1. Introduction
Can the renewable energy potential of Latin America help curb climate change? This study formally analyzes this question estimating the economic and climate impacts of this energy potential. To do this end, we extend the integrated assessment model (IAM) used in [
1] to quantify the long-term climate and economic consequences of developing the huge renewable energy potential of Latin America. Including this renewable energy potential in an IAM as a substitute for the use of fossil fuels offers analytical advantages. In fact, this modeling strategy allows us to determine simultaneously the efficiency gains in terms of production in different regions from this development, but also its effects on the climate change captured by its consequences in terms of changes in the global temperature.
There are several reasons to view Latin America as a crucial player to combat the climate change. Note that climate change mainly originates by carbon emissions. Moreover, the origins of these emissions are mainly attributed to the energy sector. In fact, according to [
2], in 2016, around 73% of global carbon emissions were caused by the energy sector, whereas only 18% were attributed to agriculture and land use change. Moreover, emissions from the energy sector are greatly due to the burning of fossil fuels. It is therefore imperative to reduce the use of this type of fuel in order to comply with the limit of 1.5 ºC temperature increase by 2100. In this context, Latin America offers huge potential in terms of renewable and green sources of energy.
Hence, one significant opportunity to decarbonize the energy matrix worldwide is to change the use of fossil fuels for renewable energies such as solar or wind energy. These sources of renewable energy have reduced the levelized cost of energy (LCOE) (
, where
is investment expenditures in year
t,
is the variable costs in year
t,
is the electrical energy generated in year
t, and
r is the discount rate) by almost 90% and 70%, respectively, in the last ten years, reaching global weighted average values of below 50 (USD/MWh) (see
Table 1). Such a reduction in costs make these technologies much more competitive, since a fossil fuel power plant has an average LCOE of about 60 (USD/MWh) before taxes [
3].
Although there is a heterogenous distribution of renewable energy potential across the world, Latin America has the biggest one. For instance, in the case of solar energy, it has the highest
practical solar PV potential, which corresponds to the average radiation which includes physical and technical restrictions, as well as restrictions associated with regulating access to protected areas or land used for agriculture (see [
4]). This is found in the Atacama Desert in northern Chile, where the practical solar PV potential reaches values close to 6.4 (kWh/kWp), followed by Africa or the Middle East region with 5.6 (kWh/kWp) and some other regions like California or Australian Desert with 5.2 (kWh/kWp), as we show in
Figure 1.
With this potential, Latin America could satisfy the entire world’s energy demand. For instance, if Chile, Argentina, Bolivia, and Peru could develop only 25% of their practical solar potential level, they would generate around 139.000 (TWh/year) based on [
4] (this value was calculated using a conversion efficiency of 15%, a percentage of the territory associated with practical solar potential level 2 of 10%, and an average daily practical potential of 4.71 (kWh/m
2)). This figure is in the same order of magnitude as the global primary energy demand, which was 162.673 (TWh/year) in 2019. If we also consider the potential of the rest of LATAM countries and the huge potential from wind energy and other renewable energy sources, these numbers could substantially exceed the energy demand projected in the medium and long term in the region.
Moreover, this renewable energy potential in LATAM could be converted into different kinds of energy like electricity or synthetic fuels (power-to-X) in order to store and transport energy to other regions. The production of power-to-X fuels is based on the generation of green hydrogen through water electrolysis using renewable energies (see [
5]). This hydrogen can be used directly, further processed, or synthesized, for example, by adding carbon dioxide (CO
2) or nitrogen (N
2). This allows for the production of various power-to-X fuel variants, ranging from gaseous and liquid hydrogen to synthetic natural gas (SNG), synthetic kerosene, diesel, methanol, or ammonia. Since the production of power-to-X is highly energy-intensive (40–70 (USD/kgH
2)) and associated with high losses, even with future efficiency improvements, it seems economically sensible to produce it only in regions with excellent renewable energy resources and corresponding land availability. For countries that have such potential in large quantities, exceeding their own needs, power-to-X provides an entry into an attractive future market in the transformation of a global energy system. This possibility is supported by [
6], which argues that those regions in the world with the greatest potential to develop a green synthetic fuels export industry are the Atacama Desert, Southern Patagonia, and Australia. This, together with the National Green Hydrogen Strategy [
7] promoted by Chile, makes the materialization of this export opportunity more feasible. In the same line, electricity could exported from Latin America to other regions through feasible electrical interconnections. One great example of this worldwide is ENTSO-E, the European Network of Transmission System Operators for electricity. This association makes it possible to interconnect the European electricity systems with those of North African countries, Great Britain, Nordic countries, Eurasia, and the Middle East. Alternatively, this energy potential could be used to produce synthetic fuels (e.g., green hydrogen) and export them to any region of the world.
Therefore, the objective of this research is to quantify and evaluate what renewable energy potential Latin America can offer both in terms of economic benefits and curbing climate change. Given the lack of previous studies on the subject, the main goal is to have an analytical model to understand and quantify the economic and climatic effects of developing and exporting the renewable energy from LATAM. As described above, to perform this analysis, we extend the integrated assessment model developed to include the renewable energy potential from LATAM and the Asia–Pacific region.
The main results of our analysis are as follows. First, renewable energy exports from LATAM generate economic benefits for all regions, but do not reduce the effects of global warming and, on the contrary, exacerbate the problem. Second, if the renewable energy exports are accompanied by policy measures that discourage the use of fossil fuel (e.g., carbon taxes), greater economic benefits can be obtained together with a reduction in global warming. This last result is independent of the allocation of the global demand for renewable energy exports between LATAM and Asia–Pacific regions. Third, the economic gains in LATAM could be as big as about five times the global average due to its exporting nature and the relatively low (per capita) income in comparison with most other regions. Fourth, due to the gradual capital accumulation process, delaying the development of exports reduces economic gains not only during the delay period, but also in the years following the commencement of exports. Finally, stochastic simulations suggest that uncertainties related to the renewable energy development are better attenuated when policy measures that discourage carbon emissions are deployed.
Related literature and contribution. Our research is related to the three main strands of the previous literature. First, there are studies that focus on quantifying the economic consequences of imposing policies to reduce carbon emissions. Second, other studies analyzing how production changes towards greener technologies can contribute to a more sustainable economic development. Finally, other works formalize the economic externalities from carbon emissions, explicitly incorporating the carbon cycles and its temperature consequences in macro-economic models, which have been named integrated assessment models (IAMs).
Regarding the first strand of the literature, some recent papers, like [
8,
9], studied the macroeconomic effects of the imposition of a carbon tax in Europe, finding opposite results in terms of GDP or unemployment. In the same line, refs. [
10,
11,
12] analyze the effects of the carbon tax on the Chilean economy showing the trade-off between the effectiveness in reducing emissions and the contractionary effects on macroeconomic results (lower growth and higher inflation).
However, our work is also related to the second type of literature, which is the one that studies technological change. The first study in this context is [
13] which introduces endogenous and directed technical change in an environmentally constrained growth model to argue that, when inputs are substitutable, sustainable growth can be achieved with temporary policies that redirect innovation towards clean inputs. Recently, refs. [
14,
15,
16] added to the evidence of this phenomenon and showed the implications of certain technological developments. Specifically, ref. [
17] studied the shale gas phenomenon and its long-term effects but without explicitly modeling the climate and carbon cycle. Therefore, we understand our work like a new technological innovation. Specifically, a new kind of energy (electricity or synthetic fuels from Latin America) for the world that explicitly models the climate and carbon cycle.
Finally, our work is closely related to the growing literature of using IAMs to study climate change and its effects on the economy. Preliminary works in this area are DICE/RICE models [
18,
19,
20] which extend the neoclassical economic framework with carbon cycle dynamics, temperature, and damage function, aiming to find the social cost of carbon emissions (SCC). More recently, ref. [
21] constructed a parsimonious framework to find, under certain assumptions, an analytical expression for the SCC. Others examples such as the PAGE model [
22] was used in
The Stern Review [
23] which argues that the benefits of strong and early action on climate change outweigh the costs. Similarly, the FUND model [
24] was used to calculate the social cost of carbon (SCC) [
25], or [
26] focused on the effects of uncertainty in the parameter to calculate the SCC. Recently, the new GTAP-InVEST model [
27] has been used to map the planet’s critical natural assets, as [
28] understood the relationship between biodiversity and society [
29] to highlight the lack of relationship between markets and biodiversity [
30]. All of these last questions fall beyond the issue of climate change.
In sum, our work is related to analyze the worldwide economic consequences of changes in the energy matrix. In this line, our work is related to [
31], which uses the G-Cube model explained in [
32], in which they study the effects of demographic transition, long-term slowdown in productivity growth, and the disruption in the global economy due to increasing climate shocks with an emphasis on the short-term macroeconomics adjustment. However, we keep an aggregate approach of the different regions of the world in order to explicitly model the carbon cycle and temperature determination like [
1]. At the same time, we extend the work by [
1] to include additional energy sources to explicitly assess the joint economic and climate consequences of developing that new source of renewable energy. This allows us to quantify the effects of developing the huge renewable energy potential of LATAM and Asia–Pacific region, having a long-term perspective that simultaneously assesses the worldwide impacts on the main macroeconomic variables and the climate.
It should be noted that we want to be clear in terms of our work not taking into account the friction in the industrial organization of the market for this new kind of energy, or the friction in terms of international trade even though we try to internalize these frictions in the path of the prices of energies. Despite the above, we believe that this work is the first step and a novel contribution to quantify the long-term economic and climatic consequences of exploiting Latin America’s renewable potential. In this way, it addresses the lack of studies on the subject by highlighting the heterogeneity of the availability of renewable resources and new opportunities to curb climate change.
Road Map. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The description of the model, with a special emphasis on novel extensions, is presented in
Section 2, followed by the calibration of the model in
Section 3. The results are discussed in
Section 4, whereas a robustness analysis of the results is presented in
Section 5. The conclusions and ideas for future work are presented in
Section 6. Finally, the analytical derivations of the model and additional details on the calibration and simulations for each region are provided in the
Appendix A.
2. Model to Incorporate Renewable Energy Exports
Our model is closely based on the works by [
1,
33]. The multi-region setting consists of having one oil-producing region, and arbitrarily, many oil-importing regions. Each oil-importing region has a representative firm that uses capital, labor, and energy input to produce final goods. The energy input in each region is produced through a composition of different imperfectly substitutable energy sources. One of these energy sources is oil, which is sold internationally in the world market. The remaining energy sources are all produced regionally at given prices that vary across regions. This variation captures the difference in the capacity to produce alternative sources of energy as a substitute for oil. Each region features a government that sets the climate policy within that region. Finally, and importantly, the model features an explicit representation of the climate as well as a carbon cycle. As the final production demands energy input, which employs the sources that generate carbon emissions, this process affects the stock of CO
2 and the global temperature. The global temperature, in turn, negatively affects the productivity to produce the final goods. These negative effects are modeled through a damage function in each region and their effects are not internalized by households and firms. This implies that imposing a tax on the energy sources that generate carbon emissions can improve the welfare of the economy, as proven by [
21]. The detailed description of the baseline model is relegated to the
Appendix A, where oil is the only energy source that can be traded internationally. This type of model was developed to consider formal general equilibrium effects in a dynamic and long-term perspective.
In this section, we present two extensions to the baseline model that modify the energy production in each region to allow for energy exports from Latin America (LATAM). Formally, we allow for two types of energy exports from LATAM, namely synthetic fuel and electricity. In the case of electricity exports from LATAM, we restrict their reach exclusively to its closer regions. Our approach to adding alternative energy sources closely follows [
1], who considered fracking as a technology to produce a large amount of unconventional oil and gas in the United States.
2.1. Electricity Exports from LATAM
One way to take advantage of the renewable energy potential that exists in Latin America is by converting primary energies (solar, wind, biomass, geothermal, etc.) into electricity and exporting it through electrical interconnections with other regions. Without loss of generality, we will assume that corresponds to renewable energy. In turn, Latin America (region ) will have the option of exporting this renewable energy. Accordingly, we will define as renewable energy exportable through electricity, which corresponds to the renewable energy exported as electricity by Latin America during the period t. It is worth noting that, in the calibration section, we will specify which regions will be able to import this type of energy and how the prices of this new energy source will evolve, where such prices include the costs associated with the transportation of electricity. Also, the total supply of electricity produced by Latin America will be denoted by .
This new energy source exported from Latin America is a substitute for the domestic production of renewable energy in region
, which is defined by
. To capture this possibility, we define the
aggregate renewable energy in region
as
where
and
determine the relative efficiency of domestic and imported renewable energy in region
i. Parameter
also determines the factibility of exporting electricity from LATAM to region
i. Thus, when
, exporting electricity from LATAM to region
i is not feasible. Below, in the calibration section, we will make a precise assumption regarding the regions to which LATAM can feasibly export electricity. In the above expression,
controls the elasticity of substitution between these two types of renewable energy sources. In the case of LATAM, the renewable energy is just
. After having this renewable energy source in each region, the aggregate energy input for final good production in region
i is given by:
This aggregation is the same specification considered in Proposition A1. A relevant assumption is that the elasticity of substitution between domestic and imported renewable energy is higher than the one among different types of energy sources, such as
. With this modification in the process to aggregate energy sources, energy firms in region
will first determine the combination of domestic and imported renewable energy, which consists of solving
where
and
are, respectively, the prices of domestic and imported renewable energy during region
i in period
t (in Latin America, we will just have
). The aggregate price of renewable energy in region
i will be given by:
The optimal combination of all energy sources in region
i is obtained by solving:
which is equivalent to the optimization problem defined in (A9) and (A10).
Similarly to the case of oil, we assume that there is a single world market for this new renewable energy traded internationally. Moreover, we will consider that the electricity capacity in LATAM is sufficiently large such that its supply by period is infinitely price elastic with a price that evolves exogenously. Exporting electricity from LATAM to region i faces an additional cost of per exported unit and is expressed in terms of final goods. Hence, the price for . The technology in the electricity sector will exogenously determine the evolution for and (this factor can be interpreted as an iceberg cost widely used in modern trade models). Hence, the total supply of electricity provided by LATAM will be defined by the demand side of renewable energy, given the path of these technological factors ( and ) in the electricity sector. The income obtained from the exportation of this electricity is added to the net product previously defined in subsection (v) of Proposition A1 for region (e.g., LATAM). As in the base model, the equilibrium conditions are summarized in Proposition A2.
We can note that this extension of the model does not modify the equilibrium conditions for the households since the saving rate in each region remains constant and the oil supply during each period keeps being inelastically given by . This conclusion is obtained because the proposed extension only corresponds to a change in the static problem of the energy-aggregating firms and final goods, but not a change in the dynamic problems of the representative households in each region. Hence, finding the equilibrium period-by-period still solves an algebraic Equation (obviously different from Proposition A1) that clears the global oil market.
2.2. Export of Synthetic Fuels from LATAM and Asia–Pacific
Another way to take advantage of the renewable potential in Latin America is through the development and export of synthetic fuels such as green hydrogen. To include green hydrogen in our model, and in a similar way to what we proposed in the case of exports of electricity, we define a new energy source
that we will call
synthetic fuel and that can be traded internationally as oil. This synthetic fuel will be a close substitute for oil given its physical characteristics (see [
6]). Thus, we define a new fuel aggregate that combines oil and synthetic fuel in each region
i as
where
and
are, respectively, the demand for oil and synthetic fuel used to generate the aggregate fuel (
) in region
i during period
t. In contrast to the case of electricity exports, we will assume that the parameters that determine the relative efficiency of these two types of fuels (
and
) are equalized across regions. The synthetic fuel can be exported to any region as oil, so there will be no feasibility considerations that prevent its trading across regions. Importantly, as described in the introduction, the advantage of solar power producing green hydrogen is highly concentrated in LATAM and Australia. Therefore, the production and exports of synthetic fuels will only be from these two regions (LATAM and Asia–Pacific).
As in the case of adding the export of electricity, the aggregation in (
6) will assume that
characterizes the greater degree of substitution between oil and the
exportable synthetic fuel compared to the substitution between oil and the other existing energy sources. We now define the aggregate energy input
in region
i as:
To determine the optimal combination of oil and synthetic only in each region
i, the energy firms first need to solve the following optimization problem:
where
and
are, respectively, the prices of oil and the synthetic fuel in region
i during period
t after taxes. In turn, and in line with the export of oil, we assume that there is a single worldwide market for this synthetic fuel, implying that its price before taxes is equalized across regions:
. However, in contrast to oil, synthetic fuel is a renewable energy source and its price is determined by the cost of production, which will be a technological assumption in the model. Accordingly, we will consider that the price
evolves exogenously and, therefore, the global production is infinitely price elastic. The demand for synthetic fuel will be divided between the Latin America and Asia–Pacific regions since these are the only two regions capable of producing this new fuel. The global demand of synthetic fuel will be denoted by
and in line with [
6]; we will assume that LATAM and Asia–Pacific produce half of this global production in each period. Hence, the proceeds of these exports from LATAM and Asia–Pacific are added to their respective net incomes:
with
. It is important to mention that, in
Section 5, we will modify this assumption in order to assess the robustness of our simulated scenarios. After determining the demand for each component of the fuel aggregate, energy firms find the demand for the other type of energy sources (
) based on the aggregate demand for energy
by solving (A9) and (A10). Again, we can note that, under this model extension, the dynamic optimization of households is not modified. Hence, the characterization of the equilibrium conditions can be stated in Proposition A3.
2.3. Exports of Electricity and Synthetic Fuel
A final extension could simultaneously explore the incorporation of the exports of electricity and synthetic fuel described in the last two subsections. In consequence, the aggregate production of the energy input will be given by:
where the aggregate fuel (
) and the aggregate electricity (
) are obtained as:
Like in the previous extension, we can state a proposition that summarizes the equilibrium conditions under this joint modification in the combination of energy sources, as shown in Proposition A4.
3. Calibration
Since our model is closely based on [
1], most of the parameters’ values are taken from that study. This calibration strategy guarantees an adequate comparison of our scenarios with the baseline simulations and previous studies. As described below and in contrast to [
1], we use the update information from LCOE to estimate the energy aggregation parameters and the expected path of prices for different types of energy sources.
We start by defining that each simulation period corresponds to 10 years. There are eight regions (
) that constitute the global economy, representing an oil-producing region, North America, Europe, China, Africa, South Asia, Asia–Pacific (excluding China), and Latin America. For the model extensions, we assume that only Latin America will export energy to North America in the case of electricity exports, while for synthetic fuel exports, we assume that Latin America and the Asia–Pacific can produce this fuel based on solar energy. This last assumption is consistent with [
6]. In contrast to electricity exports, synthetic fuel can be exported to all regions of the world.
In the following subsections, we define the value of the different parameters that we will use to simulate the model scenarios described below.
3.1. Functional Forms of Preferences and Technologies
One of the central points in deriving Propositions A1–A4 is the assumption of logarithmic utilities, Cobb–Douglas production functions, and a depreciation rate equal to one for the study period. As mentioned above, the logarithmic utility corresponds to the CRRA family of functions with the elasticity of intertemporal substitution equal to one, which for the 10-year study horizon is a good approximation in line with [
21].
Regarding the depreciation rate, a value of is still a considerably high value, even if one period is 10 years, since, among other aspects, the evaluation horizon for energy projects is 40 years. However, due to the analytical solution of the model, we decided to maintain this assumption. Additionally, an annual depreciation rate of 10 percent corresponds to a depreciation rate of around 65 percent over a 10-year period.
With respect to the functional form of the production function, let us note that the Cobb–Douglas function is a special case of the CES function when the elasticity of substitution is equal to one. This is in line with [
34,
35,
36], who argue that this type of modeling is correct when the elasticity of substitution is less than one for short periods. However, in the long run, a Cobb–Douglas function is a reasonable assumption. Therefore, following [
33], we use
and
.
Finally, there is a great deal of discussion in the literature related to the calculation of the social cost of carbon with regard to the value of the intertemporal discount rate, as it has important effects on the value of the social cost of carbon (see [
37]). This is why we distinguish between two main approaches: the first one from [
23] and their later works, who argue that the discount rate should actually be an effective
(
); and the second one, which is the one we will use, namely the approach from Nordhaus’ works which uses a discount rate of
per decade, which corresponds to
. It should be noted that, since our focus is not on calculating the optimal tax or social cost of carbon, using a lower discount rate would only reinforce the long-term results obtained, which will be discussed in detail in
Section 4.
3.2. Energy Sector
First, we will assume that there will be types of energy for the case without exports, corresponding to oil, coal, and renewable energies. In turn, for the extensions of the model, we will assume that only two types of energy will exist for each of the defined energy aggregates: for the fuel aggregate, we consider that it will be composed of oil and synthetic fuel; and for the renewable aggregate, it will be composed of domestic and imported renewable energy (electricity), when importing is feasible.
Regarding the aggregation function, we use the elasticity substitution of [
38] equal to
, corresponding to the unweighted average between the elasticities of substitution between coal–oil, coal–electricity, and electricity–oil, which implies that
(
with
the elasticity of substitution). Furthermore, since we define the synthetic fuel and exported renewable energy as close substitutes for oil and domestic renewable energy, respectively, we assume that
.
Concerning the relative efficiencies among energies, we use condition (iv) of Proposition A1 to obtain
Thus, taking the global demand for different energy and fossil fuel prices from [
39], together with the LCOE of renewable technologies from [
3] and the assumption that
, we obtain that
,
, and
. It is worth noting that the use of LCOE to parameterize the energy aggregation function is an improvement over the previous works by [
1,
21,
33], since, as shown in [
3], LCOEs have been a very good approximation of the clearing prices of the different energy tenders worldwide. This is why, in the aforementioned works, it was arbitrarily assumed that the relative price between oil and renewable energy is equal to one. This made the efficiency of renewable energy,
, lower, and therefore, its contribution in the aggregation function underestimated.
For the relative efficiencies of the fuel aggregate, we use the same methodology, obtaining and . For the case of the renewable aggregate, due to the non-existence of exported electricity between the regions involved, we assume that both types of renewable energy have the same efficiency () for the regions that can import them.
Finally, to determine energy prices: for fossil fuels, we use the average of the last 10 years from [
39]; for the price of renewable energies, we obtain it as the simple average of the LCOE for small-scale hydropower, solar photovoltaic and onshore wind technologies, for the year 2018. We do not consider offshore wind sources due to their low participation in the world energy matrix; for synthetic fuel, we use the LCOE of green hydrogen taken from [
3]; and the price of the exported renewable energy corresponds to the mean between the price of the renewable energies of the regions involved in trading this energy input. This last assumption is made in order to have a higher price of the exported energy with respect to that consumed in the exporting region, which is needed to cover for the costs associated with the transportation of that renewable energy. It should be noted that, since the unit of measurement of our model is tons of carbon equivalent, we use the methodology proposed by [
21] to use the energy efficiencies of each of the technologies and the associated expenditure in terms of GDP by the energy sector. With this, we transform the prices measured in typical units (
.) into units of carbon equivalent per units of GDP; the price summary is attached in
Table A2.
3.3. Climate and Damage Function
For the carbon cycle model, we base our model directly on what is proposed in [
21], so
,
, and
, where, in addition, the concentration of carbon in the atmosphere in the pre-industrial era is 581 gigatons of carbon.
Also, with respect to emissions, we use
for fossil fuels and
for renewable technologies. It should be noted that heterogeneity in emissions by technological type is assumed, since, as mentioned in
Section 3.2, energy prices are measured in units of final goods, including efficiency.
With respect to the temperature model, we directly use the parameterization used in [
19], so
,
,
,
, and
. Finally, to parameterize
, we follow [
1], who proposed the following functional form
where
is the climate sensitivity, which is equal to 3 °C for each doubling in the carbon concentration. The parameter values of
and
are shown in
Table A1.
3.4. Initial and Long-Term Conditions
To parameterize the initial values of the model variables, we use the methodology proposed in [
40] Chapter 3, which consists of taking the variables with a lag period (10 years for our model) and leaving the productivity level free, so as to set the initial productivity level in such a way that the model correctly predicts the values of the state variables in the initial period. In this way, the values of the initial productivities are shown in
Table A1.
For this exercise, we use GDP values measured in current dollars in base 2010, and labor force as a percentage of current population for all regions, taken from [
41]. This population evolves as described in Equations (A4) and (A5), where
evolves according to
where
0.08,
0.4, and
0 corresponds to the long-term population growth rate or on a balanced growth path. This parameterization is in line with the [
42] report that projects a population of 9.7 billion in 2050 and 11 billion in 2100.
Another important point to parameterize is how the productivities of the regions will evolve in the long run in the balanced growth path (BGP). For this, following the development of [
1], we propose the existence of an effective productivity
and a productivity for the BGP
such that it evolves as follows:
where
is the productivity growth in BGP, which we will assume
, for all regions following [
21]. Equations (
16) and (17) describe the regions that are
closing the gap with respect to the BGP, so that regions that are further away from the state that will have higher productivity growth, and hence higher output growth. This is in line with the neoclassical growth models [
43,
44], as well as with the concept of convergence proposed in [
45].
Finally, to parameterize the initial productivities in the BGP for the different regions, we assume that the North American region is at
above the effective productivity. In turn, we assume that the other regions will only reach a certain percentage of North America’s productivity as shown in
Table A1, in line with [
40].
6. Conclusions and Future Work
There is a worldwide consensus that we are at a crucial moment to curb climate change, and the renewable energies are a great alternative to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Using an integrated evaluation model, this work quantifies the medium- and long-term economic and climatic impacts of the development of the renewable energy potential in Latin America (LATAM). The main lesson to be learned from this analysis is that the development and export of renewable energy from LATAM to the rest of the world alone is unable to slow down the climate change. Moreover, this development could end up aggravating the global warming problem. In fact, as summarized in
Table 2, this development can efficiently gain around 5 percent of consumption one hundred years ahead, but with a global temperature of 3.3 °C higher in the same horizon. This is the case since the economic benefits of this energy development lead to more global consumption and demand for energy, generating more carbon emissions.
In contrast to the previous case, if these renewable energy development and exports are combined with policies that discourage the use of polluting technologies, (either through carbon taxes or other regulatory measures), virtuous cycles will be obtained. In these cases, it is possible to slow down climate change and increase economic benefits in the medium and long term for all regions of the world. As shown in
Table 2, a scenario that combines renewable development with carbon tax generates economic gains in terms of world consumption of 5.3 percent with a rise of only 1.9 ºC in the global temperature one hundred years ahead. Importantly, this last result is independent of the assumption regarding the distribution of synthetic fuel development between the LATAM and Asia–Pacific regions. Moreover, given the exporting nature of LATAM and its income level, the economic benefits of this renewable energy development could be as big as about five times those of other regions.
Consistently with the existing literature, the application of carbon taxes is highly effective in decreasing global warming and, at the same time, in increasing long-term economic benefits. However, it is important to note that the effectiveness of carbon taxes decreases when its value is fixed above the optimal level. In addition, using a stochastic simulation analysis, we show that the application of taxes enables us to reduce some of the risks involved in the development of renewable energies, since the application of taxes reduces the volatility of the proportion of renewable energy in the composition of the global energy matrix.
Our analysis also highlights the consequences of delaying the development and exports of renewable energy from LATAM to the rest of the world. We show that the potential economic benefits not only decrease during the delay period, but also in the periods after the commencement of exports, which is due to the persistence of several macroeconomic variables such as capital.
There are several avenues for possible future work. For instance, to understand the fundamental causes behind the evolution of energy prices, the model could be extended to include innovation in the energy sector as a source of endogenous growth. This would help to evaluate other types of policy instruments, such as subsidizing renewable technologies, which were proposed in the recent literature [
1,
53,
54]. Another possible extension is to characterize the oil-producing region more strategically, i.e., lift the assumption of perfect competition for the oil market. Also, concerning the economic model, another possible extension is the inclusion of international trade aspects to better capture other comparative advantages and fundamental factors that can endogenously shape the supply of synthetic fuel in each region. Finally, a possible extension would be to compare different climate models, for instance, the carbon cycle model of the DICE model, or more complex versions that take into account the interaction between the temperature cycle and climate, as proposed in [
56].
Finally, we can highlight that the problem of decarbonizing the world energy matrix depends not only on developing the supply of renewable energy but also on aggressively tackling the negative externality caused by the use of fossil fuels, which is reinforced by the fact that different sources of energy are not perfect substitutes. Moreover, since the process of carbon emissions is a slow-moving process, a long-term perspective, such as the one proposed in this work, is required to properly understand and evaluate the climate consequences of different policies proposed internationally.