Next Article in Journal
Student Engagement and the Role of Technology
Previous Article in Journal
Advances in Biocultural Approaches to Understanding Stress in Humans
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Generalization Increases the Adaptive Value of Mate Choice Copying When Immediate Copying Is Costly

School of Archaeology and Anthropology, ANU College of Arts and Social Sciences, The Australian National University, Canberra, ACT 0200, Australia
Humans 2024, 4(4), 340-350; https://doi.org/10.3390/humans4040022
Submission received: 15 July 2024 / Revised: 13 October 2024 / Accepted: 21 October 2024 / Published: 29 October 2024

Abstract

:
When assessing potential mates is costly, there will be selection for copying others. Mate choice copying, which is the increased chance of mating with another individual after observing them mating with someone else (i.e., individual-based copying), has been documented in several species, including humans. It is touted as an example of the influence of culture on animal and human mating, but alone it is unlikely to lead the cultural evolution of mating. Rather, it requires mate choice copying with generalization (i.e., trait-based copying), which is the effect of immediate observations on future mating. This sort of mate choice copying has been documented in six species, including humans. Here, I extend an existing game theory model of mate choice copying to include generalization (Extension 1), a cost to immediate copying (Extension 2), and both previous extensions (Extension 3). The results show that Extensions 1 and 2 decrease the adaptive value of mate choice copying when compared to the original model. Extension 3 suggests that adding generalization to mate choice copying with a cost to immediate copying is a more likely evolutionary trajectory than adding it to mate choice copying without this cost. These results have implications for illuminating the emergence of the cultural evolution of mating preferences.

1. Introduction

Mate choice copying is a type of non-independent mate choice [1] whereby an individual uses public information, more specifically the observed mating behavior of another individual, in making their own mate choice decisions [2,3]. This phenomenon has been observed in a wide range of taxa, including at least 26 species of invertebrates, fish, birds, and mammals [4]. There is a growing body of literature showing that humans engage in mate choice copying reviewed by [5]. The phenomenon has ramifications for sexual selection as it can lead to incredibly high variance in reproductive success [6], and for illuminating the role of social learning—and, by extension, culture—in shaping mating behavior in humans and other animals [7,8,9].
The potential of cultural evolution to shape population-level diversity in mating preferences turns on the distinction between “copying” and the “cultural inheritance” of mate choice [7]. Copying involves the immediate use of socially transmitted information. Cultural inheritance requires generalization—that the socially transmitted information is used to inform future mate choice decisions in addition to current ones. Bowers et al. [10] make a slightly different distinction between “individual-based” copying, where the chance of mating with a particular individual is increased after having observed another mate with that individual, and “trait-based” copying, where the chance of mating with individuals that have a particular characteristic is increased after having observed others mating with individuals possessing similar traits. These concepts are illustrated in Figure 1A. With copying or individual-based copying, the socially transmitted information is unlikely to be transmitted beyond the model/copier dyad; with cultural inheritance or trait-based copying, the socially transmitted information becomes a preference that is likely to be transmitted to others, leading to the cultural evolution of mate preferences [11]. The generalization of mate choice preferences has been demonstrated in the species illustrated in Figure 1B [8,10,12,13,14,15,16,17,18].
Pruett Jones [19] modeled mate choice copying using evolutionary game theory, namely the logic of evolutionarily stable strategies (ESSs). An ESS is a frequency-dependent strategy that affords the greatest net fitness benefit to the individual actors and, when adopted by members of a population, cannot be invaded by alternative strategies via the forces of natural selection [20]. Discrete strategy ESS models (e.g., Hawk-Dove [21]) assess the proportion of individuals in the population that adopt each strategy. Pure ESSs are the extreme (100%), but intermediate solutions are possible also. In the focal model, the strategies are copier and chooser, the ESS proportions of which depend on the costs and benefits of choosing. Copying is supported when the costs are high, or the benefits low, for choosing.
In this paper, I build extensions of the original model [19] to include two important factors: (1) generalization; and (2) the potential for costs to accrue to the copier and the cost to immediate copying, which comes in the form of agonistic relations with the individual being copied and sperm depletion, among other things [4]. The main aim of the paper is to assess whether these factors exert an influence on the adaptive value of mate choice copying using the same, relatively simple, modeling strategy as the original model. By comparing the results of the original model and its extensions, I hope to illuminate potential evolutionary scenarios for the emergence and maintenance of mate choice copying in species (such as humans) where there is a cost to immediate copying, such as in monogamous ones, and for explaining the emergence of true cultural inheritance in species with mate choice copying. This has ramifications, albeit indirectly, for informing debates in the evolutionary behavioral sciences, such as the relative importance of domain-specific and domain-general mechanisms [22].

2. Models

2.1. Original Model

In Pruett Jones’ [19] original model of mate choice copying, individuals adopt one of two strategies, chooser and copier, and are paired up at random. Everyone in the dyad makes a mating decision as follows: Choosers select a mate independent of what the other individual in the dyad decides to do. They pay a fitness cost, k, for going to the trouble of sizing up potential mates, but realize a fitness benefit, f, for doing so. This is above and beyond the baseline payoff, W, that is earned for mating. Copiers, on the other hand, mimic the mating decision of the individual with whom they are paired, potentially reaping the benefit, but not paying the cost. The payoff matrix is shown in Table 1.
The ESS proportion of the population adopting the chooser strategy, p, is found by setting the fitness payoff to choosers equal to the fitness payoffs for copiers. This is found when
p (W + fk) + (1 − p)(W + fk) = p (W + f) + (1 − p) W
which can be simplified to
W + fk = p (W + f) + (1 − p) W
and is solved when
p = 1 − (k/f)
Under this model, the ESS proportion of copiers is high except when the benefits of assessing mates oneself far outweigh the costs. Figure 2 shows the ESS proportion of the two strategies by the benefits relative to costs, f/k. When the costs equal or exceed the benefits of assessing mates oneself (i.e., f/k ≤ 1), copying is a pure ESS.

2.2. Extension 1: Generalization

To extend the original model, I added generalization. Individuals pair up at random and accrue the immediate fitness costs and benefits in the same manner as the original model. Everyone then mates an additional time in the future and is awarded a fitness payoff for that later event conditioned on the probability, m, that the information gained in the first round is useful in the second. Copiers paired with copiers receive the same payoff for the immediate and future mating—the average fitness of potential mates. Copiers paired with choosers receive an immediate payoff of the mate choice benefit plus the average fitness of potential mates, and a future payoff that is conditioned on whether the information is useful. In essence, 1 − m is a cost of generalizing mate choice copying. There are several potential sources of such a cost, including that the trait on which generalization has occurred is associated with a mate with lower fitness, and that there are insufficient potential mates with the particular trait on which generalization has occurred. Choosers, regardless of who they are paired with, receive the same payoff for immediate and future mating. The payoff matrix is shown in Table 2.
The fitness payoffs for copiers are found when
p [2(W + fk)] + (1 − p) [2(W + fk)]
= p [W + f + m (W + f) + (1 − m) W] + (1 − p) 2W
which can be simplified to
2(W + fk) = p [W + f + m (W + f) + (1 − m) W] + (1 − p) 2W
and is solved when
p = [2(fk)]/[f (m + 1)]
In this model, as with the original model, copying is a pure ESS when the cost of mate choice is equal to or greater than the benefit (i.e., f/k ≤ 1). As illustrated in Figure 3A, when the benefits outweigh the costs of mate choice, the adaptive value of copying depends on the probability the observed mate choice in the current round of mating is helpful in the future round. When the information acquired is 100% likely to help future mating (i.e., m = 1), the ESS proportion of choosers and copiers predicted by the extended model is identical to the proportion predicted by the original. When the information’s usefulness is less than certain (i.e., m < 1), the ESS proportion of copiers is greater without generalization and, at intermediate values of f/k, choosing is a pure ESS. This is a striking contrast to the original model within which choosing is never a pure ESS. The results suggest that adding generalization decreases the adaptive value of mate choice copying.

2.3. Extension 2: Costs to Immediate Copying

To extend the original model, I added costs to immediate copying, c. While this could encapsulate any of several potential costs, including sperm depletion and an agonistic response from the individual being copied [4], for the purposes of the model it was considered an intrinsic aspect of copiers (e.g., that they spend more time because they must wait to assess the actions of the individual they copy). When conceptualized in this fashion, the cost is incurred to all copiers regardless of with whom they are paired. The payoffs to choosers are identical to those in the original model. The payoffs to copiers are almost identical to those in the original model, except that the cost of immediate copying is subtracted from them. The payoff matrix is shown in Table 3.
The ESS proportion of the population adopting the chooser strategy, p, is found by setting the fitness payoff to choosers equal to the fitness payoffs for copiers. This is found when
p (W + fk) + (1 − p) (W + fk) = p (W + fc) + (1 − p) Wc
which can be simplified to
W + fk = p (W + f − c) + (1 − p) Wc
and is solved when
p = (c + fk)/(fc)
When there are no costs for immediate copying (i.e., c = 0), the extended model is identical to the original model. As can be seen in Figure 3B, there are substantial decreases in the ESS proportion of copiers when the cost of immediate copying is added. When the cost equals or exceeds 50% of the costs of mate choice (i.e., c/k ≥ 0.5) choosing becomes a pure ESS. The results suggest that adding a cost to immediate copying decreases the adaptive value of mate choice copying.

2.4. Extension 3: Incorporating Both Extensions

To extend the original model, I added both generalization and the costs of immediate copying. As such, the payoffs were split into current and future components, and cost was added for copiers in the current component. The payoff matrix is shown in Table 4.
The ESS proportion of the population adopting the chooser strategy, p, is found by setting the fitness payoff to choosers equal to the fitness payoffs for copiers. This is found when
p [2(W + fk)] + (1 − p) [2(W + fk)]
= p [W + fc + m (W + f) + (1 − m) W] + (1 − p) [(Wc) + W]
which can be simplified to
2(W + fk) = p [W + fc + m(W + f) + (1 − m)W] + (1 − p) [(Wc) + W]
and is solved when
p = (c + 2f − 2k)/[f (m + 1)]
Although adding either extension by itself leads to decreased or held-constant ESS proportions of copiers, adding the remaining extension to create the current model has contrasting effects on the ESS proportions of copiers depending on which was the starting point. As shown in Figure 4A, adding generalization to a system that already has a cost to immediate copying in some cases can lead to substantial increases in the ESS proportion of copiers. That is, adding generalization when there is already a cost for immediate copying increases the adaptive value of copying. As shown in Figure 4B, the converse does not appear to be the case. Under no conditions does adding a cost to immediate copying to a system that already includes generalization increase the ESS proportion of copiers. The amount by which the ESS proportion of copiers decreases depends on the value of c/k. This means adding costs to immediate copying when there is already generalization decreases the adaptive value of mate choice copying.

3. Discussion

Pruett Jones’s [19] model of mate choice copying showed that, when there is a cost to choosing a mate by oneself, copying is selected for as a pure or mixed ESS, as shown in Figure 2. Here, I have extended the original model in three ways by adding generalization (Extension 1), a cost to immediate copying (Extension 2), and both generalization and a cost to immediate copying (Extension 3). The results, outlined in Figure 5, show that when either generalization or a cost to immediate copying is added by itself to the original model, except in a very limited range of circumstances, there is a decrease in the ESS proportion of copiers. Put another way, either factor, by itself, leads to a decrease in the adaptive value of mate choice copying. When there is already a cost to immediate copying, however, generalization increases the adaptive value of copying. The converse fails to hold. When there is already generalization, adding a cost to immediate copying decreases the adaptive value of mate choice copying. These results suggest that a system marked by the “cultural inheritance” of mate choice (i.e., mate choice copying with generalization) would be more likely to have evolved from a system that had a cost to immediate copying. That is, a trajectory that went from individual-based copying with a cost to immediate copying to trait-based copying may be more likely than a trajectory that went from individual-based copying to trait-based copying.
The distribution of mating systems among species that engage in mate choice copying supports the evolutionary trajectory suggested by the models presented in this paper. Most species that engage in mate choice copying engage in polygyny or promiscuity to some extent, and many of them are lekking species [4,23,24]. There is only one obligatory monogamous species with biparental care that engages in mate choice copying, the zebra finch (Taenipygia guttata)—a species that happens to engage in trait-based mate copying [14,16]. Many of the other species that generalize mate choice copying have biparental care to some extent. As predicted by my model, generalization might be one way to avoid the costs of mating with an already-mated male, which Vakirtzis [4,25] outlines as follows: (i) increased competition with other females, (ii) diminishing paternal care, (iii) low male mating skew which renders the public information gathered related to mate choice less reliable, (iv) copying unattractive females who are paired with low-quality males, and (v) an ambiguous relationship between male qualities and his number of mates. DuBois [26] explores another possibility—that mate choice copying in monogamous species might be adaptive for extrapair copulations. The model results suggest an evolutionary trajectory for the emergence of key features of human mating strategies using a theory-based approach, rather than a purely speculative or induction-based approach.
The generalization of mate choice copying has potential ramifications for shaping male displays. Several authors have shown that the intensity and nature of sexual selection on male traits can be influenced by how females use socially acquired information about mate choice [27,28,29]. Wade and Pruett Jones [6] showed that mate choice copying could lead to increased variance in mating success accompanied by strong directional sexual selection, even traits that reduce male viability [30] and runaway sexual selection in the absence of genetic correlations [31,32]. Others have argued that, while these effects might follow from trait-based copying, they are more likely to lead to stabilizing selection and the fixation of male displays [10,28,33].
One simplification I employed was modeling the future contribution of the socially transmitted information to the copier’s fitness as the consequences of a single future mating event. It is unlikely that many, if any, species reproduce this way, so it might be useful to at least consider how the results might change if generalization affected multiple future matings. Because generalization appears to counterbalance the negative effects of a cost to immediate copying, generalizing over multiple future matings would likely increase the fitness consequences of copying when the cost exists.
The approach I have adopted here models equilibrium states and may downplay constraints on the ability of frequency-dependent selection to lead to an ESS [34,35,36]. Evolutionarily stable strategies are those that, when monomorphic in a population, resist the invasion of rare mutants [20]. McNamara and Weissing [35] clarify that although “the reasoning behind an ESS suggests a population that reaches an ESS will not evolve away from this strategy, it does not guarantee that evolution will actually lead to an ESS.” Constraints on their evolution include the specifics of the underlying genetics, the existence of additional equilibria, and the dynamic nature of the adaptive landscape under frequency dependence [35]. Several authors [34,36] have argued for the use of a dynamic approach using “replicator dynamics” [37] over the sort of static one used here. I offer the following in defense of my choice to adopt a static approach. First, the original model [19] used it. Second, each of the extensions of the original model has a single ESS and a simple strategy set. The dynamic approach would have presented unnecessary complexity. Third, my intention was to derive as-general-as-possible qualitative conclusions from the models. The static approach, it can be argued, is better suited for such a goal.
Of course, any modeling exercise will peel away some of the complexity of the real-world system under study [38]. In the case of human mating (or the mating of most species where mate choice copying occurs), where strategies are complex rather than binary, the results must always be interpreted with caution. For instance, DuVal et al. [39] have modeled the evolutionary dynamics of preferences for specific traits. At the same time, whether this should be considered a shortcoming or feature of the model depends on one’s aims (as realism and the generalizability of a model may trade off against each other [40]).
The generalization of mate choice preferences, or trait-based copying, is necessary for the cultural evolution of inter- and intra-population diversity in mating preferences. Much is already known about this diversity in human mating [41,42]; less is known about other species that generalize their preferences (see Figure 1B). One avenue for further research is the investigation of this diversity, including elucidating the cultural evolutionary dynamics for the origin and maintenance of mate choice preferences. Part of this enterprise will be to systematically unravel the sometimes intertwined influences of innate and learned factors on mate choice [43,44], which is easier to do in experimentation-amenable species, much more difficult for ethical reasons in humans. In addition, future research should address the question of whether mate choice copying is driven by domain-specific or domain-general mechanisms [22,45], and whether this differs for species with individual- versus trait-based copying. Ideally, experimental approaches [46] should address the shortcomings of existing research, not the least of which is the issue of the ecological validity of stimuli (e.g., pictures of potential mates with or without a juxtaposed picture of a female) and responses (e.g., whether ‘preferences’ equate to actual behavior).

Funding

While writing this article, GK was supported by the Outside Studies Program, ANU College of Arts and Social Sciences, The Australian National University.

Data Availability Statement

No new data were created or analyzed in this study. Data sharing is not applicable to this article.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Westneat, D.F.; Walters, A.; McCarthy, T.M.; Hatch, M.I.; Hein, W.K. Alternative mechanisms of nonindependent mate choice. Anim. Behav. 2000, 59, 467–476. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Hoglund, J.; Alatalo, R.V.; Lundberg, A. Copying the mate choice of others? observations on the female black grouse. Behaviour 1990, 114, 221–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Dugatkin, L.A. Sexual selection and imitation: Females copy the mate choice of others. Am. Nat. 1992, 139, 1384–1389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Vakirtzis, A. Mate choice copying and nonindependent mate choice: A critical review. Ann. Zool. Fenn. 2011, 48, 91–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Gouda-Vossos, A.; Nakagawa, S.; Dixson, B.J.W.; Brooks, R.C. Mate Choice Copying in Humans: A Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis. Adapt. Hum. Behav. Physiol. 2018, 4, 364–386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Wade, M.J.; Pruett-Jones, S.G. Female copying increases the variance in male mating success. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA 1990, 87, 5749–5753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Brooks, R. The importance of mate copying and cultural inheritance of mating preferences. Trends Ecol. Evol. 1998, 13, 45–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Little, A.C.; Jones, B.C.; DeBruine, L.M.; Caldwell, C.A. Social learning and human mate preferences: A potential mechanism for generating and maintaining between-population diversity in attraction. Phil Trans. R. Soc. B 2011, 366, 366–375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Nöbel, S.; Jacquet, A.; Isabel, G.; Pocheville, A.; Seabright, P.; Danchin, E. Conformity in mate choice, the overlooked social component of animal and human culture. Biol. Rev. 2023, 98, 132–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bowers, R.I.; Place, S.S.; Todd, P.M.; Penke, L.; Asendorpf, J.B. Generalization in mate-choice copying in humans. Behav. Ecol. 2012, 23, 112–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Danchin, E.; Giraldeau, L.-A.; Valone, T.J.; Wagner, R.H. Public information: From nosy neighbors to cultural evolution. Science 2004, 305, 487–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  12. White, D.J.; Galef, B.G., Jr. ‘Culture’ in quail: Social influences on mate choices of female Coturnix japonica. Anim. Behav. 2000, 59, 975–979. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Godin, J.-G.J.; Herdman, E.J.E.; Dugatkin, L.A. Social influences on female mate choice in the guppy, Poecilia reticulata: Generalized and repeatable trait-copying behaviour. Anim. Behav. 2005, 69, 999–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Brown, G.R.; Fawcett, T.W. Sexual selection: Copycat mating in birds. Curr. Biol. 2005, 15, R626–R628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  15. Witte, K.; Noltemeier, B. The role of information in mate-choice copying in female sailfin mollies (Poecilia latipinna). Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol. 2002, 52, 194–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Swaddle, J.P.; Cathey, M.G.; Correll, M.; Hodkinson, B.P. Socially transmitted mate preferences in a monogamous bird: A non-genetic mechanism of sexual selection. Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2005, 272, 1053–1058. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Mery, F.; Varela, S.A.M.; Danchin, É.; Blanchet, S.; Parejo, D.; Coolen, I.; Wagner, R.H. Public versus personal information for mate copying in an invertebrate. Curr. Biol. 2009, 19, 730–734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Danchin, E.; Nöbel, S.; Pocheville, A.; Dagaeff, A.-C.; Demay, L.; Alphand, M.; Ranty-Roby, S.; van Renssen, L.; Monier, M.; Gazagne, E.; et al. Cultural flies: Conformist social learning in fruitflies predicts long-lasting mate-choice traditions. Science 2018, 362, 1025–1030. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Pruett-Jones, S. Independent versus nonindependent mate choice: Do females copy each other? Am. Nat. 1992, 140, 1000–1009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Maynard Smith, J. Evolution and the Theory of Games; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1982. [Google Scholar]
  21. Maynard Smith, J.; Price, G.R. The logic of animal conflict. Nature 1973, 246, 15–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Barrett, H.C. The Shape of Thought: How Mental Adaptations Evolve; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  23. Galef, B.G.; White, D.J. Evidence of social effects on mate choice in vertebrates. Behav. Process. 2000, 51, 167–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  24. White, D.J. Influences of social learning on mate-choice decisions. Learn. Behav. 2004, 32, 105–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  25. Vakirtzis, A.; Roberts, S.C. Nonindependent mate choice in monogamy. Behav. Ecol. 2010, 21, 898–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Dubois, F. Mate choice copying in a monogamous species: Should females use public information to choose extrapair males? Anim. Behav. 2007, 74, 1785–1793. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Agrawal, A.F. The evolutionary consequences of mate choice copying on male traits. Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol. 2001, 51, 33–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Verzijden, M.N.; ten Cate, C.; Servedio, M.R.; Kozak, G.M.; Boughman, J.W.; Svensson, E.I. The impact of learning on sexual selection and speciation. Trends Ecol. Evol. 2012, 27, 511–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Gibson, R.M.; Höglund, J. Copying and sexual selection. Trends Ecol. Evol. 1992, 7, 229–232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Kirkpatrick, M.; Dugatkin, L.A. Sexual selection and the evolutionary effects of copying mate choice. Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol. 1994, 34, 443–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Bailey, N.W.; Moore, A.J. Runaway sexual selection without genetic correlations: Social environments and flexible mate choice initiate and enhance the Fisher process. Evolution 2012, 66, 2674–2684. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Richerson, P.J.; Boyd, R. The role of evolved predispositions in cultural evolution: Or, Human Sociobiology meets Pascal’s Wager. Ethol. Sociobiol. 1989, 10, 195–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Laland, K.N. Sexual selection with a culturally transmitted mating preference. Theor. Popul. Biol. 1994, 45, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Nowak, M. An evolutionarily stable strategy may be inaccessible. J. Theor. Biol. 1990, 142, 237–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  35. McNamara, J.M.; Weissing, F.J. Evolutionary game theory. In Social Behaviour: Genes, Ecology and Evolution; Székely, T., Moore, A.J., Komdeur, J., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2010; pp. 88–106. [Google Scholar]
  36. Huttegger, S.M.; Zollman, K.J.S. Methodology in biological game theory. Br. J. Philos. Sci. 2013, 64, 637–658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Taylor, P.D.; Jonker, L.B. Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics. Math. Biosci. 1978, 40, 145–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Kokko, H. Modeling for Field Biologists and Other Interesting People; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  39. DuVal, E.H.; Fitzpatrick, C.L.; Hobson, E.A.; Servedio, M.R. Inferred attractiveness: A generalized mechanism for sexual selection that can maintain variation in traits and preferences over time. PLOS Biol. 2023, 21, e3002269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Levins, R. The strategy of model building in population biology. Am. Sci. 1966, 54, 421–431. [Google Scholar]
  41. Darwin, C. The Descent of Man and Sex in Relation to Sex; John Murray: London, UK, 1871. [Google Scholar]
  42. Ford, C.S.; Beach, F.A. Patterns of Sexual Behavior; Harper: New York, NY, USA, 1951. [Google Scholar]
  43. Dugatkin, L.A. The interface between culturally based preferences and genetic mate preferences: Female mate choice in Pocilia reticulata. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA 1996, 93, 2770–2773. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Santos, M.; Varela, S.A.M. Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Mate Choice. In Illuminating Human Evolution: 150 Years After Darwin; Bertranpetit, J., Peretó, J., Eds.; Springer Nature: Singapore, 2022; pp. 187–199. [Google Scholar]
  45. Street, S.E.; Morgan, T.J.H.; Thornton, A.; Brown, G.R.; Laland, K.N.; Cross, C.P. Human mate-choice copying is domain-general social learning. Sci. Rep. 2018, 8, 1715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Dougherty, L.R. Designing mate choice experiments. Biol. Rev. 2020, 95, 759–781. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Mate choice copying is normally used to refer to (A) individual-based copying, where an individual preferentially mates with an individual who they observed mating with somebody else. Mate choice copying can lead to (B) “generalisation” or trait-based copying, where an individual preferentially mates with individuals that have the features of an individual that they observed mating with somebody else. The former can lead to the cultural evolution of mating preferences. The generalization of mate choice copying has been observed in several species, including (C) fruit flies (Drosophila melanogaster), (D) sailfin mollies (Poecilia latipinna), (E) guppies (Poecilia reticulata), (F) zebra finches (Taenipygia guttata), (G) Japanese quail (Coturnix japonica), and (H) humans (Homo sapiens). Credits: fruit fly, CC Attribution 2.0 Generic, Paco Romero-Ferrero; sailfin mollie, CC Attribution-Share Alike 3.0 Unported, Bjoertvedt; guppy, CC Attribution-Share Alike 4.0, Marrabbio2; zebra finches, CC Attribution 4.0 International, Christoph_moning; Japanese quail, public domain; humans, CC Attribution 2.0 Generic, Scarleth White.
Figure 1. Mate choice copying is normally used to refer to (A) individual-based copying, where an individual preferentially mates with an individual who they observed mating with somebody else. Mate choice copying can lead to (B) “generalisation” or trait-based copying, where an individual preferentially mates with individuals that have the features of an individual that they observed mating with somebody else. The former can lead to the cultural evolution of mating preferences. The generalization of mate choice copying has been observed in several species, including (C) fruit flies (Drosophila melanogaster), (D) sailfin mollies (Poecilia latipinna), (E) guppies (Poecilia reticulata), (F) zebra finches (Taenipygia guttata), (G) Japanese quail (Coturnix japonica), and (H) humans (Homo sapiens). Credits: fruit fly, CC Attribution 2.0 Generic, Paco Romero-Ferrero; sailfin mollie, CC Attribution-Share Alike 3.0 Unported, Bjoertvedt; guppy, CC Attribution-Share Alike 4.0, Marrabbio2; zebra finches, CC Attribution 4.0 International, Christoph_moning; Japanese quail, public domain; humans, CC Attribution 2.0 Generic, Scarleth White.
Humans 04 00022 g001
Figure 2. ESS proportions of choosers and copiers in the original model.
Figure 2. ESS proportions of choosers and copiers in the original model.
Humans 04 00022 g002
Figure 3. Model results for each of the two extensions: (A) In the original model plus generalization (Extension 1), the ESS proportion of copiers decreases with decreasing values of m, as indicated by the arrows. The extended model’s results are identical to the original model when m = 1, but otherwise leads to a lower ESS proportion of copiers (i.e., the adaptive value of copying decreases). At some levels of m, as illustrated, the ESS proportion of copiers is 0. That is, the chooser can be a pure ESS. (B) In the original model plus cost to immediate copying (Extension 2), the ESS proportion of copiers decreases with increasing c, as indicated by the arrows. The extended model’s results reduce to the original model’s when there is no cost to immediate copying. When the cost of immediate copying is greater than or equal to half the cost of mate choice, the chooser strategy is a pure ESS.
Figure 3. Model results for each of the two extensions: (A) In the original model plus generalization (Extension 1), the ESS proportion of copiers decreases with decreasing values of m, as indicated by the arrows. The extended model’s results are identical to the original model when m = 1, but otherwise leads to a lower ESS proportion of copiers (i.e., the adaptive value of copying decreases). At some levels of m, as illustrated, the ESS proportion of copiers is 0. That is, the chooser can be a pure ESS. (B) In the original model plus cost to immediate copying (Extension 2), the ESS proportion of copiers decreases with increasing c, as indicated by the arrows. The extended model’s results reduce to the original model’s when there is no cost to immediate copying. When the cost of immediate copying is greater than or equal to half the cost of mate choice, the chooser strategy is a pure ESS.
Humans 04 00022 g003
Figure 4. Comparing model results: (A) comparing the model with cost to immediate copying (Extension 2) and the model with both extensions (Extension 3), and (B) comparing the model with generalization (Extension 1) and the model with both extensions (Extension 3). In both, the lines are ESS proportions of copiers in the model with both extensions and the edges of the shaded areas are the ESS proportions of copiers in the models with a single extension. As shown in (A), under several conditions, adding generalization to a mate choice copying system where there is a cost to immediate copying leads to substantive increases in the ESS proportion of copiers (i.e., there is an increase in adaptive value). As shown in (B), under no conditions does adding a cost to immediate copying in a system with generalization increase the ESS proportion of copiers. That is, there is a decrease in the adaptive value of copying, however small.
Figure 4. Comparing model results: (A) comparing the model with cost to immediate copying (Extension 2) and the model with both extensions (Extension 3), and (B) comparing the model with generalization (Extension 1) and the model with both extensions (Extension 3). In both, the lines are ESS proportions of copiers in the model with both extensions and the edges of the shaded areas are the ESS proportions of copiers in the models with a single extension. As shown in (A), under several conditions, adding generalization to a mate choice copying system where there is a cost to immediate copying leads to substantive increases in the ESS proportion of copiers (i.e., there is an increase in adaptive value). As shown in (B), under no conditions does adding a cost to immediate copying in a system with generalization increase the ESS proportion of copiers. That is, there is a decrease in the adaptive value of copying, however small.
Humans 04 00022 g004
Figure 5. Summary of results, which suggests that the generalization of mate choice copying (also known as trait-based copying) would have been more likely to arise out of a system of mate choice copying with a cost to immediate copying. Light-gray shading indicates extensions to the original model; dark-gray shading indicates scenarios where the adaptive value of copying increases.
Figure 5. Summary of results, which suggests that the generalization of mate choice copying (also known as trait-based copying) would have been more likely to arise out of a system of mate choice copying with a cost to immediate copying. Light-gray shading indicates extensions to the original model; dark-gray shading indicates scenarios where the adaptive value of copying increases.
Humans 04 00022 g005
Table 1. Payoff matrix for the original model [1].
Table 1. Payoff matrix for the original model [1].
When Paired with:
ChooserCopier
Payoff to:ChooserW + fkW + fk
CopierW + fW
Table 2. Payoff matrix for the original model plus generalization (Extension 1).
Table 2. Payoff matrix for the original model plus generalization (Extension 1).
When Paired with:
ChooserCopier
ImmediateFutureImmediateFuture
Payoff to:ChooserW + fkW + fkW + fkW + fk
CopierW + fm (W + f) + (1 − m) WWW
Table 3. Payoff matrix for the original model plus costs to immediate copying (Extension 2).
Table 3. Payoff matrix for the original model plus costs to immediate copying (Extension 2).
When Paired with:
ChooserCopier
Payoff to:ChooserW + fkW + fk
CopierW + fcWc
Table 4. Payoff matrix for the original model plus both other extensions (Extension 3).
Table 4. Payoff matrix for the original model plus both other extensions (Extension 3).
When Paired with:
ChooserCopier
ImmediateFutureImmediateFuture
Payoff to:ChooserW + fkW + fkW + fkW + fk
CopierW + fcm (W + f) + (1 − m) WWcW
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kushnick, G. Generalization Increases the Adaptive Value of Mate Choice Copying When Immediate Copying Is Costly. Humans 2024, 4, 340-350. https://doi.org/10.3390/humans4040022

AMA Style

Kushnick G. Generalization Increases the Adaptive Value of Mate Choice Copying When Immediate Copying Is Costly. Humans. 2024; 4(4):340-350. https://doi.org/10.3390/humans4040022

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kushnick, Geoff. 2024. "Generalization Increases the Adaptive Value of Mate Choice Copying When Immediate Copying Is Costly" Humans 4, no. 4: 340-350. https://doi.org/10.3390/humans4040022

APA Style

Kushnick, G. (2024). Generalization Increases the Adaptive Value of Mate Choice Copying When Immediate Copying Is Costly. Humans, 4(4), 340-350. https://doi.org/10.3390/humans4040022

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop