4.1. Descriptive Statistics
Table 1 shows summary statistics for the entire sample and grouped by educational level. The table reveals higher average absolute incomes enjoyed by individuals with higher educational attainment, here expressed as integer base amounts. Furthermore, individuals with lower educational attainment appear to experience a higher incidence of sickness absence, indicated by a higher number of spells, as well as a shorter duration of employment between each period of sickness absence. This could be indicative of a number of factors, including worse health habits among individuals with less schooling, as well as poorer working conditions in occupations that typically should be characterized by a lower degree of independence and control, as well as a greater prevalence of physically strenuous tasks.
The overall incidence of sickness absence is consistent with the development over time in Sweden as a whole. More specifically, the period examined in this article can be divided into two distinctly different periods, where the 1980s were characterized by considerably higher and generally increasing rates of sickness absence than the 1990s. The lower incidence of sickness absence during the 1990s was caused by the Swedish economic crisis during the early years of the decade, causing substantial changes in the system governing sickness absence compensation.
One empirical contribution of this article pertains to the use of duration analysis in investigating the mechanisms underlying the relationship existing between an individual’s labor market performance and the propensity for sickness absence.
Figure 1 tentatively indicates the existence of such a relationship, where relatively deprived individuals, on average, display a considerably higher raw probability of sickness absence. Evidently, there are several potential explanations to an individual’s position in the relative income distribution. To the extent that one’s position in the relative income distribution is synonymous with increased work-related stress and general discontent with one’s situation, this could possibly have adverse health consequences, thereby explaining the observed pattern. However, the greater propensity of sickness absence among the lowest performing individuals could also be linked to a greater incidence of shirking.
Table 1.
Descriptive statistics: full sample and grouped by educational level.
Table 1.
Descriptive statistics: full sample and grouped by educational level.
| Full sample | Primary education | Secondary education | University education |
---|
| Mean | Min | Max | Mean | Min | Max | Mean | Min | Max | Mean | Min | Max |
---|
Relative income | 0.964 | 0.001 | 4.597 | 0.975 | 0.047 | 4.597 | 0.972 | 0.006 | 4.591 | 0.939 | 0.001 | 4.597 |
Absolute income | 4.911 | 3 | 76 | 4.450 | 3 | 28 | 4.643 | 3 | 49 | 5.803 | 3 | 76 |
Education: |
Primary | 0.250 | 0 | 1 | 1.000 | 0 | 1 | 0.000 | 0 | 1 | 0.000 | 0 | 1 |
Secondary | 0.477 | 0 | 1 | 0.000 | 0 | 1 | 1.000 | 0 | 1 | 0.000 | 0 | 1 |
University | 0.273 | 0 | 1 | 0.000 | 0 | 1 | 0.000 | 0 | 1 | 1.000 | 0 | 1 |
Gender (female = 1) | 0.487 | 0 | 1 | 0.439 | 0 | 1 | 0.477 | 0 | 1 | 0.549 | 0 | 1 |
Civil status (1 = married) | 0.480 | 0 | 1 | 0.515 | 0 | 1 | 0.439 | 0 | 1 | 0.520 | 0 | 1 |
Age | 38.07 | 18 | 65 | 40.10 | 18 | 65 | 36.64 | 18 | 65 | 38.70 | 18 | 65 |
Age squared | 1,564 | 324 | 4,225 | 1,733 | 324 | 4,225 | 1,457 | 324 | 4,225 | 1,595 | 324 | 4,225 |
Years since migration | 6.121 | 0 | 65 | 7.372 | 0 | 65 | 5.780 | 0 | 61 | 5.569 | 0 | 63 |
Years since migration squared | 121.1 | 0 | 4,225 | 144.3 | 0 | 4,225 | 116.3 | 0 | 3,721 | 108.1 | 0 | 3,969 |
Metropol.residence | 0.485 | 0 | 1 | 0.465 | 0 | 1 | 0.457 | 0 | 1 | 0.553 | 0 | 1 |
Local unemployment rate | 6.100 | 0.160 | 24.02 | 5.748 | 0.160 | 24.02 | 6.212 | 0.160 | 24.02 | 6.227 | 0.160 | 24.02 |
Year | 1993 | 1982 | 2001 | 1992 | 1982 | 2001 | 1993 | 1982 | 2001 | 1994 | 1982 | 2001 |
Duration | 2.494 | 1 | 20 | 2.063 | 1 | 20 | 2.464 | 1 | 20 | 3.168 | 1 | 20 |
Lag duration | 1.369 | 0 | 19 | 1.279 | 0 | 19 | 1.384 | 0 | 19 | 1.459 | 0 | 19 |
Number of spells | 2.953 | 1 | 6 | 3.183 | 1 | 6 | 3.043 | 1 | 6 | 2.543 | 1 | 6 |
Spell duration conditional on the spells ending in sickness absence: |
1st spell | 2.551 | 1 | 20 | 2.165 | 1 | 20 | 2.543 | 1 | 20 | 3.200 | 1 | 20 |
2nd spell | 1.986 | 1 | 19 | 1.747 | 1 | 19 | 1.993 | 1 | 19 | 2.375 | 1 | 18 |
3rd spell | 1.756 | 1 | 18 | 1.589 | 1 | 17 | 1.774 | 1 | 18 | 2.016 | 1 | 18 |
Observations | 1,525,310 | 381,839 | 727,438 | 416,033 |
Spells | 611,599 | 185,094 | 295,180 | 131,325 |
Individuals | 184,494 | 50,854 | 85,952 | 47,688 |
In order to properly identify the influence from relative income on the sickness absence propensity, it is important to recognize the mechanisms generating the individual’s position in the relative income hierarchy. More specifically, it is possible that sickness absence propensity and relative income attainment are jointly determined by some third factor. In illustrating this possibility, panel (a) in
Figure 2 displays the unconditional relationship between the duration of an employment spell and the raw propensity to become absent due to sickness. As is evident, the propensity of sickness absence decreases with the duration of the employment spell, suggesting that incidences of sickness absence are recurrent and, thereby, negatively affecting the duration of employment spells among individuals with a higher propensity to be sick. Turning to panel (b), additional evidence is provided for the importance of taking the duration of employment spells into account. Individuals enjoying longer uninterrupted spells of employment on average also perform better in terms of relative income attainment, likely to be due to being positioned on a more favorable career trajectory. As a consequence, the negative relationship between income and sickness absence could therefore, at least partly, result from individuals who are disproportionately allocated to shorter durations of employment being characterized by certain characteristics.
Figure 1.
Relative income and sickness absence.
Figure 1.
Relative income and sickness absence.
Figure 2.
The effect of duration. (a) Duration and sickness absence; (b) duration and relative income.
Figure 2.
The effect of duration. (a) Duration and sickness absence; (b) duration and relative income.
4.2. Regression Analysis
In order to account for the simultaneous correlation of an ongoing work spell’s duration with the probability of being absent due to sickness and the attained relative income, the multivariate analysis relies on discrete-time duration models. The purpose of this modeling strategy is to obtain unbiased estimates of the relationship between relative income and sickness absence. As discussed in
Section 3.4, discrete-time duration models can be estimated using the standard binary choice model framework for panel data. This makes it possible to directly compare the results obtained from duration models with those obtained from conventional binary choice models used in previous studies on transitions into sickness absence. In fact, the previously used binary choice models can be regarded as discrete-time duration models, where the baseline hazard is restricted to be constant, implying that the sickness absence probability is forced to be independent of the duration of the current employment spell.
Table 2 displays regression coefficients from discrete-time duration models employing a logit link function and Gaussian random effects to account for unobserved individual heterogeneity. Although accounting for unobserved individual heterogeneity is common practice in micro-panel studies, it is of particular importance in the context of this study. It has long been known in the literature that neglecting unobserved heterogeneity in duration models causes spurious negative duration dependence in the estimated hazard function (see, for example, [
40]). Since, as shown in
Figure 2 above, both the relative income and the hazard of becoming absent due to sickness depend on the duration of uninterrupted employment, a failure to correctly estimate the effect of duration on the hazard will also cause bias in the estimated effect of relative income. In order to correctly evaluate the effect of relative income on the sickness absence propensity, it is, therefore, essential to control for unobserved individual characteristics.
Model 1 is similarly specified as the models encountered in the previous literature, without any controls for characteristics pertaining to the individual’s employment and sickness absence history. Apart from the variables of paramount interest for this article, the relative income vigintiles, the model includes a comprehensive set of individual and contextual covariates, including the individual’s position in the absolute income distribution. The results are largely consistent with previous findings and a priori expectations, suggesting substantially lower probabilities of transiting into sickness absence among the highly educated and among men. Contrary to expectations, the results suggest a link between absolute income and the sickness absence hazard, where increased income attainment is related to elevated odds of becoming absent due to sickness. This result only emerges when simultaneously controlling for the individual’s position in the relative income distribution, thus indeed suggesting different mechanisms linking these two aspects of an individual’s SES and the risk of sickness absence. The effect of relative income, however, is virtually unaffected by the inclusion or exclusion of absolute income. Recalling the essentially nonexistent link between financial resources and access to healthcare in Sweden, this result indicates that increasing economic resources—if anything—cause an increase in the consumption of goods that are detrimental to the individual’s health. In order to better understand these mechanisms, extended models will interact absolute income attainment and the individual’s educational level.
Table 2.
Estimations of the discrete-time hazard of being absent due to sickness in a given year: logit models with Gaussian random effects.
Table 2.
Estimations of the discrete-time hazard of being absent due to sickness in a given year: logit models with Gaussian random effects.
| Baseline analysis | Robustness analysis |
---|
| Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 |
---|
Secondary education | −0.4787 | −0.4146 | −0.3852 | −0.3357 | −0.2964 | −0.4690 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
University education | −1.5668 | −1.3951 | −1.2115 | −0.9829 | −0.8198 | −1.2607 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Gender | 1.0991 | 0.9924 | 0.9164 | 0.9380 | 0.7972 | 0.8653 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Metropolitan dummy | 0.1042 | 0.0958 | 0.0657 | 0.0650 | 0.0789 | 0.1177 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Unemployment rate | 0.0088 | 0.0088 | 0.0095 | 0.0095 | 0.0076 | 0.0078 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.006)} |
Age | −0.1235 | −0.0888 | −0.1259 | −0.1299 | −0.0928 | −0.0899 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Age squared | 0.0019 | 0.0015 | 0.0017 | 0.0018 | 0.0012 | 0.0012 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Years since migration | 0.0108 | 0.0184 | −0.0144 | −0.0149 | −0.0200 | 0.0042 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.113) |
Years since migration squared | −0.0003 | −0.0004 | 0.0001 | 0.0001 | 0.0003 | −0.0002 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.000) | (0.008) |
Civil status | 0.0263 | 0.0199 | 0.0044 | 0.0064 | 0.0098 | 0.0738 |
| (0.000) | (0.003) | (0.479) | (0.299) | (0.134) | (0.000) |
Relative income categories (13 = reference category) |
Category 1 | 1.2968 | 1.1267 | 1.1422 | 1.4450 | 1.4082 | 1.1718 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 2 | 0.9920 | 0.8611 | 0.8673 | 1.1585 | 1.0513 | 0.8999 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 3 | 0.8535 | 0.7486 | 0.7498 | 0.9686 | 0.8633 | 0.7360 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 4 | 0.7109 | 0.6226 | 0.6224 | 0.7760 | 0.6723 | 0.5486 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 5 | 0.6218 | 0.5506 | 0.5476 | 0.6791 | 0.5613 | 0.4436 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 6 | 0.5280 | 0.4721 | 0.4679 | 0.5991 | 0.4882 | 0.4504 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 7 | 0.4614 | 0.4143 | 0.4080 | 0.5505 | 0.4736 | 0.4484 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 8 | 0.3873 | 0.3521 | 0.3473 | 0.4523 | 0.3729 | 0.4181 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 9 | 0.3289 | 0.2997 | 0.2961 | 0.3957 | 0.3202 | 0.4052 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 10 | 0.2353 | 0.2171 | 0.2131 | 0.2634 | 0.2128 | 0.2106 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 11 | 0.1498 | 0.1371 | 0.1345 | 0.2227 | 0.1716 | 0.2237 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 12 | 0.0864 | 0.0820 | 0.0814 | 0.1122 | 0.0868 | 0.0749 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.004) | (0.142) |
Category 14 | −0.1020 | −0.0949 | −0.0898 | −0.0872 | −0.0837 | −0.0961 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.001) | (0.006) | (0.066) |
Category 15 | −0.1792 | −0.1639 | −0.1584 | −0.1487 | −0.1455 | −0.2091 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 16 | −0.2785 | −0.2560 | −0.2472 | −0.2653 | −0.2264 | −0.2207 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 17 | −0.3620 | −0.3302 | −0.3183 | −0.3536 | −0.3141 | −0.3479 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 18 | −0.4196 | −0.3830 | −0.3701 | −0.4468 | −0.3829 | −0.3854 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 19 | −0.5529 | −0.5018 | −0.4877 | −0.6670 | −0.5504 | −0.5450 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Category 20 | −0.6201 | −0.5687 | −0.5530 | −0.8326 | −0.7442 | −0.8147 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Absolute income in base amounts (1 and 2 are excluded from the sample; 4 = reference category) |
3 | −0.3631 | −0.4259 | −0.3846 | −0.4907 | −0.1780 | −0.4296 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
5 | 0.1604 | 0.1951 | 0.1773 | 0.2614 | 0.1339 | 0.1750 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
6 | 0.2579 | 0.3134 | 0.2916 | 0.4569 | 0.2632 | 0.2423 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
7 | 0.3425 | 0.4035 | 0.3846 | 0.5946 | 0.3487 | 0.2715 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
8–9 | 0.3655 | 0.4260 | 0.4194 | 0.6975 | 0.4543 | 0.3922 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
≥10 | 0.2122 | 0.2673 | 0.3017 | 0.4653 | 0.1717 | −0.3442 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.043) | (0.043) |
Country dummies | yes | yes | yes | yes | yes | yes |
Year dummies | yes | yes | yes | yes | yes | yes |
Duration dummies | no | yes | yes | yes | yes | yes |
Spell dummies | no | no | yes | yes | yes | no |
Lagged duration | no | no | yes | yes | yes | no |
Income-education interactions | no | no | no | yes | yes | yes |
ρ | 0.4240 | 0.3377 | 0.2425 | 0.2420 | 0.1622 | 0.3360 |
| (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) |
Observations | 1,525,310 | 1,525,310 | 1,525,310 | 1,525,310 | 1,322,498 | 592,405 |
Spells | 611,599 | 611,599 | 611,599 | 611,599 | 408,787 | 184,494 |
Individuals | 184,494 | 184,494 | 184,494 | 184,494 | 184,494 | 184,494 |
Log likelihood | −719,085 | −708,801 | −702,840 | −702,317 | −545,275 | −240,238 |
Turning to the relative income categories, a quite expected relationship between the individual’s degree of relative deprivation and their probability of sickness absence emerges. Compared to an otherwise similar individual with an income equal to the average for a given age, sex and education (denoted in the table as relative income category 13), the odds of sickness absence among the lowest three vigintiles are, in a steadily increasing fashion, between 135 and 266% higher (corresponding to β-coefficients of about 0.85 and 1.30, respectively). For the highest vigintile, the odds of becoming absent due to sickness are, rather, 46% lower (β ≈−0.62) than for those facing no relative deprivation. Furthermore, the narrow confidence intervals (95%, not shown) around the estimates generally suggest that the relative income vigintiles are significantly different from one another. Thus, the data support the findings from previous research suggesting that the individual’s placement in the relative income hierarchy is strongly negatively correlated with the probability of transiting into sickness absence.
Consequently, an individual’s degree of relative deprivation appears to operate as a major determinant of the hazard of becoming sickness absent. This is consistent with the expectation that an individual’s degree of relative deprivation is a valid indicator of their degree of work-related stress, with negative repercussions on the individual’s (primarily psychosocial) health.
Model 2 is extended with a set of dummy variables capturing the duration of the current employment spell. Comparing the values of the maximized log-likelihood functions reveals that the addition of this information substantially improves the model’s explanatory power. Moreover, the respective values of ρ indicate that the importance of unobserved individual characteristics is markedly greater in the conventional model specification (Model 1) than in the duration model (Model 2). This confirms that the duration of uninterrupted employment indeed is an important determinant of an individual’s probability of transiting into sickness absence.
The estimates for the duration dummies (available upon request) indicate a rapidly decreasing probability of sickness absence as the duration of the employment spell increases, until approximately seven years of uninterrupted employment. Past this point, the sickness absence risk gradually increases, yet never reaching the baseline risk experienced during the first year (reference category) of the employment spell.
Figure 3 shows the estimated hazard rate (and point-wise 95% confidence intervals) as a function of duration when all explanatory variables are kept constant at their overall means, and only the effect of duration changes. Unlike the raw probability of becoming absent due to sickness depicted in
Figure 2, the estimated hazard does not decrease monotonically with duration, but exhibits a roughly u-shaped form. This indicates that the negative effect of duration on the raw hazard can be partly explained by the explanatory variables included in the regression model. In particular, the relative income, which increases with duration and has a negative impact on the hazard, captures a substantial part of the duration dependence. The remaining variations in the hazard function shown in
Figure 3 can be interpreted as the effects of unobserved temporal heterogeneity,
i.e., effects that vary with duration and are not captured by the covariates included in the regression.
As a consequence of including duration dummies, the influence of relative income is considerably moderated, especially for the most relatively deprived. The odds ratios now range from 3.09 (i.e., β ≈ 1.13) for the lowest category to 0.57 (i.e., β ≈−0.57) for the highest category, which can be compared with a corresponding range of 3.66 to 0.54 in Model 1. Again, the odds ratios are calculated compared to an otherwise similar individual with a relative income of one. Thus, while the link between relative income and the probability of experiencing sickness absence appears to be robust, the strength of this relation appears to be upwardly biased when failing to account for duration.
Figure 4 confirms this, showing predicted hazards as mean of covariates, as well as point-wise confidence intervals, only manipulating the typical individual’s relative income. The hazards are calculated based on Models 1 and 2, confirming that a failure to account for employment duration produces an exaggerated effect of relative income on the sickness absence hazard. In absolute terms, the bias is particularly accentuated at low relative incomes. This suggests that the conventional (binary choice model) approach over-estimates the influence of relative income on the sickness absence propensity among low performers in the labor market. At the other end of the relative income spectrum, the bias serves to underestimate the influence of relative income in models not controlling for duration. When the effect of duration is accounted for, the sickness absence hazard ranges from 0.39 for the typical individual with the lowest relative income (category 1) to 0.10 for the typical individual with the highest relative income (category 20). This shows that relative deprivation has a substantial effect on the sickness absence propensity, even when the effect of duration is taken into account.
Figure 3.
The effect of duration on the sickness absence hazard.
Figure 3.
The effect of duration on the sickness absence hazard.
Figure 4.
The effect of relative income on the sickness absence hazard.
Figure 4.
The effect of relative income on the sickness absence hazard.
Model 3 further controls for aspects relating to the dynamics of the individual’s labor market career. Again, the increase in log-likelihood suggests an improved model fit, also indicated by the decreased value of ρ. Compared to Model 2, the relative income effect is hardly affected by these additional control variables, however. The odds ratios range from 3.13 (i.e., β ≈ 1.14) for the lowest category to 0.58 (i.e., β ≈−0.55) for the highest category. Again, this can be compared with a corresponding range of 3.66 to 0.54 in Model 1.
While the relevance of controlling for the dynamics of the individual’s labor market career emerges quite clearly from the results of Models 1–3, it remains difficult to discuss the likely mechanisms driving the observed results. The theoretical section postulated a rather complex relationship between various aspects of individual SES and health. Holding other measures of SES constant, it was argued that individuals with more education should enjoy superior health and, consequently, a lower risk of sickness absence.
In order to further investigate the mechanisms determining sickness absence, both income measures are allowed to differ according to the individual’s educational level. More specifically, an individual’s position in the relative income distribution is intended to be informative regarding the degree to which an individual is exposed to psychosocial stress through their labor market performance. To the extent that individuals with low relative incomes are increasingly psychosocially stressed, they should experience poorer health. While individuals in the same relative income position experience similar relative labor market returns, the health advantage should arguably be increasing with the individual’s educational level. More specifically, the more highly educated should enjoy more rewarding jobs, as well as a lower exposure to physically hazardous work environments. However, at the lower end of the relative income spectrum, it is possible that the degree of psychosocial stress is accentuated among the highly educated through the comparatively larger discordance between expected and realized outcome within this group.
Lastly, the
a priori expectations would suggest that individuals with higher education have superior skills in translating economic resources into health promoting goods. This ability originates through superior knowledge regarding and utilization of health-promoting behaviors, combined with better capabilities to gather and process information. Consequently, individuals may differ in their consumption behavior, with the highly educated being increasingly likely to direct resources, measured through absolute income, towards consumption behaviors that are health promoting. The estimates are presented in Model 4, with baseline effects for both relative and absolute income for individuals with primary education. In
Figure 5, predicted probabilities of sickness absence are presented for a typical individual belonging to each respective educational category.
As expected,
Figure 5(a) confirms the overall lower hazard of transiting into sickness absence among individuals with higher education. Since the individual’s degree of satisfaction with their labor market returns should be captured by their relative income, this could be indicative of the aforementioned differences in baseline health or suggest differences in working conditions, linked to the individual’s educational level. The figure suggests a consistent decline in the probability of sickness absence with increasing relative income, for all educational levels. In absolute terms, the difference between educational levels, holding relative income constant, is declining with relative income. However, a more relevant way of identifying between-group behavioral differences is arguably as is done in
Figure 5(b). Here, the primary and secondary groups’ predicted hazards are expressed relative to the university educated. The figure clearly shows the relative risks of sickness absence among the secondary school educated and, particularly, the primary school educated to be declining substantially at the most elevated relative income levels. More specifically, at relative incomes exceeding 100% (
i.e., income categories above 13), the likelihood of being absent due to sickness, relative to the university educated, diminishes in an accentuated fashion. This is clearly most pronounced among the primary school educated, whose relative risk of sickness absence declines from around 250% higher to around 140% higher than the hazard of the typical university educated individual in the sample. Furthermore, the declining relative risk is not consistent with the situation displayed at lower relative incomes, where the relative risk appears to hover at a comparatively stable level. As expected, the higher risk of sickness absence experienced by the secondary school educated is consistently less accentuated, but displays a similar pattern.
Figure 5.
The effect of relative income and education on the sickness absence hazard. (a) Relative income and absolute hazard; (b) relative income and relative hazard.
Figure 5.
The effect of relative income and education on the sickness absence hazard. (a) Relative income and absolute hazard; (b) relative income and relative hazard.
Turning to absolute income attainment, the results indicate quite differing influences on the sickness absence hazard, by educational level.
Figure 6 shows predicted sickness absence hazards for different levels of absolute income attainment, again at educational level means. The positive association between absolute income attainment and sickness absence propensity that was previously observed is clearly driven by the primary and, albeit to a considerably lesser extent, secondary school educated. Among the university educated, the influence from the individual’s economic resources is seemingly irrelevant. The pattern could suggest fundamentally different consumption behaviors between the social groups, where increasing economic affluence among, in particular, the primary school educated does little to improve their poorer baseline health. Instead, the increasing economic resources appear to be reinforcing the adverse health behavior that is sometimes suggested in the literature.
Figure 6.
The effect of absolute income on the sickness absence hazard.
Figure 6.
The effect of absolute income on the sickness absence hazard.
Out of necessity, certain assumptions regarding the definition of a sickness absence period had to be made when generating the study sample outlined in
Section 3. In order to investigate to what extent the results are sensitive to the definition of a sickness absence period, Model 5 considers subsequent years during which the individual is sickness absent as one coherent period of sickness absence. Otherwise, Model 5 is specified in an analogous manner as Model 4, which sees each year with a sickness absence period as a unique event. As confirmed by parameter estimates, as well as predicted hazards, this alternative definition hardly alters the previously obtained results. The same conclusions are reached from Model 6, which is estimated on a sample where only the individual’s first employment spell is included, effectively removing problems caused by repeated spells being interrelated. Again, the model specification is otherwise analogous to Model 4. The rationale for conducting this sensitivity analysis is to test the assumption of conditionally-independent spells. Since many individuals experience multiple employment spells (either ending in sickness absence or being right-censored), the assumption of conditional independence might be violated. Although the inclusion of individual-specific random intercepts into the regression models should suffice to ensure conditional independence among individuals’ (potentially many) spells, estimating a model using one spell per individual only is a viable way of testing the robustness of the results with respect to the independence assumption.