Next Article in Journal
Keeping Watch on Intangible Cultural Heritage: Live Transmission and Sustainable Development of Chinese Lacquer Art
Previous Article in Journal
Phenyl-C61-Butyric Acid Methyl Ester Hybrid Solution for Efficient CH3NH3PbI3 Perovskite Solar Cells
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Market Power and Technology Diffusion in an Energy-Intensive Sector Covered by an Emissions Trading Scheme

School of Economics and Management, Beihang University, Beijing 100191, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2019, 11(14), 3870; https://doi.org/10.3390/su11143870
Submission received: 3 July 2019 / Revised: 13 July 2019 / Accepted: 15 July 2019 / Published: 16 July 2019

Abstract

:
The emissions trading scheme (ETS) has been long advocated to address climate change not only because it is cost effective but also because it can provide economic incentives for the adoption of new technologies. The emissions abatement of the energy-intensive sector covered by ETS is of great significance for the whole nation to attain sustainable and low-carbon development, especially for developing countries. This paper investigates the effect of market power in the emissions trading market on the diffusion of a new emissions abatement technology when firms in the energy-intensive sector interact in an imperfectly competitive output market. In the model, each firm needs to determine the optimal time to adopt the new emissions abatement technology, taking into account its benefits and costs, as well as its rival’s strategic behavior. With this framework, the results suggest that firms will delay adoption of the new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Moreover, when the output demand is larger and more elastic, emissions abatement technology diffusion will occur earlier. It implies that the technology diffusion in the weak elastic sector, such as the Chinese iron and steel sector, may have more barriers than that in the strong elastic sector, such as the Chinese nonferrous metals sector.

1. Introduction

Economists have long advocated an emissions trading scheme (ETS) to fight against climate change not only because it is cost effective but also because it can provide economic incentives for the adoption of new emissions abatement technologies. Moreover, these economic incentives may be the most crucial approaches to ensure the attainment of the deep carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions reduction target in the long term [1]. However, in common with many other commodity markets, the emission trading market has also been affected by market power, and several dominant firms play a key role in permit prices [2,3,4,5,6]. Following Hahn’s seminal article [7], there is substantial theoretical literature analyzing the issues of market power in the permits market. Developing a dominant firm–competitive fringe model, Hahn concluded that the dominant firm will use its market power to manipulate the permit price. Based on Hahn’s model framework, Westskog extended to multiple agents with market power [8], and other articles considered the output market and noted that the dominant firm will exercise its market power to raise its rivals’ cost [9,10]. This main finding has also been demonstrated by other scholars [5,11,12,13,14]. In the context of international ETS, the issue of market power in the permits market has been recognized to be a challenging potential problem [15,16]. Furthermore, several laboratory experiments have provided evidence that the exercise of market power can be rather extreme when taking into account both permit and output markets [17,18,19]. Additionally, to reduce the efficiency loss in the permits market affected by market power, some scholars focus on related policy design [20,21].
As a consequence, the market efficiency will be distorted due to the presence of market power, especially considering the output market. Thus, there would be strategic behaviors in the ETS market that make the equilibrium price deviate from the marginal abatement cost. Moreover, these strategic behaviors further have influence on a firm’s decision-making of technology renewal. Hence, compared with a perfect emission trading market, it is worthwhile to study whether or not ETS increases the economic incentive for technology adoption in the imperfectly competitive permit market. Therefore, this key issue needs to be urgently investigated, providing policymakers more understanding and facilitating referencing in ETS policy development.
The effect of market power in the emission trading market on technology adoption has not been extensively studied in the literature. Scholars compared taxes and ETS in terms of motivating investment in environmental research and development (R&D) [22,23,24]. However, our paper focuses on the design of ETS rather than on the policy choice between ETS and taxes. More specifically, compared with a perfect emission trading market, do firms delay (or accelerate) the adoption of emissions abatement technologies in the presence of market power? Studying this point has important policy implication since ETS is typical in the real world. Nowadays a great number of countries or regions, including the European Union, Norway, Switzerland, Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Japan, Korea, and India, have set up their own national or regional ETS or intend to do so [25,26]. Specially, China, the largest emitter in the world, has already implemented the emission trading pilot in its seven regions and started the world’s largest carbon trading system on 19 December 2017.
To our knowledge, there is a limited number of studies investigating this problem [27,28], but the result has been a matter of debate. André and Arguedas [27] did not consider the output market and found that technology adoption is related to the initial distribution of permits. That implies that the output market is completely competitive. In fact, most firms with market power in the permits market often engage in an imperfectly competitive output market such as power sector [11,12,29] or iron and steel sector [28,30]. With the development of the microgrid [31,32,33,34,35,36,37], many renewable-energy power generation companies will also engage in imperfectly competitive output markets in the future. Hence, it is necessary to explicitly take into account the output market. Wang et al. [28] assumed that all firms have market power in the permits market and noted that market power can accelerate technology adoption. Differing from this literature, we use the dominant firm–competitive fringe model to describe an imperfect emissions trading market structure. Moreover, Wang et al. [28] considered the adoption of end-of-pipe technologies, while we pay attention to energy-saving technologies. In fact, energy-saving technologies are more common than end-of-pipe technologies for curbing carbon emissions, since the end-of-pipe technology (i.e., carbon capture and storage technology) is extremely expensive and has not been widely applied in reality. Additionally, Wang et al. [28] assumed zero costs of production, while we take into account the constant marginal production cost in our model. This makes it more general because that would allow for the possibility to do sensitivity analysis with respect to production cost parameters.
To investigate the issues that raised above, and motivated by these research gaps, this paper presents a general model of the diffusion of a new emissions abatement technology when firms take part in imperfect competition in the output market. In particular, consider an energy-intensive sector that is composed of two representative heterogeneous firms—a dominant firm (or some collusion firms) with market power in the permits market and a price-taking fringe. Based on a classical framework [38], this paper makes the extension by introducing heterogeneous firms to describe the situation where market power in the emissions trading market does exist. Assume that the R&D of new technology is exogenous, when a new emissions abatement technology appears in the market, each firm needs to decide when to adopt it. Each firm makes the decision based on the discounted cost of adopting new emissions abatement technology and the behavior of its competitor. On the one hand, a firm can earn great profits at the cost of the other firms when it adopts the new emissions abatement technology before its competitor. On the other hand, it may save cost if the firm adopts the new technology later. This is because the discounted cost of adopting new technology may decrease over time. Therefore, the firm must balance the costs and benefits of delaying adoption, as well as take into account its competitor’s strategic behavior.
The main contribution of this paper is twofold. First, this study contributes to the literature by investigating the effect of market power on the adoption of emissions abatement technologies. As mentioned, the issue has not been extensively studied in the literature and there are only two studies investigating the impact of market power in carbon ETS on technology adoption. However, the result has been a matter of debate. Through theoretical analysis and numerical simulation, we found that firms will delay the adoption of new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Second, from the point of industry level, we explored emissions abatement technology diffusion in China’s energy-intensive sectors covered by ETS. This analysis was motivated by the fact that policy makers ultimately must assess and design an ETS policy by the degree to which ETS provides economic incentive for new technology diffusion into the industry. Furthermore, the energy-intensive sector contributes large amounts of carbon emissions and its emissions abatement is of great significance for the whole nation to attain sustainable and low-carbon development, especially for developing countries. The result shows that when the output demand is larger and more elastic, emissions abatement technology diffusion will occur earlier.

2. Materials and Methods

Suppose in an energy-intensive sector, a pair of representative heterogeneous firms, which consist of a dominant firm (firm 1) with market power in permits market and a price-taking fringe (firm 2), is producing a homogeneous good (e.g., iron and steel or cement). The linear inverse demand function is given by:
P = P ( Q ) = a b ( q 1 + q 2 ) ,    a ,    b > 0 ,
where q 1 and q 2 denote the output level of firm 1 and firm 2, respectively. The production cost function c ( q i ) for firms is assumed to be of linear form, i.e., c ( q i ) = c i q i , c i > 0 , i = 1 , 2 , where c i is the production cost coefficient, that is, the marginal production cost is constant in this study. The production of goods q i   ( i = 1 , 2 ) generates carbon emissions e i   ( i = 1 , 2 ) as a by-product with intensity k i > 0    ( i = 1 , 2 ) . Following the previous literature [28,39,40,41,42,43,44], we consider a linear production function q i = k i e i in the case of the current technology and the emissions intensity of the output is k 0   ( k 0 > k i ,   i = 1 , 2 ) in the case of the new emissions abatement technology. Thus, firms adopting the new technology use less energy per unit of output and therefore generate less emissions per unit of output. The cost function ρ ( t ) of adopting the new technology is expressed as ρ ( t ) = K e ( δ + θ ) t [39], where K is a positive parameter, t is the date of adoption of the firm, δ is the discount rate, and θ is the diffusion rate. The strategic behaviors between firm 1 and firm 2 are described by the following two-stage mechanism, and the schematic of the study framework is depicted in Figure 1.
Stage 1: Model of optimal timing of technology adoption. At any instant, each firm can either adopt the new technology or postpone the adoption decision. Hence, each firm needs to determine the optimal time to adopt the new technology, taking into account its benefits and costs, as well as its competitor’s strategic behavior.
Stage 2: Model of an imperfect competition permit market. Given the emissions abatement technology, firms make output and emissions decisions to maximize profits. This stage is described as a leader–follower model.
The two-stages mechanism plays out backwards, since firms’ decisions in stage 2 affect their technology adoption decision.

2.1. Model of an Imperfect Competition Permit Market

Firms are subject to tradable permits regulation that sets up a binding cap on aggregate emissions and look for the output and the emissions that maximize profits. The emissions cap E is equal to ( 1 λ ) E 0 , where E 0 is the total emissions in the absence of an environmental policy and λ is the percent of emissions reduction. The solution process of E 0 can be found in Appendix A.
Acting as a Stackelberg leader, the dominant firm 1 announces first how many permits to trade and how much output to bring to the output market. Having observed that, the fringe firm 2 chooses its output and clears the permits market.
Firm 1 solves the problem:
π 1 = M a x e 1 [ ( a b ( k 1 e 1 + k 2 e 2 ) ) k 1 e 1 c 1 ( k 1 e 1 ) p ( e ) ( e 1 ε 1 ) ] ,
and firm 2 solves the problem:
π 2 = M a x e 2 [ ( a b ( k 1 e 1 + k 2 e 2 ) ) k 2 e 2 c 2 ( k 2 e 2 ) p ( e ) ( e 2 ε 2 ) ] ,
where p ( e ) is the permit price, ε 1 and ε 2 are the quantity of emissions permits freely received by firm 1 and firm 2, respectively, based on the grandfathering or benchmarking method allocation. Moreover, firms comply with the environmental regulation in this study.
The problem is solved by backward induction. Firm 2 takes p ( e ) as given, as a follower, and maximizes π 2 . According to the first order conditions (FOCs), we have:
p ( e ) = b k 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) e 1 2 b k 2 2 E + ( a c 2 ) k 2 ,
As a leader, firm 1 maximizes π 1 . The FOCs and permit market clearing condition yields the emissions levels of firms:
e 1 = ( a c 1 ) k 1 ( a c 2 ) k 2 b ( 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 ) + k 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) ( ε 1 + E ) 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 ,
e 2 = ( a c 2 ) k 2 ( a c 1 ) k 1 b ( 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 ) + 2 ( k 2 2 k 1 k 2 + k 1 2 ) E k 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) ε 1 4 k 2 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 2 k 1 2 .
Then, the outputs levels of firms:
q 1 = ( a c 1 ) k 1 2 ( a c 2 ) k 1 k 2 b ( 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 ) + k 1 k 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) ( ε 1 + E ) 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 ,
q 2 = ( a c 2 ) k 2 2 ( a c 1 ) k 1 k 2 b ( 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 ) + 2 k 2 ( k 2 2 k 1 k 2 + k 1 2 ) E k 2 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) ε 1 4 k 2 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 2 k 1 2 ,
and the permit price p ( e ) is given by:
p ( e ) = k 2 ( 2 k 1 k 2 k 1 2 ) ( a c 1 ) + k 2 ( 2 k 2 2 2 k 1 k + 2 k 1 2 ) ( a c 2 ) 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 + b k 2 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) 2 ( ε 1 + E ) 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 2 b k 2 2 E
Taking the partial derivative of a , b , and E , we have the following:
p a = k 2 ( 2 k 2 2 + k 1 2 ) 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 = k 2 ( 2 k 2 2 + k 1 2 ) ( k 1 2 k 2 ) 2 + k 1 2 + k 1 k 2 > 0 ,
p b = k 2 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) 2 ( ε 1 + E ) 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 2 k 2 2 E < 2 k 2 2 E ( k 1 2 + k 1 k 2 ) ( k 1 2 k 2 ) 2 + k 1 2 + k 1 k 2 < 0 ,
p E = b k 2 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) 2 2 k 1 2 3 k 1 k 2 + 4 k 2 2 2 b k 2 2 = b k 2 2 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) 2 + 2 k 1 2 ( k 1 2 k 2 ) 2 + k 1 2 + k 1 k 2 < 0 .
Hence, the permit price p ( e ) is increasing in a and decreasing in b , E . That implies that the permit price is larger if the output demand is larger and more elastic and greater stringency of the environmental policies is implemented.
To compare the difference of technology adoption in the imperfect competition permits market and perfectly competitive permits market, the corresponding problem in the perfect competition permits market should been solved. If the emission trading market is perfectly competitive, all market participants are price takers. That is, both firms make their output and emissions decisions simultaneously taking the permit price as given. Then the equilibrium permit price p c is given by:
p c = ( a c 1 ) k 2 + ( a c 2 ) k 1 2 k 1 k 2 k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 3 b E 2 k 1 2 k 2 2 k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 .
The proofs of the results in the perfectly competitive permits market can be found in Appendix B.

2.2. Model of Optimal Timing of Technology Adoption

Based on the classical framework [38], this paper makes an extension by introducing heterogeneous firms to describe the situation where market power in the emission trading market does exist. Let t 1 and t 2 be the adoption dates of firms 1 and 2, respectively. Then, we can make a summary of the profit opportunities described above in Table 1.
In order to be a perfect equilibrium, the following assumptions illustrate the relative magnitudes of profits.
Assumption 1.
π i i > π i A > π i j > 0 , π i i > π i N A > π i j > 0 , i ,   j = 1 , 2 , i j .
This assumption implies that profit to the firm is greatest when it has adopted the new emissions abatement technology but the other has not. Moreover, the next greatest profits come up in the case where firms both have adopted (or no firm has yet adopted). Finally, the profit opportunity for a firm is least when the other has adopted the new emissions abatement technology but it has not.
Assumption 2.
π i i π i N A > π i A π i j , i ,   j = 1 , 2 , i j .
That is, the increase in revenue when one is first exceeds the increase in revenue when one is second.
Assumption 3.
ρ ( t ) > δ ( π i i π i 0 ) e δ t , i = 1 , 2 .
That is, the decrease in the adoption costs ρ ( t ) cannot continue indefinitely, which rules out infinity. This assumption also makes sure that the firm’s objective function is strictly concave and each firm has the optimal date of adoption.
Similar to what was shown by Reinganum [38], the payoffs to two firms are defined as follows.
Definition 1.
The payoff to firm 1 is
V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = { f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) i f   t 1 t 2 f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) i f   t 1 > t 2 ,
where
f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = 0 t 1 π 1 N A e δ t d t + t 1 t 2 π 1 1 e δ t d t + t 2 + π 1 A e δ t d t ρ ( t 1 ) ,
and
f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = 0 t 2 π 1 N A e δ t d t + t 2 t 1 π 1 2 e δ t d t + t 1 + π 1 A e δ t d t ρ ( t 1 ) .
Definition 2.
The payoff to firm 2 is
V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = { f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) i f   t 2 t 1 f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) i f   t 2 > t 1 ,
where
f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 )   = 0 t 2 π 2 N A e δ t d t + t 2 t 1 π 2 2 e δ t d t + t 1 + π 2 A e δ t d t ρ ( t 2 ) ,
and
f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = 0 t 1 π 2 N A e δ t d t + t 1 t 2 π 2 1 e δ t d t + t 2 + π 2 A e δ t d t ρ ( t 2 ) .
Without loss of generality, we will handle firm 1’s optimal timing of technology adoption problem, and the corresponding results for firm 2 can be solved the same way.
Note that V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) is continuous in t 1 (for fixed t 2 ) and is not differentiable at t 1 = t 2 . As a matter of fact, the left-hand derivative at t 2 is f 11 1 = ( π 1 N A π 1 1 ) e δ t 2 ρ ( t 2 ) , while the right-hand derivative at t 2 is f 11 2 = ( π 1 2 π 1 A ) e δ t 2 ρ ( t 2 ) . Furthermore, it is not difficult to show that f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) and f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) are strictly concave by Assumption 3. Therefore, there exist t 1 1 and t 1 2 , which maximize f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) and f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) , respectively. It follows that first-order conditions for f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) and f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) are given by:
( δ + θ ) K e ( δ + θ ) t 1 1 ( π 1 1 π 1 N A ) e δ t 1 1 = 0 ,    ( δ + θ ) K e ( δ + θ ) t 1 2 ( π 1 A π 1 2 ) e δ t 1 2 = 0 .
That is,
t 1 1 = 1 θ ln ( δ + θ ) K π 1 1 π 1 N A ,    t 1 2 = 1 θ ln ( δ + θ ) K π 1 A π 1 2 .
Furthermore, it is easy to show that t 1 1 < t 1 2 by Assumption 2.
Lemma 1.
t ˜ 1 ( t 1 1 , t 1 2 ) such that f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) as t 2 t ˜ 1 , and vice versa.
Proof. 
See Appendix C. □
Theorem 1.
R 1 ( t 2 ) = { t 1 2 t 2 < t ˜ 1 { t 1 1 , t 1 2 } t 2 = t ˜ 1 t 1 1 t 2 > t ˜ 1 ,
where the mapping R 1 is firm 1’s best response correspondence.
Proof. 
See Appendix C. □
For firm 2, we can derive some similar conclusions by the same way.
Lemma 2.
t ˜ 2 ( t 2 1 , t 2 2 ) such that f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) as t 1 t ˜ 2 , and vice versa, where
t 2 1 = 1 θ ln ( δ + θ ) K π 2 2 π 2 N A ,   t 2 2 = 1 θ ln ( δ + θ ) K π 2 A π 2 1 .
Proof. 
See Appendix C. □
Theorem 2.
R 2 ( t 1 ) = { t 2 2 t 1 < t ˜ 2 { t 2 1 , t 2 2 } t 1 = t ˜ 2 t 2 1 t 1 > t ˜ 2 ,  
where the mapping R 2 is firm 2’s best response correspondence.
Proof. 
See Appendix C. □
Theorem 3.
(1) 
If t ˜ 2 > t 1 2 or { t ˜ 2 < t 1 2 t ˜ 1 < t 2 1 , then there exists a unique Nash equilibrium ( t 1 1 , t 2 2 ) .
(2) 
If { t 2 1 < t ˜ 1 < t 2 2 t 1 1 < t ˜ 2 < t 1 2 or { t 2 1 = t ˜ 1 t ˜ 2 t 1 2 or { t 1 1 t ˜ 2 t ˜ 1 = t 2 2 , then there exist two Nash equilibria ( t 1 1 , t 2 2 ) and ( t 1 2 , t 2 1 ) .
(3) 
If t ˜ 1 > t 2 2 or { t ˜ 1 < t 2 2 t ˜ 2 < t 1 1 , then there exists a unique Nash equilibrium ( t 1 2 , t 2 1 ) .
Proof. 
See Appendix C. □
Additionally, the proposed study framework can be extended from the following aspects. First, to obtain a closed-form solution, two representative asymmetric firms are considered in our model. It would be even more general to study the situation where finite multiple heterogeneous firms are included in the ETS. Second, our model is suitable for a single sector. It will be meaningful to extend our model to multiple sectors. Third, our model is operated under environmental certainty. It will be interesting to extend our study framework in environmental uncertainty, such as economic uncertainty (e.g., the output demand is always changing in the future) and technological uncertainty (e.g., the arrival time of new emissions abatement technologies is uncertain).

3. Results

In this section, we select the Chinese iron and steel sector as a case study to illustrate several key analytical results, and the main reasons are as follows. First, the market structure of China’s iron and steel sector is imperfect competition [28,30,43,44]. Second, among all the sources of CO2 emissions in China, the iron and steel sector plays a crucial role. Furthermore, the iron and steel sector is one of the first eight key emissions sectors to be included in the national carbon emissions trading market.
Following Zhu et al. [44], let P ( Q ) = 7191 5.2 ( q 1 + q 2 ) be the demand curve, the production cost coefficients of the firms are c 1 = 2374 and c 2 = 3543 , respectively. The emissions intensity of the output is k 1 = 0.60 and k 2 = 0.47 in the case of the current technology, respectively. The diffusion rate in adoption cost θ = 0.038 [39]. Moreover, the positive parameter K in the adoption cost is equal to one million and the emissions intensity of output K 0 in the case of the new emissions abatement technology is assumed to be 0.8. Additionally, the percentage of emissions reductions λ is set as 0.1, and the discount rate δ used here is 0.05. Table 2 describes all the parameters used in the numerical simulation.
For the sake of convenience in writing, we name the imperfectly competitive permits market as market 1 and the perfectly competitive permits market as market 2. Additionally, the software used in our study is MATLAB and the version is R2015b. We believe that most computers meet this condition.

3.1. The Effect of Output Market

Changes in the output market are described by changes in parameters a and b in this study. Figure 2 and Figure 3 show the effect of the output market on technology adoption, and the following conclusions can be drawn. First, firms adopt the new emissions abatement technology earlier when the output demand is larger (larger a ) or more elastic (smaller b ). Second, compared to market 2, both firms adopt the new emissions abatement technology later in market 1. That is, firms both delay the adoption of the new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Third, when the product demand is larger or more elastic, technology diffusion will occur earlier. The analysis is as follows. On the one hand, given the parameter b , the higher the output demand in the output market (larger a ), the higher the output levels of the firms will be. Hence, the firms adopt the new emissions abatement technology earlier to meet the higher level of emissions. On the other hand, given the parameter a , the initial level of carbon emissions is higher if the output demand is more elastic (smaller b ). Therefore, this could cause the greater stringency of the environmental policies required, which leads to an increase in the adoption benefits and speed up the adoption of new technology.

3.2. The Effect of Production Cost

The difference between the production cost of firm 1 and 2 (i.e., c 2 c 1 ) is shown by changing the marginal production cost of firm 1 and keeping the marginal production cost of firm 2 constant. As shown in Figure 4, the following conclusions can be drawn. First, compared to market 2, the firms adopt the new emissions abatement technology later in market 1. In other words, both firms delay the adoption of the new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Second, for a smaller difference between the production costs of firms 1 and 2 (larger c 1 ), the firm that first adopts the new technology switches from firm 1 to firm 2, and then the difference between the adoption date of firm 1 and 2 gradually becomes smaller and then becomes larger.

3.3. The Effect of Emissions Reduction Target

Changes in the emissions reduction target are described by changes in the parameter λ . More specifically, the higher the percent of emissions reduction (larger λ ), the larger the emissions reduction target will be (smaller E ). As shown in Figure 5, the following conclusions can be drawn. First, as expected, the firms adopt the new emissions abatement technology earlier when the emissions reduction target is larger. Therefore, implementing larger emissions reduction target will induce an earlier diffusion of emissions abatement technology. Second, compared to market 2, firms adopt the new emissions abatement technology later in market 1. In other words, both firms delay the adoption of the new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Third, with a larger emissions reduction target (larger λ ), the difference between the adoption date of firms under market 1 and market 2 gradually becomes smaller.

4. Discussion

4.1. Changes in Social Welfare

Social welfare contains four parts: Consumer surplus (CS), firm’s profits (FP), emissions damages, and investment costs (IC). The aggregate damage caused by the total emissions E is equal to γ E 2 / 2 , γ > 0 [28,39]. Hence, the emissions damages stay constant throughout the sequence of adoption in different market structures since emissions are capped before adoption starts. Let Q ( i ) represent the total output in the case where i    ( i = 1 , 2 ) firms have adopted the new emissions abatement technology in the market and ( 2 i ) firms still use current technology. In addition, it is easy to show that the consumer surplus is given by Q 2 ( i ) b / 2 because the demand curve is defined by P ( Q ) = a b Q .
Hence, if i firms have adopted the new emissions abatement technology in the market, then the social welfare is given by W ( i ) = Q 2 ( i ) b / 2 + π 1 + π 2 γ E 2 / 2 K e ( δ + θ ) t i . Let W 1 ( i ) and W 2 ( i ) be the social welfare when the firms participate in market 1 and 2, respectively. Then, changes in social welfare Δ W ( i ) = W 1 ( i ) W 2 ( i ) can be expressed as
Δ W ( i ) = [ Q 2 1 ( i ) Q 2 2 ( i ) ] b / 2 Δ C S ( i ) + [ π 1 + π 2 π 1 π 2 ] Δ F P ( i ) [ K e ( δ + θ ) t i K e ( δ + θ ) t i ] Λ I C ( i ) .
where t i , t i are the date of adoption in market 1 and 2; π 1 , π 1 are the profits of firm 1 in market 1 and 2; and π 2 , π 2 are the profits of firm 2 in market 1 and 2, respectively.
Table 3 and Table 4 show changes in the consumer surplus Δ C S , changes in the firm’s profits Δ F P , changes in the investment costs Δ I C , and changes in the social welfare in different market structures.
From Table 3 and Table 4, two main conclusions can be drawn. First, the social welfare in an imperfect competition permits market is larger than that in firms in a perfect competition permits market. The analysis is as follows. When only one firm is using the new technology in the market, changes in social welfare primarily relied on the investment cost. This is because the investment cost of the firm that first adopted the new technology was high. As shown in Section 3.1, firms delay the adoption of the new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Thus, the substantial reduction in investment costs leads to an increase in social welfare. When firms both are using the new technology in the market, changes in social welfare are mainly dependent on the firm’s profits. This is because the investment cost declines quickly with time and technological diffusion. Thus, the increase in the firm’s profits brings about the social welfare increase.
Second, the larger the output demand (larger a ) or the more elastic the output demand (smaller b ), the greater the changes in social welfare. As shown in Section 3.1, firms adopt the new technology earlier when the output demand is larger. Therefore, the sooner the adoption, the larger the changes in investment costs will be and, hence, the greater the changes in social welfare.

4.2. Comparison with Related Studies

As mentioned in the introduction, there are only two studies investigating this problem [27,28], However, the result has been a matter of debate. André and Arguedas [27] assumed that the output market is completely competitive and minimized the cost. That is, they did not consider the impact of the output market on technology adoption. However, several scholars confirmed that the exercise of market power can be rather extreme when taking into account both permit and output markets [17,18,19]. Furthermore, most firms with market power in a permits market often engage in an imperfectly competitive output market in the real world, such as the power sector [11,12,29] and the iron and steel sector [28,30]. Therefore, it is necessary to explicitly consider the output market when studying this problem.
Wang et al. [28] supposed that all firms have market power in a permits market and focused on the effect of production capacity on technology adoption. Our paper differs from this literature in several respects. First, we use the dominant firm–competitive fringe model to describe an imperfect emissions trading market structure. More specifically, we study the cases of a dominant firm with market power in a permits market and a price-taking firm. Second, Wang et al. [28] considered the adoption of end-of-pipe technologies, while our paper pays attention to the adoption of energy-saving technologies. In fact, energy-saving technologies are more common than end-of-pipe technologies for curbing carbon emissions, since the end-of-pipe technology (i.e., carbon capture and storage technology) is extremely expensive and has not been widely applied in reality. Furthermore, several authors have found that there might be potential differences between the adoption of the two types of abatement technologies by using empirical approaches [45,46,47]. For example, Frondel et al. [46] found that cost savings are more important for the energy-saving technologies, while policy stringency is more important for the end-of-pipe technologies. Hence, the impact of market power on two completely different emissions abatement technologies is clearly distinct, and a firm’s investment behaviors regarding these two technologies are also distinct. Third, Wang et al. [28] assumed zero costs of production, while we take into account the constant marginal production cost in our model. This makes it more general because that would allow for the possibility to do sensitivity analysis with respect to production cost parameters.

4.3. Limitations and Further Research

For mathematical tractability, there are several limitations in our study. First, the assumption of a constant marginal production cost might be rigorous. It would be even more general if production cost had a generic (not necessarily linear) shape. Second, a better data source, which is used for calibrating the key parameters in the model, would help to obtain more accurate findings. Third, the case of perfect compliance is studied, and the firm’s non-compliance behavior has not yet been considered.
The issue of technology adoption in the presence of market power is rather sophisticated. In reality, a firm will face various uncertainties when makes the adoption decision, mainly including economic uncertainty (e.g., the output demand is always changing in the future) and technological uncertainty (i.e., the arrival time of new emissions abatement technologies is uncertain). Therefore, to heighten its applicability and provide policymakers with more insights on this issue, the study framework could be extended in uncertainty environments. On the other hand, our model is suitable for a single sector. In fact, many sectors will be covered in the carbon ETS. Hence, it will be meaningful to extend our model to multiple sectors. These points are the main suggestions for future research.
Finally, our model can be applied to analyze other sectors with high market concentration covered in the carbon ETS. Furthermore, the proposed analytical framework can also be extended to the setting where the agents are located in different countries, not just heterogeneous firms, and the governments are usually bound by international climate agreements such as the Paris Agreement. In this context of international ETS, China and the U.S. may have market power in the international carbon market, because they are the two countries with the most carbon emissions in the world. Therefore, to promote the adoption of new emissions abatement technologies, these countries should be set a relatively high emissions reduction target on specific time horizons.

5. Conclusions

This paper provides an analytical framework to investigate the effect of market power in the emission trading market on the diffusion of a new emissions abatement technology when firms interact in an imperfectly competitive output market. This study shows that firms will delay the adoption of the new emissions abatement technology in the presence of market power. Moreover, when the output demand is larger and more elastic technology diffusion will occur earlier. This implies that the technology diffusion in the weakly elastic sector, such as the Chinese iron and steel sector, may have more barriers than that in the strong elastic sector, such as the Chinese nonferrous metals sector. However, it should be noticed that the social welfare in an imperfect competition permits market is larger than that of firms in a perfect competition permits market throughout the sequence of adoption. A better understanding of the effects of market power on cost-effectiveness and technology diffusion would be helpful in designing better carbon ETS and related regulatory policies, especially for a country where the carbon market is still in its early stage. Therefore, in order to speed up technological diffusion and attain sustainable and low-carbon development, the policymaker should pay more attention to the market structure of sector covered in the ETS. Furthermore, the regulator can enhance supervision for the key firms to cope with the side effects of market power.

Author Contributions

B.Z. built the model of analysis used, analyzed the data, and wrote the paper. L.Z. conceived the research idea and designed the general framework of the research. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Natural Science Foundation of China, Nos. 71690245, 71673019, 71273253 and 71210005. All remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the authors.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. The Solution Process of E 0 in the Absence of Environmental Policy

Firms choose the output levels to maximize profits. Firm 1 solves the problem:
π 1 = M a x e 1 [ ( a b ( k 1 e 1 + k 2 e 2 ) ) k 1 e 1 c 1 ( k 1 e 1 ) ] ,
and firm 2 solves the problem:
π 2 = M a x e 2 [ ( a b ( k 1 e 1 + k 2 e 2 ) ) k 2 e 2 c 2 ( k 2 e 2 ) ] .
According to the FOCs, we obtain the following:
e 1 = a 2 c 1 + c 2 3 b k 1 , e 2 = a 2 c 2 + c 1 3 b k 2
Therefore, the total emissions in the absence of environmental policy is given by:
E 0 = e 1 + e 2 = a ( k 1 + k 2 ) c 1 ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) + c 2 ( k 2 2 k 1 ) 3 b k 1 k 2

Appendix B. The Results in the Perfectly Competitive Permits Market

Firms are price takers in a perfectly competitive permits market. That is, both firms make their output and emissions decisions simultaneously taking the permit price as given.
Firm 1 solves the problem:
π 1 = M a x e 1 [ ( a b ( k 1 e 1 + k 2 e 2 ) ) k 1 e 1 c 1 ( k 1 e 1 ) p c ( e 1 ε 1 ) ] ,
and firm 2 solves the problem:
π 2 = M a x e 2 [ ( a b ( k 1 e 1 + k 2 e 2 ) ) k 2 e 2 c 2 ( k 2 e 2 ) p c ( e 2 ε 2 ) ] ,
where p c is the equilibrium permit price, ε 1 and ε 2 are the quantity of emissions permits freely received by firm 1 and firm 2, respectively.
According to the FOCs, we have the following:
e 1 = a c 1 3 b k 1 + k 1 2 k 2 3 b k 1 2 k 2 p c ,    e 2 = a c 2 3 b k 2 + k 2 2 k 1 3 b k 1 k 2 2 p c .
Since e 1 + e 2 = E , the equilibrium permit price p c is given by:
p c = ( a c 1 ) k 2 + ( a c 2 ) k 1 2 k 1 k 2 k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 3 b E 2 k 1 2 k 2 2 k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 .
Hence, the emissions levels of the firms are
e 1 = 1 6 b ( a c 1 ) ( 2 k 1 k 2 ) + ( a c 2 ) ( k 1 2 k 2 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 E 2 k 2 ( k 1 2 k 2 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 ,
e 2 = 1 6 b ( a c 1 ) ( k 2 2 k 1 ) + ( a c 2 ) ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 E 2 k 1 ( k 2 2 k 1 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 .
Then, the outputs levels of the firms are
q 1 = 1 6 b k 1 ( 2 k 1 k 2 ) ( a c 1 ) + k 1 ( k 1 2 k 2 ) ( a c 2 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 E 2 k 1 k 2 ( k 1 2 k 2 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 ,
q 2 = 1 6 b k 2 ( a c 1 ) ( k 2 2 k 1 ) + k 2 ( a c 2 ) ( 2 k 2 k 1 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 E 2 k 1 k 2 ( k 2 2 k 1 ) k 1 2 + k 2 2 k 1 k 2 .

Appendix C

Proof of Lemma 1.
Let γ ( t 1 1 , t 1 2 , t 2 ) = f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) , then we can get
γ ( t 1 1 , t 1 2 , t 1 1 ) = f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 1 1 ) f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 1 1 ) < 0 ,
γ ( t 1 1 , t 1 2 , t 1 2 ) = f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 1 2 ) f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 1 2 ) > 0 .
Since γ / t 2 = [ ( π 1 1 π 1 N A ) ( π 1 A π 1 2 ) ] e δ t 2 > 0 , it follows by the intermediate value theorem and the monotonicity of γ in t 2 that there exists a unique t ˜ 1 ( t 1 1 , t 1 2 ) such that f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) as t 2 t ˜ 1 , and vice versa. □
Proof of Theorem 1.
(i) Case 1: t 2 < t ˜ 1
t 1 t 2 ,
V 1 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) = f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) > f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 )   f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
t 1 t 2 , t 1 t 1 2 ,
V 1 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) = f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) > f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 )   = V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
Thus R 1 ( t 2 ) = t 1 2 .
(ii) Case 2: t 2 = t ˜ 1
t 1 t 2 , t 1 t 1 1 ,
V 1 ( t 1 1 , t ˜ 1 ) = f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t ˜ 1 ) > f 1 1 ( t 1 , t ˜ 1 ) = V 1 ( t 1 , t ˜ 1 ) .
t 1 t 2 , t 1 t 1 2 ,
V 1 ( t 1 2 , t ˜ 1 ) = f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t ˜ 1 ) > f 1 2 ( t 1 , t ˜ 1 ) = V 1 ( t 1 , t ˜ 1 ) .
Since f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t ˜ 1 ) = f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t ˜ 1 ) , thus R 1 ( t 2 ) = { t 1 1 , t 1 2 } .
(iii) Case 3: t 2 > t ˜ 1
t 1 t 2 , t 1 t 1 1 ,
V 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) = f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) > f 1 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
t t 2 ,
V 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) = f 1 1 ( t 1 1 , t 2 ) > f 1 2 ( t 1 2 , t 2 ) f 1 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
Thus R 1 ( t 2 ) = t 1 1 . □
Proof of Lemma 2.
Let η ( t 1 , t 2 1 , t 2 2 ) = f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) , then we can get
η ( t 2 1 , t 2 1 , t 2 2 ) = f 2 1 ( t 2 1 , t 2 1 ) f 2 2 ( t 2 1 , t 2 2 ) < 0 ,
η ( t 2 2 , t 2 1 , t 2 2 ) = f 2 1 ( t 2 2 , t 2 1 ) f 2 2 ( t 2 2 , t 2 2 ) > 0 .
Since η / t 1 = [ ( π 2 2 π 2 N A ) ( π 2 A π 2 1 ) ] e δ t 1 > 0 , it follows by the intermediate value theorem and the monotonicity of η in t 1 that there exists a unique t ˜ 2 ( t 2 1 , t 2 2 ) such that f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) as t 1 t ˜ 2 , and vice versa. □
Proof of Theorem 2.
(i) Case 1: t 1 < t ˜ 2
t 2 t 1 ,
V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) = f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) > f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 )   = V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
t 2 t 1 , t 2 t 2 2 ,
V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) = f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) > f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 )   = V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
Thus R 2 ( t 1 ) = t 2 2 .
(ii) Case 2: t 1 = t ˜ 2
t 2 t 1 , t 2 t 2 1 ,
V 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 1 ) = f 2 1 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 1 ) > f 2 1 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 ) = V 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 ) .
t 2 t 1 , t 2 t 2 2 ,
V 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 2 ) = f 2 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 2 ) > f 2 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 ) = V 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 ) .
Since f 2 1 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 1 ) = f 2 2 ( t ˜ 2 , t 2 2 ) , thus R 2 ( t 1 ) = { t 2 1 , t 2 2 } .
(iii) Case 3: t 1 > t ˜ 2
t 2 t 1 , t 2 t 2 1 ,
V 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) = f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) > f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 )
t 2 t 1 ,
V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) = f 2 1 ( t 1 , t 2 1 ) > f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 2 ) f 2 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) = V 2 ( t 1 , t 2 ) .
Thus R 2 ( t 1 ) = t 2 1 .□
Proof of Theorem 3.
According to Theorems 1 and 2, the best-response correspondences R 1 and R 2 are shown in Figure A1 and Figure A2, respectively.
Figure A1. Firm 1’s best-response correspondence.
Figure A1. Firm 1’s best-response correspondence.
Sustainability 11 03870 g0a1
Figure A2. Firm 2’s best-response correspondence.
Figure A2. Firm 2’s best-response correspondence.
Sustainability 11 03870 g0a2
As shown in Figure A3, it is not difficult to show that there is only one intersection between them if t ˜ 2 > t 1 2 or { t ˜ 2 < t 1 2 t ˜ 1 < t 2 1 .
Figure A3. Part (1) in Theorem 3.
Figure A3. Part (1) in Theorem 3.
Sustainability 11 03870 g0a3
That is, if t ˜ 2 > t 1 2 or { t ˜ 2 < t 1 2 t ˜ 1 < t 2 1 , then there exists a unique Nash equilibrium ( t 1 1 , t 2 2 ) .
As shown in Figure A4, it is easy to obtain Parts (2) and (3) in Theorem 3 in the same way. □
Figure A4. Parts (2) and (3) in Theorem 3.
Figure A4. Parts (2) and (3) in Theorem 3.
Sustainability 11 03870 g0a4

References

  1. IPCC. Climate Change: The Physical Science Basis; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  2. Montero, J.P. Market power in pollution permit markets. Energy J. 2009, 30, 115–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Eyckmans, J.; Hagem, C. The European Union’s potential for strategic emissions trading through permit sales contracts. Resour. Energy Econ. 2011, 33, 247–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Min, X.J.; Dong, X.Y.; Zi, Y.C.; Pu, Y.N. Market power in auction and efficiency in emission permits allocation. J. Econ. Manag. 2016, 183, 576–584. [Google Scholar]
  5. Hintermann, B. Market power in emission permit markets: Theory and evidence from the EU-ETS. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2017, 66, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Dickson, A.; Mackenzie, I.A. Strategic trade in pollution permits. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2018, 87, 94–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Hahn, R.W. Market power and transferable property rights. Q. J. Econ. 1984, 99, 753–765. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Westskog, H. Market power in a system of tradeable CO2 quotas. Energy J. 1996, 17, 85–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Misiolek, W.S.; Elder, H.W. Exclusionary manipulation of markets for pollution rights. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1989, 16, 156–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Malik, A.S. Further results on permit markets with market power and cheating. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2002, 44, 1–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Hintermann, B. Market power, permit allocation and efficiency in emission permit markets. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2011, 49, 327–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Hintermann, B. Pass-through of CO2 emission costs to hourly electricity prices in Germany. J. Assoc. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2016, 3, 857–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Tanaka, M.; Chen, Y. Market power in emissions trading: Strategically manipulating permit price through fringe firms. Appl. Energy 2012, 96, 203–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Haita, C. Endogenous market power in an emissions trading scheme with auctioning. Resour. Energy Econ. 2014, 37, 253–278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Amundsen, E.S.; Bergman, L. Green certificates and market power on the Nordic power market. Energy J. 2012, 33, 101–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zhang, Z. Carbon emissions trading in China: The evolution from pilots to a nationwide scheme. Clim. Policy 2015, 15, S104–S126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Wrake, M.; Myers, E.; Mandell, S.; Holt, C.; Burtraw, D. Pricing Strategies Under Emissions Trading: An Experimental Analysis; RFF Discussion Paper: Washington, DC, USA, 2008; pp. 8–49. [Google Scholar]
  18. Dormady, N.C. Carbon auctions, energy markets & market power: An experimental analysis. Energy Econ. 2014, 44, 468–482. [Google Scholar]
  19. Noah, D. Carbon auction revenue and market power: An experimental analysis. Energies 2016, 9, 897–917. [Google Scholar]
  20. Álvarez, F.; André, F.J. Auctioning versus grandfathering in cap-and-trade systems with market power and incomplete information. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2015, 62, 873–906. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. D’amato, A.; Valentini, E.; Zoli, M. Tradable quota taxation and market power. Energy Econ. 2017, 63, 248–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Montero, J.P. Permits, standards, and technology innovation. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2002, 44, 23–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Montero, J.P. Market structure and environmental innovation. J. Appl. Econ. 2002, 5, 293–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Storrosten, H.B. Incentives to Invest in Abatement Technology: A Tax versus Emissions Trading under Imperfect Competition; Discussion Papers no. 606; Statistics Norway, Research Department: Oslo, Norway, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  25. Zhou, P.; Wang, M. Carbon dioxide emissions allocation: A Review. Ecol. Econ. 2016, 125, 47–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Narassimhan, E.; Gallagher, K.S.; Koester, S.; Alejo, J.R. Carbon pricing in practice: A review of existing emissions trading systems. Clim. Policy 2018, 18, 967–991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. André, F.J.; Arguedas, C. Technology adoption in emission trading programs with market power. Energy J. 2018, 39, 145–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wang, X.; Zhang, X.B.; Zhu, L. Imperfect market, emissions trading scheme, and technology adoption: A case study of an energy-intensive sector. Energy Econ. 2019, 81, 142–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Rogge, K.S.; Schneider, M.; Hoffmann, V.H. The innovation impact of the EU Emission Trading System—Findings of company case studies in the German power sector. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 513–523. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Wang, X.; Zhu, L.; Fan, Y. Transaction costs, market structure and efficient coverage of emissions trading scheme: A microlevel study from the pilots in China. Appl. Energy 2018, 220, 657–671. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Rana, M.M.; Li, L.; Su, S.W. An adaptive-then-combine dynamic state estimation considering renewable generations in smart grids. IEEE J. Sel. Areas Commun. 2016, 34, 3954–3961. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Rana, M.M. Modelling the microgrid and its parameter estimations considering fading channels. IEEE Access 2017, 5, 10953–10958. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Rana, M.M.; Li, L.; Su, S.W.; Xiang, W. Consensus-based smart grid state estimation algorithm. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inf. 2017, 14, 3368–3375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Rana, M.M. Architecture of the internet of energy network: An application to smart grid communications. IEEE Access 2017, 5, 4704–4710. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Rana, M.M.; Xiang, W.; Wang, E.; Li, X.H. Monitoring the smart grid incorporating turbines and vehicles. IEEE Access 2018, 6, 45485–45492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Rana, M.M.; Xiang, W.; Wang, E. Iot-based state estimation for microgrids. IEEE Internet Things J. 2018, 5, 1345–1346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Rana, M.M.; Xiang, W.; Wang, E. Smart grid state estimation and stabilisation. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2018, 102, 152–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Reinganum, J.F. On the diffusion of new technology: A game theoretic approach. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1981, 48, 395–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Coria, J. Taxes, permits, and the diffusion of a new technology. Resour. Energy Econ. 2009, 31, 249–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Sanin, M.E.; Zanaj, S. A note on clean technology adoption and its influence on tradeable emission permits prices. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2011, 48, 561–567. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Lecuyer, O.; Quirion, P. Can uncertainty justify overlapping policy instruments to mitigate emissions? Ecol. Econ. 2013, 93, 177–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Li, Y.; Zhu, L. Cost of energy saving and CO2 emissions reduction in China’s iron and steel sector. Appl. Energy 2014, 130, 603–616. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Guo, J.X.; Zhu, L. Optimal timing of technology adoption under the changeable abatement coefficient through R & D. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2016, 96, 216–226. [Google Scholar]
  44. Zhu, L.; Zhang, X.B.; Li, Y.; Wang, X.; Guo, J. Can an emission trading scheme promote the withdrawal of outdated capacity in energy-intensive sectors? A case study on China’s iron and steel industry. Energy Econ. 2017, 63, 332–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Khanna, M.; Zilberman, D. Incentives, precision technology and environmental protection. Ecol. Econ. 1997, 23, 25–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Frondel, M.; Horbach, J.; Rennings, K. End-of-pipe or cleaner production? An empirical comparison of environmental innovation decisions across OECD countries. Bus. Strat. Environ. 2007, 16, 571–584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Hammar, H.; Löfgren, A. Explaining adoption of end-of-pipe solutions and energy-saving technologies—Determinants of firms’ investments for reducing emissions to air in four sectors in Sweden. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3644–3651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The schematic of the study framework.
Figure 1. The schematic of the study framework.
Sustainability 11 03870 g001
Figure 2. Changes in the parameter a of demand function and technology adoption.
Figure 2. Changes in the parameter a of demand function and technology adoption.
Sustainability 11 03870 g002
Figure 3. Changes in the parameter b of demand function and technology adoption.
Figure 3. Changes in the parameter b of demand function and technology adoption.
Sustainability 11 03870 g003
Figure 4. Changes in the marginal production cost and technology adoption.
Figure 4. Changes in the marginal production cost and technology adoption.
Sustainability 11 03870 g004
Figure 5. Changes in the percent of emissions reduction and technology adoption.
Figure 5. Changes in the percent of emissions reduction and technology adoption.
Sustainability 11 03870 g005
Table 1. The profit opportunities of firms.
Table 1. The profit opportunities of firms.
Adoption Dates t The Profit of Firm 1The Profit of Firm 2
0 t min { t 1 , t 2 } π 1 N A π 2 N A
t 1 t t 2 π 1 1 π 2 1
t 2 t t 1 π 1 2 π 2 2
max { t 1 , t 2 } t < π 1 A π 2 A
Table 2. Parameters used in the numerical simulation.
Table 2. Parameters used in the numerical simulation.
ParametersDimensionDescriptionValueSource
a Parameters in linear inverse demand function7191[44]
b 5.2
c 1 (yuan/tSteel)Firm 1’s production cost coefficient2374
c 2 (yuan/tSteel)Firm 2’s production cost coefficient3543
k 1 (tSteel/tCO2)Firm 1’s initial emissions intensity0.6
k 2 (tSteel/tCO2)Firm 2’s initial emissions intensity0.47
k 0 (tSteel/tCO2)Emissions intensity of the new technology0.8Given
K (million yuan)The parameter of investment cost1Given
θ The diffusion rate0.038[39]
λ Percentage of emissions reductions0.1Given
δ The discount rate0.05Given
Table 3. Changes in a and social welfare.
Table 3. Changes in a and social welfare.
a 6891699170917192729173917491
Δ C S ( 1 ) 414426426426426425425
Δ F P ( 1 ) 48,64246,48645,76745,04944,33143,61442,898
Δ I C ( 1 ) −71,379−75,291−79,222−83,375−87,785−92,265−96,938
Δ W ( 1 ) 120,435122,203125,415128,850132,542136,304140,261
Δ C S ( 2 ) 0000000
Δ F P ( 2 ) 83,22083,22083,22083,22083,22083,22083,220
Δ I C ( 2 ) −8489−9502−10,635−11,847−13,250−14,763−16,430
Δ W ( 2 ) 91,70992,72293,85595,06796,47097,98399,651
Table 4. Changes in b and social welfare.
Table 4. Changes in b and social welfare.
b 4.64.85.05.25.45.65.8
Δ C S ( 1 ) 377393409426442459475
Δ F P ( 1 ) 50,92548,80346,85145,04943,38041,83140,389
Δ I C ( 1 ) −110,840−100,390−91,363−83,375−76,399−70,255−64,805
Δ W ( 1 ) 162,142149,586138,623128,850120,220112,545105,669
Δ C S ( 2 ) 0000000
Δ F P ( 2 ) 94,07590,15586,54983,22080,13877,27674,611
Δ I C ( 2 ) −15,819−14,281−12,982−11,847−10,915−9992−9239
Δ W ( 2 ) 109,894104,44099,53195,06791,05387,26883,850
Note. Changes in consumer surplus are shown as zero when two firms are using the new technology because its absolute value was too small (less than e 10 ).

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zeng, B.; Zhu, L. Market Power and Technology Diffusion in an Energy-Intensive Sector Covered by an Emissions Trading Scheme. Sustainability 2019, 11, 3870. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11143870

AMA Style

Zeng B, Zhu L. Market Power and Technology Diffusion in an Energy-Intensive Sector Covered by an Emissions Trading Scheme. Sustainability. 2019; 11(14):3870. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11143870

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zeng, Bingxin, and Lei Zhu. 2019. "Market Power and Technology Diffusion in an Energy-Intensive Sector Covered by an Emissions Trading Scheme" Sustainability 11, no. 14: 3870. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11143870

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop