Next Article in Journal
The Regulation of Genetically Modified Organisms on a Local Level: Exploring the Determinants of Cultivation Bans
Previous Article in Journal
Fiscal Adjustment Programs versus Socially Sustainable Competitiveness in EU Countries
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A System Dynamics Model to Evaluate Effects of Retailer-Led Recycling Based on Dual Chains Competition: A Case of e-Waste in China

1
School of Computer Science and Technology, Harbin University of Science and Technology, Harbin 150080, China
2
School of Computer and Control Engineering, Qiqihar University, Qiqihar 161000, China
3
Newcastle Business School, Faculty of Business and Law, University of Newcastle, Australia, University Drive, Callaghan, NSW 2308, Australia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2018, 10(10), 3391; https://doi.org/10.3390/su10103391
Submission received: 2 August 2018 / Revised: 5 September 2018 / Accepted: 20 September 2018 / Published: 23 September 2018

Abstract

:
China, as the largest electronic waste producer in the world, is facing a critical challenge to manage its negative impacts on the environment. Hence, e-waste management is crucial for sustainable Chinese economic development. In this paper, a system dynamics model is adopted to identify the effects of retailer-led recycling based on closed-loop dual chains competition. The influence of contracts made by manufacturers on different retail modes is also discussed. From the aspects of total revenue (TR), market share (MS) and market competitiveness (MC), this paper analyzes the impact of e-waste recycling coefficient (ERC) on supply chain and analyzes the equilibrium solution of total supply chain return. The research results show that the contract incentive mechanism can improve the retailer’s recycling enthusiasm, and the effect on the retail mode of executive shop is more obvious. When the ERC is adjusted to 44.3%, the TR of supply chain is optimal, and the MS and MC occupy an obvious advantage.

1. Introduction

According to China’s Ministry of Industry and Information Technology (MIIT, 2014), China has surpassed the United States to become the world’s largest electronic waste producer in 2013, China’s major electronic products scrap is more than 200 million units per year, weighing more than 5 million tons. The recycling and reuse of electronic waste (e-waste) is attracted more concern from both the ecological and economical points of view.
The Global E-waste Monitor 2017 shows that the development of information and communication technology (ICT) and the shortening the replacing cycle are exacerbating the growth of e-waste, the total number of e-waste generated by countries around the world reached 44.7 million cubic tones that is equivalent to 6.1 kg per inhabitant (kg/inh) in 2016, which increased from 5.8 kg/inh in 2014. In 2016, 44.7 million tons of e-waste were produced in the world, only 20% of them had been recycled through appropriate channels. It was estimated that the total value of raw materials contained in e-waste worth about 55 billion euros in 2016 that is higher than the year’s gross domestic product of most countries [1]. The value of the secondary raw materials obtained after waste management is only the value of its components or the price of used equipment. Countries need to adopt a circular economy mode to compensate for material loopholes through better design, recycling and reuse of components.
Electronic products are moving towards personalization, diversification and rapid pace of renewal. On the one hand, the complex composition of electronic products, containing heavy metals, halogen chemicals and other toxic and harmful substances cannot be decomposed by themselves, directly discarded or disposed of arbitrarily not only will cause great damage to the environment, but also may even endanger the health of the surrounding residents. On the other hand, because the characteristics of e-waste determine is different from the general urban garbage. It is a highly valuable renewable resource and is known as “urban mine”. For example, a ton of randomly collected electronic card plates can separate 129.73 kg copper, 29.48 kg aluminum, 0.45 kg gold, 19.96 kg nickel, 40.82 kg magnesium, 9.98 kg antimony and other metal elements. The benefits of the large amount of non-ferrous metals, rare metals and precious metals generated in e-waste are much higher than the metal resources available in mining ore, and the consumption of resources and costs are much lower than the latter.
The recycling and re-manufacturing of e-waste can bring great economic benefits to the related enterprises. Enterprises can greatly reduce the operating cost of enterprises by recycling e-waste through a series of reverse logistics activities to turn them into abundant and usable resources, then directly into the second-hand market and re-sell as raw materials into the enterprise’s production process.
The “Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR)” concept was proposed in Europe which was based on the principle of “The polluter is responsible for pollution” and “reduce hazardous substance” in 1993. Producers are required to bear the responsibility in the whole life cycle of their products (the circle including the production, recycling, reprocessing) to reduce the environmental pollution. It is a system that uses modern environment management concept to achieve the virtuous recycling of products. With the introduction of the EPR concept, countries around the world have responded and incorporated it into the new laws and regulations. China has passed the Recovery and Disposal of Waste Electrical and Electronic Products (WEEE) policy in the 23rd meeting of the State Council on 20 August 2008, which formally implemented on 1 January 2011. The regulations clearly stipulate matters concerning the recycling and recycling of e-waste and electronic products.
In summary, with the emergence of a large number of e-waste and electronic products, the implementation of EPR has become a national consensus. Whether it is to comply with national environmental laws and policies or based on the great profit-driven recycling and reuse, e-waste recycling is inevitable.
The first part of the paper is introduction of e-waste research. The second part is literature of e-waste research and CLSC research, and discusses the difference between these papers and our paper. The third part describes dual chains competition structure. The fourth part is the research method of our paper. The fifth part is the simulation results of our model and some discussion has been done about the results. The last part is the conclusion drawn from the fourth part.

2. Literature Review

Fleischmann et al. [2] and Guide et al. [3] has made a comprehensive elaboration on the reverse logistics management of re-manufacturing under the current research on re-manufacturing closed-loop supply chain management. Subramanian et al. [4] explains the problem of the manufacturer’s reverse supply chain coordination under the EPR. Sehultmann et al. [5] and Krikke [6] analyze the operation of reverse logistics from the perspectives of automation industry and network design respectively and propose a centralized supply chain by a decision-maker responsible for planning to achieve closed-loop supply chain overall profit maximization is optimal. Savaskan et al. [7] proposes three recycling methods based on this theory, these are recycling by manufacturers, recycling by retailers and recycling by third parties. The recycling by retailers is proved to be optimal under its hypothetical condition. Nie [8] mainly studies the influence of four channel structures on closed-loop supply chain with recycling by third parties. Wang and Da [9] identify the effects of the reward and punishment mechanism on the decision of re-manufacturing. Nie [10] explore the effects of the reward and punishment mechanism on the decision of re-manufacturing closed-loop supply chain. However, the above studies mainly focus on the perspective of decentralized decision-making to optimize the benefits of participants in the supply chain, neglected the importance to improve the operation efficiency. Li et al. [11] put forward a partnership maintaining method to improve supply chain operational efficiency at the perspective of trust. To improve the performance of the decentralized decision-making, many scholars have deepened the research on the reverse supply chain by designing the contract. He and Khouja [12] studies the Pareto model of supply chain contract under the goal satisfaction, and analyzes the factors influencing the contract in the supply chain. Xue et al. [13] compares the re-manufacturing system of decentralized decision model with centralized decision model, and four types of incentive contracts are designed to improve supply chain operation efficiency. Based on the revenue-sharing coordination mechanism, Chen and Gao [14] design revenue sharing contracts, and the model of Multi-Stage Supply Chain Coordination is established. Based on the contract theory, Kong and Luo [15] study the pricing strategy of reverse supply chain. In the case of asymmetric information of cost and demand, Lei et al. [16] coordinates the operation of supply chain participants through contract. Qiao et al. [17] design supply chain sharing contracts based on the characteristics of the product service system. The above papers analyze the effect of contracts in supply chain management on supply chain and its participants. From the view of asymmetric information, Bao and Pu [18] adopt Principal-agent framework to study the profit game between manufacturers and retailers under the contract.
In condensation of closed-loop supply chain study on competition, Heese [19] studies the effect of re-manufacturing on the competitive advantage of duopoly manufacturers, identify that the manufacturer who implement recycling and re-manufacturing will not only be able to earn more profits but also increase sales. Ferguson and Toktay [20] discusses the influence of competition on recycling strategy by comparing the re-manufacturing decision of absolute monopolized manufacturer with oligopoly manufacturer. Parlar and Weng [21] use game theory to study the coordination method between yield and price in the case of price competition. Ferrer [22] raises the problem of managing new manufacturing and re-manufacturing products by manufacturers, using the optimization method to make decisions for manufacturers. Ferrer [23] discusses manufacturer’s production decisions in the case of the new manufacturing and re-manufacturing products of market segments. In the duopoly competition of manufacturer and re-manufacturer, Webster and Mitra [24] compare the changes in the interests of manufacturers, re-manufacturers, governments and consumers between control and no control on recycling products by manufacturers. After that, Atasu et al. [25] studies the influence factors of re-manufacturing and explore the profitability of the manufacturer’s re-manufacturing in the case of absolute monopolized and competition. Chinese scholars have also conducted relevant research in this field. Zhou and Liang et al. [26], Cao and Xiong et al. [27], respectively, discuss the product substitution and the competition between manufacturer and re-manufacturer. Yi [28,29,30] constructs three game models of re-manufacturing closed-loop supply chain, such as Stackelberg game led by the manufacturer, Stackelberg game led by the retailer and Nash Equilibrium game about manufacturer and retailer. Meanwhile the influences of different market structures on recycling rate, wholesale, retail price, channel members profit and channel gross profit are analyzed. Han and Xue [31] apply evolutionary game theory to analyze the influence on recycling channels by the degree of competition between producers, re-manufacturing cost savings and the degree of difficulty in recycling. Han and Dong [32] construct the decision-making model of recycling channel of bilateral competition closed-loop supply chain for two competing manufacturers and two competing retailers, finding that the selection of recycling channel is affected by the competition between retailers and manufacturers.
From the perspective of the manufacturer, Xie et al. [33] treat the quality of products as an endogenous variable to discuss the manufacturer’s optimal manufacturing and re-manufacturing strategies in oligarch, duopoly non-cooperation and duopoly cooperation market. Zheng and Li [34] studies the influence of market competition on recycling channel selection, when the market competition is small, manufacturers choose their own recycling channels whist when the market competition is fierce, manufacturers choose retailers’ recycling channels.
There are numerous research on recycling mode, Savaskan [35] compares the system efficiency of recycling by manufacturers and recycling by retailers in the competition between two retailers, revealing that the competition between retailers significantly affect the choice of optimal recycling mode. Yi [36] constructed three hybrid recycling models of product remanufacturing closed-loop supply chain by using game theory under the premium and penalty mechanism. In different hybrid recycling modes, the profits of return rate, retail price, node enterprises and supply chain were compared and analyzed, and the selection problem of optimal hybrid recycling mode was researched. McGuire [37] first proposes the research framework of the competition between chains which discusses the dominant vertical structure of two manufacturers and two alternative retailers and identify that the decentralized structure can alleviate the severe price competition to some extent. In recent years, it has been gradually extended to the comparison between the recycling mode of competitive closed-loop supply chain dominated by retailers and channel structure. For two competitive supply chains (one is traditional supply chain with no re-manufacturing and other one is closed-loop supply chain with recycling by manufacturer). Wei [38] studies system pricing and re-manufacturing strategies in the situation of centralized and four decentralized channel structures, based on domination by manufacturers or retailers. In the context of competition between a traditional forward supply chain and a closed-loop supply chain with recycling by manufacturers, Zheng [39] compares variable equilibrium solutions and profit allocation results of centralized channel structure (both chains are centralized decision-making), distributed channel structure (both chains are decentralized decision-making by manufacturer) and hybrid channel structure(one is centralized decision-making, the other one is decentralized decision-making by manufacturer). Song et al. [40] studies channel structure selection of two competition closed-loop supply chains with recycling by third party. Li [41] studies sales model selection of two competing decentralized closed-loop supply chains with recycling by manufacturer. Li [42] compares the member profits and environment performances in closed-loop supply chain with recycling by manufacturer, retailer and third party, recognizing the optimal recycling mode with the combination of different competitive intensity and recycling compensation price parameters. Yoon and Jeong [43] propose four competition strategies to explore the advertisement costs, trade-in allowance of retailers and the difference in the avenue.
In summary, the existing closed-loop supply chain management literature concentrate on the supply chain’s decision structure, recycling channel selection and recycling price, but lacks the research on the dual chains dominated by retailers competing contracts by SD methods. The research on closed-loop supply chain competition is mostly based on two hypotheses: one is to assume that market demand is certain; the other one is to assume that information is symmetrical, in other words, the information fully shared among members in the closed-loop supply chain. Such models are less representative in the context of market demand fluctuation and the difficulty of information sharing.
In the past research, the system dynamics (SD) method is less used to study the closed-loop supply chain competition, which is dominated by retailers. In the comparison of system dynamics method with other social science research methods, such as econometric model and input-output analysis, each of them has its advantages and disadvantages. All of research objects have own appropriate method, and it is impossible for one method to completely replace the other.
However, based on the features and principles of system dynamics, our research adopts SD method due to some advantages of modeling as the follow discussion. Firstly, SD is good at dealing with cyclical problems. Secondly, SD is good at dealing with long-term problems; Thirdly, SD is good at dealing with problems in the condition of lack of data; Fourthly, SD is good at dealing with problems of non-linear and high-order time change; Finally, SD can emphasis on conditional forecasting.
Therefore, SD is used to construct two closed-loop chains with recycling by retailers in the context of information asymmetric in this paper. To match the actual situation, the market demand is set to random. Two supply chains are competing in the same market, which forms a competition environment. To gain more profit in the competition, manufacturers use contract to strengthen the cooperation with the retailer. Contracts can enhance the retailers recycling enthusiasm and increase the amount of recycling.
Two supply chains use different contracts. The contract of supply chain 1 is designed according to MS. The contract of supply chain 2 is designed according to the proportion of reuse inventory (REI) in retailers recycling inventory (RRI).
By adjusting the influence coefficient of the model and the recovery coefficient of e-waste, the total revenue of supply chain, market share, the change of market competitiveness and its influence on competitors are observed, and the related parties are provided with a scientific decision-making basis.

3. Dual Chains Competition Structure Diagram

Dual chains competition of closed-loop supply chains with recycling by retailers is shown in Figure 1. Two manufacturers in supply chains purchase raw materials from different suppliers for production. The product is delivered to retailers through the third-party logistics (3PL). Retailers are responsible for sales. To gain better revenues, both manufacturers respectively make a contract with retailers to get more discarded products. Retailers transport recycling to manufacturers through the 3PL. Manufacturers will re-enter the market by dismantling, repairing and re-creating the scrap.
In this model, the multi-supplier principle is adopted by two manufacturers, which is mainly to avoid the supply chain disruptions caused by the supply interruption of single supplier. The multi-supplier principle also has the following advantages. It can share the risk of interruption in supply. It can motivate each of retailers to remain competitiveness (cost, delivery date, service). It can encourage retailers to innovation, because they will be dropped if they fail to keep up over time.
The reasons why manufacturers choose recycling by retailers are as follows. Retailers are located all over the country to facilitate the recycling. Relying on the transportation and distribution system, retailers are easy to send recycling to manufacturers, which can save shipping costs. As the main body of recycling, retailers play the role of connecting manufacturers and market, they are mainly responsible for sales and recycling.

4. Materials and Methods

4.1. System Dynamic Method

SD is a subject of analyzing and studying information feedback system, and it is also a cross-discipline subject to recognize and solve system problem. SD is a branch of system science and management science, and it is also a horizontal discipline linking the fields of natural science and social science. In terms of system methodology, SD is a method to unify structural method, functional method and historical method. SD considers that the behavior patterns and characteristics of the system are mainly determined by its internal dynamic structure and feedback mechanism. The system refers to the complex of interactive units, the feedback refers to the relationship between the output and input of the same unit or its sub-block in the system. For the whole system, feedback refers to the relationship between the system output and the input from the external environment. It can be directly associated with the corresponding input from the output of a unit, sub-block, and system and can be implemented through media (other units, sub-block, and other systems). Since Forrester, SD has been applied to various business and strategy problems. Krikke et al. developed a model applied to a CLSC of refrigerators [44]. The model aims to minimize the costs, energy use and waste of supply chain operations. Georgiadis and Besiou developed a SD model to realize the long-term system behavior under multiple environmental events, which directly contributed to ecological motivation and impact of the policy on technological innovation [45].

4.2. System Dynamics Modeling

This model makes the following assumptions for research. Suppliers, retailers and manufacturers use a typical inventory replenishment strategy for order or production. There is no difference in quality between re-manufactured products and new products. Manufacturers prefer to use recycling for production.
According to the structure diagram shown in Figure 1, the SD model is constructed, as shown in Figure 2. The supply chain 1 contains contract 1 that is the incentive strategy made by manufacturers based on MS, and the retailer is exclusive shop mode. Manufacturers can improve incentive of contract 1 to retailer through employee, the effect on the supply chain 1 can be improved. The mechanism of contract 1 is shown in Figure 3. The supply chain 2 contains contract 2 that is the incentive strategy made by manufacturers based on the proportion of REI in RRI. Since the retailer in the supply chain 2 is common retailer that sales multiple manufacturers’ products, the retailers recycling enthusiasm is influenced by multiple manufacturers, which causes the incentive of contract 2 to retailers is stable, that the effect in the supply chain 2 stays at the same level. The mechanism of contract 2 is shown in Figure 4.
MS reflects the proportion of a company’s sales in similar products of the market. A high MS indicates the good sales in the same product market. In the case of good sales, manufacturers have the responsibility of recycling and need more recycling as raw materials, which can save more cost. Therefore, the manufacturer makes contract 1 based on MS.
The specify rules of contract 1 are as follows:
Manufacturer incentive coefficient = IF THEN ELSE (MS ≤ 0.8, IF THEN ELSE (MS ≤ 0.6, IF THEN ELSE (MS ≤ 0.4, IF THEN ELSE (MS ≤ 0.2, 0.2, 0.5), 0.6), 0.7), 0.8).
When the MS is less than or equal to 0.2, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.2.
When the MS is greater than 0.2 and less than 0.4, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.5.
When the MS is greater than 0.4 and less than 0.6, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.6.
When the MS is greater than 0.6 and less than 0.8, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.7.
When the MS is greater than 0.8, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.8.
When the proportion of REI in RRI is large, the amount of recycling used for re-manufacturing will increase. Meanwhile, the manufacturer needs to replenish the quantity of recycling in time for maintaining the reuse inventory. To gain more profit in the competition, the manufacturer makes the contract 2 based on the proportion of REI in RRI.
The specify rules of contract 2 are as follows:
IF THEN ELSE (RI ≤ (0.6 × RRI), IF THEN ELSE (RI ≤ (0.4 × RRI), IF THEN ELSE (RI ≤ (0.2 × RRI), 0.1, 0.2), 0.4), 0.6).
When RI is less than 0.2 times RRI, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.1.
When RI is greater than 0.2 times RRI and less than 0.4 times RRI, manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.2.
When RI is greater than 0.4 times RRI and less than 0.6 times RRI, manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.4.
When RI is greater than 0.6 times RRI, the manufacturer incentive coefficient is 0.6.
In the above two contracts, retailers recycling enthusiasm is equal to manufacturer incentive coefficient times effect degree.

4.3. Equation of the Model

Figure 5 is the causes tree of Manufacturers Inventory 1. Manufacturers Inventory (MI) is the stock. The change in inventory value is effected by production rate (PR), re-manufacturing rate (RER) and output rate (OR), which is the integration of PR plus the RER minus the OR. Increase of PR and RER will increase MI. The output rate can reduce MI.
The PR is influenced by production capacity (PC), raw materials inventory (RMI), production time (PT), excepted sales orders rate (ESOR), RER, manufacturers inventory adjustment (MIA) and production adjustment time (PAT). RER is limited by reuse inventory (REI) and re-manufacturing capacity (REC), which is REI times REC divided by re-manufacturing time (RET).
M   I   = t 0 t ( PR + RER OR ) d t
PR = MAX (MIN (PC, MIN (RMI/PT, MIN (ESOR−RER, MIA/PAT))), 0)
RER = REI × REC/RET
Figure 6 is the causes tree of Output Rate 1. Comparison MI with orders, the smaller one divided by transport time (TT) is compared with inventory adjustment (RIA) divided by transport adjustment time (TAT), and the smaller one is OR, which is more in line with the real world. The RIA is the difference between retailers expected inventory (REI) and retailers inventory (RI) divided by retailers inventory adjustment time (RIAT).
RIA = (REI−RI)/RIAT
OR = MAX (MIN (MIN (MI, Orders)/TT, RIA/TAT), 0)
Figure 7 is the causes tree of Retailers Inventory 1. The RI is a state variable that represents the stock. The change of RI is influenced by OR and sales rate (SR), it is the integration of OR minus SR. The OR is the increasing rate of RI, and the SR is the decrease of RI. Comparison of the orders with the RI, the smaller variable divided by sales time (ST) is the SR, which is more in line with the real world.
RI = t 0 t ( OR SR ) d t
SR = MIN (Orders, RI)/ST
Figure 8 is the causes tree of Market Competitiveness 1. MC1 is the customer loyalty (CL) 1 times green image (GI) 1 divided by the sum of the CL times GI in two chains. The GI 1 is E-waste recycling rate (ERR) 1 times re-manufacturing ratio (RER) 1. The relationship between CL and MS is the direct ratio.
MC1 = CL1 × GI1/(CL1 × GI1 + CL2 × GI2)
Figure 9 is the causes tree of Market Demands 1. Two chains compete for the total demands (TD) of the same market, and the ratio of MC 1 to the sum of MC in two chains is the ratio of TD. Market Demands (MD)1 is TD times the ratio.
MD1 = TD × (MC1 + MC2)

5. Simulation and Discussion

To match the simulation results with the reality, the constant value in the system dynamics model is set as shown in Table 1 according to actual business operation research.
In the early stage of competition, the effect degree and the e-waste recycling coefficient (ERC) are respectively 0.3 and 0.36, and the total revenues obtained from the simulation are shown in Figure 10.
It is found from Figure 10 that the total revenues of the two chains are little difference, and supply chain 2 has a slight edge. Initially, the product recycling by retailers is increasing rapidly with the incentive of contract, and the recycling cost is greater than sales revenue due to no products into the market. Thus, total revenue is negative in the beginning. Without new products to the market, retailers recycling inventory (RRI) has a peak at the second week shown in Figure 11 as retailers continue to recycle used products. Therefore total revenue has a peak at the fifth week through re-manufacturing, transportation and sales. From the 9th week, the trends of total revenues rise clearly.
To improve the total revenue, supply chain 1 strengthens the influence of contract1 on retailers by training the store staff. The effect degree 1 is adjusted to 0.5. Figure 12 shows that the market share (MS) of supply chain 1 exceeded supply chain 2 after 54th week. Because MS can reflect the customer loyalty (CL), the CL of supply chain 1 is higher than that of supply chain 2. In addition, the green image (GI) of supply chain 1 is improved due to recycling more products by retailers. As a result, the Market Competitiveness (MC) of supply chain 1 is enhanced even exceed the supply chain 2 after 36th week, causing supply chain 1 gets more demands. Therefore the total revenue of supply chain 1 increased and even exceeded the total revenue of supply chain 2 at 40th weeks as shown in Figure 13.
To turn around the bad situation, supply chain 2 decided to start a series of measures, such as strengthening environmental publicity, improving customers’ environmental awareness and enhancing the popularity of enterprises. According to the observation of the relationship between the ERC 2 and total revenue 2, there exists equilibrium relationship between the ERC 2 and total revenue 2. Extracting data from the model such as Table 2, they were fitted with matlab. The fitting curve is shown in Figure 14. Finally, when the ERC 2 reaches 0.443, the total revenue of the supply chain 2 reaches the optimal. The reason for existing the equilibrium relationship between the ERC 2 and total revenue 2 is analyzed, because the manufacturer’s re-manufacturing capacity (REC) will limit the quantity of recycling to be used, so the recycling that not used in new product can only be deposited in the warehouse. If the recycling is not controlled, it will cause inventory accumulation, so the enterprise needs funds for inventory management. The accumulation of recycling increase the recycling cost, and they cannot generate profits for the enterprise. If the quantity of the recycling is too large, the total revenue of the enterprise will decrease. Therefore enterprises should determine the amount of the recycling based on their own production capacity (PC) and REC to optimize the benefits of enterprises.
To achieve optimal revenue, supply chain 2 decides to increase the ERC 2 to 0.443 by analyzing the PC 2 and REC 2. As shown in Figure 15, the total revenue of supply chain 2 exceeds supply chain 1 after 9th week, and the supply chain 1 generates shocks. Figure 16 shows that the MS and MC of supply chain 2 outstrip supply chain 1 with absolute advantage, that causes the market demands of supply chain 1 will be dramatically decrease. The forecast information such as the excepted Demand 1 and excepted sales orders rate 1 will be dramatically reduced along with the market demands 1, which leads to reduce retailers expected inventory (REI) 1, inventory adjustment (RIA) 1, manufacturers expected inventory 1 and MIA 1, and with the random demands. So there will be uncertainty about production rate (PR) 1, output rate (OR) 1 and sales rate (SR) 1, and they effect the Manufacturers Inventory (MI) 1 and retailers inventory (RI) 1. The total revenue 1 is related to SR 1 and RI 1, so the total revenue of supply chain 1 will be shock.

6. Conclusions

In this paper, the SD modeling method is used to identify the effects of retailer-led recycling based on closed-loop dual chains competition, and the decision making by rivals is simulated. It analyzes the influence of contracts on different retail mode and the influence of ERC on supply chains to get a scientific decision improving the competitiveness of supply chain. The research results show that the contract incentive mechanism can improve the retailer’s recycling enthusiasm, and the effect on the retail mode of executive shop is more obvious. When the ERC is adjusted to 44.3%, the TR of supply chain is optimal, and the MS and MC occupy an obvious advantage. Enterprises can strengthen the influence of contract on retailers recycling enthusiasm by adopting the retail mode of executive shop. The equilibrium relationship between the ERC and total revenue is analyzed, and the appropriate quantity of recycling is determined based on the PC and REC of the enterprise, so that the enterprise funds are allocated rationally. In the subsequent research, it is considered to establish a replenishment strategy between REI of different supply chains to solve the inventory accumulation caused by excessive recycling. So as for a manufacture in a supply chain, it can choose effective contract incentive mechanism to enhance retailer’s recycling enthusiasm. For retailers, an appropriate incentive contract can be discussed with the manufacturer to profit more.
Although this paper gives a SD model for dual chains competition under retailer-led recycling mode, it does not consider enough details to improve the model. Relevant influencing factors and the addition of the framework have yet to be deepened and still need further research.

Author Contributions

R.X. conducted the study design, prepared data, performed the simulation analysis and drafted the manuscript. F.Z. organized this study, contributed to study design, interpretation of analysis. F.T. revised the manuscript.

Funding

This study was funded by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Project No. 61172168), Heilongjiang Province Education Department Scientific Research Project (Project No. 135109248) and Qiqihar University Young Teacher Startup Project (Project No. 2014k-M11).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Baldé, C.P.; Forti, V.; Gray, V.; Kuehr, R.; Stegmann, P. Global E-Waste Monitor 2017. Available online: https://www.itu.int/en/ITU-D/Climate-Change/Pages/Global-E-waste-Monitor-2017.aspx (accessed on 27 July 2017).
  2. Fleisehmann, M.; Bloemhof-Ruwaard, J.M.; Dekker, R.; van der Laan, E.; van Nunen, J.A.E.E.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Quantiative models for reverse logistic: A review. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 1997, 103, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Guide, D.; Jayraman, R.; Srivastava, R.; Benton, W.C. Supply chain management for recoverable manufacturing systems. Interfaces 2000, 30, 125–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Subramanian, R.; Gupta, S.; Talbot, B. Product design and supply chain coordination under extended producer responsibility. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2009, 18, 259–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Sehultmann, F.; Zumkeller, M.; Rentz, O. Modeling reverse logistic tasks within closed-loop supply chains: An example from the automotive industry. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2006, 171, 1033–1050. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Krikke, H. Recovery Strategies and Reverse Logistics Network Design. Ph.D. Thesis, Universiteit Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  7. Savaskan, R.C.; Bhattacharya, S.; Wassenhove, L.N. Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manag. Sci. 2004, 50, 239–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Nie, J. The Effect of Channel Structures on Third-party Collecting Closed-loop Supply Chain. J. Ind. Eng./Eng. Manag. 2012, 26, 151–158. [Google Scholar]
  9. Wang, W.; Da, Q.; Sun, H. Design of the Premium Mechanism and the Premium and Penalty Mechanism for Re-manufacturing Reverse Supply Chain Coordination. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2009, 17, 46–52. [Google Scholar]
  10. Nie, J.; Wang, W.; Wu, Q. The Effects of Premium and Penalty Mechanism on Manufacturer Take-back Closed-loop Supply Chain. Ind. Eng. Manag. 2011, 16, 52–59. [Google Scholar]
  11. Li, H.; Li, X.; Xu, X. A Method of Supply Chain Partnerships Maintenance Management Based on Trust. J. Ind. Eng./Eng. Manag. 2007, 21, 71–79. [Google Scholar]
  12. He, X.L.; Khouja, M. Pareto analysis of supply chain contracts under satisficing objectives. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2011, 214, 53–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Xue, S.; Xu, Y.; Su, J. Design of Optimal Contract in Remanufacturing System. J. Cent. Univ. Financ. Econ. 2007, 4, 71–77. [Google Scholar]
  14. Chen, F.; Gao, C. Multi-Stage Supply Chain Coordination by Revenue Sharing Contracts. J. Wuhan Univ. 2006, 52, 291–295. [Google Scholar]
  15. Kong, L.; Luo, T. Reverse-supply Chain Pricing Strategy Based on Contract Theory. Chin. J. Manag. 2012, 9, 594–602. [Google Scholar]
  16. Lei, D.; Li, J.B.; Liu, Z.X. Supply chain contracts under demand and cost disruptions with asymmetric information. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2012, 139, 116–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Qiao, H.; Jiang, Z.; Xie, W.; Liu, W. Supply Chain Revenue Sharing Contract Design Based on Products Services System. Ind. Eng. Manag. 2013, 18, 25–30. [Google Scholar]
  18. Bao, X.; Pu, Y. Incentive contract in reverse supply chain with asymmetric information. Comput. Integr. Manuf. Syst. 2008, 14, 1717–1720. [Google Scholar]
  19. Heese, H.S.; Carrani, S.K.; Ferrer, G.; Gilland, W.; Roth, A.V. Competitive advantage through take-back of used products. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2005, 164, 143–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Ferguson, M.E.; Tokray, L.B. The effect of competition on recovery strategies. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2006, 15, 351–368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Parlar, M.; Weng, Z.K. Coordination pricing and production decision in the presenceofprice competition. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2006, 170, 211–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Ferrer, G.; Swaminathan, J.M. Managing new and remanufactured products. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 15–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Ferrer, G.; Swaminathan, J.M. Managing new and differentiated remanufactured products. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 203, 370–379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Webster, S.; Mitra, S. Competitive strategy in remanufacturing and the impact of take-back laws. J. Oper. Manag. 2007, 25, 1123–1140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Arasu, A.; Sarvary, M.; Wassenhove, LN. Remanufacturing as a marketing Strategy. Manag. Sci. 2008, 54, 1731–1746. [Google Scholar]
  26. Zhou, C.; Liang, L.; Gou, Q.; Xu, C.; Zha, Y. Decision of Remanufacturing Product Choice with Product Substitution. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2008, 16, 57–61. [Google Scholar]
  27. Cao, J.; Xiong, Z.; Liu, L. Price and Quality Competition Between the New and Remanufactured Producer in the Closed-loop Supply Chain. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2010, 18, 82–90. [Google Scholar]
  28. Yi, Y. Study on Closed-loop Supply Chain Model under Different Market Power. J. Syst. Manag. 2010, 19, 389–395. [Google Scholar]
  29. Yi, Y. Closed-loop supply chain game models with product remanufacturing in a duopoly retailer channel. J. Manag. Sci. China 2009, 12, 45–54. [Google Scholar]
  30. Yi, Y. Closed-loop supply chain game models with product remanufacturing. Syst. Eng.-Theory Pract. 2009, 29, 28–35. [Google Scholar]
  31. Han, X. Decision Analysis of Recycling Channel of Closed-loop Supply Chain Based on Manufacturer’s Competition. Syst. Eng. 2010, 28, 36–41. [Google Scholar]
  32. Han, X.; Dong, Z. Reverse Channel Decision Analysis for Bilateral Competing Closed-loop Supply Chain. Ind. Eng. J. 2010, 4, 25–29. [Google Scholar]
  33. Xie, J.; Chi, L.; Liang, L. Optimal manufacturing/remanufacturing production decision based on endogenous product quality. J. Manag. Sci. China 2012, 15, 12–23. [Google Scholar]
  34. Zheng, J.; Li, C. The Market Competition of the Closed-loop Supply Chain Effects on the Recycling Channel Choice. Sci. Technol. Eng. 2012, 12, 3419–3423. [Google Scholar]
  35. Savaskan, R.C.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Reverse channel design: The case of competing retailers. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Yi, Y.; Liang, J. Hybrid recycling modes for closed-loop supply chain under premium and penalty mechanism. Comput. Integ. Manuf. Syst. 2014, 20, 215–223. [Google Scholar]
  37. McGuire, T.W.; Staelin, R. An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Mark. Sci. 1983, 2, 161–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Wei, J.; Zhao, J. Pricing and remanufacturing decisions in two competing supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2015, 53, 258–278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Zheng, Y.; Shu, T.; Wang, S.; Chen, S.; Lai, K.K.; Gan, L. Analysis of product return rate and price competition in two supply chains. Oper. Res. 2016, 24, 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Song, M.; Huang, M.; Wang, X. Selection strategies of channel structure for competition closed-loop supply chains. Control Decis. 2013, 28, 1247–1252. [Google Scholar]
  41. Li, X.; Ai, X.; Tang, X. Marketing channel structure of remanufactured products under competing supply chain. J. Syst. Eng. 2016, 31, 666–675. [Google Scholar]
  42. Li, X.; Ai, X.; Tang, X. Research on Collecting Strategies in the Closed-loop Supply Chain with Chain to Chain Competition. J. Ind. Eng./Eng. Manag. 2016, 30, 90–98. [Google Scholar]
  43. Yoon, S.; Jeong, S. Investment strategy in a closed loop supply chain: The case of a market with competition between two retailers. Sustainability 2017, 9, 1712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Krikke, H.; Bloemhof-Ruwaard, J.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Concurrent product and closed-loop supply chain design with an application to refrigerators. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2003, 41, 3689–3719. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Georgiadis, P.; Besiou, M. Sustainability in electrical and electronic equipment closed-loop supply chains: A system dynamics approach. J. Clean. Prod. 2008, 16, 1665–1678. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Dual chains competition structure of closed-loop supply chain recycling by retailers.
Figure 1. Dual chains competition structure of closed-loop supply chain recycling by retailers.
Sustainability 10 03391 g001
Figure 2. Dual chains competition system dynamics model.
Figure 2. Dual chains competition system dynamics model.
Sustainability 10 03391 g002
Figure 3. Mechanism of contract 1.
Figure 3. Mechanism of contract 1.
Sustainability 10 03391 g003
Figure 4. Mechanism of contract 2.
Figure 4. Mechanism of contract 2.
Sustainability 10 03391 g004
Figure 5. Causes Tree of Manufactures Inventory 1.
Figure 5. Causes Tree of Manufactures Inventory 1.
Sustainability 10 03391 g005
Figure 6. Causes Tree of Output Rate 1.
Figure 6. Causes Tree of Output Rate 1.
Sustainability 10 03391 g006
Figure 7. Causes Tree of Retailers Inventory 1.
Figure 7. Causes Tree of Retailers Inventory 1.
Sustainability 10 03391 g007
Figure 8. Causes Tree of Market Competitiveness 1.
Figure 8. Causes Tree of Market Competitiveness 1.
Sustainability 10 03391 g008
Figure 9. Causes Tree of Market Demands 1.
Figure 9. Causes Tree of Market Demands 1.
Sustainability 10 03391 g009
Figure 10. The effect degree is 0.3, the ERC is 0.36.
Figure 10. The effect degree is 0.3, the ERC is 0.36.
Sustainability 10 03391 g010
Figure 11. The situation of Retailers Recycling Inventory.
Figure 11. The situation of Retailers Recycling Inventory.
Sustainability 10 03391 g011
Figure 12. Comparison of Market share and Market Competitiveness. When the effect degree 1 is 0.5.
Figure 12. Comparison of Market share and Market Competitiveness. When the effect degree 1 is 0.5.
Sustainability 10 03391 g012
Figure 13. Comparison of Total Revenue. When the effect degree 1 is 0.5.
Figure 13. Comparison of Total Revenue. When the effect degree 1 is 0.5.
Sustainability 10 03391 g013
Figure 14. Fitting curve.
Figure 14. Fitting curve.
Sustainability 10 03391 g014
Figure 15. Comparison of Total Revenue. When the effect degree 1 is 0.5, the ERC 2 is 0.443.
Figure 15. Comparison of Total Revenue. When the effect degree 1 is 0.5, the ERC 2 is 0.443.
Sustainability 10 03391 g015
Figure 16. Comparison of Market Share and Market Competitiveness.
Figure 16. Comparison of Market Share and Market Competitiveness.
Sustainability 10 03391 g016
Table 1. Constant set.
Table 1. Constant set.
ConstantValue
Testing Time1
Random Error0.2
REC0.36
RET1.2
Recycling Delay48
PAT2
PT2
PC8
Manufacturers Inventory Duration12
Demands Adjustment Time2
RIAT1
Retailers Inventory Duration1.5
TAT2
TT3
Delivery Time1
Manufacturers Inventory Adjustment Time2
Table 2. Situation data.
Table 2. Situation data.
E-Waste Recycling CoefficientSUMAVERAGEMAX
0.4014,279,100.9978,890.06072135,770
0.40514,410,035.0779,613.4534137,091
0.4114,543,175.2380,349.03442138,402
0.41514,672,013.2781,060.84677139,704
0.4214,799,821.881,766.97127140,997
0.42514,926,562.8682,467.19809142,281
0.4315,051,949.8983,159.94414143,561
0.43515,177,626.8883,854.29213144,831
0.4415,276,552.4184,400.84204145,969
0.44515,278,716.9884,412.80097146,038
0.4515,237,076.9984,182.7458145,361
0.45515,171,904.1683,822.67489144,231
0.4615,051,498.9183,157.45254142,662
0.46514,936,488.2282,522.03434141,097
0.4714,814,642.2181,848.85199139,475
0.47514,690,458.481,162.75356137,838
0.4814,537,968.3580,320.26713136,064
0.48514,417,666.5379,655.61616134,420
0.4914,301,504.179,013.83481132,766
0.49514,182,778.6679,013.83481132,766
0.5014,071,631.2377,743.81895129,460

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Xue, R.; Zhang, F.; Tian, F. A System Dynamics Model to Evaluate Effects of Retailer-Led Recycling Based on Dual Chains Competition: A Case of e-Waste in China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3391. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10103391

AMA Style

Xue R, Zhang F, Tian F. A System Dynamics Model to Evaluate Effects of Retailer-Led Recycling Based on Dual Chains Competition: A Case of e-Waste in China. Sustainability. 2018; 10(10):3391. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10103391

Chicago/Turabian Style

Xue, Renzheng, Fengbin Zhang, and Feng Tian. 2018. "A System Dynamics Model to Evaluate Effects of Retailer-Led Recycling Based on Dual Chains Competition: A Case of e-Waste in China" Sustainability 10, no. 10: 3391. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10103391

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop