Deeds and Words: Farmers’ Attitude-Paradox in Collective Action for Small-Scale Irrigation
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Mechanisms of Farmers’ Attitude–Behavior Paradox
2.1. Farmers Who “Have Positive Attitude but No Behavior”
2.2. Farmers Who Have Negative Attitude but Do Have Behavior
3. Theoretical Framework
4. Study Area and Methods
4.1. Study Area and Variables
4.2. Measures
4.2.1. Income Heterogeneity
4.2.2. Social Ties
4.3. Control Variables
4.4. Methods
4.5. Instrument Variable of Social Ties
5. Results
5.1. Total Effects of the Attitude–Behavior Paradox
5.2. Separate Effects of the Attitude–Behavior Paradox
6. Discussion
7. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Dependent Variables | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Weak Ties | Strong Ties | Weak Ties*Income Heterogeneity | Strong Ties*Income Heterogeneity | |
Instrumental variable 1 | 0.056 (0.043) | 0.482 *** (0.060) | 1.133 *** (0.023) | 0.934 *** (0.019) |
Instrumental variable 2 | 0.204 ** (0.082) | −0.107 (0.115) | 0.403 *** (0.147) | 0.089 (0.123) |
Education | 0.085 *** (0.049) | 0.032 (0.069) | −0.008 (0.016) | −0.015 (0.013) |
Cultivated area | −0.005 (0.019) | 0.046 * (0.027) | 0.004 (0.006) | −0.004 (0.005) |
Cultivation experience | 0.009 ** (0.004) | −0.003 (0.005) | −0.001 (0.001) | 0.0004 (0.001) |
Water stealing | 0.035 (0.033) | 0.264 *** (0.046) | −0.0007 (0.010) | 0.017 * (0.009) |
Water use conflicts | 0.020 (0.040) | 0.110 ** (0.056) | −0.013 (0.013) | −0.021 ** (0.010) |
Income heterogeneity | −0.055 (0.224) | −0.102 (0.314) | ||
Community rules | 0.602 *** (0.065) | −0.047 ** (0.092) | −0.056 *** (0.020) | −0.004 (0.017) |
Community atmosphere | −0.058 (0.066) | −0.252 (0.093) | 0.027 (0.021) | −0.050 *** (0.018) |
Cons | 1.005 ** (0.446) | 1.607 ** (0.627) | 0.219 (0.136) | 0.228 ** (0.114) |
R-squared | 0.281 | 0.307 | 0.934 | 0.929 |
F-statistics | 11.59 | 13.15 | 465.33 | 430.10 |
References
- Bastakoti, R.C.; Shivakoti, G.P. Rules and collective action: An institutional analysis of the performance of irrigation systems in Nepal. J. Inst. Econ. 2012, 2, 225–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Anderies, J.M.; Janssen, M.A.; Lee, A.; Wasserman, H.; Cleveland, C.J. Environmental variability and collective action: Experimental insights from an irrigation game. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 93, 166–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ostrom, E. Reflections on “Some unsettled problems of irrigation”. Am. Econ. Rev. 2011, 1, 49–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Uusitalo, L. Economic man or social man-exploring free riding in the production of collective goods. In Understanding Economic Behavior; Springer: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 1989; pp. 267–283. [Google Scholar]
- Claudy, M.; Peterson, M.; O’Driscoll, A. Understanding the attitude-behavior gap for renewable energy systems using behavioral reasoning theory. J. Macro-Mark. 2013, 4, 273–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cumming, G.S.; Cumming, D.H.M.; Redman, C.L. Scale mismatches in social-ecological systems: Causes, consequences, and solutions. Ecol. Soc. 2006, 1, 11–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Olson, M. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1965. [Google Scholar]
- Ahn, T.; Ostrom, E.; Walker, J. Heterogeneous preference and collective action. Public Choice 2003, 3–4, 295–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- McDonald, R.I.; Fielding, K.S.; Louis, W.R. Conflicting norms highlight the need for action. Environ. Behav. 2014, 2, 139–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bleidorn, W.; Lenhausen, M.R.; Hopwood, C.J. Proenvironmental attitudes predict proenvironmental consumer behaviors over time. J. Environ. Psychol. 2021, 1–2, 101627. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Taylor, E.C.; Livingston, L.A.; Callan, M.J.; Hanel, P.; Shah, P. Do autistic traits predict pro-environmental attitudes and behaviors, and climate change belief? J. Environ. Psychol. 2021, 76, 101–648. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Katzev, R.D.; Johnson, T.R. Promoting Energy Conservation: An Analysis of Behavioral Techniques; Westview Press: Boulder, CO, USA, 1987. [Google Scholar]
- Black, J.S.; Stern, P.C.; Elworth, J.T. Personal and contextual influences on household energy adaptations. J. Appl. Psychol. 1985, 70, 3–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Downey, D.B.; Ainsworth, J.W.; Qian, Z. Rethinking the attitude-achievement paradox among blacks. Sociol. Educ. 2009, 1, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Banwari, M. Achieving higher seat belt usage: The role of habit in bridging the attitude-behavior gap. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 1988, 12, 993–1016. [Google Scholar]
- Caruana, R.; Carrington, M.; Chatzidakis, A. Beyond the attitude-behaviour gap: Novel perspectives in consumer ethics: Introduction to the thematic symposium. J. Bus. Ethics 2016, 2, 215–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Juvan, E.; Dolnicar, S. The attitude-behavior gap in sustainable tourism. Ann. Tour. Res. 2014, 9, 76–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Redondo, I.; Puelles, M. The connection between environmental attitude-behavior gap and other individual inconsistencies: A call for strengthening self-control. Int. Res. Geogr. Environ. 2017, 2, 107–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nolan, J.M.; Schultz, P.W.; Cialdini, R.B.; Goldstein, N.J.; Griskevicius, V. Normative social influence is under-detected. Pers. Soc. Psychol. B. 2008, 7, 913–923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Schultz, P.W.; Nolan, J.M.; Cialdini, R.B.; Goldstein, N.J.; Griskevicius, V. The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms. Psychol. Sci. 2007, 5, 429–434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Röttger, S.; Vetter, S.; Kowalski, J.T. Ship management attitudes and their relation to behavior and performance. Hum. Factors 2013, 3, 659–671. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stern, P.C. Toward a coherent theory of environmentally significant behavior. J. Soc. Issues 2000, 3, 407–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Santos, F.; Pacheco, J.; Lenaerts, T. Evolutionary dynamics of social dilemmas in structured heterogeneous populations. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2006, 9, 3490–3494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Naidu, S. Heterogeneity and Common Pool Resources: Collective Management of Forests in Himachal Pradesh, India; Amherst Resource Economics Working Paper No. 2005-8; University of Massachusetts: Amherst, MA, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Lavergne, K.J.; Pelletier, L.G. Predicting individual differences in the choice of strategy to compensate for attitude-behaviour inconsistencies in the environmental domain. J. Environ. Psychol. 2015, 44, 135–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Engel, U.; Pötschke, M. Willingness to pay for the environment: Social structure, value orientations and environmental behaviour in a multilevel perspective. Innov. -Abingdon 1998, 3, 315–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baland, J.M.; Platteau, J.P. Coordination problems in local resource management. J. Dev. Econ. 1997, 1, 197–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crespo, J.; Requier-Desjardins, D.; Vicente, J. Why can collective action fail in local agri-food systems? A social ties analysis of cheese producers in Aculco, Mexico. Food Policy 2014, 6, 165–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Robbins, T.W.; Sahakian, B.J. “Paradoxical” effects of psychomotor stimulant drugs in hyperactive children from the standpoint of behavioural pharmacology. Neuropharmacology 1979, 12, 931–950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gould, R.V. Collective action and network structure. Am. Sociol. Rev. 1993, 2, 182–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Marwell, G.; Oliver, E.; Prahl, R. Social tiess and collective action: A theory of the critical mass. Am J Sociol. 1988, 3, 502–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Macy, M.W. Chains of cooperation: Threshold effects in collective action. Am. Sociol. Rev. 1991, 12, 730–747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Agnitsch, K.; Flora, J.; Ryan, V. Bonding and bridging social capital: The interactive effects on community action. Community Dev. 2006, 37, 36–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Woolcock, M. Social capital and economic development: Towards a theoretical synthesis and policy framework. Theor. Soc. 1998, 27, 151–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Temkin, K.; Rohe, W. Social capital and neighborhood stability: An empirical investigation. Hous. Policy Debate 1998, 1, 61–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Saxton, G.D.; Benson, M.A. Social capital and the growth of the non-profit section. Soc. Sci. Quart. 2005, 1, 16–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, NY, USA, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Barrett, C.B.; Travis, A.J.; Dasgupta, P. On biodiversity conservation and poverty traps. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2011, 34, 13907–13912. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Klofstad, C.A. Peer group discussions and civic participation: How long does the effect last? In Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, USA, 30 August 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Oliver, P.; Myers, D. The coevolution of social movements. Mobilization Int. Q. 2003, 8, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Adhikari, B.; Lovett, J.C. Institutions and collective action: Does heterogeneity matter in com-munity-based resource management? J. Dev. stud. 2006, 42, 426–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Neitzel, J.; Saaksvuori, L. Normative Conflict and Cooperation in Sequential Social Dilemmas. VfS Annual Conference 2013 (Duesseldorf): Competition Policy and Regulation in a Global Economic Order. No. 79904. Verein für Socialpolitik/German Economic Association. 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Baland, J.M.; Platteau, J.P. The ambiguous impact of inequality on local resource management. World Dev. 1999, 27, 773–788. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dayton-Johnson, J.; Bardhan, P. Inequality and conservation on the local commons: A theoretical exercise. Econ. J. 2002, 112, 577–602. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clark, P.B.; Wilson, J.Q. Incentive systems: A theory of organizations. Admin. Sci. Quart. 1961, 6, 129–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Verba, S.; Schlozman, K.L.; Brady, H.E. Voice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in American Politics; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1995; p. 640. [Google Scholar]
- Stefan, P.; Katherine, N. Social tiess, collective action and the evolution of governance for sustainable tourism on the Gili Islands, Indonesia. Mar. Policy 2018, 112, S0308597X17308734. [Google Scholar]
- Willy, D.K.; Holm-Müller, K. Social influence and collective action effects on farm level soil conservation effort in rural Kenya. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 90, 94–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bowles, S.; Gintis, H. Social capital and Community Governance. Econ. J. 2002, 483, 419–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feiock, R.C.; Steinacker, A.; Park, H.J. Institutional collective action and economic development joint ventures. Public Admin. Rev. 2009, 2, 256–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Coleman, J. Foundation of Social Theory; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Henfrey, T.; Maschkowski, G.; Penha-Lopes, G. Resilience, Community Action and Societal Transformation; Permanent Publications: East Meon, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Porter, C.O.L.H.; Webb, J.W.; Gogus, C.I. When goal orientations collide: Effects of learning and performance orientation on team adaptability in response to workload imbalance. J. Appl. Psychol. 2010, 5, 935–943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bandiera, O.; Barankay, I.; Rasul, I. Cooperation in collective action. Econ. Transit. 2005, 13, 473–498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Briggs, X.N.D.S. Social Capital and Segregation: Race, Connections, and Inequality in America; Working Paper RWP02-011; Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Granovetter, M. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers, 2nd ed.; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
- Miller, G. Consumerism in sustainable tourism: A survey of UK consumers. J. Sustain. Tour. 2003, 1, 17–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhao, K. Theory of farmers’ professional cooperative heterogeneity and its quantitative determination method. J. South China Agric. Univ. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2012, 4, 57–66. [Google Scholar]
- Molina-Morales, F.; Martinez-Fernadez, M. Does homogeneity exist within industrial districts? A social capital-based approach. J. Reg. Sci. 2009, 1, 210–229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Briggs, S.R. Shyness: Introversion or neuroticism? J. Res. Per. 1988, 22, 290–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yamoah, F.A.; Acquaye, A. Unravelling the Attitude-behaviour Gap Paradox for sustainable food consumption: Insight from the UK apple market. J. Clean Prod. 2019, 217, 172–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grimmer, M.; Miles, M.P. With the best of intentions: A large sample test of the intention-behavior gap in pro-environmental consumer behavior. Int. J. Consum. Stud. 2017, 1, 2–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jackson, T. Motivating Sustainable Consumption: A Review of Evidence on Consumer Behavior and Behavioral Change. Sustain. Dev. Res. Netw. 2005, 29, 30–40. [Google Scholar]
- Richerson, P.J.; Boyd, R. Not by Genes Alone: How Culture Transformed Human Evolution; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. Do institutions for collective action evolve? J. Bioecon. 2014, 1, 3–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Das, U. Can the rural employment guarantee scheme reduce rural out-migration: Evidence from West Bengal, India. J. Dev. Stud. 2015, 6, 621–641. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Angrist, J.D.; Lavy, V.; Schlosser, A. Multiple experiments for the causal link between the quantity and quality of children. J. Labor Econ. 2010, 4, 773–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mont, D.; Nguyen, C. Does parental disability matter to child education? Evidence from Vietnam. World Dev. 2013, 8, 88–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhou, G.; Fan, G.; Shen, G. Income disparity, social capital and health—A case study based on China family panel studies. Manag. World 2014, 7, 12–21. [Google Scholar]
- Hassan, R.; Birungi, P. Social capital and poverty in Uganda. Dev. S. Afr. 2011, 1, 19–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Durlauf, N.; Fatchamps, M. Social Capital; Working Paper Series; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2004; Available online: www.nber.org/papers/w10485 (accessed on 16 January 2022).
- Maweijie, J.; Holden, S. Does social ties capital buy higher agriculture prices? A case of coffee in Masaka district, Uganda. Int. J. Soc. Econ. 2014, 7, 573–585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Staiger, D.; Stock, J.H. Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 1997, 3, 557–586. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ruttan, L.M. Economic heterogeneity and the commons: Effects on collective action and collective goods provisioning. World Dev. 2008, 5, 969–985. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Burt, R.S. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
- Santos, F.C.; Santos, M.D.; Pacheco, J.M. Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games. Nature 2008, 7, 213–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Poteete, A.; Ostrom, E. Heterogeneity, group size and collective action: The role of institutions in forest management. Development and Change 2004, 35, 435–461. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bromley D, W. Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual Foundations of Public Policy; Basil Blackwell: New York, NY, USA, 1989. [Google Scholar]
- Siegel, D.A. Social tiess and collective action. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 2009, 1, 122–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aldrich, H.; Zimmer, C. Entrepreneurship through Social Tiess: The Art and Science of Entrepreneurship; Ballinger: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1986. [Google Scholar]
- Wellman, B.; Gulia, M. The network basis of social support: A network is more than the sum of its ties. In Networks in the Global Village; Routledge: London, UK, 2018; pp. 83–118. [Google Scholar]
- Granovetter, M. The strength of weak ties. Am. J. Sociol. 1973, 6, 1360–1380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Johannes, R. The renaissance of community-based marine resource management in Oceania. Annu. Rev. Ecol. Syst. 2002, 33, 317–340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roegen, N.G. Choice, expectations and measurability. Q. J. Econ. 1954, 4, 503–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Variable | Description | Minimum | Maximum | Mean (S.D.) | Expected Effects |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Independent variables | |||||
Attitude | Would you like to contribute labour or money in small-scale irrigation facilities collective action? | 0 | 1 | 0.501 | |
Behavior | The real participating behavior collected from list of irrigation managing committee personnel | 0 | 1 | 0.478 | |
Paradox | Paradox between attitude and behavior (paradox = 1, no paradox = 0) | 0.00 | 1.00 | 0.6396 (0.4809) | |
Dependent variables | |||||
Weak ties | The number of people outside your immediate family and close friends for contacts and acquaintances (1 = 1–3; 2 = 4–7; 3 = 8–11; 4 = 12–15; 5 = above 16) | 2.00 | 5.00 | 4.4740 (0.7716) | − |
Strong ties | The number of people you could ask for help to cope with the inconvenience and difficulties in daily life (1 = 1–3; 2 = 4–7; 3 = 8–11; 4 = 12–15; 5 = above 16) | 1.00 | 5.00 | 3.5812 (1.1052) | − |
Income heterogeneity | Based on the computation | −0.37 | 0.73 | −0.0080 (0.7160) | +/− |
Cultivated area | Real cultivated area (mu) | 0.00 | 11.00 | 3.5170 (2.0520) | +/− |
Water stealing | The frequency of water stealing happens (1 = never; 2 = occasionally; 3 = sometimes; 4= frequently; 5 = always) | 1.00 | 5.00 | 3.6100 (1.2081) | +/− |
Water use conflict | The frequency of water-use conflicts (1 = never; 2 = occasionally; 3 = sometimes; 4 = frequently; 5= always) | 1.00 | 5.00 | 2.5377 (1.0100) | +/− |
Community rules | The village’s rules and regulations executive conditions (1 = very bad; 2 = bad; 3 = neither bad nor good; 4 = good; 5 = very good) | 2.00 | 5.00 | 4.6753 (0.6135) | +/− |
Community atmosphere | What is the community’s atmosphere? (1 = very bad; 2 = bad; 3 = neither bad nor good; 4 = good; 5 = very good) | 1.00 | 4.00 | 3.6169 (0.5898) | +/− |
Instrumental variable 1 | The distance to the highway 1 = 1–2 km; 2 = 3–5 km; 3 = 6–8 km; 4 = 9–12 km; 5 = above 12 km | 1.00 | 5.00 | 3.6331 (0.9088) | |
Instrumental variable 2 | Whether family members have the experience of metropolitan city migrant working (1 = work; 2 = no work) | 0.00 | 1.00 | 0.3604 (0.4809) |
Bivariate Model | IV Probit Model | IV Probit Model with Social Ties*Income Heterogeneity | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 | |
Weak ties | −0.213 (0.176) | −1.885 * (1.143) | −0.321 (0.224) | |||
Strong ties | 0.312 *** (0.111) | −0.688 ** (0.335) | 0.289 *** (0.110) | |||
Weak ties*income heterogeneity | 4.026 (4.818) | |||||
Strong ties*income heterogeneity | −0.041 (1.168) | |||||
Income heterogeneity | −1.862 *** (0.667) | −1.994 *** (0.702) | −2.073 *** (0.778) | −2.171 *** (0.836) | −19.956 (21.741) | −1.816 (4.154) |
Education | −0.266 * (1.452) | −0.036 ** (0.059) | −0.109 (0.199) | −0.275 (0.181) | −0.240 (0.155) | −0.310 ** (0.153) |
Cultivated area | −0.017 (0.057) | −0.036 (0.059) | −0.031 (0.066) | 0.007 (0.073) | −0.040 (0.065) | −0.042 (0.060) |
cultivation experience | 0.006 (0.011) | 0.006 (0.011) | 0.019 (0.015) | −0.004 (0.013) | −0.005 (0.011) | −0.004 (0.011) |
Water stealing | 1.290 *** (0.147) | 1.251 *** (0.138) | 1.366 *** (0.159) | 1.692 *** (0.218) | 1.317 *** (0.144) | 1.295 *** (0.143) |
Water use conflicts | 0.299 *** (0.112) | 0.225 * (0.116) | 0.367 *** (0.139) | 0.354 ** (0.146) | 0.293 ** (0.118) | 0.225 * (0.116) |
Community rules | −0.261 (0.240) | −0.455 ** (0.216) | 0.813 (0.773) | −0.515 ** (0.263) | −0.135 (0.306) | −0.472 ** (0.223) |
Community atmosphere | −0.314 (0.199) | −0.300 (0.208) | −0.456 * (0.248) | −0.699 ** (0.282) | −0.400 (0.238) | −0.282 (0.224) |
Cons | −0.812 (1.302) | −1.483 (1.405) | 1.066 (1.971) | 1.927 (1.994) | −0.595 (1.382) | −1.364 (1.409) |
Pseudo R-squared | 0.5836 | 0.6006 | ||||
Log-likelihood | −83.826 | −80.406 | ||||
F-statistics | 11.59 | 13.15 | 1090.08 | 364.77 | ||
Wald test of exogeneity | Chi2(1) = 3.09 Prob > chi2 = 0.079 | Chi2(1) = 13.11 Prob > chi2 = 0.0003 | Chi2(1) = 1.10 Prob > chi2 = 0.2945 | Chi2(1) = 0.75 Prob > chi2 = 0.3873 | ||
R-squared | 0.2811 | 0.3249 | 0.9759 | 0.9313 | ||
Adj R-squared | 0.2544 | 0.2998 | 0.9750 | 0.9287 |
Having Negative Attitude but Have Behavior | Having Positive Attitude but No Behavior | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
IV Probit Model | IV Probit Model Social Ties*Income Heterogeneity | IV Probit Model | IV Probit Model Social Ties*Income Heterogeneity | |||||
Weak ties | −2.781 * (1.657) | −1.340 (1.061) | ||||||
Strong ties | 1.048 (1.011) | 0.324 (0.736) | ||||||
Weak ties*income heterogeneity | −0.821 *** (0.241) | −0.241 (0.168) | ||||||
Strong ties*income heterogeneity | −1.145 *** (0.351) | −0.394 (0.267) | ||||||
Income heterogeneity | −3.652 *** (1.370) | −3.633 *** (1.188) | −1.440 * (0.788) | −1.202 * (0.720) | ||||
Education | −0.143 (0.369) | −0.438 * (0.244) | −0.523 ** (0.217) | −0.493 ** (0.218) | −0.139 (0.191) | −0.204 (0.178) | −0.249 (0.161) | −0.248 (0.162) |
Cultivated area | 0.018 (0.111) | 0.060 (0.089) | 0.063 (0.079) | 0.054 (0.078) | −0.022 (0.066) | −0.048 (0.068) | −0.028 (0.063) | −0.024 (0.063) |
Cultivation experience | 0.041 (0.026) | 0.021 (0.018) | 0.014 (0.015) | 0.015 (0.151) | 0.008 (0.015) | 0.002 (0.014) | −0.003 (0.012) | −0.003 (0.012) |
Water stealing | 1.567 *** (0.264) | 1.002*** (0.357) | 1.342 *** (0.186) | 1.344 *** (0.187) | 1.344 *** (0.162) | 1.179 *** (0.256) | 1.261 *** (0.148) | 1.280 *** (0.150) |
Water use conflicts | 0.404 * (0.234) | 0.330 * (0.189) | 0.220 (0.146) | 0.223 (0.146) | 0.375 *** (0.145) | 0.345 ** (0.171) | 0.292 ** (0.124) | 0.293 ** (0.124) |
Community rules | 1.014 (1.041) | −0.493 * (0.297) | −0.682 *** (0.246) | −0.610 ** (0.240) | 0.807 (0.914) | −0.183 (0.310) | −0.317 (0.270) | −0.275 (0.270) |
Community atmosphere | −0.459 (0.409) | −0.359 (0.323) | −0.305 (0.283) | −0.259 (0.282) | −0.412* (0.236) | −0.340 (0.219) | −0.360 (0.221) | −0.389 * (0.223) |
Cons | 2.240 (2.894) | −3.566 (3.392) | −0.306 (1.664) | −0.855 (1.658) | −1.417 (1.711) | −2.965 (3.216) | −1.255 (1.634) | −1.422 (1.626) |
F-statistics | 6.24 | 4.81 | 240.18 | 152.52 | 12.55 | 6.15 | 372.00 | 178.07 |
Wald test of exogeneity | Chi2(1) = 5.21 Prob > chi2 = 0.022 | Chi2(1) = 1.26 Prob > chi2 = 0.2622 | Chi2(1) = 0.12 Prob > chi2 = 0.7241 | Chi2(1) = 1.08 Prob > chi2 = 0.2991 | Chi2(1) = 1.10 Prob > chi2 = 0.2946 | Chi2(1) = 0.00 Prob > chi2 = 0.9561 | Chi2(1) = 0.13 Prob > chi2 = 0.7184 | Chi2(1) = 0.21 Prob > chi2 = 0.6445 |
R-squared | 0.2651 | 0.2176 | 0.9255 | 0.8875 | 0.3591 | 0.2153 | 0.9370 | 0.8769 |
Adj R-squared | 0.2226 | 0.1724 | 0.9216 | 0.8817 | 0.3305 | 0.0.1803 | 0.9345 | 0.8720 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Miao, S.; Zhu, X.; Heijman, W.; Xu, Z.; Lu, Q. Deeds and Words: Farmers’ Attitude-Paradox in Collective Action for Small-Scale Irrigation. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2023, 20, 549. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20010549
Miao S, Zhu X, Heijman W, Xu Z, Lu Q. Deeds and Words: Farmers’ Attitude-Paradox in Collective Action for Small-Scale Irrigation. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2023; 20(1):549. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20010549
Chicago/Turabian StyleMiao, Shanshan, Xueqin Zhu, Wim Heijman, Zengwei Xu, and Qian Lu. 2023. "Deeds and Words: Farmers’ Attitude-Paradox in Collective Action for Small-Scale Irrigation" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 20, no. 1: 549. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20010549
APA StyleMiao, S., Zhu, X., Heijman, W., Xu, Z., & Lu, Q. (2023). Deeds and Words: Farmers’ Attitude-Paradox in Collective Action for Small-Scale Irrigation. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 20(1), 549. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20010549