Next Article in Journal
Intelligence on Threats—Municipal Management of Maritime Warnings in 15th-Century Catalonia
Previous Article in Journal
Signalling Safe-Conduct(s): The Fiscalisation of Market Access for Castilian and Catalan Traders in Flanders During the First Half of the Fifteenth Century
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Popular Sovereignty, Shays’s Rebellion, and Populism in Early New England

Stanford Law School, Stanford University, Crown Quadrangle, Stanford, CA 94305, USA
Histories 2025, 5(2), 26; https://doi.org/10.3390/histories5020026
Submission received: 27 January 2025 / Revised: 24 March 2025 / Accepted: 19 May 2025 / Published: 27 May 2025
(This article belongs to the Section Political, Institutional, and Economy History)

Abstract

Massachusetts in the 1780s was deeply polarized. In the preparty era, the most developed communities were able to monopolize the levers of policymaking and governance in order to secure their interests. The least commercial–cosmopolitan communities, lacking organization and resources, were unable to advance their interests. The least commercial–cosmopolitan communities’ inability to influence politics and secure relief stemmed from the absence of party competition. The absence of oppositional political organizations to counteract the natural advantages of elites in preparty politics obstructed the representation of the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities. Such obstruction caused the accumulation of populist frustration, culminating in Shays’s Rebellion.

1. Introduction

“I’ve labored hard all my days and fared hard. I have been greatly abused, have been obliged to do more than my part in the war; been loaded with class rates, town rates, province rates, Continental rates, and all rates...been pulled and hauled by sheriffs, constables and collectors, and had my cattle sold for less than they were worth. I have been obliged to pay and nobody will pay me. I have lost a great deal by this man and that man and t’other man, and the great men are going to get all we have, and I think it is time for us to rise and put a stop to it, and have no more courts, nor sheriffs, nor collectors, nor lawyers, and I know that we are the biggest party, let them say what they will...We’ve come to relieve the distresses of the people. There will be no court until they have redress of their grievances.”—Jedediah Peck (“Plough Jogger”) c. 1785
Here, I argue that Shays’s Rebellion was the result of the absence of party competition. The absence of political parties also meant the absence of the political institutions that accompany political parties: the ability to coordinate political activity, the ability to compile a unified list of candidates, the ability to disseminate information, and the ability to mobilize a unified voting bloc. Despite the absence of political parties, the most commercial–cosmopolitan communities are able to use the natural advantages of elites to organize in a quasi-party fashion.
To examine these dynamics, I employ a mixed-method approach, combining qualitative historical analysis with quantitative data on town-level socio-economic indicators. These variables—such as control of executive and judicial offices, newspaper ownership, and religious or social organization leadership—offer a framework to understand how commercial–cosmopolitan communities consolidated power while others were excluded. By analyzing these factors statistically, I illuminate the structural disadvantages that ultimately precipitated violent insurrection.
The analysis begins by identifying the four key advantages of commercial–cosmopolitan towns: political office control, legislative representation, information dissemination, and social organization. These advantages allowed elites to act in a quasi-party fashion, further entrenching inequality. In contrast, the least commercial–cosmopolitan towns lacked the resources and institutions necessary to mount an organized political response.
The findings suggest that these disparities, rather than simple economic distress, created a political vacuum that fostered populist frustration. This paper seeks to answer a central question: What socio-economic factors led to common political interests, and why were these interests unable to find institutional representation? By situating Shays’s Rebellion in this context, I aim to provide a deeper understanding of the political organization—or lack thereof—in early New England.1

2. Two Coalitions of Interests

There were no political parties in the first full decade of the Commonwealth. Nonetheless, interest groups existed, and they used their political power to attain economic and political goals and defend their judicial, political, and economic institutions. The organization of such political efforts was the driving force behind the arrangement of preparty politics in Massachusetts. The ability of particular interest groups to organize effectively and influence politics was grounded in their access to resources. A careful analysis of the social and economic characteristics of 1780s Massachusetts is required in order to understand the political behavior of the era.
To grapple with the competing interests, a typology—replicated and adapted from Hall (1972)—is laid out: the commercial activity of Massachusetts’ 343 towns is measured using an index of commercialization, with Boston at one end and rural towns in the Berkshires and Maine at the other end (Condon 2015; Hall 1972).2 Four variables are used to construct the gradient: stock in trade, silver, money lent at interest, and average vessel tonnage. Towns are ranked along these four variables. The rankings in each of the four categories are used to calculate a commercial index number for each town, generating a gradient of commercial activity. Appendix B contains a breakdown of these variables.3
Each town’s social institutions are measured using a nine-point scale. Each town is evaluated for the presence or absence of the following: newspapers, court sessions, barristers present in 1786 or 1791, two or more barristers present in either 1786 or 1791, one or more barrister present in 1786 or 1791, the presence of a clergyman in the town for two of three years (1780, 1786, or 1791), representatives in the lower house of the General Court for at least nine of the twelve years from 1780 to 1792, and representatives in the lower house for at least six of the same twelve years. Based on the total number of points, towns are placed into one of nine groups. Appendix C contains a breakdown of these nine groups.
The commercial index and social scale are combined into a single gradient that reflects each town’s commercial–cosmopolitan character. Each town is assigned one to ten points based on its commercial decile and from one to eight depending on the number of social variables present. These points are summed and then divided into three groups. Towns with more than twelve points fall into group A; towns with nine through twelve points fall into group B; and towns with fewer than nine points fall into group C. Appendix D contains a breakdown of the commercial–cosmopolitan gradient.
The 54 group A towns were the sites of the most significant commercial activity and were home to nearly all social and cultural institutions, as well as the institutions of state government (Table 1). Group B contains 88 towns with moderate commercial activity and has some connections with important social and cultural institutions. Group C contains 201 towns that were the least commercial–cosmopolitan and had little connection to any significant social or cultural institutions. In placing the towns on a commercial–cosmopolitan gradient (Table 2), one is better able to see the division among the towns. Furthermore, this allows for the political activity of each group to be associated with its social and economic characteristics.
Across the three groups of towns, interest groups sought to influence politics. The most commercial–cosmopolitan category is found in the 54 group A towns. Individuals in the group A towns worked as commercial businessmen, bankers, investors, lawyers, clergymen, shipowners, coastal and global traders, manufacturers, and commercial fishermen. Group A residents were most concerned with advancing their own economic interests and sought to uphold the 1780 constitution and its accompanying judicial, administrative, and political institutions.4 Artisan craftsmen, merchant sailors, and small manufacturers comprised a moderately commercial–cosmopolitan category that were also found in group A towns. Commercial farmers fall into a third category with the most significant presence in the 88 group B towns. The political interests of this third category tend toward those of the group A towns; commercial farmers in the group B towns voted and thought along the same lines as the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests because they benefited from being in sync with the interests of group A, who held the reins of power. On the other extreme of the gradient are the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests, largely composed of subsistence farmers in the 201 group C towns.
Ultimately, the four general categories of interests and the three towns boil down to two coalitions of interests, particularly in terms of polarization. On the one hand, there are the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests, motivated by the pursuit of commercial expansion, financial success, and upholding the 1780 constitution. The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests organize diligently in order to preserve their advantages. The political interests of the second and third categories very often align with the interests of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. Through placeholders that may have formally represented or lived in group B or group C towns but acted in line with the interests of the most commercial–cosmopolitan, group A held significant political clout.
On the other hand, the least commercial–cosmopolitan towns tended to be located in rural Massachusetts, western Massachusetts, and the inland areas of Maine. Residents of the least commercial–cosmopolitan towns focused on subsistence farming with little eye on profit-driven enterprise. These farmers participated in a bartering economy and tended to be uneducated. Those living in such communities who were not farmers were the merchants and artisans who subsisted in the rural, agrarian economy, providing services and goods to the inhabitants of the group C communities. Group C towns possessed a dearth of social and professional institutions, resources, and the means for political organization.
As I will show in the following pages, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests were able to use their advantages in terms of social cohesion, resources, information sharing, and representation to ensure the levers of policymaking and governance were in their favor. At the same time, I will show how the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests, lacking such advantages, were unable to mount an effective political response.

2.1. Politics by Other Means

Each group of towns contained roughly one-third of the total population and roughly one-third of the polls (Table 3).5 In principle, the political power of each group should be roughly equal. However, despite the roughly equal distribution of population and polls across the towns, the group A towns were disproportionately well represented in policymaking and governance. The disproportionate presence of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests is the result of four advantages possessed by the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests.

2.2. The Power Brokers

The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests monopolize the major executive, legislative, and judicial offices in Massachusetts during the 1780s. Such a monopoly on power gives the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests an advantage in setting the policy agenda and using the institutions of the state to pursue their interests at the expense of the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities.
At the apex of the executive branch are the governor and lieutenant governor. The Massachusetts constitution of 1780 provided for the annual election of the governor and lieutenant governor (Condon 2015; Hough 1872; Pole 1957). The governor holds veto power, and both offices were elected by direct popular vote, with the lieutenant governor sitting on the Governor’s Council. Furthermore, more than half of the nine seats on the Governor’s Council are held by residents of group A towns from 1780 to 1791. During these same eleven years, the governorship and lieutenant governorship passed between John Hancock, James Bowdoin, Thomas Cushing, Benjamin Lincoln, and Samuel Adams during the same years. All of these men had longstanding social and professional ties, all graduated from Harvard College, and all had homes near each other in Boston. Additionally, all of these men are important political leaders in the years prior to Independence.6 With the governorship, the lieutenant governorship, and the Governor’s Council, controlled by residents from group A towns, the executive branch of government was a bulwark against the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests.
Qualifications for holding the governorship and lieutenant governorship gave further advantage to the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. To qualify for the governorship, a resident needed to possess a minimum property value of £1000 (Hough 1872).7 The high qualifications for holding such offices posed an insurmountable barrier for any polls other than the most affluent in group A towns (Table 4).
The justices of the state supreme court were cut from the same cloth. The supreme court was composed of four men who rode circuit throughout Massachusetts and Maine. During the eleven years from 1780 to 1791, the eight men who served as justices were all from group A towns. Moreover, all but one justice graduated from Harvard College.8 All eight justices had significant ties to commercial activity. Justices Cushing, Sargeant, Paine, and Sewall all appeared in the record of interest payments in 1786 and 1787, indicating their significant involvement in speculative or investment activity.9 Additionally, during this era, it was customary for supreme court justices to deliver addresses before grand juries throughout the commonwealth. These addresses often veered far from legal matters and were opportunities for the justices to soliloquize, advocating their own political views to local audiences throughout the commonwealth (Cushing 1965).
In addition to the justices of the supreme court, the judiciary’s rank and file, as well as administrative officers, were often occupied by placeholders. In this context, placeholders were leading local politicians, lawyers, officers, judges of the Court of Common Pleas and justices of the peace who lived throughout the commonwealth (Table 5). Many of these placeholder positions were appointed by the governor without the democratic safeguards provided by civil service rules and popular elections.
Such appointed positions came with cash income, something that was rare throughout the hinterlands of Massachusetts. Desperate to hold onto their posts and their income, many of these placeholders supported the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. Others, particularly the more important positions like those on the Governor’s Council and those selected for national office, came largely from group A towns and had close social and commercial ties with commercial entrepreneurs and learned professionals in group A towns. Ultimately, inhabitants of group A towns held more than half of the terms as judges in the Court of Common Pleas (Table 6). Judges used their position to engage in lending and other commercial activity, using their influence as judges to secure favorable terms.
Justices of the peace also exercised significant influence in local matters. Justices of the peace sat at the county level, in general sessions of the peace. The justices of the peace handed down decisions in criminal and civil cases, as well as acted as policymakers. Justices of the peace approved local infrastructure plans, issued business licenses, and set local tax rates. Justices also served as mediators for disputes among residents. Justices of the peace received fees for providing judicial and government services. Such fees were often determined by the volume of cases and matters taken up, thus giving incentive to add layers of bureaucracy and try any number of minor criminal or civil cases.
In the eleven years from 1780 to 1791, more than half of the justices of the peace were from group A towns. However, those justices who lived in the group B and C towns were placeholders and often served in the General Court. Those justices of the peace and judges of common pleas, who also served in the Senate and the house of representatives, supported the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in exchange for the support of the judiciary and the judicial fee system that enriched the justices and judges.
Congregational ministers also served as placeholders for the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. Ministers were visible and trusted members of society and thus played an important public role in early Massachusetts. The Congregational Church was the de facto establishment church and had strong ties to the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. The upper ranks of the church hierarchy and the Congregational seminaries were anchored in the group A towns. Many Congregational ministers were educated, preached, and worked in the group A towns. Congregational ministers who were dispatched to the peripheries of the commonwealth answered to the senior clergymen located in the group A towns. As a consequence, the interests of the Congregational Church and the interests of the most commercial–cosmopolitan overlapped. The shared interests of the Congregational Church and the most commercial-commercial communities began nearly a century earlier.
Beginning in 1692, the General Court determined the geographic jurisdiction of particular Congregational Churches and set the boundaries for parishes. The General Court also imposed statewide parish taxes, levied on the residents of each parish (Cushing 1969). The church taxes, levied by the state, were the primary source of revenue for the Congregational Church. Moreover, the General Court passed legislation that endowed each parish with the same powers of a municipal corporation, but limited to the scope of administering a system of worship (Cushing 1969). As a result, Congregational ministers wielded significant political influence in local politics (Table 7).
Prior to the constitution of 1780, religious organizations established outside of the formal system of municipal, Congregational parishes were not endowed with the same authority nor benefited from levied taxes. Non-Congregational denominations were widely considered subversive organizations during the colonial era and early Republic. All residents falling within a particular parish were required to pay taxes to support their respective Congregational parish, regardless of whether they regularly attended the Congregational Church or attended services for an unrecognized denomination. However, the 1780 constitution disestablished the Congregational Church. The formal disestablishment of the Congregational Church led to an increase in petitions to the General Court for the recognition of previously unrecognized denominations.
Successful petitions to the General Court for recognition afforded a newly recognized denomination the same corporate powers and tax support as a Congregational parish. After 1780, when parishioners within an existing Congregational parish splintered off, those parishioners’ levied taxes were reallocated to their newly recognized denomination. The proliferation of newly recognized denominations threatened to reduce tax revenue and local political influence for the Congregational Church. In order to stymie the proliferation of new denominations, the Congregational ministers were compelled to support the programs and policies of the most commercial–cosmopolitan class, who also had a monopoly over the executive, judiciary, and much of the General Court. In a quid pro quo, the Congregational ministers pushed the agenda of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in their preaching and ministerial work in exchange for support of the Congregational Church in the General Court, the executive, and the judiciary. While some new denominations did emerge after the ratification of the 1780 constitution, the General Court was reluctant to recognize new religious denominations, thus preserving the Congregational Church’s revenue and political power.
However, on the other hand, the presence of new, non-Congregational denominations in the group A towns also contributed to the polarization between group A and C towns. As a result of the presence of new and non-Congregational denominations, there was greater religious diversity, primarily in group A communities. In the 1780s, 100% of group A towns had at least one minister, and 57% of those same towns had only Congregational ministers, as seen in Table 8. Forty-three percent of group A towns had ministers from denominations other than Congregational. However, on the other extreme of the gradient, only 69% of group C towns had at least one minister, 52% of those same towns had only a Congregational minister, and a mere 10% of towns had ministers of a denomination other than Congregational.
The presence and diversity of ministers in group A towns exposed the residents to various organized religions and made residents more tolerant of religious ideas other than their own, thus making group A residents more cosmopolitan. However, group C towns, a third of which had no minister and only a tenth of which had any religious diversity, highlighted the absence of different ideas and the social isolation of the group C towns. The lack of religious diversity in the group C towns also points to the near monopoly over religious institutions held by the Congregational Church, thus giving Congregational ministers—who were placeholders for the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests—a bully pulpit from which to affect public opinion in the group C towns.

2.3. Masters of the Senate

The commercial–cosmopolitan elite had a stranglehold on the state Senate. The commercial–cosmopolitan elite’s control over the upper chamber was linked to two factors: first was qualifications for holding office. State senators were required to have a freehold worth of £300 on property with a value of at least £600. Senators had to be residents of Massachusetts for at least five years, as well as residents of the constituency they represented (Pole 1957). Senators often had homes in Boston or Salem in addition to second homes in the hinterlands. Many of the residents of group A towns had owned their homes for more than five years at the time of the ratification of the 1780 constitution. It was easy for residents of group A towns to meet the 5-year residency requirement. Polls in the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities often worked as itinerant farm laborers in their early years before settling in a specific location, putting them at a disadvantage in the early years of the Commonwealth. If a given farmer established their own farm in 1780, he was unable to run for office until at least 1786, given the Senate election cycle. The political institutions surrounding the Senate gave the elite a clear advantage in winning Senate seats while disadvantaging polls in the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities (see Table 9 and Table 10).
Second, a disproportionate number of senators were also judges of the Court of Common Pleas. The outright numerical advantage of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in the Senate was compounded through placeholders. The combination of senators elected from group A towns and those who also served as judges represented roughly 70% of all Senate seats. Antifederalist senators held less than one-tenth of the seats in the Senate, while roughly half of the senators supported the new constitution of 1788.10 Group A towns and judges often had aligned interests; throughout the 1780s, the Senate was a bulwark against measures sent up from the lower house that were contrary to the interests of group A towns and the judiciary, including proposals for tax reform, suspension of debt cases before the courts, once again implementing legal tender notes, and the softening of punishment for Shaysite rebels in 1786.
Seats in the House of Representatives—the lower chamber of the General Court—were more equally apportioned. The commercial–cosmopolitan interests were unable to monopolize the lower chamber with a numerical advantage. To the contrary, the western counties had forty-four percent of the eligible voters and were represented by fifty-two percent of the total representatives in the lower chamber. Representatives from Maine held ten percent of the seats in the House while having twenty percent of the population. As a result, the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests were overrepresented in the lower chamber. Nevertheless, the commercial–cosmopolitan interests were able to make inroads in the lower chamber through placeholders.
Like in the upper chamber, there is a significant number of representatives who were also justices (Table 11). Representatives with dual status as justices accounted for one-third of the seats in the lower chamber. Justices of the peace and group A representatives combined represented more than half of the seats in the lower chamber. While in the upper chamber, the presence of senators with dual status as judges contributed to the commercial–cosmopolitan interests’ utter monopoly on the upper chamber.
However, in the lower chamber, the justices of the peace were not as reliable. The justices of the peace were sometimes swayed by the interests of their constituency. While the commercial–cosmopolitan interests were unable to exert sufficient pressure on the lower chamber to advance their agenda, they were able to halt unfavorable legislation when it reached the Senate and through their control of the governorship and the Governor’s Council.
Group A towns’ effective control over the legislature impacted national representation. The General Court, charged with electing representatives to the Confederation Congress, chose individuals along the same lines. Roughly four-fifths of the Confederation congressmen lived in group A towns. From 1788 to 1791, seventy-seven percent of representatives sent to the National Congress lived in group A towns.
In controlling the upper chamber outright and having significant influence in the lower chamber, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests set the agenda, controlled policy, and halted countervailing interests. In also controlling the executive branch and the judiciary, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests cemented their advantages over the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities.

2.4. Control of the Press

Group A towns were the informational epicenter of the Commonwealth. The widespread circulation of newspapers and magazines in group A towns served as a unifying force for the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. In the eleven years between 1780 and 1791, all of the newspapers and magazines published in the commonwealth were published in group A towns (Table 12). These publications were owned and operated by residents of group A towns. Furthermore, advertisers in the press were merchants, artisans, and other service-based professionals who overwhelmingly lived in the group A towns. The press’s dependence on advertising revenue gave further strength to the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in controlling what and how information was communicated. The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests were able to make the case for their programs and policy positions through propagandizing in newspapers and magazines.
A notable example was John Adams’ Defense of the Constitutions of the Government, of which four-fifths of all subscribers lived in group A towns. The concentration of periodicals in group A towns highlights the cultural sensibilities and learnedness of those individuals living in group A towns. This also highlights the remote desolation in which many of the residents outside group A towns found themselves.
The press served as a means to inform and unify constituents holding shared interests and thus the press, and those who controlled the press were able to shape public opinion (Bachrach and Baratz 1962; Lane 1965; Zaller 1984, 1992). In a context without parties, periodicals served as a form of quasi-party organizing. In the case of political parties, party newspapers and pamphlets served to counteract the influence ofthe elite press. However, in the preparty era, the elite press dominated communication in Massachusetts and, as a result, had a high degree of influence over public opinion and thus the policy agenda.
The least commercial–cosmopolitan communities had a dearth of periodicals. Even if residents of one town managed to come together for a convention and agreed upon grievances and action steps, the residents of an adjacent town were unaware and thus unable to participate, thus fracturing the less commercial–cosmopolitan interests. Without periodicals, the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests were unable to get their constituents on the same page. Without periodicals, those same interests were unable to promote particular candidates or advocate for or against particular bills.
In controlling the press, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests controlled what information was shared. In the eleven years from 1780 to 1791, the press did not cover the proceedings of the General Court. Constituents were unable to know the roll call votes of their particular delegates. During those same years, the Senate did not keep a journal, and the House kept an unpublished journal of its proceedings. Constituents had no way of knowing the specific work of the General Court. Additionally, the press did not publish details on the holders of the Commonwealth’s debts or other details regarding the financial status of the state. Furthermore, the state government did not publish such financial information independently. As a result, the details of the legislature and the state’s finances were obscured from public view. Consequently, information was doled out in the currency of social contact—valuable information was transmitted by word of mouth.
Those with social contacts in public office were able to find out the internal details of the legislature and the state government. The members of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests had a high degree of social contact with government officers, judges, and delegates to the General Court, with many group A residents serving in such capacities. As a consequence, members of the group A towns often had greater access to valuable information. This valuable information was then shared through an informal network of commercial entrepreneurs, public officers, and learned professionals across the state. That same information was kept hidden from other citizens, particularly those citizens in the communities outside group A towns.
The matter of communication was further exacerbated by the mechanics of mail. From 1786 and 1791, between 70% and 100% of post offices were in group A towns. As a consequence, group B and C residents were forced to travel into group A towns to retrieve their mail. The difficulty and length of travel in the era made the dissemination of information slow and sporadic. Without post offices or with few post offices by 1791, there was little ability to physically transmit information or disseminate a unified policy agenda, posing another obstacle for the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests.
Ultimately, the control of the press by the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests had two advantages: first, the periodicals circulated among the group A communities helped unify and put public opinion behind bills or policies that were advantageous to the group A interests. Furthermore, elite control of the press also allowed the few periodicals that were read by residents of the peripheral communities to only see one side of any given story; the opposing views, the views of the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests, were not included, thus giving additional advantage to elite’s in shaping public opinion.
The lack of press coverage on important matters before the legislature and the commonwealth’s financial status, the concentration of post offices in the group A towns, and the need for social contact with government officers to obtain such information, all point to the elite’s clear advantage in terms of information sharing.

2.5. Means of Ascent

Education was a social infrastructure that advantaged the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in group A towns. The strong social ties in group A communities began in the private academies where the affluent sent their children.11 The effects of the social ties formed in private academies and later in college on reproducing social class stratification are well documented (Aries and Seider 2007; Karen 1991; Martin 2009; Persell and Cookson 1985). Graduation from an elite private academy and Harvard were common features in the backgrounds of nearly the entirety of the governing class and the most commercial–cosmopolitan communities.
In the executive branch of government, all of the governors and lieutenant governors, with the exception of Benjamin Lincoln, attended Harvard College. Among the eight men who served on the supreme court between 1780 and 1791, only one was not a graduate of Harvard College. Additionally, more than three-quarters of the men selected to represent the commonwealth in the Confederation and National Congress were graduates of Harvard College. Seventy-five percent of Confederation congressmen from Massachusetts graduated from Harvard, and more than four-fifths of the congressmen lived in group A towns. The 1788 change to the popular election of congressmen did not increase popular control, despite reformers’ intentions. From 1788 to 1791, 77% of congressmen graduated from Harvard, and seventy-seven percent lived in group A towns.12
In attending Harvard College, many members of the commercial–cosmopolitan elite became socially acquainted and received similar educations. Moreover, affluent parents in group A towns established private schools for their children, which served as pipelines to Harvard College. From there, Harvard College served as the pipeline for commercial ventures, political careers, and lives of affluence, power, and influence.
In addition to the social reproduction of elite stratification brought on by elite schools and colleges, the nature of education in the era was itself a source of polarization between group A and group C towns. Schools and colleges created literate and informed citizens. Literacy allowed for citizens to read newspapers, magazines, political treatises, and the popular pamphlets of the era. The educational system of the day also contained a significant religious and moral component. This led citizens to develop ideas about political principles and how society should be governed. The payment of the state debt was seen not only in economic terms but also in terms of moral virtue. The issue of allowing the courts to sit in 1786 and 1787 in the face of armed insurrection was a matter of maintaining civil society and ensuring the continued and proper functioning of the judiciary, one of the three pillars of republican democracy. Ultimately, such issues are viewed in light of principled ideas about right and wrong. Such moral principles are commonly learned and discussed in the classroom of private academies and Harvard.
Schools and colleges provided a forum for discussions of social ills and the state of politics. Ultimately, the varied consequences of education, a privilege largely experienced by the most commercial–cosmopolitan class, created a chasm between the educated citizens of the group A towns and the often illiterate and poorly educated residents of group C towns, whose lives were dictated by visceral and practical considerations. Education also produced learned professionals who interacted socially, further bolstering the unity of interests and political advantages of the most commercial–cosmopolitan class.
The varied learned professionals who first formed social ties at Harvard College then had those social ties continued and reinforced by the many social, professional, and voluntary organizations of the era. Many such organizations had longstanding presences in Massachusetts society beginning well before the Revolution. The Masons, by the 1780s, were wholly integrated into elite society. Eighteen of the nineteen Masonic lodges in Massachusetts were located in group A towns.13 As for the leadership, 100% of the holders of the office of Grand Master and other senior Masonic offices were residents of the group A towns (Fleet 1793, pp. 80–81).
The merchant marine societies held significant sway in the ten leading shipowning towns, as well as in the ninety additional shipowning towns. The marine societies function as an early version of an industry lobbying group, promoting the cause of merchant mercantilism and the interests of shipowning communities. The societies for advanced degree professionals—physicians and barristers—had officers and members that were nearly exclusively from group A towns (Fleet 1792, p. 84). The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests controlled these organizations and used the organizations to their advantage in terms of political organizing. This gives the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests a platform for organizing in the preparty era, a platform for which the residents of the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities did not partake and were actively excluded.
Honorary and cultural institutions were also controlled by the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. The American Academy of Arts and Sciences was founded by the Massachusetts General Court in 1780. The Academy was directed by leading commercial entrepreneurs and learned professionals, exclusively from the group A towns. The ranks of the Academy were populated by placeholders and other learned individuals from group A towns. The Massachusetts Historical Society was founded by leading politicians in the 1780s and was charged with studying and documenting the history of Massachusetts. Charitable and voluntary organizations were founded by senior Congregational ministers with the financial support from the affluent residents in group A towns.14 The Massachusetts Agricultural Society, an early version of the farm lobby, was founded and led by members of the most commercial–cosmopolitan class and hosted its regular meetings in central Boston (Fleet 1792, p. 75; Fleet 1793, p. 32).15
Professional, social, and voluntary associations in the early commonwealth unified the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. Strong social ties began with education in the private academies of group A towns and later in the ties formed at Harvard College. This foundation led to lifelong ties through professional and social organizations such as the Masonic Lodge, marine societies, merchant societies, physician and barrister associations, honorary societies, and charitable associations. Through the interactions brought on by such associations, the commercial–cosmopolitan elite were able to advance their economic interests through collaboration. In collaborating in business, society, and politics, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests were able to monopolize the levers of power and exclude dissent, in this case, the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests.

3. Legislating Without Parties

The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests are organized in primitive fashion compared with modern political parties. Furthermore, any organization of the most commercial–cosmopolitan was, in principle, non-political. The basis of the organization of the Massachusetts elite was through the natural forms of social and institutional organizing that were commonly found among elites. Such an organization became political in Massachusetts because there were no formal parties, and the elite’s social infrastructure served political ends. As a result of their non-political associations, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests controlled the levers of political power—the General Court, the judiciary, the executive, the Church, and social and educational institutions—thus allowing for the implementation of favorable policy. The most developed interests were able to pass laws to consolidate the commonwealth’s debt and pay it back at a high rate of interest—to the benefit of speculators and lenders, who were residents of group A towns; pay the commonwealth’s share of Continental debt; quash tender laws; quash stay laws and debt relief; and raise taxes.
The least developed interests opposed all of these measures. The least developed interests tried to make their opposition known through their representatives in both chambers of the General Court. However, such efforts were futile. The most developed interests exerted their will in the lower chamber through placeholders; in the rare instance that a reform bill passes the lower chamber, it is swiftly quashed in the elite-controlled Senate. Politics without parties brought significant frustration to the least developed communities.
The political strength of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests came from their high degree of political involvement. Between 1780 and 1791, 98% of representatives from the 54 group A towns served for 9–11 years, as compared to the 201 group C towns, in which only 14% of towns had representatives serving 9–11 years. On the contrary, the bulk of towns in the 201 group C towns, 61%, sent representatives for 0–5 years. The 10 leading shipowning towns of Massachusetts—considered the most affluent—contained 12% of the polls while having 16% of all Senate seats and 11% of seats in the House. On the other hand, 57% of the polls lived across 243 non-shipowning towns and held 53% of the Senate seats and 64% of the seats in the House (see Table 13).
The substantive political disagreements between the most and least commercial–cosmopolitan interests arose over matters of taxation, credit, and judicial policies, pitting the coalitions against each other. The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests supported a taxation program that favored commercial property, keeping taxes low on the merchant class. The ten leading shipowning towns within the group A towns contained 12% of the rateable polls in 1784.16 This same set of individuals held two-thirds of commercial warehouse inventory in the state, 72% of the state’s total vessel tonnage, and 87% of the state’s wharfage.
Despite the significant concentration of commercial value among these 12% of rateable polls, total tax payments from this group only accounted for 14% of the state’s total tax bill (Acts and Resolves 1782, pp. 903–06; Hall 1972). Half of the collected tax revenue in the 1780s came from taxes on rateable polls and personal real estate. Taxes needed to be paid in paper tender, specie, or financial securities. The most commercial–cosmopolitan towns, with significant cash flow and affluence, had no issue meeting their tax obligations. However, in group C towns, hard currency or specie were nearly nonexistent.
The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in group A towns were able to present a united front to achieve policies to their benefit or quash disadvantageous policies. The data presented in Table 14 show the polarization between the poles of the commercial–cosmopolitan gradient. Furthermore, the roll call votes in Table 14 are evidence that the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests were, in a large part, able to push through legislation in their interest and quash countervailing legislation. Ultimately, this points to the unified and organized front of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests.
Group C towns were unable to present a united front. The representatives sent to the General Court, while in principle sent to the General Court to represent their constituencies’ interests, often voted in line with the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests. The lack of information sharing and the absence of parties created a situation in which those individuals who had public profiles and were most widely visible won elections. Judges and justices were very often the most visible persons in the least developed communities. However, the interests of judges and justices were often in line with those of the group A towns and the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests and not in line with those of the constituents who elected them to office.
Looking at Table 15, Table 16 and Table 17, one sees a granular breakdown of the western communities—the site of the bulk of the least developed communities—by commercial–cosmopolitan development, in the context of only western communities. Nonetheless, representatives from group A towns within the western counties voted at a lower rate than their counterparts from the western group B and C towns when considering bills that were favorable to commercial–cosmopolitan interests. One also sees that those representatives who were also justices or judges generally voted against such bills at an even lower rate than their colleagues who only served as representatives. Such voting patterns point to the judges and justices in their role as placeholders, even within the generally less developed western counties of Massachusetts. This data also illustrate the polarization between the two extremes of the commercial–cosmopolitan gradient.
Group C towns pushed for tender law reform to increase the legitimacy and flow of paper currency. However, the commercial–cosmopolitan elite opposed tender law reform, so as to keep the value of their assets high. Furthermore, the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests supported the judiciary’s judgments and the enforcement of debt judgments. The elite were opposed to legislation suspending debts. Underlying debt suits were the sanctity of contract, a central tenet of Common Law. Furthermore, the suspension of debt judgments would imperil the flow of credit upon which the commercial economy depends. Views on suspending debt were distinctly polarized along the commercial–cosmopolitan gradient (see Table 18).
The elite control of major public offices; the outright control of the Senate; the substantial influence on the house; the network of placeholders in the church, business, and the judiciary; and control of the press and control of social, professional, and voluntary associations gave the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests the ability to implement their programs and laws that were to their advantage. The advantages of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests came at the cost of the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests. Without the ability to gather information, disseminate political ideas, and organize, the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests were unable to exercise influence in the political system and their frustrations began to accumulate.
In the years prior to the insurrection of 1786, questions pertaining to state and national taxation laid bare the deep chasm between the most and least commercial–cosmopolitan interests. The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests advanced a policy program that included legislation for repaying the state’s debt, as well as legislation for collecting direct and poll taxes to be used for paying the national debt. The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests pushed a narrative that rapid repayment of state and national debt would benefit Massachusetts’ economic health and that it was a moral imperative to repay the state’s debts. However, the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests were opposed to these measures, seeing such high taxes and moral imperatives as serving elite interests, enriching those already at the top. However, attempts to counteract the elite’s policy agenda by the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests were futile. The most commercial–cosmopolitan interests were organized and always a step ahead of the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests.
Bills for greater taxation passed through both chambers of the General Court with little ability of the least commercial–cosmopolitan to put a stop to such bills. The least commercial–cosmopolitan’s numerical advantage was ineffective because of placeholder representatives who voted in line with elite interests. Once bills passed the lower chamber, the outright monopoly of the Senate and the governorship by the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests ensured the smooth passage of bills. Between 1780 and 1786, three-quarters of the votes taken in the General Court pertained to bills regarding taxation, state and national debt, and private debt. Of the 20 bills regarding such matters, only 1 received consensus support. On 19 roll call votes, there was polarization between the most and least commercial–cosmopolitan interests, as displayed in Table 14 and Table 15. The same table also points to the binary nature of the polarization, with the greatest difference between the group A and group B towns. This evidence points to the fact that the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests attempted to get relief from their economic distress. Their efforts turned out to be futile.

4. Populist Backlash: From Discontent to Uprising

At the outset of the economic crisis beginning in 1780, Massachusetts farmers had faith in the political system to provide relief (Starkey 1955, pp. 7–19). Between 1780 and 1786, rural constituents held scores of conventions, where grievances were aired and efforts were organized. Political conventions generated many and sundry petitions and letters with a unifying theme: rural communities were in distress and the state government was exacerbating the conditions. Records of such conventions show that the conditions farmers were most concerned with were private debts, burdensome taxes, lack of currency, and the courts (Starkey 1955; Richards 2003; Warren 1905, pp. 5–7).
In 1781, attendees of political conventions in Hampshire and Berkshire counties declared the farmers’ opposition to the repeal of paper currency as legal tender. The farmers argued that the repeal of paper currency would cause further currency contraction, further depress farm prices, and render what little paper currency farmers possessed invalid in debtor’s court (Taylor 1954). Aggrieved farmers at a convention in Lancaster sent a letter to their representative at the General Court, Ephraim Carter, with instructions to pass “a law to ease the burden of taxation upon the husbandman” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). The letter also included instructions for “the abolition of the courts of common pleas and general sessions of the peace and a transfer of their jurisdiction to the supreme judicial court, and in other matters to justices of the peace” as well “the reduction of salaries” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). To mitigate the effects of high taxes, Carter was instructed to use “the payment of fines into the public treasury and lighten the poll tax” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). The letter reveals rural constituents’ distrust of distant power by instructing Carter to seek the “removal of the legislature to some other place than Boston” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). The many and sundry instructions from the Lancaster convention point to rural constituents’ concern with taxes and court judgments, as well as emphasizing their desire for local governance.
By 1786, common men in the group C towns realized that participating through the conventional means of political change was in vain. Conventions that had once been the venue for civil political discussion became the venue for organizing armed insurrection. In August 1786, the participants of a convention in Hatfield drafted a pledge committing the signers “to prevent the sitting of the Court of Common Pleas for the county, or of any other court that shall attempt to take property by distress and to prevent at the risk of their lives and fortunes the public sale of property seized by distressed” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). In September 1786, Job Shattuck sent a letter to the judges of the court on behalf of the rebels from Middlesex county, stating, “that it was the voice of the people of the county that the court of general sessions of the peace and of common pleas shall not sit in this county until such time as the people shall have a redress of a number of grievances they labor under at present, which will be set forth in a petition or remembrance to the next General Court” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86).
At a Hampshire county convention of distressed farmers, the participants wrote, “the expensive mode of collecting debts which by the reason of the scarcity of cash will fill the gaols with unhappy debtors and thereby hinder a respectable body of people from being serviceable either to themselves or community” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). In January 1787, attendees at a convention in Brookfield sent a petition to Governor Bowdoin demanding the “[adjournment] of the court of general sessions, and of the common pleas, for the three western counties, until after the next general election and session of the legislature” (Smith 1948, pp. 83–86). The petitions generated from political conventions were useful only insofar as they were acted upon by the politicians receiving the petitions—in the case of Massachusetts in the 1780s, not at all.
Popular discontent became popular insurrection. The insurrection in Massachusetts began in late August 1786 and lasted until August 1787. The insurrection persisted, and farmers in the western counties of Massachusetts continued to perceive their grievances as falling on deaf ears.
Governor Bowdoin convened the legislature in November 1786 to address the ongoing insurrection. The conservative elite in Boston, led by Samuel Adams, were vehemently opposed to appeasing the farmers and argues for harsh punishment for agitators, stating, “in monarchies the crime of treason and rebellion may admit of being pardoned or lightly punished, but the man who dares rebel against the laws of a republic ought to suffer death” (Pencak 1989, p. 64; Richards 2003, p. 16). Governor Bowdoin, while not sympathetic to the farmers, was more interested in bringing the insurrection to an end and restoring law and order. The legislature passed a series of measures that were not as harsh as what Adams wanted but instead reflected a compromising approach (Richards 2003, pp. 16–17).
To help farmers, the legislature passed measures to ease the tax burden by allowing payment in paper currency, specie, land, services, or other assets. The legislation also extended the due date for current taxes from 1 January to 1 April 1787. Moreover, the legislature approved a plan to sell 1800 square miles of Maine to pay publicly held debt. In terms of private debt, a measure passed postponing legal fees for two years for farmers brought to the debtor’s court. Additionally, between January and September 1787, farmers were permitted to pay private debts with land and other property (Cain and Dougherty 2016; Richards 2003, pp. 16–17).
On the other hand, the legislature also passed measures to help the state quash the rebellion, inflaming the polarization between the two coalitions of interests, elite and common. In a bill passed on November 10, the legislature suspended habeas corpus until 1 July 1787, and gave Governor Bowdoin the right to imprison “all persons whatsoever” who were dangerous to the public welfare (Richards 2003, p. 19). Another such measure, the Riot Act, gave legal immunity to sheriffs for killing rebels who resisted capture or failed to disperse. The Riot Act also specified punishment for captured rebels: the forfeiture of their land, personal property, livestock, and other goods to the state. Furthermore, rebels “shall be whipped 39 stripes on the naked back, at the public whipping post and suffer imprisonment for a term not exceeding 12 months”, as well as an additional thirty-nine lashes every three months during imprisonment (Richards 2003, pp. 16–17). The legislature also passed the Disqualification Act, barring all rebels from serving on juries, holding office, or voting in elections (Richards 2003, p. 33).
The legislature also passed the Militia Act, punishing those members of the militias who defected in support of the farmers, proclaiming “whosoever officer or soldier shall abandon any post committed to his charge, or shall speak words inducing others to do the like in time of engagement, shall suffer death” (Richards 2003, p. 17). The Militia Act spoke to a serious obstacle for state leadership in quashing the insurrection: the defection and weakness of the state militias.
In the western counties, militiamen were reluctant to comply with the orders of the state leadership in Boston. The militias were composed of local, able-bodied men. The very men who were expected to form the militia were often sympathetic to rebel farmers, and many were active in the rebellion. Militias in the eastern counties were compliant with Governor Bowdoin’s orders. However, the few compliant militias were ill-equipped. The Continental government had an arsenal with ample artillery in Springfield. However, the state did not have access to the artillery in the Springfield arsenal without the permission of Secretary of War, Henry Knox, who was unwilling (Richards 2003, pp. 23–25).
Without effective state militias to quash the insurrection, Governor Bowdoin hired a mercenary army of 4400 men. The mercenary army was summoned without legislative authorization, thus making no funds available to pay for the mercenaries. Instead, the governor contributed £250 from his own pocket and gathered an additional £6000 from businessmen in Boston. Governor Bowdoin and General Lincoln, who were in charge of the mercenary army, persuaded businessmen to contribute by justifying the contributions as a small amount to pay in order to preserve the bulk of their fortunes from the effects of the insurrection (Richards 2003, pp. 23–25). The use of private donations from businessmen points to the divide between the most and least commercial–cosmopolitan communities. Moreover, it points to the ability and willingness of the elite to organize collectively for the sake of their best interest: the resumption and maintenance of law and order, the absence of which would negatively affect commercial enterprise.17
Measures passed by the legislature and the hiring of a standing army further stoked the agitation of farmers in the western counties. The deployment of the mercenary troops to the western counties was initially met by rebel farmers in kind, with an escalation in violence. However, the rebels were overwhelmed by the better-equipped and better-trained troops.
Shays’s Rebellion began with the bravado of halting the courts, causing the breakdown in law and order. Shays’s Rebellion ended in mundane failure. The insurrection was finally put down by the mercenary army in a string of ever smaller skirmishes across the Berkshires in the Spring and Summer of 1787. The rebels did not get what they wanted. The taxes, debts, courts, and system of representation that frustrated common men and led to insurrection remained in place.
The War for Independence promised greater equality and freedom from tyranny. Yet, for the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests, life under colonial rule and reality in the early Republic were starkly similar. The Revolution had been an elite transition.

4.1. The Tyranny of Geocracy

In 1780s Massachusetts, polarization was about where one lived. Where one lived determined one’s social place, one’s economic fate, and ultimately, one’s political fate. The variables described in previous pages, all of which demonstrated the formidable advantages of the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests, show the power of geography in early New England.
The structure of representation in Massachusetts advantaged the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests and precluded the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests from active political participation. The advantages of the elite were reinforced by their physical proximity to each other and the venues of government: the General Court, commercial centers, social clubs and associations, the state house, the press, and the church.
The utter inability of commercial–cosmopolitan interests to mount a response stemmed from the geographic mechanics of political participation. For example, rural communities, where the bulk of group C towns were found, had no post offices or government services. If one takes a look, for example, at the small coastal town of Hull, a group C town across the bay from Boston, one can see the effect of location on political participation. By land, Hull is roughly 43 km from Boston. Using approximations from historical records, a stagecoach could travel roughly 60 km if traveling for a full day along a well-worn path.18 This does not take into consideration the weather and road conditions of less-worn paths most typically used by common men.19 The weather played a major role in the ability to travel—a meter of freshly fallen snow, not uncommon in a typical New England winter snowstorm—entirely obstructed travel for weeks.20 Rainstorms could muddy the paths, breaking the wooden carriage wheels, stranding travelers along the route. Thus, a resident of Hull traveling to Boston needed to wait for good weather and then dedicate much of a day to travel each way. A simple trip to Boston was a multi-day journey. Today, residents of Hull may reach Boston either by motor vehicle, taking roughly 45 min, or by ferry, taking roughly 23 min.
If a common man in Hull wished to retrieve his mail and newspaper at the nearest post office 12 km away in Hingham (a group A town), he needed to account for his round-trip travel—roughly 24 km. A 24 km round trip took roughly 10 h, not including time spent in Hingham retrieving the mail and letting the horses recover for the return trip.21 Ultimately, the simple trip to Hingham by a common man from Hull may have taken as many as 12 h. To put this in perspective, today, a one-way trip by motor vehicle from Hull to Hingham takes roughly 16 min.
A common man, a poll, residing in New Salem (a group C town) and answering a summons to the Court of Common Pleas needed to travel to the county seat at Northampton, 38 km away. If such a common man was traveling alone by horseback, he may have traveled on average roughly 32 km per day. Thus, a one-way trip from New Salem to Northampton required an overnight stop. To put this in perspective, today, a one-way trip by motor vehicle from New Salem to the Northampton courthouse takes roughly 38 min.
Geography was a significant factor for residents of the least commercial–cosmopolitan communities in a way that the most commercial–cosmopolitan communities did not face. Casting one’s ballot, attending conventions, court hearings, running for office, paying one’s taxes, and other political participation, or obtaining government services, required complex travel logistics. The relatively vast distances of Massachusetts and laborious forms of travel further weakened the political strength of the group C communities.
Low voter turnout was pervasive among polls in the group C communities, particularly those in western Massachusetts and the district of Maine. Without political parties, there was no means of political organization. The absence of organization meant the absence of the tools used for mobilizing voters: policy platforms, political advertising, endorsements, vote canvassing, and party conventions. Residents of group C communities found it difficult to acquire information about the government because of the lack of transparency and press coverage and the lack of available periodicals in group C communities. Underlying the lack of informational dissemination was the fact that many of the group C residents were uneducated and illiterate, causing them further confusion about the intricacies of tripartite republican government.
As a consequence of this lack of available information and the lack of understanding, political participation was depressed among group C communities. Voter turnout eventually increased after 1787 as the result of persistent and accumulated frustrations held by the least commercial–cosmopolitan interests, as a backlash to the response of the Bowdoin government’s heavy-handed military response to the Shays’s Rebellion, and as a consequence of reforms to voting rights: the lowering of property requirements and the waiving of debt issues as cause for disenfranchisement.22

4.2. A Tale of Two States

During the same years and despite facing similar conditions, insurrection was averted in the neighboring Rhode Island. In Rhode Island, geography prevented polarization. Comparing Massachusetts with its smaller and less populous neighbor, Rhode Island, illustrates how the geographic mechanics of political participation fundamentally altered the economic and political experience of Rhode Islanders in the tumultuous 1780s.
In Rhode Island, the distance between the seat of state government, Providence, and the most distant location by radial distance was roughly 77 km. All other towns fell within a radius of less than 77 km of the capital. The closer proximity of polls and the population as a whole led to greater social integration and thus a more egalitarian political landscape in the 1780s.
The same natural advantages that give the most commercial–cosmopolitan interests in group A towns in Massachusetts an upper hand—significant social associations, press availability, and physical proximity—applied to the whole of Rhode Island (see Table 19 and Figure 1). Rhode Island possessed seven newspapers. However, Rhode Island newspapers were widely distributed across the state because the distances were significantly smaller, thus making distribution easier. Additionally, post offices were more widely distributed and in closer proximity to the population, facilitating the dissemination of information. Furthermore, Rhode Island did not possess the same entrenched elite class that is found in Massachusetts. Boston was the focal point of British control during the colonial era and was long a economic and political engine of New England. Providence was substantially smaller geographically, with fewer residents and less commercial activity. Without a longstanding and entrenched elite class, there was greater space for common men to participate. The greater political integration facilitated by the relative geographic proximity of the population was evidenced in the political events of 1780s Rhode Island.
In 1785, distressed rural residents of Rhode Island formed the Country Party. Common people living outside the urban centers were able to do so because of more fair access to periodicals and more fair access to information in such periodicals, thus helping get polls on the same page. In 1786, the Country Party swept statewide elections and took control of the legislature, campaigning under the slogan “to relieve the distressed” (Richards 2003, p. 83). The ability of the rural communities to hold a majority in the legislature was due to Rhode Island’s low requirements for voting and holding office. Qualification to vote requires property ownership of £40 or annual rent of at least £2, as well as not having any delinquent tax debt (Hough 1872, pp. 246–71).23 Veterans of the Revolution and currently enlisted troops were permitted to vote regardless of income or assets. Moreover, private debts, delinquent or otherwise, were not a cause for disqualification. Despite the rule on delinquent tax debt, it was rarely enforced. All polls were able to hold elected office without additional qualifications. Low barriers to voting and holding office allowed for rural constituents to participate in politics.
The allocation of representation was more evenly distributed in Rhode Island. Elections for governor, lieutenant governor, the House of Representatives, and the Senate were held annually. Representatives in the lower chamber were elected at the town level, and the number of representatives from each town was contingent on the population, with each town receiving at least one representative. The number of representatives from any given town could not exceed twelve or one-sixth of the total number of representatives in the lower chamber. The lower chamber was limited to seventy-two representatives. Each town elected one senator for the upper chamber, with ten senators in total. The lieutenant governor, elected separately in statewide elections, presided over the upper chamber (Hough 1872, pp. 246–71). In 1786, the Country Party held forty-five seats in the lower chamber and five seats in the Senate. The Country Party won majorities in either one chamber or both in each annual election until 1795. The ability of rural constituents to be aptly represented in the legislature gave voice to the concerns of common people in Rhode Island and served as a pressure valve, relieving frustrations.
The effective representation of rural constituencies in the legislature yielded significant relief for those communities. In 1786, the Rhode Island legislature passed laws instituting the legal status of paper currency, increasing access to currency for farmers, and enforcing the legitimacy of paper money (Szatmary 1980). Additionally, the legislature voted not to make simultaneous payments on its war debt and its share of the continental government’s war debt. As a result, the tax burden was far lighter for Rhode Island’s constituents.
The use of paper currency as legal tender was of particular consternation for the merchant class in Rhode Island. The merchant class preferred specie, gold and silver coins, because of their value in global trading markets. Merchants often attempt to skirt the tender law by refusing to accept paper money. The legislature answers with strict legislation punishing creditors or merchants who refused to accept paper currency with a fine of £100 per instance of refusal.24 Creditors and merchants who refused paper currency were banned from seeking elected office and had commercial licenses revoked, including the prohibition of sailing in or out of Rhode Island ports, a draconian measure in the day (Szatmary 1980, pp. 47–55).
Figure 1. Commonwealth of Massachusetts, c. 1785.25
Figure 1. Commonwealth of Massachusetts, c. 1785.25
Histories 05 00026 g001
Two additional proposed bills point to the egalitarian nature of the legislature. First was a bill proposing a requirement for all constituents to swear an oath supporting the use of paper currency. Failure to take the oath resulted in the suspension of an individual’s voting rights. Another bill proposed seizing all commercial enterprises, giving control of trade to the state government (Szatmary 1980, pp. 47–55). The consideration of such measures indicates the legislature’s impatience with exploitation and its zeal in defending the interests of common men.
Further helping distressed common men was the legislature’s supremacy over the judiciary. The Rhode Island Constitution did not vest the judiciary with separate and independent power (Hough 1872, pp. 246–71). Instead, the state constitution vested the legislature with authority over judicial matters.26 The legislature was responsible for appointing justices and was allowed to override court decisions. Once the Country Party was in the majority in the legislature, court decisions perceived to favor commercial interests and disadvantage farmers were swiftly reversed by the legislature. In a 1786 case involving a merchant’s refusal to accept paper currency as payment, a local court dismissed the case without remedy. The legislature overrode the court’s decision, ordered the merchant to accept paper currency, and provided compensation as a remedy to the plaintiff (Szatmary 1980). Furthermore, the justices responsible for the decision were summoned to the legislature, dismissed from their positions, and issued criminal charges, evidencing the pro-debtor and populist orientation of the Rhode Island legislature.
Massachusetts and Rhode Island faced similar economic circumstances in the 1780s. Both were new states within the nascent nation (for a geographic, visual comparison, see Figure 2 and Figure 3). Both had significant state debts and had large sums to pay for the Continental government’s requisition. The credit contraction and economic fallout that impacted Massachusetts, from the wealthy merchants and landowners down to the subsistence farmers, also impacted Rhode Island. The states diverged in their reactions to such an economic fallout. In Massachusetts, group C towns were unable to mount a response because of the lack of ability to communicate, receive information, and mobilize for collective political action. At the same time, most commercial–cosmopolitan interests monopolized the levers of power, further weakening the political power of common men. Massachusetts’ common men also contended with the vast distances over which they had to travel to participate in politics and governance.
Figure 2. Comparative view of Massachusetts and Rhode Island.27
Figure 2. Comparative view of Massachusetts and Rhode Island.27
Histories 05 00026 g002
Figure 3. State of Rhode Island.28
Figure 3. State of Rhode Island.28
Histories 05 00026 g003
Rhode Island’s common men contended with a far smaller geography; Rhode Island is roughly one-fortieth the size of Massachusetts (for a visualization of this, see Figure 2 and Figure 3). Rhode Island’s population was roughly one-sixth that of Massachusetts. Rhode Island also possessed seven post offices, evenly distributed throughout the state.29 On average, each post office served 7564 residents. The newspapers published were better able to reach a broad swath of the population. Many newspapers included portions that were specifically dedicated to rural life.30 Moreover, Rhode Island papers provided coverage of political affairs in the state. Among the most popular Rhode Island periodicals, The United States Chronicle: Political, Commercial, Historical, provided Rhode Island residents with a thorough breakdown of the political happenings of the day; vote counts, names of representatives, bills passed, vetoed, and signed into law. In so doing, Rhode Island residents were able to have an understanding of the political landscape in their state.
A confluence of variables yielded better representation of common men in Rhode Island: more evenly distributed allocation of seats in the legislature, low barriers to qualify to vote and hold office, better press coverage of politics, and the benefits of a relatively small geography, and shorter distances to travel to participate in politics and retrieve periodicals and other forms of communication through the postal service. The arrangement of such variables in Rhode Island served as a pressure valve for the frustrations of Rhode Island’s common men. The relief of common men’s frustrations prevented persistent and accumulated frustrations from boiling over and triggering insurrection.

5. Discussion

In the 1780s, politics was geographic. Where you lived determined what representation you obtained. At the beginning of the nation, Americans struggled with how to extend the Republican ideals of the Revolution across the vast land that was now theirs. The new nation was larger than the ideal size for republics claimed by Montesquieu and Locke. In the first years of the Republic, states of different sizes faced different problems (Zagarri 1987, pp. 4–5; Soja 1971).
Policymakers in small states deal with a generally homogeneous and static population. Cities and towns are densely packed, there is limited land in which to spread out, and no residents tend to possess large tracts of land. In this context, political institutions do not need wholesale reforms. Rather, policymakers in small states like Rhode Island would “tinker” with their political institutions; they passed relief bills, formed new political factions/parties, and changed the composition of the courts. All of this took place well within the parameters of routine Republican government. In the context of small states, cyclical elections sufficed to usher in change. In small states, the apportionment of representation by geography worked both in principle and in practice. However, in large states like Massachusetts, such tinkering and geographic representation did not suffice.
Geographic representation was incongruent with reality in a large state like Massachusetts. Policymakers in Massachusetts confronted a different set of problems: a significantly larger and growing population and demographic and socioeconomic diversity to a much greater extent than in their small neighbor, Rhode Island. The dispersed population over great distances made mobility a central issue. As a result of the unstable and evolving communities in Massachusetts, legislators incorporated representative institutions based on population rather than solely on geography. In name, this was represented by demography and population. However, in Massachusetts, representative institutions determined by demography and population were ineffective in practice because of the ability of elites to manipulate Republican government through placeholders and the exercise of influence and affluence.
The ineffectiveness of Massachusetts’ representative institutions was a consequence of the lack of parties. Between 1780 and the summer of 1786, roughly one-third to one-half of Massachusetts’ population lived in the less developed parts of the state. While in principle they had representation, sending delegates to the General Court, and while formal rules on voting were in the books, such rules were rarely enforced. At first glance, one would not understand why frustrations accumulated among the constituents in Massachusetts’ less developed areas. Despite Massachusetts’ policymakers reforms to expand voting further in 1787 and further apportionment on the basis of demography and population, such reforms were meaningless without oppositional political organization.
The absence of formal parties, as we understand parties today, allowed the most developed communities to exercise their natural advantages: their interconnectedness through education, professional ties, social associations, and shared interests. The elite were able to exercise their will by holding important public offices and putting into office a sweeping network of placeholders. Such placeholders, on paper, represented a particular, less-developed community, but in reality, were planted to bolster the political strength of the elite. The unified front put forward by the most developed communities was bolstered by the control of the press. The press was used to get residents on the same page in the most developed communities. Furthermore, the issue of mobility again further expanded the chasm between communities, making information difficult to access for those outside the most developed communities. Moreover, the press did not provide crucial political information, thus denying common men the ability to learn about their government or know how their delegate voted on a given bill.
In such ways, the elite were organized by nonpolitical forces but used such organization for political ends. At the same time, the elite’s counterparts, common men, were utterly unorganized politically or otherwise. In the face of such a formidable adversary, common men in group C communities were compelled to take alternative action. Common men held conventions and sent petitions to the governor and the General Court. Conventions were futile because of the mobility issues already discussed—even if residents of one community were able to come together to discuss their grievances and send those grievances in writing to their delegates in the General Court, only those who were nearby and heard about them by word-of-mouth attended. The residents of a neighboring town remained utterly unaware because of a lack of communication systems (i.e., post offices) and the vast distances between rural towns (using the transportation methods of the day). Petitions to governors and instructions to legislators fell on deaf ears. Governors were solidly part of the elite and governed as such. In the General Court, placeholder delegates from western communities were inclined to vote for elite interests. Even on occasions when western delegates voted in line with their constituents’ interests, the grip on the power of the elites through other placeholders in the lower chamber and the elite’s outright stranglehold on the upper chamber rendered meaningless the individual votes of western delegates. The frustrations of common men in western and rural Massachusetts came to a head in 1786 and 1787; the courts were blocked from sitting, halting the judiciary and more broadly disrupting the order of society.
Despite armed insurrection, the demands of common men were left unanswered. In the second half of the 1780s, political participation increased. Voter turnout surged; on election day in 1787, with the plight of common men brought to the fore by the insurrection, voters turned out in mass. In 1787, there was nearly 200% greater voter turnout for the governor’s election than in 1786 and 175% greater turnout in the Senate elections. The greatest increases in turnout were in Bristol and Plymouth counties, at 582% and 547%, respectively. In Hampshire and Berkshire counties, turnout increased by 41% and 52%, respectively.31
Despite the much greater voter turnout from the less developed communities, little changed in the overall configuration of political institutions. Bowdoin lost the governorship, and Hancock—an entrenched member of the elite—took office. The most developed communities continued to monopolize the Senate, with the Senate becoming a de facto social club. The elections of 1787 and the mild reforms put into place by the General Court—laws suspending debit suits, reductions in court fees, anti-corruption laws for judges, and reduced specie requirements for certain import taxes—did little to reform the overall political situation.
In the absence of political parties, important political issues of the day were subject to the reaction of distinct groups with their own interests. Without parties to mitigate between constituencies and policymaking, informal factions based on socioeconomic characteristics were more divisive and polarizing and less willing to engage in discussion and compromise. The political tensions of Massachusetts in the 1780s illustrate the combustible potential for populism to run roughshod over society and democracy if political parties are not present to give order and structure to grievances and to advocate for particular constituencies.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Please contact the author for questions regarding data.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

Appendix A. Polarization Roll Call Votes

Data and information regarding roll call votes described in the table on polarization are sourced from Hall (1972, pp. 100–4). The original roll call votes and the description of the bills may be found in the unpublished Journals of the House of Representatives of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts (Secretary of State 1780). All roll call votes for Table 14 are reported as a percentage of yes votes, except where it is indicated as a percentage of no votes.
The following are the bills listed as they are displayed in tables on polarization:
  • “On the question whether the House will this session take into consideration the propriety of giving leave to bring in a bill for the repeal of any act or acts or any clause of any act or acts of this Commonwealth...which will oblige any creditor public or private to receive any Debtors demand, at a less sum than the just value thereof”.
  • “And on the question of the report of Committee of Ways and Means...and that the several acts of government which now related to the currency of the state be altered and conform with the foregoing [a system re- ported by the Committee, ‘founded in Justice and Equity’, that would repeal any legal tender provisions of Massachusetts currency] principle upon such a plan that all Debts public and private that are already contracted or that may hereafter be contracted at the real current value of the passing money of the state such value must be determined from time to time by some Impartial Judges, except in case of special contract”.
  • “That all such Government Securities shall be liquidated by the scale of depreciation established by the state and that the sums so liquidated shall be paid in gold and silver or in current money of this Commonwealth at the real value of said liquidated sums”.
  • “Be it therefore enacted by the authority aforesaid that the above mentioned Bills of Credit or such others may hereafter be emitted on the credit of this or the United States...shall be received in all payments within the same...but subject however to the...last cited clause at the true real value of current money compared with gold and silver...and shall avail as the tender had been in Gold and Silver”.
  • “House resumed consideration of [the above] bill. Vote to ‘assign tomorrow for a third reading”.
  • “Above bill passed to be engrossed, to `send up for concurrence”’.
  • “Above bill having had three readings, passed to be enacted”.
  • “That a certain clause of an Act passed the 25th of Jan. last [the above] which authorizes the Judges to determine the value of paper money and another clause in said act which repeals the tender act so called be repealed”. (NB: percentage of no vote)
  • “That the issuing of another Tax Act be referred to the next session of the General Court”. (NB: percentage of no vote)
  • “Motion made to reconsider the vote of the house passed 26 June 1782 not to issue a tax upon the polls and estates of this commonwealth the present session”.
  • “A Bill intitled [sic] an Act directing the appraising of certain articles of personal estate when taken to satisfy execution at the suit of any private person or persons...read a third time...That it pass to be engrossed”. (NB: percentage of no vote)
  • “On the Report of Committee of Ways and Means...agreed to take the articles separately...‘Whether a duty of 1s per barrel shall be laid upon all cyder [sic] made or imported into this state’ [with the revenue from the state impost and excise to be used to meet some general state expenses]”. (NB: percentage of no vote)
  • “House considered resolve of the Senate for treasurer to issue executions against all collectors who have not returned tax money and to `make complaint against towns and plantations that have neglected to make return to him”’.
  • “House took up again a bill entitled `An Act Imposing duties on licensed vellum, parchment, and paper’, should “bill pass to be en-grossed”.
  • “House proceeded to consider the subject of a tax and the fol- lowing was again made a question before the house: “Whether the appropriations of the monies arising from the Impost and Excise laws be altered and that said monies...be appropriated to comply with the requisitions of Con- gress””. (NB: percentage of no votes.)
  • “When the question was called for to have the excise bill not to be engrossed”.
  • “Question that a committee be appointed to bring in a bill to repeal the excise act”.
  • “House took up the bill intitled [sic]...An Act imposing duties on licensed vellum, parchment, and papers...read a third time;...motion made to refer bill to the next session of the General Court...carried in the affirmative;...motion made to reconsider this vote so bill would lie open to debate”.
  • “Committee on new draught of the bill in addition to the Act for laying a duity on licensed vellum and other articles...reported that the house agree to a new draught with a clause levying a duty of one shilling on every bond and writing under seal...not by law recorded in any office to give it full validity. Question then put as to whether the said new draught should be agreed to be inserting the above amendment reported by the committee”. (NB: percentage of no votes.)

Appendix B. Commercial Index

Appendix B contains each town in Massachusetts as of 1784. The commercial index is calculated by ranking towns by the variables listed. Then, the rankings for each town are summed and divided by the number of variables (three or four depending on the town). The towns are listed by their commercial index number, from lowest to highest. The 343 towns are divided into ten groups (deciles).
NB: The contents of Appendix B, Appendix C and Appendix D are reproduced and adapted from the statistical appendices of Hall (1972). The author, Professor Van Beck Hall (Department of History, University of Pittsburgh), has given his written permission for the content of the statistical appendices to be used for any purpose without the consent of the author. However, in the interest of disclosure, Professor Hall is attributed here (Hall 1972). Professor Hall obtains the primary source data from the Archives of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts.
Table A1. First decile.
Table A1. First decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
BostonSuffolk11111.00
SalemEssex33222.50
NewburyportEssex22432.75
BeverlyEssex413747.00
SherburneNantucket8819610.25
CambridgeMiddlesex2553 11.00
PlymouthPlymouth91121812.25
DartmouthBristol187151012.50
IpswichEssex159161112.75
WorcesterWorcester12198 13.00
HinghamSuffolk1710141714.50
ScituatePlymouth451661520.50
AndoverEssex212324 22.67
DorchesterSuffolk264192625.50
DanversEssex1422185828.00
LancasterWorcester362920 28.33
RoxburySuffolk74139028.50
BraintreeSuffolk3112116028.50
WatertownMiddlesex163833 29.00
MarbleheadEssex166102730.25
SpringfieldHampshire305710 32.33
WeymouthSuffolk4631173632.50
LynnEssex2224226332.75
GloucesterEssex52687533.25
RutlandWorcester245331 36.00
ConcordMiddlesex271765 36.33
SandwichBarnstable7220382338.25
NewburyEssex5541124538.25
MarshfieldPlymouth5525403538.75
MedfordMiddlesex6018394440.25
SwanzeyBristol5851282741.00
CharlestownMiddlesex1014876243.25
MiltonSuffolk3420358744.00
KingstonPlymouth7440235247.25
Table A2. Second decile.
Table A2. Second decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
FalmouthCumberland118394949.25
NorthamptonHampshire293386 49.33
HaverhillEssex1335102 50.00
TauntonBristol1989524150.25
BarnstableBarnstable7415991951.75
ManchesterEssex4364683251.75
DeerfieldHampshire665046 54.00
BrookfieldWorcester416358 54.00
WestfieldHampshire694648 54.33
WalthamMiddlesex86725 54.33
YorkYork8443672554.75
PembrokePlymouth7630417956.50
CohassetSuffolk9358572458.00
LexingtonMiddlesex732776 58.67
BoltonWorcester985626 60.00
FreetownBristol52481312263.25
DunstableMiddlesex1173244 64.33
BridgewaterPlymouth35109278764.50
DedhamSuffolk887432 64.67
WoburnMiddlesex873671 64.67
StockbridgeBerkshire3362100 65.00
MarlboroughMiddlesex704779 65.33
EdgartownDukes10099501866.75
FalmouthBarnstable11945663867.00
ChelmsfordMiddlesex818736 68.00
MiddleboroughPlymouth7199258469.75
NewtownMiddlesex1323447 71.00
HallowellLincoln5096974872.25
HadleyHampshire4928142 73.00
HatfieldHampshire1075461 74.00
SalisburyEssex62150533474.75
ScarboroughCumberland38163802175.50
BerwickYork113441182875.75
AbingtonPlymouth807970 76.33
Table A3. Third decile.
Table A3. Third decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
BradfordEssex6313830 77.00
RichmondBerkshire3965128 77.33
SuttonWorcester9710729 77.67
PownalboroLincoln32731733778.75
WellsYork47921691280.00
BrooklineSuffolk8937120 82.00
LeominsterWorcester1217155 82.33
LunenbergWorcester2097135 84.00
GranvilleHampshire5394105 84.00
WestfordMiddlesex1168156 84.33
DightonBristol12784597385.75
PepperelboroYork281261009286.50
BerkleyBristol107153494087.25
LanesboroBerkshire51102111 87.67
RowleyEssex1438537 88.33
NorthfieldHampshire6413369 88.67
FraminghamMiddlesex9565109 89.67
KitteryYork139391166589.75
PetershamWorcester44119107 90.00
W. SpringfieldHampshire6711590 90.67
StoughtonSuffolk13510834 92.33
YarmouthBarnstable1431041101492.75
WestboroughWorcester4216475 93.67
SheffieldBerkshire1158782 94.67
AlmsburyEssex371541048695.25
MethuenEssex4714693 95.33
PittsfieldBerkshire4085163 96.00
BarreWorcester1229771 96.67
BoothbayLincoln174122603998.75
WrenthamSuffolk13711351 100.33
HarwichBarnstable9413612253101.25
HopkintonMiddlesex9013481 101.67
TisburyDukes213784279103.00
RehobothBristol12652144100105.50
Table A4. Fourth decile.
Table A4. Fourth decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
GeorgetownLincoln1636113268106.00
RochesterPlymouth1627714347107.25
NortonBristol12011989 109.33
SudburyMiddlesex1828264 109.33
BrunswickCumberland12316112431109.75
GrotonMiddlesex10175154 110.00
N. YarmouthCumberland907024833110.25
MedfieldSuffolk16710562 111.33
ChilmarkDukes998017989111.75
BristolLincoln9012422720115.25
HanoverPlymouth213699696118.50
SturbridgeBerkshire57155146 119.33
DuxboroughPlymouth21313911313119.50
WestonMiddlesex6455240 119.67
Plan. No. 3Lincoln12712918241119.75
ArundelYork16511814751120.25
New CastleLincoln13115513659120.25
PittstonLincoln6818918246121.25
ShrewsburyWorcester17710583 121.67
Gt. BarringtonBerkshire79134152 121.67
NeedhamSuffolk21311043 122.00
AmherstHampshire12415095 123.00
MachiasLincoln12712918254123.00
MaldenMiddlesex11158202 123.67
HarpswellCumberland14216613361125.50
TopsfieldEssex2128977 126.00
SherburneMiddlesex15116963 127.67
BiddefordYork969924830127.67
RainhamBristol10918913094130.50
BathLincoln2322624830131.75
LeicesterWorcester16095141 132.00
MedwaySuffolk18413974 132.33
NorthboroughWorcester18512492 133.67
GraftonWorcester54209145 136.00
SterlingWorcester61182165 136.00
Table A5. Fifth decile.
Table A5. Fifth decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
Cape ElizabethCumberland10516922150136.25
UkbridgeWorcester77169164 136.67
E. SudburyMiddlesex19568147 136.67
BelchertownHampshire147114152 137.67
Deer IslandLincoln21311718241138.25
MansfieldBristol150161108 139.67
WilliamstownBerkshire59169191 139.67
HarvardWorcester167116138 140.33
WaldoboroLincoln13616817484140.50
AttleboroBristol14322653 140.67
LynnfieldEssex21316945 142.33
HalifaxPlymouth13212721299142.50
FoxboroSuffolk19093147 143.33
LincolnMiddlesex15148232 143.67
MendonWorcester21315573 147.00
WarehamPlymouth21313918749147.00
BillericaMiddlesex12767248 147.33
EastonBristol104224115 147.67
SandisfieldBerkshire85169189 147.67
BedfordMiddlesex21314884 148.33
StowMiddlesex15175221 149.00
RoyalsboroCumberland21318912078150.00
SandfordYork21314891 150.67
OxfordWorcester138169147 151.33
WestministerWorcester177169114 153.33
WalpoleSuffolk149187127 154.33
WellfleetBarnstable19822616829155.25
SpencerWorcester163166137 155.33
LittletonMiddlesex125150192 155.67
HardwickWorcester105128235 156.00
DaltonBerkshire77146248 157.00
PrincetonWorcester21358202 157.67
Plan. No. 1Lincoln15122620254158.25
Table A6. Sixth decile.
Table A6. Sixth decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
ConwayHampshire167155154 158.67
WilbrahamHampshire177169134 160.00
SouthboroWorcester139169172 160.00
S. HadleyHampshire118204159 160.33
EdgecombLincoln8222624890161.50
Plan. No. 2Lincoln15122620270162.25
HullSuffolk2139124896162.00
BlandfordHampshire21318985 162.33
GreenfieldHampshire112219161 164.00
MiddletonEssex21322612395164.25
CarlisleMiddlesex185204106 165.00
BoxfordEssex213129156 166.00
BerlinWorcester213169117 166.33
PaxtonWorcester113226162 167.00
OakhamWorcester213137157 169.00
ShirleyMiddlesex21320988 170.00
PlymptonPlymouth18918524863171.25
Long MeadowHampshire170119225 171.33
MilfordWorcester21322678 172.33
SharonSuffolk151209158 172.33
DoverSuffolk213139167 173.00
DracutMiddlesex151155215 173.67
Fox IslandLincoln21322620254173.75
EasthamBarnstable19816924881174.00
S. HamptonHampshire159199165 174.33
HollistonMiddlesex148129248 175.00
WalpoleLincoln177102248 175.67
ProvincetonBarnstable21322624816175.75
FranklinSuffolk213139177 176.33
BowdoinhamLincoln16622624866176.50
ReadingMiddlesex213188129 176.67
ChathamBarnstable17722624857177.00
ActonMiddlesex213202126 180.33
NorthbridgeWorcester213209119 180.33
Table A7. Seventh decile.
Table A7. Seventh decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
PelhamHampshire170226147 181.00
DouglasWorcester185112248 181.67
BrimfieldHampshire213155180 182.67
AshburhamWorcester103199248 183.23
WilmingtonMiddlesex213226111 183.33
TopshamLincoln21320924866184.00
Plan. No. 5Lincoln21322622775185.25
CoxhallYork213204139 185.33
TempletonWorcester83226248 185.67
StonehamMiddlesex213226125 188.00
Pen. L. I.Lincoln21322624074188.25
BuxtonYork102226239 189.00
ChelseaSuffolk196123248 189.00
Plan. W. SideLincoln21322624870189.25
Plan. No. 2Lincoln21322624870189.25
WenhamEssex213189169 190.33
GorhamCumberland213110248 190.33
WesternWorcester213218140 190.33
Plan. No. 6Lincoln21322624875190.50
MeduncockLincoln21322624875190.50
Plan. No. 6Lincoln21322624881192.00
Plan. No. 5Lincoln21322624881192.00
SunderlandHampshire110226247 194.33
WoolwichLincoln21322624893195.00
St. George’sLincoln21322624896195.75
FitchburghWorcester132209248 196.33
LudlowHampshire192226171 196.33
ColerainHampshire213202176 197.00
WarwickHampshire206139248 197.67
N. BraintreeWorcester192189213 198.00
AshbyMiddlesex202169226 199.00
TownsendMiddlesex143226230 199.67
TewksburyMiddlesex213226160 199.67
PepperillMiddlesex196209193 199.33
Table A8. Eighth decile.
Table A8. Eighth decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
NatickMiddlesex213139248 200.00
WindsorBerkshire213209181 201.00
WardWorcester213209182 201.33
WorththingtonHampshire158204248 203.33
SylvesterCumberland208226178 204.00
LenoxBerkshire139226248 204.33
WinchendonWorcester213226175 204.67
ThomastownLincoln161226230 205.67
HoldenWorcester213185220 206.00
ShelburneHampshire185226211 207.33
WareHampshire202226194 207.33
CharltonWorcester213164248 208.33
WinslowLincoln213226188 209.00
AlfredBerkshire176221232 209.67
PartridgefieldBerkshire213226190 209.67
TruroBarnstable208226197 210.33
PalmerHampshire204182248 211.33
AtholWorcester213226195 211.33
HubbardstownWorcester213226195 211.33
CanaanLincoln208226202 212.00
RoyalstonWorcester192226218 212.00
N. MarlboroBerkshire213189235 212.33
MiddlefieldHampshire213226198 212.33
New SalemHampshire213226199 212.67
LeeBerkshire213224202 213.00
UptonWorcester213226200 213.00
GranbyHampshire213226201 213.33
WarrenLincoln213199229 213.67
VassalboroughLincoln213226202 213.67
SouthwickHampshire213226202 213.67
CharlemontHampshire170226248 214.67
WinthropLincoln170226248 214.67
WindhamCumberland213184248 215.00
WhatleyHampshire175226248 216.33
Table A9. Ninth decile.
Table A9. Ninth decile.
TownCountyStock in TradeSilverMoney LentTonnageIndex Number
W. StockbridgeBerkshire213189248 216.67
AdamsBerkshire213189248 216.67
BellinghamSuffolk213189248 216.67
DudleyWorcester213219219 217.00
OrangeHampshire204226221 217.00
S. BrimfieldHampshire170226235 217.00
N. GloucesterCumberland213226213 217.33
WendellHampshire213226216 218.33
BridgetonCumberland213226217 218.67
EgremontBerkshire183226248 219.00
CummingtonHampshire213226221 220.00
BrownfieldYork213204248 221.67
BecketBerkshire213221235 223.00
MonsonHampshire200226245 223.67
PearsontownCumberland213226234 224.33
AshfieldHampshire201226246 224.33
ChesterHampshire213223243 226.33
MontagueHampshire206226248 226.67
BalltownLincoln213226242 227.00
HancockLincoln208226248 227.33
N. AshfordBerkshire213226244 227.67
Table A10. Ninth decile, continued.
Table A10. Ninth decile, continued.
TownCountyMoney on Hand
TyringhamBerkshire16
GreenwichHampshire15
HancockBerkshire15
HollandHampshire12
BernardstownHampshire10
ChesterfieldHampshire10
WilliamsburghHampshire10
LoudounBerkshire10
GoshenHampshire8
BoxboroughMiddlesex8
LebanonYork8
ShutesburyHampshire8
W. HamptonHampshire7
LeverettHampshire7
Source note: These towns are ranked only by money on hand.
Table A11. Tenth decile.
Table A11. Tenth decile.
TownCountyMoney on Hand
WashingtonBerkshire6
FryeburghYork6
NorwichHampshire5
LeydenHampshire5
MontgomeryHampshire5
BucklandHampshire4
Little FallsYork4
RoweHampshire4
HeathHampshire4
BakerstonCumberland3
WaterboroYork3
RaymondstownCumberland3
ParsonfieldYork3
ShapleighYork3
BelfastLincoln2
LemingtonYork2
LewistonLincoln2
LimerickYork2
Mt. WashingtonBerkshire2
Note: These towns are ranked only by money on hand.
Table A12. Final group—towns with no commercial index data.
Table A12. Final group—towns with no commercial index data.
TownCounty
FrancisboroLincoln
Washington P.York
UnionLincoln
NorridgewalkLincoln
SheppardstownCumberland
Plan. No. 2 (22)Lincoln
GrayCumberland
CamdenLincoln
OtisfieldCumberland
WalesLincoln
Mt. DesertLincoln
Plan. No. 22 (21)Lincoln
Plan. No. 3 (22)Lincoln
Plan. No. 1 (23)Lincoln
Plan. No. 4 (24)Lincoln
Plan. No. 4 (25)Lincoln
Plan. No. 7 (26)Hampshire
Note: These towns have no recorded values for any of the commercial variables.

Appendix C. Social Scale

Appendix C provides the following information for Massachusetts’ 343 towns as of 1784: number of newspapers, years of publication, sessions of the Supreme Judicial Court, the Court of Common Pleas and General Sessions of the Peace, barristers present, number of lawyers, number of Congregational ministers, and the number of years that a town sent representatives to the lower chamber of the General Court.
The towns are assigned a point for each of the following: presence of a newspaper, sessions of any of the three courts listed, the residence of a barrister in 1786 or 1791, the presence of two or more lawyers in 1786 or 1791, the presence of a Congregational minister, whether or not a town sends a delegate to the lower chamber for 9 or more years between 1780 and 1791, and sending a delegate to the lower chamber for 6 or more years between 1780 and 1790. The points are then summed. Each town is placed into one of nine groups based on the total number of points; those towns with eight points are placed in group 1, and towns with zero points are placed in group 9.
Table A13. Suffolk County.
Table A13. Suffolk County.
Suffolk County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Boston1675Yes75131714141711I–8
Roxbury 101222211III–6
Dorchester 111111VI–3
Milton 111110V–4
Braintree 1134511V–4
Dedham 1243311IV–5
Weymouth 21210VI–3
Hingham 22211VI–3
Brookline 11110VI–3
Medfield 12219V–4
Stoughton 21211VI–3
Wrentham 22211VI–3
Cohasset 1117VII–2
Medway 122210VI–3
Walpole 0119VI–3
Sharon 1119VI–3
Franklin 11110VI–3
Hull 0IX–0
Chelsea 1114VIII–1
Dover 110VIII–1
Bellingham 116VII–2
Needham 1208VII–2
Foxboro 115VIII–1
Table A14. Essex County.
Table A14. Essex County.
Essex County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years) Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Salem414Yes101467711I–8
Newburyport18Yes221144411I–8
Ipswich Yes 144411IV–5
Beverly 1111211V–4
Marblehead 112339V–4
Gloucester 143311V–4
Andover 122211V–4
Haverhill 2144411IV–5
Danvers 22211VI–3
Newbury 43411VI–3
Lynn 32311VI–3
Bradford 12211VI–3
Rowley 23210VI–3
Salisbury 22211VI–3
Methuen 1118VII–2
Manchester 11 1VIII–1
Almsbury 22410VI–3
Topsfield 1117VII–2
Boxford 21210VI–3
Middleton 1110VIII–1
Wenham 1111VIII–1
Lynnfield 110VIII–1
Table A15. Plymouth County.
Table A15. Plymouth County.
Plymouth County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Plymouth12Yes 2222211IV–5
Bridgewater 146511V–4
Scituate 12311VI–3
Pembroke 122210V–4
Kingston 1 11110V–4
Middleborough 155410V–4
Marshfield 22211VI–3
Abington 11111VI–3
Duxborough 11110VI–3
Hanover 110117VI–3
Rochester 33111VI–3
Plympton 22111VI–3
Halifax 1114VIII–1
Wareham 114VIII–1
Table A16. Barnstable County.
Table A16. Barnstable County.
Barnstable County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Barnstable Yes11 22311IV–5
Sandwich 3229VI–3
Harwich 2219VI–3
Falmouth 2115VIII–1
Yarmouth 2226VII–2
Wellfleet 1117VII–2
Chatham 1117VII–2
Eastham 2227VII–2
Truro 1013VIII–1
Provincetown 1110VIII–1
Table A17. Bristol County.
Table A17. Bristol County.
Bristol County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Taunton Yes 4322111III–6
Dartmouth 53211VI–3
New Bedford 1 14V–4
Westport
Swansey Somerset 3327VII–2
Freetown 22 9VI–3
Norton 111011V–4
Dighton 2228VII–2
Rehoboth 58811VI–3
Berkely 1017VII–2
Attleboro 32311VI–3
Mansfield 1119VI–3
Easton 2119VI–3
Rainham 11110VI–3
Table A18. Nantucket County.
Table A18. Nantucket County.
Nantucket County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Shelburne Yes 2224VI–3
Edgartown Yes 1114VI–3
[Unintelligible] 1125VI–3
Table A19. Dukes County.
Table A19. Dukes County.
Dukes County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Tisbury Yes 3325VI–3
Table A20. Middlesex County.
Table A20. Middlesex County.
Middlesex County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Concord Yes 1211111III–6
Cambridge Yes 1124311IV–5
Charlestown13 211019III–6
Watertown 1111110V–4
Waltham 1111110V–4
Woburn 11 3310V–4
Newton 11 3310V–4
Medford 11110VI–3
Lexington 11110VI–3
Chelmsford 12111VI–3
Groton Yes 31119III–6
Marlborough 1110VI–3
Sudbury 11110VI–3
Framingham 11110V–3
Weston 111211V–4
Malden 21110VI–3
Westford 11 10VII–2
Sherburne 1118VII–2
Hopkinton 1118VII–2
Carlisle 119VI–3
Dunstable 0IX–0
Stow 1115VIII–1
Bedford 11111VIII–2
Reading 32311VI–3
Dracut 1119VI–3
Billerica 1 11110V–4
East Sudbury 11110VI–3
Lincoln 114VIII–1
Littleton 1117VII–2
Pepperell 1119VI–3
Tewksbury 1119VI–3
Shirley 1110VIII–1
Wilmington 1114VIII–1
Acton 1110VIII–1
Townshend 1117VII–2
Stoneham 110VIII–1
Holliston 1113VIII–1
Natick 1110VIII–1
Ashby 1 0IX–0
Boxboro 110VIII–1
Table A21. Worcester County.
Table A21. Worcester County.
Worcester County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Worcester315Yes112411211I–8
Lancaster 11 221111III–6
Rutland 111129V–4
Brookfield 2233311V–4
Sutton 43311VI–3
Bolton 1117VII–2
Lunenburg 11110VI–3
Uxbridge 1121 10V–4
Barre 11110VI–3
Westboro 1 18VII–2
Petersham 1211210IV–5
Grafton 22 9VI–3
Shrewsbury 21211VII–3
Northboro 1116VII–2
Leominster 2218VII–2
Sterling 118VII–2
Sturbridge 12110VI–3
Mendon 131110V–4
Hardwick 110110V–4
Leicester 3428VII–2
Harvard 1218VII–2
Southboro 111 110V–4
Spencer 11110VI–3
Westminster 1119VI–3
Paxton 1 06VII–2
Fitchburg 11118VI–3
Winchendon 101117VI–3
Princeton 1 8VIII–1
Templeton 1116VII–2
Milford 0114VIII–1
Oxford 1 19VI–3
Oakham 116VII–2
Western 1 16VII–2
Royalston 2129VI–3
Ashburnham 1114VIII–1
Northbridge 114VIII–1
Berlin 110VIII–1
Dudley 1117VII–2
Holden 1117VII–2
Ward 115VIII–1
Upton 1112VIII–1
Hubbardston 1113VIII–1
Athol 1 15VIII–1
Charlton 12211VI–3
Douglas 1116VII–2
New Braintree 2119VI–3
Table A22. Hampshire County.
Table A22. Hampshire County.
Hampshire County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Springfield28Yes22 232210I–8
Northampton16Yes21 211111I–8
Westfield 22 1210IV–5
Hadley 111119V–4
Deerfield 1 110VI–3
Northfield 11119V–4
West Springfield 1133310V–4
Hatfield 1119VI–3
Granville 1111VI–3
Amherst 11 1228VI–3
Belchertown 1228VII–2
South Hadley 1119VI–3
Greenfield 1118VII–2
Southampton 11110VI–3
Colrain 11210VI–3
Conway 11115VII–2
Worthington 1 19VI–3
Blandford 16VI–3
Pelham 1 6VII–2
Sunderland 11 6VII–2
Warwick 1216VII–2
Granby 1 1129VI–3
Southwick 11110VI–3
Shelburne 11 8VII–2
New Salem 2227VII–2
Ludlow 4IX–0
Wilbraham 1 1138VI–3
Whately 1122VIII–1
South Brimfield 2115VIII–1
Charlemont 1 6VIII–1
Montague 1126VII–2
Monson 1117VII–2
Palmer 1118VII–2
Chester 1117VII–2
Ashfield 2236VII–2
Cummington 1116VII–2
Ware 2IX–0
Middlefield 0IX–0
Rowe 10IX–0
Table A23. Berkshire County.
Table A23. Berkshire County.
Berkshire County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group & Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Pittsfield24Yes 1132210III–6
Stockbridge13 111222111II–7
Richmond 111VI–3
Sheffield 11111VI–3
Great Barrington Yes 11 1110IV–5
Lanesborough 12210VI–3
Williamstown 1111111V–4
Sandisfield 12211VI–3
Lenox Yes 11119IV–5
Windsor 1110VI–3
Lee 9VII–2
Egremont 11111VI–3
Alford 217VII–2
Dalton 0IX–0
Becket 11 8VII–2
Hancock 128VII–2
Washington 228VII–2
New Marlborough 110VII–2
Tyringham 1 110VI–3
New Ashford 0IX–0
Mount Washington 0IX–0
Loudoun 1IX–0
West Stockbridge 114VIII–1
Partridgefield 117VII–3
Adams 1111VI–3
Table A24. York County.
Table A24. York County.
York County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
York Yes 22210V–4
Pepperelboro 1119VI–3
Wells 23311VI–3
Kittery 34211VI–3
Berwick 1339VI–3
Biddeford Yes 11 116V–4
Arundel 1114VIII–1
Sandford 1 24VIII–1
Buxton 117VII–2
Coxhall 110VIII–1
Lebanon 1116VII–2
Freyburgh 1118VII–2
Brownfield 0IX–0
Massabeck 1 12VII–2
Limerick 0IX–0
Little Falls 0IX–0
Shapleigh 11IX–0
Little Ossipee 0IX–0
Table A25. Cumberland County.
Table A25. Cumberland County.
Cumberland County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Falmouth–Portland310Yes 2455511II–7
Scarborough 22210VI–3
North Yarmouth 1 19VI–3
Brunswick 11 3VIII–1
Harpswell 1224VIII–1
Cape Elizabeth 1115VIII–1
New Gloucester Yes 11118V–4
Royalsboro 0IX–0
Gorham 1118VII–2
Sylvester 10IX–0
Windham 1110VIII–1
Raymondstown 0IX–0
Bridgetown 10IX–0
Pearsontown 1 0IX–0
Bakerstown 0IX–0
Tray 11IX–0
Shepardstown 0IX–0
Table A26. Lincoln County.
Table A26. Lincoln County.
Lincoln County
NewspapersCourt SessionsBarristersLawyersMinistersReps in GC (Years)Group &
Points
Town#Yrs1786179117861791178017861791
Bowdoinham 112VIII–1
Winthrop 8VIII–1
Woolwich 1114VIII–1

Appendix D. Commercial–Cosmopolitan Gradient

Appendix D shows the commercial decile, social category, and total points for each of Massachusetts’ 343 towns. Each town is assigned one to ten points based on its commercial decile. Each town is assigned zero to eight points based on its social category. Based on each town’s score, the towns are assigned to one of three groups: towns with 13 points or more, group A; towns with 9 through 12 points, group B; towns with 8 or fewer points, group C.
Table A27. Suffolk County.
Table A27. Suffolk County.
Suffolk County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
BostonII18A
RoxburyIIII16A
MiltonIV14A
BraintreeIV14A
DedhamIIIV14A
DorchesterIVI13A
WeymouthIVI13A
HinghamIVI13A
BrooklineIIIVI11B
MedfieldIVV11B
StoughtonIIIVI11B
WrenthamIIIVI11B
CohassetIIVII11B
MedwayIVVI10B
WalpoleVVI9B
NeedhamIVVII9B
SharonVIVI8C
FranklinVIVI8C
FoxboroVVIII7C
DoverVIVIII6C
ChelseaVIIVIII5C
HullVIIX5C
BellinghamIXVII4C
Table A28. Essex County.
Table A28. Essex County.
Essex County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
SalemII18A
NewburyportII18A
IpswichIIV15A
BeverlyIV14A
MarbleheadIV14A
GloucesterIV14A
AndoverIV14A
HaverhillIIIV14A
DanversIVI13A
NewburyIVI13A
LynnIVI13A
SalisburyIIVI12B
BradfordIIIVI11B
RowleyIIIVI11B
AlmsburyIIIVI11B
MethuenIIIVII10B
ManchesterIIVIII10B
TopsfieldIVVII9B
BoxfordVIVI8C
LynnfieldVVIII7C
MiddletonVIVIII6C
WenhamVIIVIII5C
Table A29. Plymouth County.
Table A29. Plymouth County.
Plymouth County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
PlymouthIII17A
KingstonIV14A
BridgewaterIIV13A
ScituateIVI13A
PembrokeIIV13A
MiddleboroughIIV13A
MarshfieldIVI13A
AbingtonIIVI12B
DuxboroughIVVI10B
HanoverIVVI10B
RochesterIVVI10B
PlymptonVIVI8C
HalifaxVVIII7C
WarehamVVIII7C
Table A30. Bristol County.
Table A30. Bristol County.
Bristol County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
TauntonIIIII15A
DartmouthIV14A
SwanseyIVII12B
FreetownIIVI12B
NortonIVV11B
RehobothIIIVI11B
DightonIIIVII10B
RainhamIVVI10B
BerkleyIIIVII10B
AttleboroVVI9B
MansfieldVVI9B
EastonVVI9B
Table A31. Barnstable County.
Table A31. Barnstable County.
Barnstable County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
BarnstableIIV13A
SandwichIVI13A
HarwichIIIVI11B
FalmouthIIVIII10B
YarmouthIIIVII10B
WellfleetVVII8C
ChathamVIVII7C
EasthamVIVII7C
ProvincetownVIIX5C
TruroVIIIVIII4C
Table A32. Nantucket County.
Table A32. Nantucket County.
Nantucket County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
SherburneIVI13A
EdgartownIIVI12B
TisburyIIIVI11B
ChilmarkIVVII9B
Table A33. Middlesex County.
Table A33. Middlesex County.
Middlesex County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
ConcordIIII16A
CharlestownIIII16A
CambridgeIIV15A
WaltertownIV14A
WalthamIIV13A
WoburnIIV13A
NewtonIIV13A
MedfordIVI13A
GrotonIVIII13A
LexingtonIIVI12B
ChemlsfordIIVI12B
MarlboroughIIVI12B
FraminghamIIIVI11B
WestonIVV11B
WestfordIIIVI11B
SudburyIVVI10B
MaldenIVVI10B
HopkintonIIIVI10B
BillericaVV10B
SherburneIVVII9B
DunstableIIIX9B
StowVVII8C
BedfordVVII8C
ReadingVIVI8C
DracutVIVI8C
East SudburyVVII8C
LittletonVVII8C
LincolnVVIII7C
PepperillVIIVI7C
TewksburyVIIVI7C
CarlisleVIVI8C
ShirleyVIVIII6C
ActonVIVIII6C
TownsendVIIVII6C
HollistonVIVIII6C
WillmingtonVIIVIII5C
StonehamVIIVIII5C
NatickVIIIVIII5C
AshbyVIIIX4C
BoxboroIXVIII3C
Table A34. Worcester County.
Table A34. Worcester County.
Worcester County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
WorcesterII18A
LancasterIIII16A
RutlandIV14A
BrookfieldIIIV14A
PetershamIIIIV13A
SuttonIIIVI11B
BoltonIIVII11B
LunenbergIIIVI11B
BarreIIIVI11B
UxbridgeVV10B
WestboroIIIVII10B
GraftonIVVI10B
ShrewsburyIVVI10B
SturbridgeIVVI10B
MendonVV10B
NorthboroIVVII9B
LeoministerIIIVII10B
HardwickVV10B
SterlingIVVII9B
SpencerVVI9B
WestministerVVI9B
LeicesterIVVII9B
SouthboroVIV9B
HarvardVVII8C
OxfordVVII8C
PaxtonVIVII7C
FitchburghVIIVI7C
PrincetonVVIII7C
OakhamVIVII7C
New BraintreeVIIVI7C
WinchendonVIIIVI6C
TempletonVIIVII6C
MilfordVIVIII6C
WesternVIIVII6C
RoyalstonVIIIVI6C
NorthbridgeVIVIII6C
BerlinVIVIII6C
DouglasVIIVII6C
AshburhamVIIVIII5C
HoldenVIIIVII5C
WardVIIIVIII4C
UptonVIIIVIII4C
HubbardstownVIIIVIII4C
AtholVIIIVIII4C
CharltonVIIVI6C
DudleyIXVII4C
Table A35. Hampshire County.
Table A35. Hampshire County.
Hampshire County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
SpringfieldII18A
NorthamptonIII17A
WestfieldIIIV14A
HadleyIIV13A
DeerfieldIIVI12B
NorthfieldIIIV12B
West SpringfieldIIIV12B
HatfieldIIVI12B
GranvilleIIIVI11B
AmherstIVV11B
BelchertownVVII8C
South HadleyVIVI8C
WilbrahamVIVI8C
South HamptonVIVI8C
BrimfieldVIIV8C
ConwayVIVII7C
GreenfieldVIVII7C
ColerainVIIVI7C
BlandfordVIVIII6C
SunderlandVIIVII6C
WarwickVIIVII6C
GranbyVIIIVI6C
SouthwickVIIIVI6C
Long MeadowVIVIII6C
WorthingtonVIIIVI5C
PelhamVIIVIII5C
ShelburneVIIIVII5C
New SalemVIIIVII5C
PalmerVIIIVII5C
LudlowVIIIX4C
WhatleyVIIIVIII4C
CharlemontVIIIVIII4C
MontagueIXVII4C
MonsonIXVII4C
ChesterIXVII4C
AshfieldIXVII4C
CummingtonIXVII4C
South BrimfieldIXVIII4C
WareVIIIIX3C
WilliamsburghIXVII4C
ChesterfieldIXVII4C
MiddlefieldVIIIIX3C
WendellIXVIII3C
GreenwichIXVIII3C
BernardstownIXVIII3C
ShutesburyIXVIII3C
West HamptonIXVIII3C
HollandIXVIII3C
NorwichXVIII2C
RoweXVIII2C
LeverettIXIX2C
GoshenIXIX2C
OrangeIXIX2C
LeydenXIX1C
BucklandXIX1C
HeathXIX1C
MontogomeryXIX1C
Plan. No. 7XIX1C
Table A36. Berkshire County.
Table A36. Berkshire County.
Berkshire County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
StockbridgeIIII16A
PittsfieldIIIIII14A
Great BarringtonIVIV12B
RichmondIIIVI11B
SheffieldIIIVI11B
LanesboroIIIVI11B
WilliamstownVV10B
SandisfieldVVI9B
LenoxVIIIIV8C
WindsorVIIVI6C
DaltonVIX6C
LeeVIIIVII5C
EgremontIXVI5C
AlfordVIIIVII5C
New MarlboroVIIIVII5C
PartridgefieldVIIIVII5C
AdamsIXVI5C
BecketIXVII4C
HancockIXVII4C
TyringhamIXVI5C
West StockbridgeIXVIII3C
WashingtonXVII3C
New AshfordIXIX2C
LoudounIXIX2C
Mount WashingtonXIX1C
Table A37. York County.
Table A37. York County.
York County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
YorkIIV13A
BerwickIIVI12B
PepperelboroIIIVI11B
WellsIIIVI11B
KitteryIIIVI11B
BiddefordIVV11B
ArundelIVVIII8C
SandfordVVIII7C
BuxtonVIIVII6C
CoxhallVIIVIII5C
LebanonIXVII4C
FryeburghXVII3C
MassebecXVII3C
BrownfieldIXIX2C
ParsonfieldXIX1C
LimerickXIX1C
Washington Plan.XIX1C
Little FallsXIX1C
ShapleighXIX1C
Francisboro Plan.XIX1C
Little OssippeeXIX1C
Table A38. Cumberland County.
Table A38. Cumberland County.
Cumberland County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
FalmouthIIII16A
ScarboroughIIVI12B
North YarmouthIVVI10B
BrunswickIVVIII8C
HarpswellIVVIII8C
Cape ElizabethVVIII7C
RoyalsboroVIX6C
GorhamVIIVII6C
New GloucesterIXV6C
WindhamVIIIVIII4C
BridgetownIXIX2C
SylvesterVIIIIX3C
PearsontownIXIX2C
BakerstownXIX1C
GrayXIX1C
SheppardstownXIX1C
Otisfield Plan.XIX1C
RaymondstownXIX1C
Table A39. Lincoln County.
Table A39. Lincoln County.
Lincoln County
TownCommercial DecileSocial CategoryTotal PointsComm-Cosmo Category
PownalboroughIIIIV13A
HallowellIIVI12B
GeorgetownIVVI10B
MichiasIVVI10B
BoothbayIIIVIII9B
BristolIVVIII8C
PittstonIVVIII8C
BathIVIX7C
New CastleIVVIII8C
WaldoboroughVVIII7C
Plan. No. 32IVIX7C
Plan. No. 13VIX6C
BowdoinhamVIVIII6C
Deer IslandVIX6C
EdgecombVIIX5C
WalpoleVIIX5C
TopshamVIIVIII5C
WoolwichVIIVIII5C
Plan. No. 25VIIX5C
Fox IslandVIIX5C
Penobscot Lon I.VIIIX4C
Plan. No. 57VIIIX4C
ThomastownVIIIVIII4C
WinslowVIIIVIII4C
WinthropVIIIVIII4C
St. George’sVIIIX4C
Plan. No. 29VIIIX4C
Plan. No. 610VIIIX4C
Plan. No. 611VIIIX4C
Plan. No. 512VIIIX4C
Plan. W. Side13VIIIX4C
MeduncockVIIIX4C
VassalboroughVIIIIX3C
CananVIIIIX3C
WarrenVIIIIX3C
BalltownIXIX2C
HancockIXIX2C
Plan. No. 114XIX1C
Mount DesertXIX1C
Plan. No. 22XIX1C
BelfastXIX1C
WalesXIX1C
NorridgewalkXIX1C
Plan. No. 217XIX1C
CamdenXIX1C
LewistonXIX1C
Plan. No. 318XIX1C
SterlingtonXIX1C
Plan. No. 420XIX1C
Plan. No. 421XIX1C

Notes

1
For more on the cultural and economic milieu of Shays’s Rebellion in historical context, see Parker (1991), Richards (2003), Smith (1948), Starkey (1955), and Szatmary (1980)
2
The “District of Maine”, as it was known prior to 1820, was a territory that pertained to the Commonwealth of Massachusetts until 1820, at which point it became the independent state of Maine (Williamson 1832, pp. 658–79).
3
The gradient(s) and original data referred to here are replicated and adapted from the work of Professor Van Beck Hall, Department of History, University of Pittsburgh (Hall 1972).
4
Many of the residents of the group A towns were involved in the creation of the 1780 state constitution and were also involved in the founding of the nascent nation and were active as Whigs during the colonial era.
5
“Polls” refers to eligible voters. In this context, eligible voters are white, male, property holders. Other voting qualifications, such as poll taxes, asset value minimums, and tax status, are often on the books but are rarely enforced (Pole 1957). I also want to acknowledge Dr. Charles H. Stewart, Department of Political Science, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Dr. Stewart provided invaluable help and discussion about polls in the early American context.
6
All of these men, with the exception of Lincoln, were major Whig figures prior to independence.
7
When adjusted for inflation and converted to United States Dollars, £ 1000 = U S D 230 , 186.06 .
8
Justice Sullivan did not graduate from Harvard College.
9
Primary source information regarding the financial dealings of the justices is found in the unpublished Interest Payment Books in the archives of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts. Additional primary source information is found in Fleet (1789) Register for the years 1780–1791. This information is compiled in Hall (1972), footnote no.54.
10
While there were no formal political parties in 1780s Massachusetts, there were two vague, informal, political factions: Federalists and Antifederalists. These factions did not resemble formal political parties at all. Federalists tended to be those who supported a strong central government and a strong judiciary; Federalists tended to be from group A towns. Antifederalists supported local governance and a weak central government. Antifederalists tended to be from group C towns.
11
Common private academies in the group A towns are the Roxbury Latin School, Phillips Academy Andover, and the Governor’s Academy.
12
A minority of the 77% graduate from Yale College, effectively the same in terms of its effect on reproducing social stratification.
13
Machias, Massachusetts is the site of the only Masonic lodge outside of the group A towns.
14
Additional academic, scientific, and charitable associations are: Massachusetts Historical Society, Massachusetts Humane Society, Society to Propagate the Gospel, Scots Charitable Society, Massachusetts Congregational Society. For primary source information see Fleet (1789). The compiled information may be found in Hall (1972).
15
The president of the Massachusetts Agricultural Society was Thomas Russell, a leading financier; John Lowell, a respected merchant, served as vice president; Moses Gill, a judge with significant commercial activities, also served as vice president (Hall 1972, p. 76).
16
A rateable poll is a taxpaying, landowning, adult white male that is also eligible to vote.
17
Later in 1787, the state legislature authorizes £40,000 for paying for the mercenary army and for reimbursing the donations of Boston businessmen.
18
Commercial stagecoaches are able to move more quickly because they can drive the horses harder over a shorter distance. This is because commercial stagecoach companies set up predetermined stops where the horses are changed out for fresh horses. The ability to change out tired horses for fresh horses allows commercial stage coaches to move more quickly.
19
Weather is a significant source of delay and obstruction to travel in New England, as anyone who has spent any considerable time in New England will know.
20
There is no method to clear the paths of snow in the 1780s. Travelers had to wait until conditions allowed for travel.
21
Using the calculation that a commercial stagecoach could travel 60 km on a well worn path in 24 h, then 20 km should take 8 h. However, most common men don’t often travel by commercial stagecoach on well worn paths, rather, he travels using his own horse(s) and carriage on lesser known and less maintained paths, thus adding more travel time.
22
As has been previously noted, such rules on voting are rarely enforced. The formal expansion of the franchise is symbolic.
23
Respectively, and when adjusted for inflation and converted to United States Dollars: £ 40 = $ 9206.16 ; £ 2 = $ 460.30 .
24
When adjusted for inflation and converted to United States Dollars: £ 100 = $ 23 , 015.40
25
Source: map reproduced from Hall (1972, pp. 10–11).
26
The Rhode Island judiciary is granted independent and coequal status in 2004 (Gerber 2011).
27
Map from the Library of Congress, Geography and Map Division. Public domain.
28
Source: Lemons (2020). By courtesy of Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc., copyright 2009; used with permission.
29
Rhode Island post offices: East Greenwich, Newport, Providence (x2), Tower Hill (now known as South Kingston), Warren, and Westerly. Sources on post offices in 1780s Rhode Island: United States Postal Service (2019a), United States Postal Service (2019b), Gallagher (1977), and Merolla et al. (1977).
30
See The Providence Gazette and Country Journal [emphasis added].
31
In Hampshire and Berkshire counties, the epicenter of Shays’s Rebellion, a great many polls are disenfranchised because of their participation in the armed insurrection. Those charged with crimes pertaining to insurrection are legally barred from voting. This explains the less spectacular increase in voter turnout in Hampshire and Berkshire counties when compared to Bristol and Plymouth counties.

References

  1. Abstract of the Report of the Committee on the Valuation. 1793. Abstract of the report of the committee on the valuation. [Google Scholar]
  2. Acts and Laws. 1780–1797. Acts and Laws of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts. [Google Scholar]
  3. Acts and Resolves. 1782. Acts and Resolves of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts, 1780–1781.
  4. Aries, Elizabeth, and Maynard Seider. 2007. The Role of Social Class in the Formation of Identity: A Study of Public and Elite Private College Students. The Journal of Social Psychology 147: 137–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Bachrach, Peter, and Morton S. Baratz. 1962. Two Faces of Power. The American Political Science Review 56: 947–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Brigham, Clarence S. 1947. History and Bibliography of American Newspapers. Worcester: American Antiquarian Society. [Google Scholar]
  7. Bureau of the Census. 1908. Heads of Families at the First Census of the United States Taken in the Year 1790. Technical Report. Suitland: U.S. Bureau of the Census. [Google Scholar]
  8. Cain, Michael J. G., and Keith L. Dougherty. 2016. Suppressing Shays’ Rebellion. Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 233–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Condon, Sean. 2015. Shays’s Rebellion: Authority and Distress in Post-Revolutionary America. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. [Google Scholar]
  10. Cushing, John D. 1960. A Revolutionary Conservative: The Public Life of William Cushing, 1732–1810. Ph.D. Thesis, Clark University, Worcester, MA, USA. [Google Scholar]
  11. Cushing, John D. 1965. The Judiciary and Public Opinion in Revolutionary Massachusetts. In Law and Authority in Colonial America: Selected Essays. Barre: Barre Publishers, pp. 168–86. [Google Scholar]
  12. Cushing, John D. 1969. Notes on Disestablishment in Massachusetts, 1780–1833. The William and Mary Quarterly: A Magazine of Early American History 26: 170–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Fleet, John. 1779–1789. Fleet’s Pocket Almanack for the Year of Our Lord [1780–1790]...to Which Is Annexed the Massachusetts Register. Boston: T&J Fleet. [Google Scholar]
  14. Fleet, John. 1786. Fleet’s Pocket Almanack for the Year of our Lord. Boston: T&J Fleet. [Google Scholar]
  15. Fleet, John. 1792. Fleet’s Pocket Almanack for the Year of Our Lord. Boston: T&J Fleet. [Google Scholar]
  16. Fleet, John. 1793. Fleet’s Pocket Almanack for the Year of our Lord. Boston: T&J Fleet. [Google Scholar]
  17. Gallagher, John S. 1977. The Post Offices of Rhode Island. Burtonsville: The Depot. [Google Scholar]
  18. Gerber, Scott Douglas. 2011. A Distinct Judicial Power: The Origins of an Independent Judiciary, 1606–1787. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  19. Greene, Evarts B., and Virginia D. Harrington. 1932. American Population Before the Federal Census of 1790. New York: Columbia University Press. [Google Scholar]
  20. Hall, Van Beck. 1972. Politics Without Parties: Massachusetts, 1780–1791. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. [Google Scholar]
  21. Hough, Franklin Benjamin. 1872. American Constitutions. 2 vols, New York: Weed, Parsons. [Google Scholar]
  22. Johnson, Allen, and Dumas Malone. 1928–1944. Dictionary of American Biography. 22 vols, New York: Scribner’s Sons. [Google Scholar]
  23. Karen, David. 1991. Achievement and Ascription in Admission to an Elite College: A Political-Organizational Analysis. Sociological Forum 6: 349–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Lane, Robert E. 1965. The politics of Consensus in an Age of Affluence. The American Political Science Review 59: 874–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Lemons, J. Stanley. 2020. “Rhode island”. Encyclopedia Britannica. Available online: https://www.britannica.com/place/Rhode-Island-state (accessed on 20 December 2024).
  26. Library of Congress. Eighteenth-Century American Newspapers in the Library of Congress. Available online: https://guides.loc.gov/united-states-newspapers/18th-century (accessed on 20 December 2024).
  27. Martin, Nathan D. 2009. Social Capital, Academic Achievement, and Postgraduation Plans at an Elite, Private University. Sociological Perspectives 52: 185–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Matthew, Alberts. 1910. Lists of New England Magazines of the Eighteenth Century. Beaumont: J. Wilson. [Google Scholar]
  29. Merolla, Lawrence, Frank Crowther, and Arthur B. Jackson. 1977. Rhode Island Postal History: The Post Offices. Rhode Island: Rhode Island Postal History Society. [Google Scholar]
  30. Parker, Rachel R. 1991. Shays’ Rebellion: An Episode in American State-Making. Sociological Perspectives 34: 95–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Peirce, Bradford Kinney, and Charles Hale. 1856. Debates and Proceedings in the Convention of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts, Held in the Year 1788, and Which Finally Ratified the Constitution of the United States. Boston: Authority of Resolves of the Legislature. [Google Scholar]
  32. Pencak, William. 1989. Samuel Adams and Shays’s Rebellion. The New England Quarterly 62: 63–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Persell, Caroline Hodges, and Peter W. Cookson, Jr. 1985. Chartering and bartering: Elite education and social reproduction. Social Problems 33: 114–129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Pole, Jack R. 1957. Suffrage and Representation in Massachusetts: A Statistical Note. The William and Mary Quarterly: A Magazine of Early American History 14: 560–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Richards, Leonard L. 2003. Shays’s Rebellion: The American Revolution’s Final Battle. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. [Google Scholar]
  36. Secretary of State. 1780. Journal of the House of Representatives. Boston: Commonwealth of Massachusetts. [Google Scholar]
  37. Smith, Jonathan. 1948. The depression of 1785 and daniel shays’ rebellion. The William and Mary College Quarterly 5: 77–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Soja, Edward W. 1971. The Political Organization of Space: Resource Paper No. 8. Washington: Association of American Geographers. [Google Scholar]
  39. Starkey, Marion L. 1955. A Little Rebellion. New York: Knopf. [Google Scholar]
  40. Szatmary, David P. 1980. Shays’ Rebellion: The Making of an Agrarian Insurrection. Amherst: University of Massachusetts Press. [Google Scholar]
  41. Taylor, Robert Joseph. 1954. Western Massachusetts in the Revolution. Providence: Brown University Press. [Google Scholar]
  42. Thorpe, Francis Newton. 1909. The Federal and State Constitutions, Colonial Charters, and Other Organic Laws of the State, Territories, and Colonies Now or Heretofore Forming the United States of America: Kentucky; Massachusetts. 3 vols, Washington: US Government Printing Office. [Google Scholar]
  43. U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1960. Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1957. Technical Report. Suitland: U.S. Census Bureau. [Google Scholar]
  44. United States Postal Service. 2019a. First U.S. Post Offices. Available online: https://about.usps.com/who-we-are/postal-history/first-post-offices-sources.pdf (accessed on 20 December 2024).
  45. United States Postal Service. 2019b. First U.S. Post Offices by State. Available online: https://about.usps.com/who-we-are/postal-history/first-post-offices.pdf (accessed on 20 December 2024).
  46. Warren, Joseph Parker. 1905. The Confederation and the Shays Rebellion. The American Historical Review 11: 42–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Williamson, William D. 1832. The History of the State of Maine: From Its First Discovery, A.D. 1602, to the Separation, A.D. 1820, Inclusive. 2 vols, Hallowell: Glazier, Masters & Company. [Google Scholar]
  48. Wroth, L. Kinvin, and Hiller B. Zobel, eds. 1965. The Legal Papers of John Adams. 3 vols, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
  49. Zagarri, Rosemarie. 1987. The Politics of Size: Representation in the United States, 1776–1850. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. [Google Scholar]
  50. Zaller, John. 1984. The Role of Elites in Shaping Public Opinion. Berkeley: University of California. [Google Scholar]
  51. Zaller, John. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
Table 1. Number of towns by region.
Table 1. Number of towns by region.
Towns Eastern RegionWestern RegionMaineTotal
Group A3120354
Group B35421188
Group C1910775201
Total 8516989343
Note: Eastern Massachusetts includes Barnstable, Bristol, Dukes, Essex, Nantucket, Plymouth, and Suffolk counties. Western Massachusetts includes Berkshire, Hampshire, Middlesex, and Worcester counties. Maine (then legally part of Massachusetts) includes Cumberland, Lincoln, and York counties.
Table 2. Commercial wealth by town groups.
Table 2. Commercial wealth by town groups.
GroupInventoryTonnageMoney on HandValue of Enterprises
Group A92.7%81.384.850.6
Group B5.510.78.625.1
Group C1.77.96.524.3
Table 3. Percentage of polls by region, 1784.
Table 3. Percentage of polls by region, 1784.
GroupEastern Mass.Western Mass.MaineTotal
Group A24.9%7.61.834.3
Group B1314.14.631.7
Group C3.621.78.734
Total41.543.415.1100
Sources: Primary source information is found in Tax Valuation Lists, from Acts and Laws (1797, 1:903–906) and Abstract of the Report of the Committee on the Valuation (1793, pp. 1–13). Compilation of primary source information is found in Hall (1972).
Table 4. Holders of major offices, 1780–1791.
Table 4. Holders of major offices, 1780–1791.
FromGovernorLt. GovernorSupreme Court JusticesPresident of SenateSpeaker of HouseConfederation CongressNational CongressGovernor’s Council
Group A100%10010010091846962
Group B00009163120
Group C000000018
Harvard Alumni1009194n/an/a7977n/a
Sources: Primary source information is found in Johnson and Malone (1944), Acts and Laws (1797), and the Legal Papers of John Adams (Wroth and Zobel 1965). Further information regarding the residence of state leaders is found in Fleet (1789). Additional information regarding the Supreme Court is found in Cushing (1960). Compilation of the information is found in Hall (1972, pp. 63–68).
Table 5. Percentage of polls, lawyers, court sessions, and justices, 1786.
Table 5. Percentage of polls, lawyers, court sessions, and justices, 1786.
GroupsPolls (1784) LawyersCourt Sessions (1786–1791)Total Justices
Group A34%846447
Group B32131828
Group C3441825
Note: Total justices refers to justices of the peace and justices of the quorum (i.e., justices of the peace). Sources: Population figures are found in Bureau of the Census (1908), and number of polls are in the tax valuation lists for 1784 and 1786 found in Secretary of State (1780, vol. 163). Information regarding judges of the common pleas is found in Fleet (1789). Partial compilation of this information is found in Hall (1972).
Table 6. Percentage of terms of judges on the Court of Common Pleas, 1780–1791.
Table 6. Percentage of terms of judges on the Court of Common Pleas, 1780–1791.
GroupsPolls (1784)% of Terms in Common Pleas
Group A34%52
Group B3235
Group C3413
Note: For information regarding polls, see source information in Table 3. Information regarding judges of the Court of Common Pleas is found in the 1787 edition of Fleet (1789). Partial compilation of this information is found in Hall (1972).
Table 7. Percentage of towns with at least one minister present, 1780–1791.
Table 7. Percentage of towns with at least one minister present, 1780–1791.
GroupAt Least One Minister
Group A100%
Group B97%
Group C69%
Note: Primary source information regarding ministers and minister residences is found in the 1787 edition, pp. 51–57, of Fleet (1789). Information is partially compiled in Hall (1972).
Table 8. Types of ministers by denomination, 1780–1791.
Table 8. Types of ministers by denomination, 1780–1791.
GroupCongregational OnlyCongregational & OtherNon-Congregational Only
Group A57%43%0%
Group B60%33%3%
Group C52%10%7%
Note: See source information provided in previous table.
Table 9. Allocation of Senate seats.
Table 9. Allocation of Senate seats.
Regions% of Population% of Polls% of Seats Allotted
Eastern40%42%50%
Western40%43%40%
Maine20%15%10%
Note: Primary source information regarding the apportionment of senators is found in Thorpe (1909) and Acts and Laws (1797). This information is partially compiled in Hall (1972).
Table 10. Senate composition.
Table 10. Senate composition.
Groups% of Population% of Senate Seats% Served as Judges
Group A33%47%23%
Group B29%38%39%
Group C39%16%38%
Note: Primary source information regarding population is found in Bureau of the Census (1908). Information regarding Senate apportionment is in Acts and Laws (1797) and Thorpe (1909). This information is partially compiled in Hall (1972).
Table 11. House composition, 1780–1791.
Table 11. House composition, 1780–1791.
Groups% of Polls% of Members% of Justices
Group A34%3352
Group B323433
Group C343325
Note: Percentage of polls refers to the share of total polls in that particular group of towns. Percentage of members refers to the share of the total House composed of members from that group. Percentage of justices refers to the share of representatives from that group who also held judicial office. Sources: Primary source information is found in Acts and Laws (1797). Additional information is found in Greene and Harrington (1932). A compilation is found in Hall (1972).
Table 12. Periodicals and post offices, 1780–1791.
Table 12. Periodicals and post offices, 1780–1791.
GroupNewspapersMagazinesPost Offices (1786)Post Offices (1791)
Group A100%10010070
Group B00013
Group C00017
Note: Sources for the following: Information regarding newspapers is found in Brigham (1947). Information regarding magazines is found in Matthew (1910). Information regarding post offices is found in Fleet (1793, p. 63) and Fleet (1786, pp. 51–52). Compilation of this information is found in Hall (1972).
Table 13. Percentage of towns with representatives by length of time, 1780–1791.
Table 13. Percentage of towns with representatives by length of time, 1780–1791.
Group9–11 Yrs.6–8 Yrs.0–5 Yrs.
Group A98%20
Group B70246
Group C142561
Note: Length of political involvement refers to the percentage of towns that sent representatives to the General Court for a certain number of years. Sources: Primary source information is found in the tax valuations for 1784 and 1786, recorded in Acts and Laws (1797) and compiled in Hall (1972).
Table 14. Polarization in roll call votes, 1780–1786.
Table 14. Polarization in roll call votes, 1780–1786.
Towns12345678910
Group A58%768078777580604869
Group B23394546514247301346
Group C29324242424733242034
Total37545858595454382649
Note: The numbers correspond to the 19 roll call votes for which there was no consensus. The 19 bills were enumerated and are described in Appendix A, which also contains information regarding sources. All roll call votes for this table are reported as percentages of “yes” votes, except where indicated otherwise in Appendix A (reported as percentage of “no” votes).
Table 15. Percentage of representatives voting against two pro-elite roll call votes.
Table 15. Percentage of representatives voting against two pro-elite roll call votes.
TownsDebt Consolidation BillExcise Tax Bill
Western Group A33%31
Western Group B5977
Western Group C7378
Total6169
Note: The percentages listed show the proportion of Representatives opposed to the measures proposed. The first roll call vote refers to the Consolidation Act of January 1781, consolidating the Commonwealth’s debt and refunding it at a higher rate of interest, to the advantage of elites. The second refers to the Excise Tax Bill of March 1785, proposing an excise tax to help meet Continental government expenses. Both measures were strongly favored by commercial–cosmopolitan interests and opposed by others. Sources: Primary information is found in Secretary of State (1780). Compilation appears in Hall (1972, pp. 168–70).
Table 16. Voting of dual representative justices on the same two roll call votes.
Table 16. Voting of dual representative justices on the same two roll call votes.
GroupDebt Consolidation BillExcise Tax Bill
Western Group A50%25
Western Group B5667
Western Group C5070
Total5256
Note: See note for Table 15 for bill descriptions and sources.
Table 17. Voting of All Other Representatives on Same Two Roll Call Votes.
Table 17. Voting of All Other Representatives on Same Two Roll Call Votes.
GroupDebt Consolidation BillExcise Tax Bill
Western Group A22%50
Western Group B6983
Western Group C7882
Total6478
Note: See note for Table 15 for bill descriptions and sources.
Table 18. Votes against the extension of debt stay measures, 1786 and 1787.
Table 18. Votes against the extension of debt stay measures, 1786 and 1787.
Group17861787Change
Group A68%58 10
Group B2636 + 10
Group C3126 5
Note: Primary source information is found in Peirce (1856, pp. 87–92). Roll call vote information is drawn from Secretary of State (1780, 1786:294–295) and Secretary of State (1780, 1787:367). Compiled and aggregated data is presented in Hall (1972, pp. 270–2).
Table 19. Comparative basics for Massachusetts and Rhode Island, c. 1780.
Table 19. Comparative basics for Massachusetts and Rhode Island, c. 1780.
VariablesMassachusettsRhode Island
Size119,010 sq. km3144 sq. km
Population317,76052,946
Newspapers357
Note: The size of Massachusetts circa 1785 included the district of Maine, which remained part of Massachusetts until 1820. Population estimates are based on 1780 modeling projects found in chapter Z, “Colonial and Pre-Federal Statistics” of U.S. Bureau of the Census (1960). Additional sources: U.S. Bureau of the Census (1960); Lemons (2020). The number of Rhode Island newspapers (7) is based on publications operating between 1780 and 1791, including the Gazette Francoise, The Newport Herald, The Newport Mercury (Newport), The American Journal, The Providence Gazette and Country Journal, The Providence Journal, and the United States Chronicle (Providence). Sources for newspapers and post offices: Library of Congress (n.d.); United States Postal Service (2019a); United States Postal Service (2019b); Gallagher (1977); Merolla et al. (1977).
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Baldwin, E.A. Popular Sovereignty, Shays’s Rebellion, and Populism in Early New England. Histories 2025, 5, 26. https://doi.org/10.3390/histories5020026

AMA Style

Baldwin EA. Popular Sovereignty, Shays’s Rebellion, and Populism in Early New England. Histories. 2025; 5(2):26. https://doi.org/10.3390/histories5020026

Chicago/Turabian Style

Baldwin, Eric A. 2025. "Popular Sovereignty, Shays’s Rebellion, and Populism in Early New England" Histories 5, no. 2: 26. https://doi.org/10.3390/histories5020026

APA Style

Baldwin, E. A. (2025). Popular Sovereignty, Shays’s Rebellion, and Populism in Early New England. Histories, 5(2), 26. https://doi.org/10.3390/histories5020026

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop