1. Introduction
The rapid expansion of the online retail sector has positioned store brands as a pivotal element in redefining market competition dynamics [
1,
2,
3]. This phenomenon is largely driven by the retailer’s ability to leverage consumer preference information, which enables them to design products that precisely meet consumer needs. According to Forbes, sales of store brands in the US reached nearly USD 200 billion in 2022, accounting for 19.6% of all groceries sold [
4]. Following this trend, online retailers, such as JD and Amazon, have launched their store brands to better align with consumer preferences [
5]. For instance, Amazon introduced its store brands as early as 2009, and its store brands, such as Amazon Basics and Pinzon, ranked among the top 10 most popular names. These brands collectively contribute to approximately 81% of all sales [
6]. Similarly, JD introduced its store brand J. ZAO in January 2018, further demonstrating the strategic importance of store brands in driving retail innovation and market success [
7].
Online retailers increasingly introduce store brands, yet consumer preference for these brands varies widely. Typically, store brands are positioned as economical substitutes for national brands but are frequently regarded as lower in quality owing to their production by third-party manufacturers at reduced costs. For example, due to the higher consumer preference for Coca-Cola, Walmart’s introduction of Sam Cola is intended to appeal to price-conscious consumers through a reduction in prices. However, a recent trend shows online retailers launching premium store brands that rival national brands in quality. A notable example is Tesco’s “Tesco Finest” line, developed in collaboration with renowned chefs to offer high-end ready-to-eat dishes such as fish escalopes with Prosecco dressing and vegetable dauphinoise with premium meats [
8]. The introduction of such premium store brands can significantly boost consumer willingness to pay, thereby increasing the acceptance of store brands. This evolution underscores the importance of strategic store brand management and the potential for technological innovations to reshape consumer perceptions and behaviors in the retail sector.
Additionally, the most significant challenge in online retailing concerns asymmetrical information between manufacturers and online retailers, particularly amidst highly diverse consumer preferences for store brands. Online retailers, empowered by information technology, can gather data on consumer preferences regarding store brands [
9]. This wealth of data provides valuable insights into evolving consumer behavior and preference [
10], enabling online retailers to strategically develop and tailor their store brands to align with market demands [
11,
12]. In contrast, manufacturers often lack comprehensive information on consumer preferences regarding store brands, impeding effective demand monitoring and pricing, thus relying heavily on online retailers to acquire this information. For example, after realizing the importance of this information, JD implemented large-scale data technology to assist manufacturers in gaining a deeper understanding of consumer behavior. Similarly, Amazon employed information technology to efficiently transfer consumer information to its principal manufacturers [
13]. Consequently, the effective integration of information technology management is crucial for online retailers aiming to navigate and capitalize on the dynamic landscape of store brands.
Motivated by these observations, this study aims to answer the following important issues. How does information asymmetry affect the online retailer’s sale prices and the manufacturers’ wholesale prices for the national brand and store brand? Is there any motivation for an online retailer to share consumer information with manufacturers? And, if yes, is this with the national manufacturer or the third-party manufacturer? Which factor will affect the online retailer’s information-sharing strategy?
To address these inquiries, we have established a distribution channel model wherein an online retailer markets both a national brand (sourced from a national manufacturer) and a store brand (sourced from a third-party manufacturer) to end consumers. Notably, consumer preference for the store brand varies significantly, ranging from low to high acceptance levels. Leveraging IT technology, the online retailer privately observes actual consumer preference for store brands, while manufacturers maintain their assumptions about this information. The online retailer makes an ex ante decision on whether to share this valuable consumer information with manufacturers, leading to four distinct information-sharing strategies: (1) ‘no information sharing’ (Scenario NN), where the online retailer shares no information with either manufacturer; (2) ‘full information sharing’ (Scenario II), where the online retailer shares consumer preference information with both manufacturers; (3) ‘information sharing with the national manufacturer only’ (Scenario IN); and (4) ‘information sharing with the third-party manufacturer only’ (Scenario NI). Our model first derives the equilibrium prices for each game player under these four scenarios. Subsequently, by comparing profits across different scenarios, we identify the online retailer’s optimal information-sharing strategy and analyze the impact of key parameters such as the probability of low brand loyalty (low-type) consumers, the proportion of comparison shoppers, the side payment, and the degree of information uncertainty regarding the outcomes.
This paper employs game theory in conjunction with the Hotelling model. Game theory, which captures the interactive decisions of multiple decision-makers, has been extensively applied in supply chain management literature to model decision-making dynamics among supply chain partners [
1,
2,
3,
11,
12]. The Hotelling model offers a spatial competition framework that is particularly well-suited for examining product differentiation and consumer preference within a competitive market context [
14,
15]. By integrating the two theoretical frameworks, this study examines how the online retailer’s information-sharing strategy influences the interactions among the national manufacturer, the third-party manufacturer, and the online retailer. Furthermore, the Hotelling model’s focus on spatial differentiation provides a framework for analyzing how consumer preference for store brands is influenced by product positioning and competitive interactions. This theoretical underpinning facilitates an examination of how an online retailer’s information-sharing decisions impact pricing strategies, market competition dynamics, and overall supply chain efficiency.
The results can be summarized as follows. First, our findings highlight key factors influencing the online retailer’s strategy selection, including the probability of consumers being low-type purchasers, the proportion of comparison shoppers, the side payment, and the degree of information uncertainty. Notably, without side payment, the online retailer is hesitant to share information with manufacturers, while manufacturers do not always derive significant benefits from obtaining such information. Second, an increased likelihood of consumers being low-type purchasers does not reliably encourage information sharing by the online retailer, whereas a greater proportion of comparison shoppers (information uncertainty) restrains (motivates) information-sharing decisions. These findings have substantial implications for the online retailer in developing an optimal information-sharing strategy, highlighting the essential role of information management in facilitating effective decision-making and performance optimization in the dynamic online retail industry.
We contribute to the store brand literature in the following two respects. First, we focus on consumer preference for store brands, rather than product-related information, such as cost [
16], supplier [
17], or potential demand [
18]. By classifying consumers into low-type and high-type purchasers based on their preferences for store brands, we develop a novel market demand function using the Hotelling model. This function integrates horizontal differentiation (product–consumer fitness) and vertical differentiation (consumers’ perceived quality level of the store brand), offering a more nuanced understanding of market dynamics compared to previous studies. Second, we extend the literature on information sharing by exploring whether an online retailer should share private information with the national manufacturer, the third-party manufacturer, or both. Using an information strategy matrix, we analyze the impact of information sharing on store brand operations. Our model incorporates key factors such as the probability of low-type consumers, the proportion of comparison shoppers, the side payment, and the degree of information uncertainty, providing new insights into when and how information sharing is beneficial. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to investigate an information strategy matrix in the context of uncertain consumer preference for store brands. Our findings offer practical guidance for store brand operators on strategic decision-making and the conditions under which sharing information with different manufacturers is advantageous.
The subsequent sections of this paper will be organized as follows.
Section 2 reviews the relevant literature.
Section 3 proposes our model setup. The equilibrium outcomes of different strategies are shown in
Section 4.
Section 5 provides the main results.
Section 6 considers an extension, followed by our conclusions in
Section 7.
Appendix A provides supplementary information regarding the proofs.
3. Model Setup
In this model, we consider an online retailer () that sells products from a national manufacturer () and a third-party manufacturer (). The manufacturer produces the national brand () and sets the wholesale price . Then, the online retailer sells the product with a sales price . Similarly, the online retailer can also introduce a store brand () from manufacturer at and then sell the product with . Assuming that there is no loss in generality, the cost of producing one item by manufacturer is normalized to be zero and the production cost of manufacturer is normalized to be . captures the scenario that manufacturer incurs a greater cost when producing brand than manufacturer when producing brand .
We assume that two distinct categories of consumers exist in the market: loyal consumers, who only consider purchasing product
, and comparison shoppers, who will compare the products
and
and select the one with more utility. Each consumer has a maximum demand of one unit. We normalize the market size of consumers to 1, in which the proportion
(
) of consumers represents comparison shoppers, while the remaining proportion
of consumers represents loyal consumers. For the comparison shoppers, given set retail prices of
and
, the net utilities from purchasing the products
and
can be given as:
The above utility functions indicate that products in the market may be both horizontally and vertically differentiated [
15]. Horizontal differentiation arises as a result of imperfect product–consumer fitness, resulting in misfit costs being borne by consumers, which can be captured with the Hotelling model [
44]. In particular, we assume that products
and
are placed at locations
and
on a linear scale, along which line consumers are uniformly distributed. The degree of misfit between the consumer and products
and
are
and
, respectively, where
. Therefore, by purchasing them, the consumer incurs the cost
and
, respectively.
Vertical differentiation can be attributed to the difference in product quality and the consumer’s valuation of product quality. Let
(
) and
represent the consumer’s perceived quality levels of brands
and
, respectively. For simplicity, we assume
without loss of generality.
reflects the degree to which consumers see brand
as a similar replacement for brand
; it may, thus, be understood as the consumer’s perception of brand
’s quality compared to that of brand
[
45]. Following the work of Wu et al. [
46] and Li et al. [
24], we assume
to capture the lower consumer preference for brand
as compared with brand
. We assume the value of the random variable
follows a uniform distribution within the intervals
and
:
, with a probability of
(
), or between
and
:
, with a probability of
. This indicates that brand
is subject to heterogeneous consumer preferences, which can be categorized into two distinct ranges: the lower-preference range
and the higher-preference range
. To simplify the calculations, we use 0.5 as the threshold to distinguish between high and low preferences. However, to provide a more comprehensive analysis, we further consider a general threshold in
Section 6.1. The results show that the conclusions remain consistent, regardless of the chosen threshold.
Then, for the consumer with
(
) to brand
(
), the utility difference between the two brands,
is:
When
, we have
. Then, as can be seen from
Figure 1, with
-type consumers, we have
and
; with
-type consumers, we have
and
. With loyal consumers, as they are loyal to brand
and will not consider brand
, they will purchase product
as long as
.
Therefore, with low-type consumers, we have:
With high-type consumers, we have:
As mentioned above, the online retailer can initially confirm consumer preference by acquiring data. In contrast, manufacturers
and
only hold an identical preconceived notion about preference, which can be divided into lower preference and higher preference, with equal probability [
12,
28]. This phenomenon can be attributed to the fact that the online retailer often possesses sophisticated information technology and data analytics capabilities, hence obtaining more comprehensive insights into customer behavior. Thus, the online retailer uses four kinds of information-sharing strategies: (a) no information sharing (Scenario
), that is, the online retailer shares no information with the manufacturer; (b) full information sharing (Scenario
), that is, the online retailer shares information with both manufacturers; (c) the online retailer only shares information with the national manufacturer (Scenario
); and (d), the online retailer only shares information with the third-party manufacturer (Scenario
).
The game sequence of this model is as follows. First, before assessing the value of consumer preference for brand
, the online retailer makes an ex ante decision on information sharing; i.e., whether or not to share such private consumer information with manufacturers, and if yes, to which one. Meanwhile, the online retailer charges a side payment
if it shares the information [
42]. For example, JD provides a data analytics tool, named JD Business Intelligence (
https://dataworks.jd.com/ (accessed on 20 January 2025)), to its manufacturers. When using its advanced functionalities (such as consumer data analysis), the manufacturer has to pay a certain fee to JD. Secondly, after
is realized and shared accordingly, the two manufacturers set their wholesale prices
and
, followed by the online retailer, who sets the retail prices
and
. All decision variables can be given through profit maximization.
4. Equilibrium
This section analyzes the three game-players’ equilibrium decisions under different information-sharing strategies. To ensure non-negative prices and sales, we limit
in the following analysis. The practical significance of this assumption about
is that the production cost is relatively small, so the two brands will compete for the same consumers in the end market. Otherwise, a sufficiently large production cost will lead to a sufficient difference in the retail prices of the two brands, thus intensifying price competition [
12]. In that situation, consumers tend to purchase products with lower prices, making it difficult for high-cost products to compete in the market.
4.1. Scenario
In Scenario
, the online retailer shares information with either manufacturer. According to their preconceived notion of consumer preference, two manufacturers formulate their decisions. The profit functions of three game players can be given by:
The equilibrium results of firms are shown in the following lemma.
Lemma 1. In Scenario , the optimal wholesale prices are and , leading to retail prices where , , and , respectively.
4.2. Scenario
In Scenario
, the online retailer shares information with two manufacturers. It aligns with the real-world situation where the retailer makes its accumulated sales information available on a publicly accessible data platform. Hence, consumer preference for store brands will become common knowledge. The profit functions of firms in Scenario
are given as:
The equilibrium results of firms are shown in the following lemma.
Lemma 2. In Scenario , the optimal wholesale prices are , , , and , leading to retail prices where , , , and , respectively.
4.3. Scenario
In Scenario
, the online retailer only shares information with the national manufacturer. The pricing decision of the third-party manufacturer relies on the preconceived notion of consumer preference, while the national manufacturer determines the wholesale price using the shared consumer preference. The profit functions of firms in Scenario
are given as:
The equilibrium results for the firms are shown in the following lemma.
Lemma 3. In Scenario
, the optimal wholesale prices are , , and , leading to retail prices where , , , and , respectively.
4.4. Scenario
In Scenario
, the online retailer only shares information with the store manufacturer. Similarly, the national manufacturer makes the pricing decision via its preconceived notion of consumer preference, whereas the third-party manufacturer decides this based on shared consumer preference. The profit functions of firms in Scenario
are given as:
The equilibrium results for the firms are shown in the following lemma.
Lemma 4. In Scenario NI, the optimal wholesale prices are , , and , leading to retail prices where , , and , respectively.
4.5. Market Outcomes
This subsection shows certain market outcomes, such as prices and demands. Propositions 1 and 2 compare the optimal pricing decisions of three game players and the demands of two brands under different information-sharing strategies.
Proposition 1. By comparing the pricing decisions, we have:
- i.
and ;
- ii.
and ;
- iii.
and ;
- iv.
and .
We first shed light on the online retailer’s retail prices and the two manufacturers’ wholesale prices. From Proposition 1, we see that the effect of information sharing on optimal wholesale prices varies in the differences between brands and consumer types. Specifically, for brand , we show that information sharing enables manufacturer to charge a higher wholesale price if no information is shared with manufacturer (except for when ), no matter whether the realized consumer type is either low or high. The rationale hinges on the positive effect of information sharing on mitigating uncertain behavior, thus helping manufacturer price their product more accurately.
However, for brand , the effect of information sharing on the wholesale price is different, depending on the realized consumer type. When consumers express a low preference for store brands, Proposition 1(i) shows that information sharing enables manufacturer to charge a higher wholesale price if no information is shared with manufacturer . This is because, with low-type consumers, manufacturer enjoys both brand and information advantages compared with manufacturer , thus charging a higher wholesale price for brand . In contrast, sharing the high-type consumer preference with manufacturer does not always help to raise the wholesale price, no matter whether manufacturer is informed or not, i.e., . This is because sharing a high preference for brand weakens the brand advantage for manufacturer and, thus, intensifies brand competition between the two brands. As a result, manufacturer has to lower the wholesale price to compete with brand .
It is worth noting that higher wholesale prices will boost retail prices for the online retailer. Thus, the impact of information sharing on retail prices is virtually equivalent to that on wholesale prices.
Proposition 2. Through a comparison of the demands of the two brands, we have:
- i.
;
- ii.
;
- iii.
;
- iv.
.
Proposition 2 presents the opposite effect of information sharing on the demands of the two brands, depending on the types of consumers. Specifically, when consumers express a low preference for brand , information sharing will decrease the demand for brand (i.e., , where ) but boost the demand for brand (i.e., ). For brand , information sharing leads to a higher retail price, thus deterring consumers from purchasing product , resulting in a decline in its demand. In contrast, awareness of low consumer preference for brand motivates the online retailer to reduce the retail price of brand and boost its demand. Thus, sharing low preference for brand fosters demand for brand while concurrently curbing demand for brand .
The situation is quite the opposite with high-type consumers. As can be seen from Propositions 2(iii) and (iv), when consumers show a high preference for brand , information sharing will assist in enhancing the demand for brand (i.e., ) but, conversely, restrain the demand for brand (i.e., ). This phenomenon arises because, for brand , sharing a high preference for brand heightens the competition between the two brands, inhibiting the online retailer from setting a higher retail price. As a result, consumers are more likely to purchase brand due to its lower retail price. Conversely, this information discourages consumers from purchasing brand , reducing its demand. While information sharing strengthens the competitive position of manufacturer , allowing them to raise the wholesale price, the subsequent increase in the retail price adversely affects demand for brand .
5. Discussion
5.1. Information Sharing Without Side Payment
Proposition 3. Without side payment (), the third-party (national) manufacturer benefits from receiving information from the online retailer if the national (third-party) manufacturer is (not) informed, i.e., and . In contrast, the third-party (national) manufacturer does not always benefit from receiving information from the retailer if the national (third-party) manufacturer is not informed, i.e., and does not always hold.
Proposition 3 presents a noteworthy finding that challenges the prevailing beliefs. Prior research revealed that without the side payment, both manufacturers benefit from information sharing (Proposition 1(a) of Shang et al. [
42]). However, we find that information sharing does not always benefit manufacturers in the context of the consumer’s different preferences for store brands. Specifically, when the national manufacturer is informed, the third-party manufacturer also has the incentive to acquire such consumer information. The rationale hinges on the higher wholesale prices (i.e.,
and
) and greater demand for brand
if consumers are of the low type (i.e.,
). However, when the national manufacturer is uninformed, the third-party manufacturer does not always benefit from receiving the online retailer’s information. Although the information advantage enables manufacturer
to charge a higher wholesale price (note that
and
), the higher retail price may inhibit consumers from purchasing brand
if consumers are of the high type. As a result, manufacturer
does not always benefit from receiving information from the online retailer if the national manufacturer is not informed.
In contrast, when the third-party manufacturer is not informed, the national manufacturer has the incentive to acquire consumer information, to enjoy both the brand advantage and the information advantage. However, when the third-party manufacturer is informed, the national manufacturer does not always benefit from receiving the retailer’s information. This is because although information sharing can mitigate uncertain behavior and help manufacturer price more accurately, it will intensify the brand competition between the two products. As a result, the national manufacturer may, conversely, gain more benefits from not acquiring such consumer information.
Such a finding enriches the existing literature on the impact of information sharing on uninformed manufacturers, one that has important implications for manufacturers regarding whether or not to acquire information regarding consumer preferences for store brands. Therefore, even if there is no cost to investing in information infrastructure, e.g., a shared database [
47], the manufacturer has to think twice about whether to reach an agreement on information sharing.
Proposition 4. Without side payment (), the online retailer will not share any information with either manufacturer.
The above result is in line with the literature [
43]. This is because not sharing the low-type consumer preference with either manufacturer has the potential to induce manufacturer
to set the lowest wholesale price of the national brand, thereby enlarging the sales of this brand (see Proposition 1(
i) and Proposition 2(
i)). For the store brand, the online retailer will set the highest sales price to squeeze out a larger marginal profit, although doing so will lead to the smallest sales for this brand. In contrast, when consumers are of the high type, then not sharing information with either manufacturer has the potential to induce manufacturer
to set the lowest wholesale price for the store brand, thereby enlarging the sales of this brand (see Proposition 1(
iv) and Proposition 2(
iv)). For the national brand, the online retailer will set the highest sales price to squeeze out a larger marginal profit, although doing so will lead to the smallest sales numbers for this brand. Nevertheless, the online retailer still benefits from the highest total profit by selling the two brands under Scenario
NN, especially when sharing its private consumer information with the manufacturer cannot bring additional profit (i.e.,
).
5.2. Information Sharing with Side Payment
We then consider the situation in which manufacturers must pay the online retailer a side payment to acquire information, i.e., . The findings are summarized in the subsequent propositions.
Proposition 5. With a side payment (), neither the third-party manufacturer nor the national manufacturer will always benefit from receiving information from the online retailer, no matter whether the rival is informed or not, i.e., and does not always hold when .
As compared with the findings revealed in Proposition 3, Proposition 5 shows different findings regarding the effect of information sharing on the profitability of manufacturers. The rationale hinges on the side payment. When the advantage of receiving information cannot offset the disadvantage of side payment, the manufacturer may react negatively to receiving such information.
Proposition 6. With a side payment (), thresholds , , , and exist, such that:
(1) when , the online retailer’s optimal information-sharing strategy is NN if , then shifts to IN if , and finally, to II if ; (2) when , the online retailer’s optimal information-sharing strategy is NN if , then it shifts to II if where , , , and .
Proposition 6, as also illustrated in
Figure 2, shows that the online retailer’s optimal information-sharing strategy will be affected by three model parameters: the probability of which consumers are of the low type (
), the proportion of comparison shoppers (
), and the side payment (
). Specifically, when the proportion of comparison shoppers is below a set threshold (i.e.,
), a comparatively low side payment will still inhibit the online retailer from sharing private consumer information with either manufacturer. The rationale is quite similar to the case when
. In contrast, a sufficiently high side payment (i.e.,
) stimulates the online retailer to share information with both manufacturers, due to the dominant effect of the side payment.
More interestingly, with a moderate , i.e., , the online retailer prefers to share information solely with manufacturer rather than with manufacturer . The rationale is as follows. As stated in Proposition 1, sharing high-type consumer preferences solely with manufacturer rather than with manufacturer can induce both manufacturers to lower the wholesale prices of the two brands (i.e., and ), thereby enlarging the sales of the two brands (i.e., and ). Although sharing low-type consumer preferences solely with manufacturer has the potential to induce the manufacturer to lower the wholesale price, thereby leading to smaller sales of the two brands, it turns out the total payoff, including two types of consumers, under Scenario IN is larger than that under Scenario NI. As a result, a moderate side payment stimulates the online retailer to share its private consumer information solely with the manufacturer . When consumers are more likely to be shoppers (i.e., ), the online retailer will not share information with either manufacturer (Scenario ) due to a low side payment (i.e., ), or it will share information with both manufacturers (Scenario ) when the side payment exceeds a threshold (i.e., ).
Corollary 1. (1) Threshold () increases in if and decreases in otherwise. As a result, a larger does not always induce the online retailer to share its private consumer information. (2) and always increase in , while increases in if and decreases in if , where . As a result, a larger does not always induce the online retailer to share its private consumer information.
As one might expect, a larger
value has the potential to inhibit the online retailer from sharing information with the manufacturer; both
Figure 2 and Corollary 1 reveal that a larger
may conversely stimulate the online retailer to share information with the manufacturer. As can be seen from
Figure 2 for the fixed values of
and
(taking
and
as an example), the online retailer’s optimal information-sharing strategy switches from
with a small
(e.g.,
) to
with a moderate
(e.g.,
), and finally to
when the value for
is large enough (e.g.,
).
Additionally, although the online retailer’s payoff under these four scenarios is always increasing in , the effect under Scenario is more pronounced than that under other scenarios (e.g., Scenario and Scenario ). Therefore, as increases, the online retailer becomes more reluctant to share its private information with the manufacturer.
7. Conclusions
This paper considers a channel structure in which an online retailer sells both the national brand sourced from the national manufacturer and the store brand sourced from the third-party manufacturer to end-consumers. Consumers express different preferences toward the two brands. We investigate, under the assumption that the online retailer can obtain consumer information in confidence, whether the online retailer is motivated to share this information, and if so, to which manufacturer. We specifically consider four possible information-sharing strategies: (a) no information sharing (Scenario ), that is, the online retailer shares the consumer preference information with no manufacturer; (b) full information sharing (Scenario ), that is, the online retailer shares the consumer preference information with both manufacturers; (c) the online retailer shares the consumer preference information with only the national manufacturer (Scenario ); and (d) the online retailer shares the consumer preference information with only the third-party manufacturer (Scenario ).
7.1. Theoretical Implications
Our study makes significant contributions to both the store brand and supply chain information literature by addressing a previously unexplored area: the information strategy matrix in the context of uncertain consumer preferences for store brands. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to systematically analyze how consumer preference information influences the retailer’s decision to share information with manufacturers, offering novel insights into the strategic dynamics of store brand operations.
First, we focus exclusively on consumer preference information regarding store brands, distinguishing our work from prior research that examines cost, demand, supplier, or quality information. By categorizing consumers into low-type and high-type, based on their preference for store brands, we demonstrate how this classification shapes market distributions and strategic decisions. By integrating horizontal differentiation (consumer fitness) and vertical differentiation (the perceived quality of store brands) within the Hotelling model, we establish a unique market demand function that advances our theoretical understanding of store brand competition.
Second, we expand the research on information strategy by examining whether the online retailer should share its private consumer preference information with both the national and third-party manufacturers. Unlike existing studies that focus on traditional supply chain frameworks or specific types of information, our model incorporates key factors such as the probability of low-type consumers, the proportion of comparison shoppers, the side payment, and the degree of information uncertainty. This comprehensive framework allows us to identify scenarios in which sharing information with various stakeholders is advantageous, providing actionable insights for store brand operators.
These contributions not only enrich the theoretical understanding of store brands but also advance the supply chain information literature by highlighting the critical role of consumer preference information in shaping supply chain dynamics and decision-making. Our findings offer a foundation for future research on information-sharing strategies in the context of store brands and beyond.
7.2. Managerial Implications
The findings of this study offer valuable insights and actionable strategies that can directly benefit managers operating within the retail sector, especially those involved with store brands.
Firstly, the decision to share or withhold information is influenced by factors such as side payment thresholds, consumer types, and the proportion of comparison shoppers. Managers should evaluate these factors systematically to determine the most effective strategy. For instance, in markets with a high proportion of comparison shoppers, sharing information with manufacturers can help align pricing strategies and attract price-sensitive consumers. Additionally, managers can use side payment mechanisms to incentivize information sharing when it aligns with their strategic goals. Secondly, managers should leverage advanced data analytics and technology tools to optimize decision-making. For example, machine learning algorithms can predict consumer preferences, while real-time data monitoring systems can track market trends. These tools enable managers to enhance product positioning, pricing strategies, and marketing efforts, ensuring that they can respond swiftly to changing market conditions. By adopting these strategies, managers can improve operational efficiency, enhance collaboration with manufacturers, and drive sustainable growth in the retail sector.
7.3. Limitations and Suggestions for Future Research
Our study has several limitations that offer opportunities for future research. First, we assume that the information shared by the online retailer is completely accurate. In terms of the difficulty of acquiring consumer information or the occurrence of real-world data errors, one can extend the model to incorporate information accuracy to better reflect real-world scenarios. Second, manufacturers may conduct their own marketing research (e.g., surveys) to obtain consumer preference information at a limited cost, which is not considered in our model. Future research could explore the impact of such activities on information-sharing strategies. Third, our model simplifies consumer loyalty by assuming fixed preferences for the national brand, ignoring potential loyalty to the retailer or other brands. Future research could explore dynamic loyalty models to capture shifting consumer behaviors. Addressing these limitations in future research will further improve our understanding of information-sharing strategies in retail supply chains.