Next Article in Journal
Discovering Customer Purchase Patterns in Product Communities: An Empirical Study on Co-Purchase Behavior in an Online Marketplace
Previous Article in Journal
More Haste, Less Speed: How Update Frequency of Mobile Apps Influences Consumer Interest
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Social Welfare Analysis under Different Levels of Consumers’ Privacy Regulation

1
Institute of Big Data Intelligent Management and Decision, College of Management, Shenzhen University, Shenzhen 518060, China
2
College of Management, Shenzhen University, Shenzhen 518060, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2021, 16(7), 2943-2964; https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16070161
Submission received: 10 September 2021 / Revised: 15 October 2021 / Accepted: 23 October 2021 / Published: 27 October 2021

Abstract

:
With the rapid development of information technology, digital platforms can collect, utilize, and share large amounts of specific information of consumers. However, these behaviors may endanger information security, thus causing privacy concerns among consumers. Considering the information sharing among firms, this paper constructs a two-period duopoly price competition Hotelling model, and gives insight into the impact of three different levels of privacy regulations on industry profit, consumer surplus, and social welfare. The results show that strong privacy protection does not necessarily make consumers better off, and weak privacy protection does not necessarily hurt consumers. Information sharing among firms will lead to strong competitive effects, which will prompt firms to lower the price for new customers, thus damaging the profits of firms, and making consumers’ surplus higher. The level of social welfare under different privacy regulations depends on consumers’ product-privacy preference, and the cost of information coordination among firms. With the cost of information coordination among firms increasing, it is only in areas where consumers have greater privacy preferences that social welfare may be optimal under the weak regulation.

1. Introduction

In the era of big data, the progress of information technology enables firms to collect consumer information with unprecedented speed and capacity, and identify consumers in more and more sophisticated ways [1]. Firms can analyze consumers’ personal characteristics and preferences by collecting consumers’ information, so as to practice personalized pricing [2]. For example, cookies, loyalty cards, Wi-Fi, and other automated data collection devices can be used to track consumers’ virtual purchase footprints [3]. Firms can identify new and old customers, and provide them with different products, services, and prices based on their purchase history data [4]. Using consumers’ past purchase history to differentiate new and old customers and make price-discrimination is called behavior-based price discrimination (BBPD). This pricing model relies on the collection of consumer information by firms. The more information collected by firms, the more sophisticated pricing can be made for consumers.
In addition to collecting information from old customers, firms can even collect more information about consumers through information sharing. For example, in the grocery store and pharmacy market, Catalina Marketing organizes retailers to share customer purchase history data to help them design promotional activities [5]. In the aviation industry, Delta claims that it shares consumer information with SkyMiles alliance partners, including Alaska Airlines, Hawaiian Airlines, etc. This enables airlines to track passengers’ flyer statuses together, to better understand their needs. In the retail industry, Lands’ End Inc., which sells clothing online and through catalogues, shares consumer information with competitive firms. WalMart and Target cooperated with other large retailers to develop a mobile payment system called Merchant Customer Transaction (MCX). MCX’s CurrentC supports data collection. These retailers promise to use CurrentC as their exclusive payment system, strictly control customer data, and cooperate effectively [6]. These examples prove that there are a large number of information sharing practices among firms in reality, which shows that information sharing is helpful for firms to understand consumers, thus making more accurate price discrimination.
However, the information security problem created by the large-scale collection, utilization, and sharing of consumers’ private information by firms will cause consumers privacy concerns. For example, after Cambridge Analytica was found to abuse Facebook user information, Facebook shares fell by 5% [7]. Acxiom, one of the largest information providers, claims to have the information of more than 200 million Americans. Large technology companies, such as Facebook, Google, and Amazon, collect more than 1 billion discrete units of information from users every month [8]. The evidence mentioned above indicates that consumers will incur disutility when they purchase from a firm that has obtained their information. Sharing information about consumers among firms will also cause consumers privacy concerns, but this information sharing behavior can alleviate the problem of information asymmetry in the market to some extent, improve the efficiency of resource allocation in the market economy, and promote competition. For example, the banking and insurance markets will exchange the records of customer default and risk characteristics, so as to know the customers with credit default and reduce their risk.
In view of this, should the government regulate on how competing firms collect and share private data of specific users, or should the government promote firms to exercise self-regulating when privacy issues are involved [9]? With the growing concern for consumers’ privacy, scholars have begun to propose various regulations to protect consumers’ privacy. A large number of related studies focus on increasing consumers’ control over privacy, and restricting firms’ information collection behavior [1,10], but few studies consider the information sharing behavior among firms. In addition, most studies try to put forward a powerful privacy protection measure to put consumers in a better position, but many studies point out that privacy protection measures that seem to be beneficial to consumers will actually harm them [9,11]. Considering the uncertainty of the benefits of privacy protection measures, this paper, based on the research of Shy and Stenbacka [9], attempts to explore the impact of different degrees of privacy protection measures on consumers.
In this paper, we study the influence of three different levels of privacy regulation concerning information sharing among firms on each market party. This paper studies the pricing strategies of competing firms under different levels of privacy regulation, and explores what role consumers’ privacy preferences and product preferences play in the competition game. In this study, the level of privacy regulation determines the extent to which firms can use consumers’ private information for differentiated pricing. Specifically, this paper attempts to answer the following questions: (1) considering consumers’ privacy concerns, how do firms charge new and old customers under different levels of privacy regulation? (2) What kind of competitive effect will information sharing cause among firms? (3) What is the relationship between industry profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare under different levels of privacy regulation? (4) Which privacy regulation should the government implement in order to optimize social welfare? In order to solve the above problems, this paper establishes a two-stage duopoly Hotelling competition game model, which applies to the market structure of duopoly, and we consider competition between the duopoly. We discuss the equilibrium results under different levels of privacy regulation, and try to determine which level is more appropriate. The research results not only provide new ideas for scholars to examine the dynamic competition game regarding consumers’ privacy concerns, but also provide some theoretical guidance and suggestions for relevant government agencies to formulate appropriate privacy regulation, and stimulate the market to develop more smoothly and effectively.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the related literature. Section 3 describes the problem, explains the symbols, and presents the model. Section 4 shows the equilibrium results of the model under three privacy regulations. Section 5 analyzes the welfare of all parties in society under different privacy regulation. Section 6 shows implications for policy and management, and Section 7 concludes the paper. Appendix A contains proof of the results.

2. Literature Review

This study is closely related to two streams of literature. The first is economics literature related to BBPD. There is much literature concerning BBPD, and most of these papers examine the impact of BBPD on firms and consumers, based on the horizontal differences of firms. The classic literature on BBPD holds that, if firms can discriminate against prices, it will lead to intense price competition and lower prices, thus bringing positive effects on consumer surplus [12,13]. There are some similarities between the results of this paper and the conclusions of the prior studies [12,13,14]. This paper shows that BBPD will lead to more intense price competition to some extent, which is mainly manifested in the price set for old customers in the second stage, while whether there is strong competition in the price set for new customers in the second stage depends on consumers’ product-privacy preference. In addition, BBPD weakens the first price competition of firms. There are other scholars who extend BBPD, such as considering product quality [4], analyzing BBPD based on vertical differentiation, and so on. In our model, we consider a problem concerning consumer privacy, i.e., considering that the behavior of firms collecting consumer information will cause consumer privacy concerns. Carroni [14] admitted that firms’ access to consumer information will cause privacy concerns, but academic circles seldom consider the privacy cost of consumers. Therefore, this paper attempts to explore the impact of consumer privacy costs on BBPD.
Second, this paper is related to the literature on information sharing among firms. Most researchers pay attention to the motivation of vertical or horizontal information sharing among firms. The vertical information sharing happens between the upstream Firm and the downstream firm in a supply chain, while horizontal information sharing involves competing parties, such as two retailers. As far as vertical sharing is concerned, most studies on information sharing focus on market demand information [15,16,17]. For example, Jiang et al. [16] studies information sharing in a distribution channel where the manufacturer possesses better demand-forecast information than the downstream retailer. They show that among the three formats, ex ante, the retailer prefers the no-sharing format, whereas the manufacturer prefers the mandatory-sharing format. With the development of a platform economy, the platform can collect a lot of information about consumers, and decide whether to share such information with sellers on platform [7]. Liu et al. [7] show that, when the platform strategy has two potential constraints (privacy constraint and fairness constraint), the platform always has the incentive to share information, which is beneficial to the platform and all sellers. As far as horizontal sharing is concerned, Chen et al. [18] show that when both firms have the ability to identify consumers, it is a competitive advantage to identify them more accurately. When competitive firms are in the early stages, i.e., their recognition ability is low, sharing consumer information among firms can achieve a win-win situation. Liu and Serfes [19] extend the research of Chen et al. [18]: they report that if the customer bases of the two firms are quite different, information sharing will happen. Kim and Choi [20] build a two-period model with BBPD and information sharing, which reveals that when firms know that their products are substitutes, information sharing enables them to refine their cognition of each consumer’s preferences. Some studies focus on horizontal information sharing behavior among sellers on the platform. For example, Boon et al. [21] show that information sharing among competing members in the community improves the productivity of the whole community. Chen and Zhu [22] explore whether information sharing can benefit individual sellers, and how the market effectively encourages sellers to share information. The results show that information sharing significantly improves the business performance of a single seller. In addition, some studies believe that the connection and social interaction between sellers can produce economic value, and investigate how the platform can better support the social interaction between sellers [23,24]. However, some scholars reveal that there is a negative correlation between sellers’ mutual assistance and performance [25,26], which is consistent with the results of this study. This study focuses on horizontal information sharing among firms, and shows that when firms are allowed to share information, the profit of firms is the lowest while the consumer surplus is the highest.
There are also papers that consider the interaction between information sharing and market competition. Chen et al. [18] show that when targetability in a market reaches a very high level, it will intensify the price competition and lead to a prisoner’s dilemma. Liu et al. [7] and Shy and Stenbacka [27] also believe that information sharing may intensify competition, and lead to other undesirable results. However, Nijs [5] believes that information sharing has an anti-competitive effect, and the anti-competitive effect of information exchange may occur even before the exchange itself occurs. This is because forward-looking firms that expect information exchange to generate extra profits will raise prices. The results of this study show that information sharing among firms will intensify competition to a certain extent, and make firms set lower prices for new customers in two periods.
Finally, our paper is also related to literature on privacy regulation. Scholars put forward many privacy regulations methods, and study their influence on competition and social welfare. They focus either on how to improve consumers’ control over privacy [1,28], or on how to restrain firms from collecting information [10]. However, scholars have not reached a consensus on whether privacy regulation is beneficial to consumers. Conti et al. [10] investigate an opt-in regime of privacy regulation, which requires firms to obtain the consent of consumers before collecting information, and how to affect product quality and consumer surplus. The results reveal that when the complementarity between information and quality is strong, the product quality is higher under the opt-in regime, so consumers are in a better situation. Therefore, they believe that privacy regulation is beneficial to consumers to a certain extent. However, Stigler [29] states that privacy protection may cause inefficiency, and the government’s policy of protecting consumers’ privacy may not improve welfare. Li et al. [30] show how the transparency of BBPD affects firms and consumers. He states that the transparency of BBPD leads to price increases, which is good for the company, but harms consumers and society. This result means that forcing firms to disclose their BBPD model to the public is originally intended to protect consumers’ privacy and welfare, but it turns out that it is even worse for consumers. This study has something in common with the above literature, i.e., under the stronger privacy regulation, the welfare of consumers and society may not be better. In addition, some studies on privacy regulation have noticed that consumers’ information may be shared among firms, so they also try to restrain the information sharing behavior among firms. For example, Shy and Stenbacka [9] evaluate the impact of different degrees of privacy regulation concerning information sharing among firms on corporate profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare in a static environment. They report that when firms are under the weak regulation, i.e., they can collect consumer information but cannot share it with each other, the profits of firms are higher than those under the strong regulation and no regulation, and the consumer surplus and total welfare will always increase with the strengthening of privacy protection. Based on this research, this paper considers the privacy cost of consumers in a dynamic environment, and draws a different conclusion.
In summary, it can be found that there are many studies on firms collecting consumer information for pricing, but the pricing problem involving horizontal information sharing among firms is still relatively limited, and there are mainly the following limitations: first, the research on BBPD is relatively mature, but these studies do not consider the privacy concerns of consumers. The pricing model of firms using consumer-specific information will bring privacy concerns to consumers, and the behavior of information sharing among firms will also cause privacy concerns of consumers, but many models do not consider the privacy cost of consumers. Secondly, most scholars pay attention to sharing market demand information among vertical firms, but few studies focus on sharing consumer information among horizontal firms. Finally, since consumers are paying more and more attention to information security, scholars have put forward various privacy regulations to protect consumers, but most of these studies involve improving consumers’ privacy control and how to restrain firms from collecting consumer information. Very little literature discusses whether to restrict information sharing among firms. In view of this, this paper, based on the research of Shy and Stenbacka [9], considers the privacy cost of consumers, constructs a privacy regulation regarding firms collecting and sharing consumer information, and tries to explore how this privacy regulation affects the two-stage product price game of competing firms based on consumer purchase history. This paper mainly analyzes the equilibrium results of competing firms under different intensity of privacy regulation, including industry profit, consumer surplus, and social welfare. This study has certain reference significance for relevant government personnel to formulate appropriate privacy regulation to guide the effective operation of the market. In addition, from the consumer’s point of view, consumers can understand the formulation process of firm-related strategies, so as to make rational consumption decisions.

3. The Model

3.1. Problem Description

This paper assumes that there is privacy regulation involving firm information sharing, and the intensity of regulation is divided into three levels. Strong regulation (S) means that firms are not allowed to collect consumer information; medium regulation (M) means that firms are allowed to collect consumer information, but are not allowed to share it with each other; and weak regulation (W) means that firms allow the collecting and sharing of consumer information. By constructing the Hotelling model of duopoly’s two-stage price competition, this paper analyzes the influence of three privacy regulations on industry profit, consumer surplus and social welfare.

3.2. Notation Description

Table 1 summarizes all notations in our models.

3.3. Model Building

We model a duopoly setting, in which two competing firms, A and B, produce the same product or offer the same service in the market. However, the products or services they offer have different features, and this paper uses the Hotelling model to define the product differences between the firms. In the Hotelling model, these two firms are located at both ends of a linear city, with the assumption that, at the end of the interval [0, 1], the distance between them denotes their difference. At the same time, the number of consumers in the market is normalized to one, which is evenly distributed in linear cities. The location of consumers represents their preference for products, and the closer they are to a certain firm, the more they prefer the firm’s products. Therefore, consumers will buy the products closest to themselves. If consumers cannot buy products which are exactly the same as their own preferences, they will face a cost. This disutility is associated to the distance between consumers and firms, and it is produced by each unit distance as t . Therefore, t represents the product preference of consumer. All consumers have a retention value v on products, and v will equal zero when they do not buy any products. It is assumed that each consumer only buys a single-unit product in each period, and v is large enough to make sure the market fully is covered in each period.
The two-period game unfolds as follows: in the first stage, all consumers are new to the firm, and both firms know nothing about them, so only uniform prices can be offered. After the end of the first period, the two firms can collect the purchase history of consumers, and distinguish between new and old customers under the M and W regulation. After entering the second period, under the S regulation, the situation is the same as that in the first period, i.e., the firms know nothing about consumers, hence the uniform prices are formulated. While under the M and W regulation, firms can identify consumers’ features according to consumers’ information they leave in the first period, and then recommend products that meet consumers’ preferences and set personalized prices. Under the M regulation, two firms only know the preferences of old customers, and formulate two kinds of prices, respectively, for their new and old customers, i.e., p a n , p a o ; p b n , p b o . Under the W regulation, two firms can share information about consumers. For consumers whose information is shared, firms can recommend products that meet their preferences, and set poaching prices, i.e., p a p ; p b p , while for consumers whose information is not shared, firms can only set a uniform new customer price. Similarly, firms will set a personalized price for their old customers. Therefore, there are three types of prices the firms need to formulate, i.e., p a n , p a o , p a p ; p b n , p b o , p b p .
In this paper, S and M regulation are taken as a benchmark model, while the W regulation is formulated as the main model, as shown in Figure 1, which is the timeline of the main model. Following the model setup in literature [4] and using the backward induction method, we solve for the subgame Nash equilibrium of the model. Model hypotheses are as follows:
1. If the firm can collect consumer information, there is a privacy cost, c , for consumers to stay with the original firm, which is an exogenous variable. If another firm holds the consumers’ information by sharing information between firms, there will also be a privacy cost when consumers buy from another firm, and this cost is related to the degree of information sharing among firms. We assume the cost is k c .
2. Under the W regulation, the degree of information sharing between firms, k , is an endogenous variable, and the firms will share the information of the consumers who are farthest from the firms. In addition, there is a coordination cost in firm information exchange, and it is an exogenous variable, which is denoted as β .
3. The marginal production cost of the two firms is standardized as zero.

4. Analysis

4.1. Benchmark Model: Under the Strong Regulation

Under the S regulation, as the firms are not allowed to collect information from consumers, the situation in the first period is the same as that in the second period. Figure 2 depicts this situation. The equilibrium result under the S regulation is the equilibrium solution of the standard Hotelling model. Therefore, the conclusion of proposition 1 is obtained, and the justifications of the results are provided in Appendix A.
Proposition 1.
Under the S regulation, the firm sets the same price for customers in both periods, i.e., p a 1 = p b 1 = p a 2 = p b 2 = t . The profit earned by the firm in the second period is π a , 2 S = π b , 2 S = t 2 . The total profit earned in both periods is π a , t S = π b , t S = t . The consumer surplus is C S S = 5 t 2 + v , and the social welfare is S W S = t 2 + 2 v .

4.2. Benchmark Model: Under the Medium Regulation

4.2.1. The Second Period

Purchasing decisions: under the Medium Regulation, consumers who buy from a firm in the first period know that the firm will collect their information, so they incur a privacy cost when these consumers stay with the original firm in the second period. Assume that the average privacy cost of all consumers is c . For those customers, θ , who consume in Firm A in the first period, i.e., 0 θ θ 1 (as shown in Figure 3), the utility they gain from staying with Firm A is v p a o t × θ c , while the utility they have from switching to Firm B is v p b n t ( 1 θ ) . Let z 1 indicate the location of the marginal consumer who is indifferent between repeatedly purchasing from Firm A and switching to Firm B. Then, allowing the two utilities to be equal, we have z 1 = p b n p a o c + t 2 t . For those customers θ who consume in Firm B in the first period, i.e., θ 1 θ 1 (as shown in Figure 3), the utility they gain from staying in Firm B is v p b o t ( 1 θ ) c , while the utility they have from switching to Firm A is v p a n t × θ . Let z 2 indicate the location of the marginal consumer who is indifferent between repeatedly purchasing from Firm B and switching to Firm A. Then, letting the two utilities be equal, we also have z 2 = p b o p a n + t + c 2 t .
Combining the two marginal consumers, it can be seen that the consumers who go to Firm A in the second period are divided into two parts, i.e., 0 θ z 1 and θ 1 θ z 2 . Similarly, the consumers who go to Firm B in the second period are divided into two parts, i.e., z 1 θ θ 1 and z 2 θ 1 .
Duopoly pricing: firms’ profit functions in the second period are:
π a , 2 M = z 1 × p a o + z 2 θ 1 × p a n
π b , 2 M = 1 z 2 × p b o + θ 1 z 1 × p b n
According to the first-order optimization conditions:
π a , 2 M p a o = c 2 p a o + p b n + t 2 t = 0 π a , 2 M p a n = c 2 p a n + p b o + t 2 t × θ 1 2 t = 0 π b , 2 M p b o = c + p a n 2 p b o + t 2 t = 0 π b , 2 M p b n = c + p a o 2 p b n t + 2 t × θ 1 2 t = 0
By solving the equations in (3), we can obtain the prices set by the two firms for new and old customers in the second period as follows:
p a o M = 1 3 c + t + 2 t × θ 1 p a n M = 1 3 c + t 3 4 θ 1 p b o M = c 3 + t 2 t × θ 1 3 p b n M = 1 3 c + t 1 + 4 θ 1

4.2.2. The First Period

Purchasing decisions: in the first period, the marginal consumer at θ 1 (as shown in Figure 3) is indifferent between two purchasing orders. In the first order, consumers buy from Firm A in the first period, and switch to Firm B in the second period, and the utility they have is v p a 1 t × θ + v p b n t × ( 1 θ ) . In the second order, the consumers buy from Firm B in the first period, and switch to Firm A in the second period, and the utility they have is v p b 1 t × ( 1 θ ) + v p a n t × θ . Letting these two utilities equal and combine equations in (4), we have θ 1 = 3 p a 1 + 3 p b 1 + 4 t 8 t . Therefore, those consumers who are located at 0 θ θ 1 will buy from Firm A, while those consumers who are located at θ 1 θ 1 will buy from Firm B.
Duopoly pricing: firms’ total profit functions are:
π a , t M = p a 1 × θ 1 + z 1 × p a o + z 2 θ 1 × p a n
π b , t M = p b 1 × 1 θ 1 + 1 z 2 × p b o + θ 1 z 1 × p b n
According to the first-order optimization conditions, we can obtain:
p a 1 M = p b 1 M = 2 c + 2 t 3
Proposition 2.
Under the M regulation, the equilibrium results of the two-period game between two firms are shown in Table 2.

4.3. Main Model: Under Weak Regulation

4.3.1. The Second Period

Under the W regulation, consumers know that firms can collect and share their information, so those consumers whose information is shared have privacy concerns. Furthmore, we assume that the firms will share the farthest consumers, and the degree of information sharing among firms is k . Therefore, Firm A will share with the consumers who are located in x 1 θ θ 1 x 1 = θ 1 θ 1 × k , and Firm B will share with the consumers who are located in θ 1 θ x 2 x 2 = 1 θ 1 × k + θ 1 . Since the greater the degree of information sharing between firms, the stronger the consumer’s privacy concerns are, we assume that those consumers who, in the second period switch to the new firm which has acquired their information, will face an average privacy cost denoted by k c , while those consumers who stay with the original firm have an average privacy cost c .
Purchasing decisions: for those customers θ who purchase from Firm A in the first period, i.e., 0 θ x 1 (as shown in Figure 4), the utility they gain from staying with Firm A is v p a o t × θ c . In addition, since their information is not shared, the utility they have from switching to Firm B is v p b n t ( 1 θ ) . Let z 1 indicate the location of the marginal consumer who is indifferent between staying with Firm A and switching to Firm B. Then, letting the two utilities be equal, we have z 1 = p b n p a o c + t 2 t . For another part of the old customers θ of Firm A, i.e., x 1 θ θ 1 (as shown in Figure 4), since their information is shared, the utility they have from staying with Firm A is v p a o t × θ c , while the utility they have from switching to another firm is v p b p t ( 1 θ ) k c . Let z 2 indicate the location of the marginal consumer who is indifferent between staying with Firm A and switching to Firm B. Then, letting the two utilities be equal, we have z 2 = p b p p a o + t + k 1 c 2 t . Similarly, we can obtain two marginal consumers from Firm B’ s old consumers, i.e., z 3 = p b o p a p + t k 1 c 2 t and z 4 = p b o p a n + c + t 2 t .
To summarize, the consumers in the second period who will buy from Firm A are divided into four parts, i.e., 0 θ z 1 , x 1 θ z 2 , θ 1 θ z 3 , and x 2 θ z 4 . Similarly, the consumers in the second period who will purchase from Firm B are those in z 1 θ x 1 , z 2 θ θ 1 , z 3 θ x 2 , and z 4 θ 1 .
Duopoly pricing: under the W regulation, firms can share information, but there is a cost. Different firms have different ways and formats to store consumer data, so firms need to pay a cost to coordinate the collected data when exchanging information. We assume that the information coordination cost is a fixed cost, and it is denoted by β .
Therefore, firms’ profit functions in the second period are:
π a , 2 W = z 1 × p a o + z 2 x 1 × p a o + z 3 θ 1 × p a p + z 4 x 2 × p a n β
π b , 2 W = x 1 z 1 × p b n + θ 1 z 2 × p b p + x 2 z 3 × p b o + 1 z 4 × p b o β
According to the first-order optimization conditions:
{ π a , 2 W p a n = c 2 p a n + p b o + t 2 k t + 2 ( 1 + k ) t × θ 1 2 t = 0 π a , 2 W p a p = c c k 2 p a p + p b o + t 2 t × θ 1 2 t = 0 π a , 2 W p a o = c ( 2 + k ) 4 p a o + p b n + p b p + 2 t + 2 ( 1 + k ) t × θ 1 2 t = 0 π b , 2 W p b n = c + p a o 2 p b n t 2 ( 1 + k ) t × θ 1 2 t = 0 π b , 2 W p b p = c c k + p a o 2 p b p t 2 t + θ 1   = 0 π b , 2 W p b o = c ( 2 + k ) + p a n + p a p 4 p b o + 2 t ( k + θ 1 k × θ 1 ) 2 t = 0
By solving the equations in (10), we can obtain that the prices set by the two firms for the three types of customers in the second period are:
p a n W = 1 12 c 4 + k + 2 t 4 + 5 k 1 + θ 1 6 θ 1 p a p W = 1 12 c 4 5 k + 2 t 4 + k 6 + k × θ 1 p a o W = 1 6 c 2 + k + 2 t + k × t × θ 1 p b n W = 1 12 c 4 + k 2 t 2 + 6 + 5 k × θ 1 p b p W = 1 12 c 4 5 k + 2 t 2 + 6 + k × θ 1 p b o W = 1 6 c 2 + k + 2 t 1 + k k × θ 1

4.3.2. The First Period

Purchasing decisions: in the first period, the marginal consumer at θ 1 (as shown in Figure 4) is indifferent between two purchasing orders. In the first order, consumers buy from Firm A in the first period, and switch to Firm B in the second period, and the utility they have is v p a 1 t × θ + v p b n t × ( 1 θ ) . In the second order, consumers buy from Firm B in the first period, and switch to Firm A in the second period, and the utility they have is v p b 1 t × ( 1 θ ) + v p a n t × θ . Let these two utilities be equal and combine equation in (11), we have θ 1 = 1 2 + 3 p a 1 p b 1 6 + 5 k t . Therefore, those consumers who are located at 0 θ θ 1 will buy from Firm A while those consumers who are located at θ 1 θ 1 will buy from Firm B.
Duopoly pricing: firms’ total profit functions are:
π a , t W = p a 1 × θ 1 + z 1 × p a o + z 2 x 1 × p a o + z 3 θ 1 × p a p + z 4 x 2 × p a n β
π b , t W = p b 1 × 1 θ 1 + x 1 z 1 × p b n + θ 1 z 2 × p b p + x 2 z 3 × p b o + 1 z 4 × p b o β
According to the first-order optimization conditions, we can obtain:
p a 1 W = p b 1 W = 1 12 c 8 k 4 + 3 k + 16 + 3 6 + k k t
Information sharing: by solving the first-order optimization conditions of the firms’ total profit functions:
π a , t W k = 0 π b , t W k = 0
We can obtain:
k = 16 c 2 + 24 c t + 50 t 2 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2
Proposition 3.
Under the W regulation, the equilibrium results of the two-period game between two firms are shown in Table 3.
Proposition 4.
As shown in Figure 5, take Firm A as an example, when 0 < c < t < 1 , p a n S > p a n M , p a n M > p a p W and p a p W > p a n W . When 0 < t < c < 1 , p a n S > p a p W , p a n M > p a p W and p a n W > p a p W .
Proposition 4 indicates that when the consumer’s product preference is greater than the privacy preference, the optimal price set by the company in the second period for new customers is the highest under the S regulation, while the lowest is under the W regulation. In terms of W regulation, the poaching price set by the company in the second period is greater than the price set for new customers. This is because, when consumers have greater product preferences, consumers pay more attention to whether the product is ideal. Under the W regulation, firms can obtain some information about new customers through competitors, and can recommend products that meet their preferences. Since their willingness to pay is relatively high, the poaching price set by the company is greater than the price set for ordinary new customers. Additionally, under the W regulation, as consumers’ information will be shared, they have privacy concerns. Therefore, in order to attract these consumers, firms set the lowest price for new customers under the W regulation. Besides, it is also clear from Proposition 4 that when consumers’ privacy preferences are greater than product preferences, companies under the W regulation set the lowest poaching price for new customers in the second period. This is because when consumers’ privacy preferences are greater, companies can share consumer information under the W regulation. For those consumers whose information is shared, their privacy concerns are the strongest. Therefore, firms formulate the lowest price to attract them to purchase.
Proposition 5.
As shown in Figure 6, take Firm A as an example, when t > ( 1 + 13 ) c 6 , p a o S > p a o M and p a o S > p a o W . When 0 < t < ( 1 + 13 ) c 6 , p a o S > p a o M and p a o W > p a o M .
Proposition 5 shows that when consumers’ preference for products is greater, firms set the highest price for old customers under the S regulation, while when consumers’ preference for privacy is greater, firms set the lowest price for old customers under the M regulation. Although consumers pay more attention to whether the products meet their own preferences at this time, firms under the M regulation can collect consumer information, while firms under the W regulation can even collect and share consumer information.Therefore, in order to alleviate customers’ privacy concerns, firms have to set lower prices. However, when consumers pay more attention to privacy, firms still consider consumers’ privacy concerns, therefore, in most cases, firms set lower prices for old customers under M and W regulation. In addition, by comparing S regulation with M regulation, it can be found that no matter what the consumer’s product-privacy preference is, under the S regulation, the price set by the firm for the old customers in the second period is always higher. This result shows that BBPD weakens the competition to a certain extent, which is reflected in the price set for old customers in the second period of the firms.
Proposition 6.
As shown in Figure 7, when 0 < c < 1 and 0 < t < 1 , p a 1 M > p a 1 S and p a 1 S > p a 1 W .
Proposition 6 provides that, no matter what consumers’ product preference and privacy preference are, the price set by firms in the first stage is always the lowest under the W regulation, which intensifies the price competition in the first stage. This is because firms can collect and share consumers’ information under this regulation, and foresee that consumers have strong privacy concerns, so firms choose to set low prices in the first period to attract consumers to buy.

5. Welfare Comparison under Different Privacy Regulation

5.1. Industry Profit

Proposition 7.
Take Firm A as an example, when 0 < t < ( 2 + 6 ) c and β > 4 c 4 + 272 c 3 t + 489 c 2 t 2 + 500 c t 3 + 800 t 4 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 , π a , t M > π a , t S and π a , t S > π a , t W . When ( 2 + 6 ) c < t < 1 and β > 4 c 4 + 272 c 3 t + 489 c 2 t 2 + 500 c t 3 + 800 t 4 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 , π a , t S > π a , t M and π a , t M > π a , t W . Figure 8 depicts the numerical analysis results of the model.
Proposition 7 shows that when the cost of firm information coordination is high, the total profit of firms is always the least under the W regulation. This is because, when the cost of information coordination among firms is high, firms need to invest too much to conduct information sharing, therefore, in this situation the total profit of firms under the W regulation is always the lowest. Proposition 7 also demonstrates that when consumers have greater product preference, the total profit is the highest under the S regulation. When consumers have greater privacy preference, the total profit is the highest under the M regulation. This is because, when consumers give more attention to products, it can be obvious from Proposition 4 and Proposition 5 that, in the case of S regulation, firms set the highest price for new and old customers in the second period, so they get the highest profits. When the consumer’s privacy preference is large, Proposition 6 shows that the firm sets the highest price for the first customer under the M regulation, so the firm obtains the highest profit in this situation.

5.2. Consumer Surplus

Proposition 8.
When 0 < c < 1 and 0 < t < 1 , C S W > C S S and C S W > C S M . Figure 9 depicts the numerical analysis results of the model.
Proposition 8 reflects that there is an anti-intuitive conclusion, i.e., the consumer surplus is the highest under the W regulation. Proposition 4 and Proposition 6 show that compared with M regulation and S regulation, firms always set lower prices for customers under the W regulation. Therefore, under the W regulation, price competition is more intense to a certain extent, which makes product prices go down, thus making consumers better off.

5.3. Social Welfare

Proposition 9.
Under weak regulation, S W W β < 0 .
Proposition 9 shows that, with the increase of information coordination cost among firms, social welfare declines under the W regulation. This is because when the cost of sharing information among firms is higher, the total profits of firms will decrease, so the social welfare under the W regulation will decrease.
Corollary 1.
When β < γ 1 , S W W > S W S and S W S > S W M . When γ 1 < β < γ 2 , S W S > S W W and S W W > S W M . When β > γ 2 , S W S > S W M and S W M > S W W . ( γ 1 = ( 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t + 6071 c 4 t 2 6856 c 3 t 3 + 8197 c 2 t 4 6090 c t 5 + 2350 t 6 ) ( 8 t ( 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 ) 2 ) , γ 2 = 3926 c 6 22056 c 5 t + 55677 c 4 t 2 59504 c 3 t 3 + 73803 c 2 t 4 52710 c t 5 + 23600 t 6 72 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 ). Figure 10 depicts the numerical analysis results of the model.
Corollary 1 reflects that the social welfare under the S regulation is always higher than that under the M regulation. This result is consistent with the conclusion of Shy and Stenbacka [9], which also shows that BBPD can make social welfare higher to a certain extent. Corollary 1 also shows that, when the cost of information coordination between firms is small, social welfare is the highest under the W regulation; when the cost of information coordination is at a medium level, social welfare under the S regulation is the highest; when the cost of information coordination is high, the social welfare is the highest under the S regulation, while the lowest under the W regulation. This is because when the information coordination cost of firms is low, the cost of information sharing among firms is low, and the consumer surplus is the highest under the W regulation, so social welfare under the W regulation is the best in this case.
Corollary 2.
When β < γ 2 , with the increase of the cost of information coordination, the smaller the area occupied by the W regulation in the optimal social welfare strategy solutions, and the consumers’ product-privacy preference determines which area has the optimal social welfare. Figure 11 depicts the numerical analysis results of the model. From Figure 11, it can be seen that, with the rising cost of information coordination among firms, the social welfare optimization with weak regulation may arise only in areas where consumers have greater privacy preferences. This is an anti-intuitive conclusion, which shows that when consumers give more attention to privacy, to a certain extent, weak regulation can optimize social welfare.

6. Implications for Policy and Management

The maininsight from our analyses is that mandatory privacy protection does not necessarily lead to a higher social surplus, and the weak privacy regulation may put consumers in a better position, which depends on consumers’ product-privacy preferences and the cost of information coordination between firms. We discuss below some implications for policy and management.
At present, there are two main modes to protect personal information in the world, that are the “decentralized legislation plus industry self-discipline” mode represented by the United States, and the state-led consent legislation mode represented by the European Union. With the development of information technology, firms can not only easily obtain consumer information from the inside, but also collect information from the external environment, such as exchanging consumer information with competitors. Under the background that consumers pay more and more attention to personal information, the above conclusions are of great significance for the legislature to formulate appropriate privacy regulation measures. The conclusions of this paper reflect that the optimal social welfare depends on the consumer’s product-privacy preference and information coordination cost, which means that legislators can consider the mode of “decentralized legislation plus industry self-discipline”. The legislators can distinguish the consumer’s product-privacy preference in different industries with reference to some relevant research, so as to formulate appropriate privacy regulation measures for different industries. Legislators can exercise weak privacy regulation in industries where consumers pay more attention to privacy, which can improve social welfare to a certain extent. For example, the research results of Kummer and Schulte [31] show that users of health and education related apps seem to be more privacy-sensitive than users of tools, entertainment, or games. Legislators may wish to implement weak privacy regulation in these industries, so as to improve social welfare to a certain extent. In addition, since the cost of information coordination among firms will affect which kind of regulation has the best social welfare, considering that the consumer surplus can reach the maximum under weak regulation, it is necessary to reduce the cost of information coordination among firms if the social welfare under weak regulation is to be optimized. This means that the government can encourage firms to use unified data recording technology, thus reducing barriers to information exchange among firms.
Our analysis also provides significant implications and applications for behavior-based pricing. We show that compared with pricing under the strong regulation, firms set lower prices for customers in each period under the weak regulation. In other words, in order to attract consumers and maximize profits, firms should set lower prices for customers under the weak regulation.

7. Conclusions

This paper constructs a two-period Hotelling competition game model, explores the industry profit, consumer surplus, and social welfare under three levels of privacy regulation concerning information sharing among firms, and uses MATLAB numerical simulation to simulate and analyze our main results. Through comparative analysis, the following conclusions are drawn: (1) under the W regulation, the total profits of firms are the lowest, while in most cases, the profits of firms under the M regulation are the highest. (2) Under the W regulation, the consumer surplus is the highest, while under the M regulation, the consumer surplus is the lowest. (3) When the cost of information coordination between firms is low, the social welfare is the highest under the W regulation; when the cost of information coordination is at a medium level, the social welfare under the S regulation is the highest; when the cost of information coordination is high, the social welfare is the highest under the S regulation and the lowest under the W regulation. (4) With the rising cost of information coordination among firms, it is only in areas where consumers have greater privacy preferences that social welfare may be optimal under the W regulation. Therefore, mandatory privacy protection does not necessarily lead to a higher social surplus. Similarly, the weak privacy regulation, which seems to harm consumers, may put consumers in a better position to a certain extent, which depends on the cost of information coordination between firms and consumers’ product-privacy preferences.
In this study, simplified assumptions, such as complete market coverage, single-homing, etc., are all aspects that can be considered in future research work. In addition, we can further consider the firm’s product quality strategy and discuss the firm’s pricing and product quality decisions under different privacy regulations.

Author Contributions

X.L., supervision, conceptualization, funding acquisition, methodology, model-setting, writing—review & editing; X.H., conceptualization, methodology, model-setting, writing—original draft; S.L., investigation, resources, writing—original draft; Y.L., software, validation, investigation; H.L., formal analysis, methodology, validation; S.Y., methodology, validation. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71991461), the Guangdong Province Soft Science Research Project (No. 2019A101002074), the Discipline Co-construction Project for Philosophy and Social Science in Guangdong Province (No. GD20XGL03), and the Project for Philosophy and Social Sciences Research of Shenzhen City (No. SZ2021B014).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank the anonymous reviewers whose insightful comments and helpful suggestions significantly contributed to improving this paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Proof of Proposition 1.
Purchasing decisions: under the S regulation, firms are unable to collect consumers’ information. Therefore, in each period, those consumers in 0 < θ < θ 1 (as shown in Figure 2) will buy from Firm A, while those consumers in θ 1 < θ < 1 (as shown in Figure 2) will buy from Firm B. □
Duopoly pricing: firms’ profit functions in each period are:
π a , 1 S = θ 1 × P a 1
π b , 1 S = ( 1 θ 1 ) × P b 1
According to the first-order optimization conditions:
π a , 1 S P a 1 = 2 p a 1 + p b 1 + t 2 t = 0 π b , 1 S P b 1 = p a 1 2 p b 1 + t 2 t = 0
By solving the equations in (A3), we can obtain the prices set by the two firms for the consumers in each period as follows:
p a 1 = t p b 1 = t
We can obtain that the equilibrium profits in each period are:
π a , 1 S = π b , 1 S = t 2
We can also obtain the equilibrium of firms’ total profits, consumer surplus and social welfare:
π a , t S = π b , t S = t
C S S = 5 t 2 + v
S W S = t 2 + 2 v
Proof of Proposition 4.
When 0 < c < t < 1 ,
p a n S p a n M = t c + t 3 = c + 2 t 3 > 0
p a n M p a p W = c + t 3 ( 2 c 3 + 25 c 2 t + 21 c t 2 20 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 ) = 40 c 3 + 69 c 2 t + 93 c t 2 + 10 t 3 102 c 2 120 c t + 210 t 2 > 0
p a p W p a n W = 40 c 3 + 69 c 2 t + 93 c t 2 + 10 t 3 102 c 2 120 c t + 210 t 2 14 c 3 17 c 2 t + 5 c t 2 30 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 = c t 8 c 2 + 12 c t + 25 t 2 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 > 0
When 0 < t < c < 1 ,
p a n S p a p W = t ( 2 c 3 + 25 c 2 t + 21 c t 2 20 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 ) = 2 c 3 + 59 c 2 t 19 c t 2 + 50 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 > 0
p a n M p a p W = c + t 3 ( 2 c 3 + 25 c 2 t + 21 c t 2 20 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 ) = 40 c 3 + 69 c 2 t + 93 c t 2 + 10 t 3 102 c 2 120 c t + 210 t 2 > 0
p a n W p a p W = 14 c 3 17 c 2 t + 5 c t 2 30 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 ( 2 c 3 + 25 c 2 t + 21 c t 2 20 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2 ) = c t 8 c 2 + 12 c t + 25 t 2 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 > 0
Proof of Proposition 5.
When t > ( 1 + 13 ) c 6 ,
p a o S p a o M = t c + 2 t 3 = c + t 3 > 0
p a o S p a o W = t 3 c 3 + 19 c 2 t 6 c t 2 + 20 t 3 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 = 3 c 5 t c 2 + c t 3 t 2 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 > 0
When 0 < t < ( 1 + 13 ) c 6 ,
p a o S p a o M = t c + 2 t 3 = c + t 3 > 0
p a o W p a o M = 3 c 3 + 19 c 2 t 6 c t 2 + 20 t 3 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 c + 2 t 3 = 8 c 3 + 3 c 2 t + 57 c t 2 10 t 3 51 c 2 60 c t + 105 t 2 > 0
Proof of Proposition 6.
p a 1 M p a 1 S = 2 c + 2 t 3 t = 2 c + t 3 > 0
p a 1 S p a 1 W = t 114 c 5 + 1900 c 4 t + 1922 c 3 t 2 + 633 c 2 t 3 + 4255 c t 4 + 1100 t 5 3 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 = 114 c 5 + 2767 c 4 t 118 c 3 t 2 + 5403 c 2 t 3 + 55 c t 4 + 4775 t 5 3 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0
Proof of Proposition 7.
When 0 < t < ( 2 + 6 ) c and β > 4 c 4 + 272 c 3 t + 489 c 2 t 2 + 500 c t 3 + 800 t 4 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 ,
π a , t M π a , t S = 1 18 4 c + 2 c 2 t + 17 t t = 1 18 4 c + 2 c 2 t t = 2 c 2 + 4 c t t 2 18 t > 0
π a , t S π a , t W = t ( 24 c 4 72 c 3 t + 23 c 2 t 2 300 c t 3 + 130 t 4 204 c 2 t 240 c t 2 + 420 t 3 β ) = 24 c 4 + 72 c 3 t + 181 c 2 t 2 + 60 c t 3 + 290 t 4 12 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 + β > 0
When ( 2 + 6 ) c < t < 1 and β > 4 c 4 + 272 c 3 t + 489 c 2 t 2 + 500 c t 3 + 800 t 4 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 ,
π a , t S π a , t M = t 1 18 4 c + 2 c 2 t + 17 t = 2 c 2 4 c t + t 2 18 t > 0
π a , t M π a , t W = 1 18 4 c + 2 c 2 t + 17 t ( 24 c 4 72 c 3 t + 23 c 2 t 2 300 c t 3 + 130 t 4 204 c 2 t 240 c t 2 + 420 t 3 β ) = 4 c 4 + 272 c 3 t + 489 c 2 t 2 + 500 c t 3 + 800 t 4 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 + β > 0
Proof of Proposition 8.
When 0 < c < 1 and 0 < t < 1 ,
C S W C S S = 300 c 6 3876 c 5 t + 11137 c 4 t 2 328 c 3 t 3 2979 c 2 t 4 + 16330 c t 5 9400 t 6 + 24 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 v 12 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 2 5 t 4 + v = 300 c 6 3876 c 5 t + 19807 c 4 t 2 20728 c 3 t 3 + 44721 c 2 t 4 25670 c t 5 + 27350 t 6 12 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0
C S W C S M = 300 c 6 3876 c 5 t + 11137 c 4 t 2 328 c 3 t 3 2979 c 2 t 4 + 16330 c t 5 9400 t 6 + 24 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 v 12 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 ( 5 c 9 5 c 2 18 t 22 t 9 + 2 v ) = 3790 c 6 12648 c 5 t + 61143 c 4 t 2 43024 c 3 t 3 + 115233 c 2 t 4 49710 c t 5 + 79600 t 6 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0
Proof of Proposition 9.
The social welfare under W regulation is:
S W W = 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t 70 c t 4 ( 47 t + 160 ( v β ) ) 8 c 3 t 2 ( 687 t + 680 ( v β ) ) 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + c 4 t ( 5493 t + 2312 ( v β ) ) + c 2 t 3 ( 5017 t + 12720 ( v β ) ) 100 t 5 ( t + 98 ( v + β ) ) 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2
According to the first-order condition:
S W W β = 2 < 0
Proof of Corollary 1.
Let γ 1 = ( 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t + 6071 c 4 t 2 6856 c 3 t 3 + 8197 c 2 t 4 6090 c t 5 + 2350 t 6 ) ( 8 t ( 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 ) 2 ) and γ 2 = 3926 c 6 22056 c 5 t + 55677 c 4 t 2 59504 c 3 t 3 + 73803 c 2 t 4 52710 c t 5 + 23600 t 6 72 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2
When β < γ 1 ,
S W W S W S = 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t 70 c t 4 47 t + 160 v β 8 c 3 t 2 687 t + 680 v β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + c 4 t 5493 t + 2312 v β + c 2 t 3 5017 t + 12720 v β 100 t 5 t + 98 v + β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 ( t 2 + 2 v ) = 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t + 6071 c 4 t 2 6856 c 3 t 3 + 8197 c 2 t 4 6090 c t 5 + 2350 t 6 8 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0
S W S S W M = t 2 + 2 v ( c 2 + 2 c t + 10 t 2 18 t + 2 v ) = c + t 2 18 t > 0
When γ 1 < β < γ 2 ,
S W S S W W = t 2 + 2 v ( 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t 70 c t 4 47 t + 160 v β 8 c 3 t 2 687 t + 680 v β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + c 4 t 5493 t + 2312 v β + c 2 t 3 5017 t + 12720 v β 100 t 5 t + 98 v + β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 ) = 372 c 6 + 2428 c 5 t 6071 c 4 t 2 + 6856 c 3 t 3 8197 c 2 t 4 + 6090 c t 5 2350 t 6 + 8 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0
S W W S W M = 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t 70 c t 4 47 t + 160 v β 8 c 3 t 2 687 t + 680 v β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + c 4 t 5493 t + 2312 v β + c 2 t 3 5017 t + 12720 v β 100 t 5 t + 98 v + β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 ( c 2 + 2 c t + 10 t 2 18 t + 2 v ) = 3926 c 6 22056 c 5 t + 55677 c 4 t 2 59504 c 3 t 3 + 73803 c 2 t 4 52710 c t 5 + 23600 t 6 72 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 β 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0
When β > γ 2 ,
S W S S W M = t 2 + 2 v ( c 2 + 2 c t + 10 t 2 18 t + 2 v ) = c + t 2 18 t > 0
S W M S W W = c 2 + 2 c t + 10 t 2 18 t + 2 v ( 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t 70 c t 4 47 t + 160 v β 8 c 3 t 2 687 t + 680 v β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + c 4 t 5493 t + 2312 v β + c 2 t 3 5017 t + 12720 v β 100 t 5 t + 98 v + β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 ) = 3926 c 6 + 22056 c 5 t 55677 c 4 t 2 + 59504 c 3 t 3 73803 c 2 t 4 + 52710 c t 5 23600 t 6 + 72 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 β 36 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 > 0

References

  1. Chen, Z.; Choe, C.; Matsushima, N. Competitive Personalized Pricing. Manag. Sci. 2020, 66, 4003–4023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Elmachtoub, A.N.; Gupta, V.; Hamilton, M.L. The Value of Personalized Pricing. Manag. Sci. 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Li, K.J. Behavior-Based Pricing in Marketing Channels. Manag. Sci. 2017, 37, 177–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Li, K.J. Behavior-Based Quality Discrimination. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2020, 23, 267–545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Nijs, R.D. Behavior-based price discrimination and customer information sharing. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2017, 50, 319–334. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Jiang, L.; Hao, Z. Incentive-Driven Information Dissemination in Two-Tier Supply Chains. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2016, 18, 309–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Liu, Z.; Zhang, D.J.; Zhang, F. Information Sharing on Retail Platforms. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2021, 23, 547–730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Buckman, J.R.; Bockstedt, J.C.; Hashim, M.J. Relative Privacy Valuations under Varying Disclosure Characteristics. Inf. Syst. Res. 2019, 30, 351–710. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Shy, O.; Stenbacka, R. Customer Privacy and Competition. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2016, 25, 539–562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Conti, C.; Reverberi, P. Price discrimination and product quality under opt-in privacy regulation. DIAG Tech. Rep. 2019, 65, 1342–1362. [Google Scholar]
  11. Ichihashi, S. Online Privacy and Information Disclosure by Consumers. Am. Econ. Rev. 2020, 110, 569–595. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Thisse, J.-F.; Vives, X. On The Strategic Choice of Spatial Price Policy. Am. Econ. Rev. 1988, 78, 122–137. [Google Scholar]
  13. Fudenberg, D.; Tirole, J. Customer Poaching and Brand Switching. RAND J. Econ. 2000, 31, 634–657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Carroni, E. Competitive customer poaching with asymmetric firms. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2016, 48, 173–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ozer, Z.; Subramanian, U.; Wang, Y. Information Sharing, Advice Provision, or Delegation: What Leads to Higher Trust and Trustworthiness? Manag. Sci. 2017, 64, 474–493. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Jiang, B.; Tian, L.; Xu, Y.; Zhang, F. To Share or Not to Share: Demand Forecast Sharing in a Distribution Channel. Mark. Sci. 2016, 35, 800–809. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Li, G.; Zheng, H.; Tian, L. Information Sharing in an Online Marketplace with Co-opetitive Sellers. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2021. forthcoming. [Google Scholar]
  18. Chen, Y.; Narasimhan, C.; Zhang, Z.J. Individual Marketing with Imperfect Targetability. Mark. Sci. 2001, 20, 23–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Liu, Q.; Serfes, K. Customer information sharing among rival firms. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2005, 50, 1571–1600. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Kim, B.C.; Choi, J.P. Customer Information Sharing: Strategic Incentives and New Implications. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2010, 19, 403–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Boon, E.; Pitt, L.; Salehi-Sangari, E. Managing information sharing in online communities and marketplaces. Bus. Horiz. 2015, 58, 347–353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Chen, L.; Zhu, S. Seller information sharing in online marketplaces. J. Mark. Manag. 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Chen, L.; Zhu, F.; Mantrala, M. The path of support-to-sales: Mediating role of seller collaborative information exchange in social commerce. Eur. J. Mark. 2020, 55, 363–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Chen, L.; Zhu, F.; Mantrala, M.; Wang, N. Seller creative selling in social commerce. Int. J. Advert. 2021, 40, 272–291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Qu, Z.; Wang, Y.; Wang, S.; Zhang, Y. Implications of online social activities for e-tailers’ business performance. Eur. J. Mark. 2013, 47, 1190–1212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Kuhn, K.M.; Galloway, T.L. With a Little Help from My Competitors: Peer Networking among Artisan Entrepreneurs. Entrep. Theory Pract. 2015, 39, 571–600. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Shy, O.; Stenbacka, R. Investment in customer recognition and information exchange. Inf. Econ. Policy 2013, 25, 92–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Conitzer, V.; Taylor, C.R.; Wagman, L. Hide and Seek: Costly Consumer Privacy in a Market with Repeat Purchases. Mark. Sci. 2012, 31, 277–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Stigler, G.J. An Introduction to Privacy in Economics and Politics. J. Leg. Stud. 1980, 9, 623–644. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Li, X.; Li, K.J.; Wang, X. Transparency of Behavior-Based Pricing. J. Mark. Res. 2020, 57, 78–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Kummer, M.; Schulte, P. When Private Information Settles the Bill: Money and Privacy in Google’s Market for Smartphone Applications. Manag. Sci. 2019, 65, 3470–3494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. The timeline of the main model.
Figure 1. The timeline of the main model.
Jtaer 16 00161 g001
Figure 2. Benchmark Model: Under the Strong Regulation.
Figure 2. Benchmark Model: Under the Strong Regulation.
Jtaer 16 00161 g002
Figure 3. Benchmark Model: Under the Medium Regulation.
Figure 3. Benchmark Model: Under the Medium Regulation.
Jtaer 16 00161 g003
Figure 4. Main Model: Under the Weak Regulation.
Figure 4. Main Model: Under the Weak Regulation.
Jtaer 16 00161 g004
Figure 5. Firms’ second-period prices for the news under three privacy regulations.
Figure 5. Firms’ second-period prices for the news under three privacy regulations.
Jtaer 16 00161 g005
Figure 6. Firms’ second-period prices for the old under three privacy regulations.
Figure 6. Firms’ second-period prices for the old under three privacy regulations.
Jtaer 16 00161 g006
Figure 7. Firms’ first-period prices under three privacy regulations.
Figure 7. Firms’ first-period prices under three privacy regulations.
Jtaer 16 00161 g007
Figure 8. Firms’ total profits under three privacy regulations ( β = 0.5 ) .
Figure 8. Firms’ total profits under three privacy regulations ( β = 0.5 ) .
Jtaer 16 00161 g008
Figure 9. Consumers’ surplus under three privacy regulations ( v = 1 ) .
Figure 9. Consumers’ surplus under three privacy regulations ( v = 1 ) .
Jtaer 16 00161 g009
Figure 10. Social welfare under three privacy regulations ( v = 1 ,   β = 0.2 ) .
Figure 10. Social welfare under three privacy regulations ( v = 1 ,   β = 0.2 ) .
Jtaer 16 00161 g010
Figure 11. Strategic solution space for optimal social welfare.
Figure 11. Strategic solution space for optimal social welfare.
Jtaer 16 00161 g011
Table 1. Summary of notations.
Table 1. Summary of notations.
NotationDescription
v Retention value of consumers
p i 1 Firm i’s first-period price ( i = a , b )
p i n Firm i’s second-period price for the new customers ( i = a , b )
p i o Firm i’s second-period price for the old customers ( i = a , b )
p i p Firm i’s second-period poaching price for the new customers under the weak privacy regulation ( i = a , b )
t Unit negative utility caused by consumers’ failure to consume an ideal product
θ Consumer’s product preference
θ 1 The marginal consumer at θ 1 is indifferent between buying from Firm A and Firm B in the first period
z j The marginal consumer in the second period ( j = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 )
x 1 The furthest consumer that Firm A shares with Firm B
x 2 The furthest consumer that Firm B shares with Firm A
k The degree of information sharing among firms
c Average privacy cost of consumers
β Cost of information coordination among firms
Table 2. Equilibrium results of the two-period game under the M regulation.
Table 2. Equilibrium results of the two-period game under the M regulation.
VariablesEquilibrium Results
Firms’ first-period price p a 1 M = p b 1 M = 2 c + 2 t 3
Firms’ second-period price p a n M = p b n M = c + t 3
p a o M = p b o M = c + 2 t 3
Firms’ second-period profit π a , 2 M = π b , 2 M = 2 c t + 2 c 2 + 5 t 2 18 t
Firms’ total profit π a , t M = π b , t M = 4 c t + 2 c 2 + 17 t 2 18 t
Consumer surplus C S M = 10 c t 5 c 2 44 t 2 18 t + 2 v
Social welfare S W M = c 2 + 2 c t + 10 t 2 18 t + 2 v
Table 3. Equilibrium results of two-period game under the W regulation.
Table 3. Equilibrium results of two-period game under the W regulation.
VariablesEquilibrium Results
Firms’ information sharing degree k = 16 c 2 + 24 c t + 50 t 2 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2
Firms’ first-period price p a 1 W = p b 1 W = 114 c 5 + 1900 c 4 t + 1922 c 3 t 2 + 633 c 2 t 3 + 4255 c t 4 + 1100 t 5 3 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2
Firms’ second-period price p a n W = p b n W = 14 c 3 17 c 2 t + 5 c t 2 30 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2
p a p W = p b p W = 2 c 3 + 25 c 2 t + 21 c t 2 20 t 3 34 c 2 40 c t + 70 t 2
p a o W = p a o W = 3 c 3 + 19 c 2 t 6 c t 2 + 20 t 3 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2
Firms’ second-period profit π a , 2 W = π b , 2 W = 136 c 6 644 c 5 t + 2157 c 4 t 2 1412 c 3 t 3 + 3427 c 2 t 4 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + 1530 c t 5 + 2250 t 6 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 β 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2
Firms’ total profit π a , t W = π b , t W = 24 c 4 72 c 3 t + 23 c 2 t 2 300 c t 3 + 130 t 4 204 c 2 t 240 c t 2 + 420 t 3 β
Consumer surplus C S W = 300 c 6 3876 c 5 t + 11137 c 4 t 2 328 c 3 t 3 2979 c 2 t 4 12 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + 16330 c t 5 9400 t 6 + 24 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 v 12 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2
Social welfare S W W = 372 c 6 2428 c 5 t 70 c t 4 ( 47 t + 160 ( v β ) ) 8 c 3 t 2 ( 687 t + 680 ( v β ) ) 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2 + c 4 t ( 5493 t + 2312 ( v β ) ) + c 2 t 3 ( 5017 t + 12720 ( v β ) ) 100 t 5 ( t + 98 ( v + β ) ) 4 t 17 c 2 20 c t + 35 t 2 2
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Lin, X.; Huang, X.; Liu, S.; Li, Y.; Luo, H.; Yu, S. Social Welfare Analysis under Different Levels of Consumers’ Privacy Regulation. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2021, 16, 2943-2964. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16070161

AMA Style

Lin X, Huang X, Liu S, Li Y, Luo H, Yu S. Social Welfare Analysis under Different Levels of Consumers’ Privacy Regulation. Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research. 2021; 16(7):2943-2964. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16070161

Chicago/Turabian Style

Lin, Xudong, Xiaoli Huang, Shuilin Liu, Yulin Li, Hanyang Luo, and Sumin Yu. 2021. "Social Welfare Analysis under Different Levels of Consumers’ Privacy Regulation" Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research 16, no. 7: 2943-2964. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16070161

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop