland and 10.2% of households rented-in cropland in 2013. The results show that the ratio of farm households who rented-in land is greater than that renting-out [26,31], mainly because some farm households who rented-out land do not live in the survey areas [31]. For the householders’ characteristics, average age of the householders renting-in cropland is 57.16, which is less than that renting-out (60.67) and the autarkic (60.49). On average, effective labor forces represent significant differences in three groups; the number of effective labor forces in households that rented-in cropland is 3.27, which is greater than other groups (3.11 and 3.16). Also, the average productive assets for the households that rented-in land is 7555 yuan, while the assets are 5061 yuan for households that rented-out land. Obviously, the head, household, and village characteristics were quite remarkable for households in different rental choices.
Considering the existence of transaction costs in the cropland rental market, the rent thresholds for renting-out and renting-in cropland were expressed as linear functions of the form:
{ R h o = k h o k o · X T C o R h i = k h i + k i · X T C i
where X T C o and X T C i are the vectors of proxy variables for transaction costs assumed to affect the threshold levels for household h, with an associated κo and κi. The superscripts o and i indicate renting-out and renting-in land, respectively.
The theory of Williamson identified the transaction costs from three dimensions, namely, the asset specificity, transaction frequency, and uncertainty [32]. Firstly, the critical dimension for characterizing transaction is the asset specificity, which denotes the degree of durable transaction-specific investments. In China, tenure security and the basic cropland protection system are two key factors generating transaction costs in the process of cropland circulation. In this study, the critical indicator for measuring the degree of tenure security is the land titling program [5,33,34]. In addition, the crop zoning index, was measured as the proportion of the total sown areas of wheat, corn, and rice, three main crops, which captured the rising transaction costs from the specificity of cropland assets in different regions [7]. Secondly, the transaction frequency also affects the transaction costs. This study selects [30] d proxy variables for characterizing transaction frequency, which included land fragmentation, land consolidation, land circulation intermediary, convenience stores in village, well-planned roads, and household assets, such as motor vehicle and mobile phone [35]. It was worth mentioning that land fragmentation led to higher transaction costs in the land rental market [36], and the number of land parcels captured the transaction costs due to higher transaction frequency [37]. The number of convenience stores in village captured the declining transaction costs due to information transmission [8]. Thirdly, the uncertainty of transaction is widely conceded to be a critical attribute. Land readjustment and the incidence of natural disasters were selected, such as drought, flooding, typhoon, and earthquake, to measure the uncertainty [32]. In China, although the HCRS has been implemented for more than 30 years, land readjustment that increased the uncertainty and investment risk of agricultural management often occurred within the villages. The definition and description of the above variables for transaction costs are given in Table 2.
To estimate the threshold parameters in Equation (3), a generalized ordered Logit model (GOLM), with a shifting threshold, was used to estimate order response probabilities for the choices in Formula (1). The form of the model was expressed as follows:
p r ( S h > j | X ) = exp ( X b ) 1 + exp ( X b )
X b = R h j + β 1 X 1 v h + β 2 X 2 v h + β 3 X 3 v + D
This model overcame the limitations of a standard ordered Logit model and allowed the thresholds to be affected by a number of proxy variables for transaction costs, which can substitute Equations (2) and (3) into Equations (4) and (5). The threshold parameters (κo, κi) are identified by GOLM [38].

4. Results

4.1. Development Level of the Land Rental Market in China

The two types of indicators that include the ratio of land transfer to total land area by land area and the ratio of land transfer by the number of households in different provinces were used to estimate the development level of the cropland rental market. Table 3 shows the statistical results. First of all, from the perspective of land transfer area statistics, about 50% of provinces where the ratio of cropland has been transferred out were less than 10% and, in all provinces, where the ratio of cropland has been transferred out, it was less than 30%, except Heilongjiang, and the national average was 10.54%. The ratio of cropland that has been transferred into was less than 30% in all provinces, except for Zhejiang and Heilongjiang.
Secondly, from the perspective of the number of households, Table 3 shows that more than 50% of provinces where the ratio of the number of households that transferred out cropland was less than 10%, and it did not exceed 30% in any provinces except Zhejiang. The ratio of the number of households that transferred in cropland did not exceed 30% in any provinces. It is obvious that the development level of the rural land rental market was still at a low level, regardless of whether from the perspective of land transfer area and the number of farm households in rural China.

4.2. Determinants of Cropland Rental Market Participation

A global test of the parallel-lines assumption was conducted using the Brant and Likelihood ratio tests. The results indicated that the parallel-line assumption was violated. Therefore, this study favored the generalized ordered Logit model at the 1% significance level. In addition, the multicollinearity of independent variables was tested using the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF). All of the independent variables had a VIF that was less than 3. Therefore, there is no serious collinearity problem between variables.
The empirical results are presented in Table 4, it was noteworthy that the dependent variables that complied with the orderly rising represented the household rental choices, and took on values of 1, 2, and 3 for renting-out, the autarkic, and renting-in, respectively. When explanatory variables were significantly positive, farm households were inclined to rent-in cropland due to higher cropland marginal production values. In contrast, explanatory variables were significantly negative, indicating that farm households tended to rent-out cropland due to the lower cropland marginal production values.
First of all, from the perspective of the householder’s characteristics, the householder’s age was negative at the 10% significance level, indicating that peasants were inclined to rent-out cropland as the age of the head of the household increased. The educational level was negative at the 1% significance level, and it suggested that farm households were more likely to rent-out cropland when the head of the household had a higher level of education, especially the head who had a college degree. Marriage and Health of household head were positive at the 1% and 10% significance levels, respectively, indicating that the farm households with more stable marriages and the peasants who were in good health were inclined to rent-in cropland. Clearly, the empirical results implied that the rental market transferred cropland from relatively labor-poor and educationally high-achieving farm households to those with relatively more healthy and stable families. The evidence supported the view that, to a certain extent, the cropland rental market can improve the land use efficiency and the allocation of labor forces.
Secondly, from the perspective of the household characteristics, effective labor forces and productive assets were significantly positive at the 10% and 1% levels, respectively, suggesting that farm households that are relatively labor-rich and asset-sufficient are more willing to expand the scale of agricultural management. However, the coefficient of occupation was negative at the 10% significance level, indicating that farm households engaged in non-agricultural employment or having part time jobs were more inclined to rent-out cropland. Therefore, the results also supported the view that the cropland rental market resulted in an efficient allocation of cropland resources at the household level.
Thirdly, from the perspective of the village characteristics, the coefficients of ratio of the emigration, ratio of the elderly, and old rural pension system (ORPS) were negative at the 5% significance level, which suggested that the households lived in villages that had a higher rate of outflow population and a higher proportion of the elderly were more inclined to rent-out cropland. The coefficients above also suggested that an efficient allocation of cropland resources was achieved by the cropland rental market. All of the evidence supported the view that the cropland rental market to some extent transferred cropland from relatively inefficient farm households to efficient farm households [31].
The study was more interested in the root of transaction costs hindering the development of the land transfer, which was determined from a series of proxy variables for transaction costs. The effects of the proxy variables on transaction costs in the households’ rental choice are reported in the lower half of Table 4. The unstandardized estimation coefficients and partially standardized estimation coefficients of proxy variables for transaction costs based on threshold equations were presented in Table 4. In addition, the relative importance of the sources of transaction costs affecting the land rental market was also presented in Table 5.
For the farm households who rented-out cropland (the supply side), there were three important factors that significantly reduced the transaction costs and improved the ratio of participation in the land rental market, i.e., well-planned roads, the land titling program, land circulation intermediaries. First of all, the coefficient of the land titling program was −0.527, which was significantly negative at 1% significance level. A land titling program that improved the stability of tenure and weakened the asset specificity of cropland could reduce the transaction costs in the process of land circulation, resulting in the incentive of prospective renting-out to take part in the land rental market [21]. In addition, well-planned roads and land circulation intermediaries that reduced the transaction costs by saving costs on transportation, information searching, negotiation, supervision, and contract management as the increase in transaction frequency, encourages farm households to participate in the rental market [39]. In contrast, the incidence of natural disasters and the number of land parcels were key roots of transaction costs that significantly reduced the willingness to take part in the land rental market. High incidence of natural disasters, such as drought, flooding, typhoon, and earthquake, increased the risk of agricultural operation and transaction uncertainty and hindered participation in the land rental market. Similarly, land fragmentation, that is to say, the number of land parcels, increased transaction frequencies or frequencies of signing a contract in the process of land circulation and also reduced the ratio of participation in land transfer.
For the farm households who rented-in cropland (the demand side), well-planned roads also had the highest rank order and positively impacted the prospective renting-in or tenants by reducing transaction costs. Land consolidation ranked second and significantly reduced the cost of searching for and screening participants, and also reduced management costs and encouraged prospective tenants to rent-in cropland [33]. Motor vehicle ownership ranked third and significantly improved the probability of participation in the land rental market by reducing the cost of searching for and screening participants, and reducing management costs. It is obvious that these results are consistent with existing research about Vietnam [7].
Therefore, the results presented in Table 4 support the interpretation of these variables as determinants of transaction costs and not as determinants of cropland productivity. For the supply side of cropland, well-planned roads, the land titling program and land circulation intermediaries were the three most important factors that reduced transaction costs; meanwhile, the incidence of natural disasters and the number of land parcels were the two most important factors that increased transaction costs. In contrast, well-planned roads, land consolidation, and the land titling program were the most important factors that reduced transaction costs associated with the demand side of cropland and encouraged prospective renting-in to rent-in cropland.

5. Conclusions, Policy Applications, and Limitations

To explore what affects participation in the cropland rental market, a theoretical model was built and a generalized ordered Logit model, with shifting thresholds that allowed transaction costs to effect on renting-out and renting-in differently, was developed and estimated using CHARLS in 2015. In addition, this paper further identified the roots of transaction costs from the supply and demand of land. The findings suggested that the land rental market, to a certain extent, improved the efficient allocation of cropland resources. Specifically, the land rental market transferred cropland from farm households with a higher educational level and relatively labor-poor to those with a relatively stable marriage, asset-abundant and more effective labor resources based on individual and household level. Furthermore, farm households who lived in villages with a higher proportion of emigration and the elderly were inclined to rent-out cropland.
More importantly, the findings also revealed that high transaction costs can hamper the development of the land rental market. What is more, this study effectively identified the roots of transaction costs that affected renting-out and renting-in in different ways and estimated the relative importance of their impacts. For the supply side of cropland, well-planned roads, the land titling program and land circulation intermediaries were the three most important factors that significantly reduced the transaction costs. It is notable that the incidence of natural disasters and land fragmentation were key factor that increased transaction costs. For the demand for cropland, well-planned roads, land consolidation, and the land titling program were key factors that reduced transaction costs.
There is an urgent need to reduce transaction costs and encourage potential participants to enter the cropland rental market. The government should continue to push forward the land titling program and guarantee the long-term stability of land rights. Land consolidation and infrastructure construction in undeveloped areas should be a priority for the government, especially in hilly and mountainous areas. In addition, information diffusion services associated with the land rental should also be improved, such as the establishment of land transfer service intermediaries at the township level.
It is worth mentioning that this study may have some limitations. To our knowledge, cross-sectional data with no control over these factors that change over time were used in this study, and panel data may reduce the potential bias in parameter estimates, but it would face a greater challenge in estimating the generalized ordered Logit model. The cross-section data that are used for empirical analysis in this paper is still a reasonable choice.

Funding

This study was funded by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 41901232), the Youth Fund for Humanities and Social Sciences Research of the Ministry of Education (Grant No. 19XJCZH006) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (No. swu118054).

Acknowledgments

Thank you very much for three anonymous reviewers.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Xu, D.-D.; Deng, X.; Guo, S.-L.; Liu, S.-Q. Labor migration and farmland abandonment in rural China: Empirical results and policy implications. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 232, 738–750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Li, S.-J.; Sun, Z.-G.; Tan, M.-H.; Li, X.-B. Effects of rural-urban migration on vegetation greenness in fragile areas: A case study of Inner Mongolia in China. J. Geogr. Sci. 2016, 26, 231–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Zhang, L.-X.; Su, W.-L.; Eriksson, T.; Liu, C.-F. How off-farm employment affects technical efficiency of china’s farms: The case of jiangsu. China World Econ. 2016, 24, 37–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Song, K.-S.; Wang, Z.-M.; Li, L.; Tedesco, L.; Li, F.; Jin, C.; Du, J. Wetlands shrinkage, fragmentation and their links to agriculture in the muleng-xingkai plain, china. J. Environ. Manag. 2012, 111, 120–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Wang, Y.-H.; Li, X.-B.; Li, W.; Tan, M.-H. Land titling program and farmland rental market participation in china: Evidence from pilot provinces. Land Use Policy 2018, 74, 281–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ma, X.-L.; Heerink, N.; van Ierland, E.; Shi, X.-P. Land tenure insecurity and rural-urban migration in rural china. Pap. Reg. Sci. 2016, 95, 383–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Huy, H.-T.; Lyne, M.; Ratna, N.; Nuthall, P. Drivers of transaction costs affecting participation in the rental market for cropland in vietnam. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2016, 60, 476–492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Le, L.; Lyne, M.; Ratna, N.; Nuthall, P. The rental market for farmland in vietnam’s mountainous north central coast region: Outcomes and constraints. Mt. Res. Dev. 2013, 33, 416–423. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Macours, K. Ethnic divisions, contract choice, and search costs in the guatemalan land rental market. J. Comp. Econ. 2014, 42, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Di Tella, R.; Galiani, S.; Schargrodsky, E. The formation of beliefs: Evidence from the allocation of land titles to squatters. Q. J. Econ. 2007, 122, 209–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Ito, J.; Bao, Z.-S.; Ni, J. Land rental development via institutional innovation in rural Jiangsu, China. Food Policy 2016, 59, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Aryal, J.P.; Holden, S.T. Livestock and land share contracts in a hindu society. Agric. Econ. 2012, 43, 593–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Gebregziabher, G.; Holden, S.T. Distress rentals and the land rental market as a safety net: Contract choice evidence from tigray, ethiopia. Agric. Econ. 2011, 42, 45–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Creighton, J.; Blatner, K.A.; Carroll, M.S. For the love of the land: Generational land transfer and the future of family forests in Western Washington Stata, USA. Small Scale For. 2016, 15, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Petrescu-Mag, R.M.; Petrescu, D.C.; Reti, O.R. My land is my food: Exploring social function of large land deals using food security-land deals relation in five Eastern European countries. Land Use Policy 2019, 82, 729–741. [Google Scholar]
  16. Deininger, K.; Jin, S.Q. The potential of land rental markets in the process of economic development: Evidence from China. J. Dev. Econ. 2005, 78, 241–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Ma, X.-L.; Heerink, N.; van Ierland, E.; van den Berg, M.; Shi, X.-P. Land tenure security and land investments in northwest China. China Agric. Econ. Rev. 2013, 5, 281–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Yan, X.-H.; Huo, X.-X. Drivers of household entry and intensity in land rental market in rural China evidence from north Henan province. China Agric. Econ. Rev. 2016, 8, 345–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Deininger, K.; Jin, S.-Q.; Nagarajan, H.K. Determinants and consequences of land sales market participation: Panel evidence from india. World Dev. 2009, 37, 410–421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Zhang, Y.-J.; Brummer, B. Productivity change and the effects of policy reform in China’s agriculture since 1979. Asian Pac. Econ. Lit. 2011, 25, 131–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wang, H.; Tong, J.; Su, F.; Wei, G.; Tao, R. To reallocate or not: Reconsidering the dilemma in China’s agricultural land tenure policy. Land Use Policy 2011, 28, 805–814. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Ma, X.-L.; Heerink, N.; Feng, S.-Y.; Shi, X.-P. Farmland tenure in China: Comparing legal, actual and perceived security. Land Use Policy 2015, 42, 293–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Van Boeckel, T.P.; Brower, C.; Gilbert, M.; Grenfell, B.T.; Levin, S.A.; Robinson, T.P.; Teillant, A.; Laxminarayan, R. Global trends in antimicrobial use in food animals. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2015, 112, 5649–5654. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  24. Hua, X.-B.; Yan, J.-Z.; Li, H.-L.; He, W.-F.; Li, X.-B. Wildlife damage and cultivated land abandonment: Findings from the mountainous areas of chongqing, China. Crop Prot. 2016, 84, 141–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Wang, Q.-X.; Zhang, X.-L. Three right separation: China’s proposed rural land rights reform and four types of local trials. Land Use Policy 2017, 63, 111–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Deininger, K.; Jin, S.-Q.; Nagarajan, H.K. Efficiency and equity impacts of rural land rental restrictions: Evidence from india. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2008, 52, 892–918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Rahman, S. Determinants of agricultural land rental market transactions in bangladesh. Land Use Policy 2010, 27, 957–964. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Gan, L.; Yin, Z.-C.; Tan, J.-J. China Household Finance Survey Report 2014; Southwestern University of Finance & Economics Press: Chengdu, China, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  29. Yan, J.-Z.; Yang, Z.-Y.; Li, Z.-H.; Li, X.-B.; Xing, L.-J.; Sun, L.-X. Drivers of cropland abandonment in mountainous areas: A household decision model on farming scale in southwest China. Land Use Policy 2016, 57, 459–469. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Farayola, C.O.; Nwachukwu, S.C.; Alao, B.I. Transaction Costs and Agricultural Household Supply: Response of Sweetpotato Farmers in Kwara State of Nigeria. In Potato and Sweetpotato in Africa: Transforming the Value Chains for Food and Nutrition Security; Cabi Publishing: Wallingford, UK, 2015; pp. 524–532. [Google Scholar]
  31. Jin, S.-Q.; Jayne, T.S. Land rental markets in kenya: Implications for efficiency, equity, household income, and poverty. Land Econ. 2013, 89, 246–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Williamson, O.E. Transaction-cost economics—Governance of contractual relations. J. Law Econ. 1979, 22, 233–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Liu, Z.-M.; Muller, M.; Rommel, J.; Feng, S.-Y. Community-based agricultural land consolidation and local elites: Survey evidence from China. J. Rural Stud. 2016, 47, 449–458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Tan, R.; Heerink, N. Public and self-organized land readjustment in rural China—a comparison. J. Rural Stud. 2017, 53, 45–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. de Janvry, A.; Gonzalez-Navarro, M.; Sadoulet, E. Are land reforms granting complete property rights politically risky? Electoral outcomes of mexico’s certification program. J. Dev. Econ. 2014, 110, 216–225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Li, J.; Qiu, R.; Li, K.; Xu, W. Informal land development on the urban fringe. Sustainability 2018, 10, 128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Skoufias, E. Household resources, transaction costs, and adjustment through land tenancy. Land Econ. 1995, 71, 42–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Williams, R. Generalized ordered logit/partial proportional odds models for ordinal dependent variables. Stata J. 2006, 6, 58–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Cai, J.; Wang, T.; Xia, X.; Chen, Y.; Lv, H.; Li, N. Analysis on the choice of livelihood strategy for peasant households renting out farmland: Evidence from western poverty-stricken areas in China. Sustainability 2019, 11, 1424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. Distribution of research areas based on prefecture-level cities.
Figure 1. Distribution of research areas based on prefecture-level cities.
Sustainability 11 07021 g001
Table 1. Summary statistics for the variables affecting land rental market participation.
Table 1. Summary statistics for the variables affecting land rental market participation.
VariableDefinitionsRenting-out
N = 505
No participation
N = 4696
Renting-in
N = 591
MeanS.DMeanS.DMeanS.D
Householder’s Characteristics
Householder’s ageThe householder’s age (years.)60.6710.9860.4910.4357.169.06
HUKOUAgricultural HUKOU (yes = 1, no = 0)0.960.200.960.200.990.09
Education level
Middle schoolLevel of schooling (middle school = 1, no = 0)0.170.380.180.380.200.40
High schoolLevel of schooling (high school = 1, no = 0)0.050.230.050.210.050.22
College degreeLevel of schooling (college degree = 1, no = 0)0.030.160.010.110.010.07
Marriage of household headMarital status (married = 1, no = 0)0.710.450.770.420.900.30
Health of household headSelf-assessment health for body (healthy = 1, no = 0)0.610.410.610.410.630.44
Family Characteristics
Effective labor forceThe amount of adult equivalent labor3.111.243.161.263.271.23
Dependency ratioFamily dependency ratio0.200.320.200.300.240.34
Productive assetsThe total value of productive assets in family (yuan)506127,074743157,242755524,441
Farm area in familyThe number of cultivated land (hm2)0.410.780.420.850.530.96
OccupationMultiple occupations (yes = 1, otherwise = 0)0.870.540.920.470.910.49
Village Characteristics
Terrain
PlainsLocated in plains (yes = 1, no = 0)0.340.470.330.470.360.48
HillsLocated in hills (yes = 1, no = 0)0.350.480.320.470.390.49
Distance to bus stopDistance from the village to bus stop (km)5.914.275.644.515.494.16
Ratio of emigrationThe ratio of outflow population in the village0.350.280.360.280.390.29
Ratio of the elderlyThe ratio of population aged 65 in the village0.170.130.170.120.160.11
ORPSHas old rural pension insurance (yes = 1, no = 0)0.240.420.150.350.170.37
Average income per capitaNet income per capita in 2010 (yuan)431939073563354639253424
CPIThe price of rice per kilogram (yuan/kg) 2.230.482.270.462.270.45
Table 2. Summary statistics for the variables determining transaction costs.
Table 2. Summary statistics for the variables determining transaction costs.
VariableDefinitionsRenting-out
N = 505
No Participation
N = 4696
Renting-in
N = 591
MeanSDMeanSDMeanSD
Asset specificity
Tenure security
Land titling programLand titling in past five years (yes = 1, no = 0)0.380.490.290.450.340.42
Basic cropland protection system
Crop zoning indexRatio of the total sown areas of wheat, corn, and rice crops0.890.270.860.280.900.31
Transaction frequency
Number of land parcels ***The number of land parcels in farm households4.283.823.973.514.453.33
Land consolidationHas conducted land consolidation (yes = 1, no = 0)0.190.400.120.320.170.37
Land circulation intermediaryHas land circulating intermediaries in township (yes = 1, no = 0)0.230.170.150.140.200.17
Well-planned roadsHas well-planned roads (yes = 1, no = 0)0.920.270.890.310.930.26
Convenience storesThe number of convenience stores in village6.594.935.384.645.664.64
Motor vehicle ownershipHas owned a motorized vehicle (yes = 1, no = 0)0.520.500.510.500.640.48
Mobile phone ownershipHas owned a mobile phone (yes = 1, no = 0)0.710.450.690.460.770.42
Uncertainty
Land readjustmentHas reallocated cropland in decade (yes = 1, no = 0)0.210.410.190.390.210.41
Incidence of natural disasterThe probability of natural disasters including drought, flooding, typhoon, and earthquake in decade0.270.480.410.500.430.50
Notes: ***, Number of land plots was the missing variable in CHARLS; this paper used the number of land parcels in a rural fixed observation points system conducted by the Chinese Ministry of Agriculture to replace the number of land parcels in CHARLS based on China’s eastern, central, and western regions, respectively.
Table 3. Development level of land transfer market based on area and number of peasants.
Table 3. Development level of land transfer market based on area and number of peasants.
ProvinceRatio of Land Transfer by Land Area/%Ratio of Land Transfer by the Number of Farm Households/%
Has Been Transferred outHas Been Transferred inHas Transferred outHas Transferred in
Anhui10.2620.8914.9618.52
Fujian12.1912.3618.3712.48
Gansu4.337.545.8314.17
Guangdong11.4210.4611.507.71
Guangxi6.234.378.754.58
Guizhou11.1422.788.8312.63
Hebei7.427.518.906.16
Henan7.7612.318.619.27
Heilongjiang30.0131.6528.5915.54
Hubei10.2916.7614.7713.86
Hunan12.0226.6815.6823.04
Jilin14.3426.8814.7018.35
Jiangsu9.2913.8719.3514.49
Jiangxi19.4327.5218.4819.39
Liaoning9.1325.139.8316.64
Inner Mongolia11.0917.849.6814.65
Shandong7.5116.858.4316.53
Shanxi5.7815.044.5611.97
Shaanxi6.3913.516.0212.05
Sichuan4.5311.725.558.78
Qinghai5.689.878.209.75
Yunnan9.8611.7514.0811.18
Zhejiang19.9563.0733.8320.57
Chongqing7.123.758.115.30
National average10.5417.9212.7313.23
Notes: Some of the provinces are not listed in the above Table because of the small number of samples.
Table 4. Simulation results of determinants of land rental market participation.
Table 4. Simulation results of determinants of land rental market participation.
VariablesEstimated CoefficientT-Value
Householder’s Characteristics
Householder’s age−0.007 *−1.77
HUKOU0.2781.47
Middle school−0.079−0.83
High school−0.254−1.57
College degree−0.869 ***−2.95
Marriage of household head0.470 ***5.03
Health of household head0.137 *1.78
Family characteristics
Effective labor force0.051 *1.71
Dependency ratio0.1201.04
Log of productive assets0.137 ***9.75
Farm area in family0.0020.60
Occupation−0.229 *−1.78
Village characteristics
Plains0.1481.19
Hills0.1381.35
Distance to bus stop−0.002*−1.88
Ratio of emigration−0.790 **−2.05
Ratio of the elderly−0.836 **−2.53
ORPS−0.215 **−2.12
Log of average income per capita−0.051−1.17
CPI−0.045−0.51
Variables determining transaction costs with thresholds
Renting-out thresholdRenting-in threshold
CoefficientT-valueCoefficientT-value
Asset specificity
Land titling program−0.527 ***−4.640.159 **2.23
Crop zoning index0.0511.370.0230.65
Transaction frequency
Number of land parcels0.0520.44−0.079−0.71
Land consolidation−0.378 ***−2.840.443 ***3.39
Land circulation intermediary−0.425 ***−3.180.097 *1.74
Well-planned roads−0.339 *−1.910.399 **2.32
Convenience stores−0.035 ***−3.320.0070.67
Motor vehicle ownership−0.120−1.070.243 **2.31
Mobile phone ownership−0.133−1.130.1120.98
Uncertainty
Land readjustment−0.141−1.100.1621.34
Incidence of natural disasters0.215 **2.02−0.118−1.21
Cut points2.603 ***4.07−3.184 ***−4.98
Pseudo R-square0.0931
Log likelihood−3343.50
Observations5792
Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10. The dependent variable is the household rental choice, which takes on values of 1, 2, and 3 for renting-out, the autarkic, and renting-in, respectively; T-statistics are corrected for heteroscedasticity and clustered by village. Regional dummies have been included in the model; their coefficients are not reported in the Table 4 due to space limitation.
Table 5. Importance of the roots of transaction costs affecting land rental market participation.
Table 5. Importance of the roots of transaction costs affecting land rental market participation.
VariableRenting-out ThresholdRenting-in Threshold
Estimated CoefficientStandardized EstimatesRankEstimated CoefficientStandardized EstimatesRank
Asset specificity
Tenure security
Land titling program−0.527 ***−0.058120.159 **0.01777
Basic cropland protection system
Crop zoning index0.0510.0019100.0230.000810
Transaction frequency
Number of land parcels0.0520.00619−0.079−0.00879
Land consolidation−0.378 ***−0.050340.443 ***0.05782
Land circulation intermediary−0.425 ***−0.056530.097 *0.01276
Well-planned roads−0.339 *−0.060310.399 **0.06881
Convenience stores−0.035 ***−0.0004110.0070.0000711
Motor vehicle ownership−0.120−0.013380.243 **0.02553
Mobile phone ownership−0.133−0.015970.1120.01295
Uncertainty
Land readjustment−0.141−0.018060.1620.01944
Incidence of natural disasters0.215 **0.02375−0.118−0.01158
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10. The standardized coefficient of each variable was not determined in accordance with the ordinary least squares (OLS) method; to solve this problem, an estimation method was followed using the formula ( η ^ = η σ [38]; T-statistics are corrected for heteroscedasticity and clustered by village.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, Y. What Affects Participation in the Farmland Rental Market in Rural China? Evidence from CHARLS. Sustainability 2019, 11, 7021. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11247021

AMA Style

Wang Y. What Affects Participation in the Farmland Rental Market in Rural China? Evidence from CHARLS. Sustainability. 2019; 11(24):7021. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11247021

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Yahui. 2019. "What Affects Participation in the Farmland Rental Market in Rural China? Evidence from CHARLS" Sustainability 11, no. 24: 7021. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11247021

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop