1. Introduction
Collective risk theory has built upon the pioneering work of Filip Lundberg [
1] and it concerns itself with the study the riskiness of an insurer’s reserve as measured by the ruin probability and related quantities [
2]. A large amount of literature now exists on such insolvency measures for a wide variety of models, the latest being the so-called Lévy insurance risk models [
3,
4].
Traditionally, collective risk theory focuses on the insurer’s ability to manage the solvency of its reserve through the control of initial investment x. The mathematical tool often cited for such task is the probability of ruin. It is indeed a measure of the likelihood that an insurer’s reserve would eventually be insufficient to cover its liabilities in the long run.
More precisely, consider the following general model for the risk reserve of an insurance company,
where the aggregate claims process
X is a spectrally positive Lévy process with zero drift, with
and jump measure denoted by
ν. Moreover,
x is the initial reserve level and
c is a constant premium rate defined as
where
is the security loading factor.
Then the associated ruin time is
and the
infinite-horizon ruin probability can be defined by
where
is short-hand notation for
.
Much of the literature in collective risk theory studies the problem of deriving expressions and reasonable approximations for the probability of ruin as a function of the initial reserve level
x. This problem is addressed within an ever-growing set of models for the aggregate claims process. See [
2] for a thorough account on the so-called ruin theory.
Within this framework, we engage our discussion from a risk management stand-point and with a capital allocation application in mind. Naturally, the ruin probability
ψ quantifies the solvency of the net-loss process
as a function of the initial reserve level
x. In fact, we can define a risk measure
on a suitable model space
(say the space of bounded càdlàg stochastic processes
). Let
be the net-loss process associated with the reserve process (
1), then
where
ψ is the associated ruin probability (
4) and
represents a given tolerance to ruin.
One can interpret
a as the smallest initial level for which the process
R has an acceptable risk level, i.e., its associated ruin probability is less or equal to a tolerable figure
β. Such risk measures have been recently studied (see [
5]) and although they exhibit interesting properties, they lack the tractability of an efficient risk management tool. In fact, any meaningful risk management application, such as capital allocation, would be hard to implement using (
5). Recently, other risk measures have been studied such as one based on the concept of
area in red, which is a measure of how large the overall deficit of the company can be (see [
6] for details). These new notions turn out to exhibit some interesting properties, yet the issue with these risk measures remains, they are very difficult to implement in a risk management problem such as capital allocation.
In this paper, we recover this idea of measuring the risk of an insurance risk process but with a view towards an application in the capital allocation problem. In fact, we reverse-engineer a risk measure with the sole purpose of addressing the non-trivial problem of capital allocation in a collective risk theory context. That is, we look at the aggregate loss from a number of, potentially dependent, lines of business and we give a way to allocate a portion of the overall risk to each component. More precisely, we define a coherent risk measure on a suitable subspace of the space of càdlàg processes,
, as a mapping
(the precise description of the subspace in question,
, is given in Definition 1). Unlike (
5), this measure is tractable enough and allows for a solution of the capital allocation problem within a suitable space of stochastic processes. This is carried out within the framework given by the theory of coherent and convex risk measures for stochastic processes. As it turns out, the problem of capital allocation for risk measures on the space of stochastic processes is a non-trivial one. In this paper we devise an ad-hoc risk measure for which the problem can be addressed. We ultimately give a definition of what we mean by capital allocation in this context and give an explicit solution for it. We also discuss connections between our approach and existing alternative solutions in the literature such as [
7].
The outline of the paper is as follows. In
Section 2, we give a brief literature review on the problem of capital allocation and risk measures for stochastic processes, thus giving a context to our contribution. In
Section 3, we introduce the notion of
Cumulative Entropic Value at Risk (CEVaR
) as a coherent risk measure on the space of bounded stochastic processes and we explore some of its relevant features. In
Section 4, we explore the capital allocation problem and give a theorem which characterizes the capital allocation set for these measures. In fact, we show that for the CEVaR
risk measure the Euler allocation method is the only way to allocate the risk capital. We also discuss the connection between our approach and existing results for capital allocation in similar framework, namely that of [
7]. In
Section 5, we apply our results to study the capital allocation problem for a particular type of insurance Lévy risk process. Finally, in
Section 6, we specialized our results to particular examples of Lévy insurance risk processes and give expressions for CEVaR
in such cases.
2. Literature Review
We set to study risk measures for stochastic processes in the context of capital allocation applications. Our starting point is to build upon the notion of ruin measures in collective risk theory to design a more suitable measure of risk. There is indeed a fair amount of research on the question of how to define risk measures for stochastic processes. Among previous works on these issues we find, for instance, [
8] and [
9] where the authors work out risk measures on the space of random processes modeling the evolution of a certain financial position or [
10] where they develop risk measures in a dynamic fashion. Indeed there is now a comprehensive theory of risk measures on the space of stochastic processes that draws from convex analysis, probability and the general theory of stochastic processes in order to build a mathematical framework for the quantification of economic risks in a dynamic fashion.
On the other hand, applications of risk measures defined on the space of stochastic processes are less abundant. In particular, the problem of capital allocation in such a framework is far from trivial. On the space of random variables, this problem is well-studied and it has been addressed in different ways. For an overview of several methods to tackle the problem of capital allocation in the insurance framework we refer to [
11] or [
12]. Moreover, in [
13], a comparison of different combinations of risk measures and allocation methods can be found. For more recent references providing a good literature review on the problem, we refer to [
7,
14].
The study of capital allocation problem can be traced back to the work of LeMaire [
15] where the author studies the capital allocation problem in the game theory framework. Later on, in [
16] we find that the author also uses a cooperative game theory approach to study the fair allocation principle for coherent risk measures. In [
17], the author also studies the problem of capital allocation for random variables in a general framework. In [
16,
17], the authors propose the Euler principle for allocating the required capital under some technical assumptions. In [
18], the author considers the particular case of multivariate normally distributed random vectors for risks and Tail Value at Risk (TVaR) as the risk measure. The author provides an explicit solution for the marginal based capital allocation. The authors in [
19] extend the work done in [
18] to the class of multivariate elliptical distributions. The author in [
20] studies the problem for distortion risk measures. The results provided in [
19] were also derived in [
21] and the problem of capital allocation were studied for risks obtained by sums of normal as well as log-normal risk variables. In [
22], the authors also study the capital allocation problem using default option with limited liability. Studying the problem for the class of convex risk measures was carried out in [
23]. The authors in [
24] study the capital allocation problem by introducing the class of weighted risk capital allocations. A different approach to the problem of capital allocation were introduced in [
25] where the author introduces an axiomatic allocation framework to study the problem. In [
26] the author studies the optimal capital allocation in a way to minimize the asymptotic ruin probability. A unifying framework for the capital allocation problem is developed in [
7] where the authors use an approach relying “on an optimization argument, requiring that the weighted sum of measures for the deviations of the business unit’s losses from their respective allocated capitals be minimized”. Another study on this problem can be found in [
27], where they propose a sensitivity analysis framework for internal risk models for the class of distortion risk measures. As a special case they study the problem of capital allocation for this class of risk measures under their sensitivity framework. For the most recent articles on the capital allocation problem we also refer to [
28,
29].
Unfortunately, when it comes to the space of stochastic processes, it is a different story. The problem of capital allocation for coherent risk measures on the space of stochastic processes turns out to be a more difficult task. A comprehensive understanding of the problem of capital allocation for coherent risk measures in this setting requires advanced notions and techniques from functional analysis as well as convex analysis. In fact, a formal treatment of the problem of capital allocation for coherent risk measures requires studying the weak sub-gradient set associated to the risk measure (see [
30]). As it turns out, in order to get a good understanding of the sub-gradient set and its properties, we need a robust representation of the underlying risk measure which, in turn, requires studying of the dual space of
. Now, the fact that, we have a sophisticated topological structure to deal with for the dual space of
, makes it difficult to characterize the sub-gradient set and to give a solution to the problem of capital allocation. To the best of our knowledge, this problem has not been thoroughly studied for risk measures defined on the space of stochastic processes. We can only cite, [
30], where the author discusses the problem of capital allocation for risk measures defined on the space of cádlág processes. Or, [
6] where the authors study the capital allocation problem for a new risk measure that, as it turned out, it does not satisfy an axiomatic definition of coherent risk measures defined on stochastic processes proposed in [
8]. As a drawback, the resulting solution of the capital allocation problem, does not follow an axiomatic definition of capital allocation. Moreover, neither the proposed risk measure, nor the capital allocation solution, have an explicit formula.
In this paper, we circumvent all these issues by giving an ad-hoc smooth explicit representation of a class of risk measures. Such construction leads naturally to an explicit solution for the capital allocation problem without having to make use of the advanced machinery from functional analysis. Based on [
31] and [
32], we design a risk measure on the space of bounded càdlàg processes that can capture the risk associated with the path-properties of an insurance model. We do this by extending the notion of
Entropic Value at Risk, first introduced in [
31], to a suitable space of stochastic processes. This measure allows us to explore the capital allocation problem in an insurance context. We show that the Euler allocation method is the only method to allocate the requiring capital for this risk measure. Moreover, we discuss a connection with existing results mainly with the results in [
7].
3. Cumulative Entropic Risk Measures
Let be a filtered probability space. We consider the space of stochastic processes on that are càdlàg, adapted and such that , with . Furthermore, assume that has a countable dense subset. Notice that, for any , the space endowed with the norm , is a Banach space.
In [
8] and [
9] the authors developed the theory of convex risk measures on the space of
(
). It is within this framework that we develop our approach. We start by defining a subset of
that serves our purposes and with which we will work for the rest of the paper.
Definition 1. We define the subspace containing the processes with the following property.for . The idea we put forward in this paper is to use a
cumulative risk measure based on the
Entropic Value at Risk that was defined in [
31]. That is, following [
30], we measure the risk of a random process
by defining a
cumulative risk measure as follows. Let
be a given risk measure on
, i.e.,
, and let
be a suitable weight function, i.e.,
. Then we can define a cumulative risk measure
based on
as the weighted aggregate risk of a random process
. More precisely,
An interesting and meaningful choice for a weight function mentioned above can be a density function for a random time which captures important moments associated to the underlined process
. Such constructions were proposed and studied in [
30]. The features of such measures inherently depend on the choice of base risk measure
. In fact, if the risk measure
is coherent then
ρ in (6) is coherent as well.
Theorem 1. Let be the space of financial positions with finite and be a coherent risk measure on . Then the risk measure , given in (6), is a coherent risk measure on the space .
Proof. First we show the positive homogeneity and translation invariance properties of
ρ. For
and
we have,
which shows the positive homogeneity and translation invariance properties since
.
As for monotonicity, if a.s., then for . Now, since ω is a positive real valued function, we have for any as well. This implies that which proves the monotonicity.
Now using the subadditivity property of
and since
ω is a positive function we have,
for
. This directly implies the subadditivity property of
ρ. i.e.,
☐
In this paper, we propose to use the
Entropic Value at Risk measure (EVaR
) as our measure
in (
6). This yields an interesting family of risk measures on the space of bounded stochastic processes. Following [
31,
33] we now give a first definition.
Definition 2. Let X be a random variable in withThen the Entropic Value at Risk, denoted by EVaR, is given byfor risk level . We can generalize this definition for random variables in
for
, as long as they meet (
7). The following key result for EVaR
can be found in [
31].
Theorem 2. The risk measure EVaR from Definition 2 is a coherent risk measure. Moreover, for any having property (
7)
, its dual representation has the formwhere and For the proof we refer to [
31].
If we use the risk measure (
8) in our general definition of a cumulative risk measure (
6), we naturally obtain a risk measure on the space
that would inherit some of the key features of the original risk measure.
We now formally introduce the concept of Cumulative Entropic Value at Risk, denoted by CEVa, on the space .
Definition 3. Let X be a stochastic process in and let EVaR be the risk measure in Definition 2. Then, for a given weight function (i.e., ), the Cumulative Entropic Value at Risk, denoted by CEVaR, is defined by The main advantage of using (
8) as our based measure is that the resulting cumulative risk measure (
11) is tractable enough for a wide family of collective risk models. This comes from the fact that the expectation appearing in (
8) is merely the Laplace exponent of the random variable
(for
). In collective risk theory, many of the models used for insurance reserves have closed-form Laplace transforms, in particular the so-called Lévy insurance risk processes. If the aggregate claims process is driven by a spectrally negative Lévy processes then a cumulative entropic risk measure based on the EVAR
is an natural choice to work with in risk management applications.
The risk measure in Definition 3 belongs to the general framework of axiomatic risk measures on the space of stochastic processes developed in [
8]. We now study some of its properties.
Corollary 1. The risk measure CEVaR, given in Definition 3, is a coherent risk measure on the space .
Proof. Since EVaR
is of the form (
6) with a coherent base risk measure
, it follows that EVaR
is a coherent risk measure as a special case of Theorem 1. ☐
Now, one can notice that in Definition 3 the weight function ω plays an important role. Different choices of weight functions would result in different cumulative Entropic risk measures. One can naturally think of ω as a density function that distributes a probability mass over the interval . Interesting choices would be to use the density function of a suitable stopping time , like the first passage time or ruin time. This would penalize certain regions of the interval according to whether a certain meaningful event is more or less likely to occur over these regions.
For tractability purposes, in this paper, we use a uniform weight function, i.e., we consider
. In the remaining of the paper we will be working with the following subfamily of CEVaR,
Now, the object of our interest in this paper is to apply the
CEVaR in (
12) within an insurance context. That is, we would be interested in applying
CEVaR in order to measure the risk of the net-loss process
in (
1), where the aggregate claims process
is a spectrally positive Lévy processes (or equivalently, the surplus process is modeled by a spectrally negative Lévy process). The following proposition enables us to include a subclass of spectrally negative Lévy processes having m.g.f in the space
for some
. This would enable us to use
CEVaR with this class of processes.
Proposition 1. Let X be a càdlàg Lévy process with and let p be a real number in . Then, the following are equivalent.- 1.
X is -integrable.
- 2.
is -integrable.
Proof. This is a special case of Theorem
in [
34]. ☐
Now that we have established, through Proposition 1, that the class of -integrable spectrally negative Lévy processes having m.g.f is in the space ; we can use such processes as models for the reserves of an insurance company and apply CEVaR in order to quantify risks.
One interesting feature is that the
Cumulative Entropic Risk Measure has the advantage of being tractable enough for a large family of processes which have moment generating function and that can be used as models for the net-loss process in (
1). Indeed, if our model for the net-loss process is a Lévy insurance model for which the moment generating function is readily available, computation of CEVaR is a somewhat straight-forward exercise. For instance, assume the net-loss process in (
1) takes the form
, where
is a standard Brownian motion,
is the drift parameter,
is the and scale parameter, and
is a gamma process with parameters
. Since
is a Lévy process, the moment generating function of
is
In this case, to obtain EVaR
we need to find
from the following equation.
The above equation is obtained by applying the moment generating function of
in the definition EVaR
and by straight-forward differentiation with respect to
s. Although there is no closed-form expression for the solution of this equation, once
is obtained numerically, we can calculate EVaR
by direct substitution
in (
8). CEVaR
can be obtained by direct integration of EVaR
over
.
This is one example that illustrates how EVar and CEVaR can be computed for processes having a closed form moment generating function. More details and examples are given in a later section where we set up an insurance model based on Lévy processes to illustrate an application of our results in a capital allocation context.
4. Capital Allocation
We now study the problem of capital allocation in an insurance context with the coherent risk measure
CEVaR that we introduced in
Section 3. A discussion of the problem of capital allocation for
CEVaR, which is a risk measure defined on
, must start with an analysis of such problem for
EVaR, which is a risk measure on a subspace of
.
Finding the capital allocation for a risk measure on the space of stochastic processes typically requires knowledge of its robust representation and its subgradient set (see [
32] for a detailed account on this problem). This robust representation is typically a hard problem in the space
that normally requires advanced functional analysis tools. In the case of
EVaR we propose to tackle the problem of finding the capital allocation for CEVaR by finding first the capital allocation for EVaR and then use the linear relation between EVaR and CEVaR to get the capital allocation for CEVaR.
We first give some definitions that will be needed throughout this section.
Definition 4. Let ρ be a coherent risk measure defined on . Now let be the largest set for which the following robust representation holds true for ρ.where is the set defined in (10)
. The set is called the determining set of ρ (see [35]). The following definition is taken from [
36].
Definition 5. Let ρ be a coherent risk measure defined on with determining set . Let . A function is called an extreme function for X if . The set of extreme functions will be denoted by .
The following result is taken from [
36] and gives conditions for the set of extreme functions defined above to be non-empty.
Proposition 2. Let be the determining set of a given coherent risk measure ρ on . Now consider the following set. If the determining set is weakly compact and , then the set of extreme functions for X is not empty, i.e., .
Now, we turn our attention to the concept of capital allocation. Consider a vector of risks , such that for , are random variables representing the cash flow or risk exposure of a portfolio consisting of d risky positions or departments.
Given a coherent risk measure ρ on , we now look at the problem of how to allocate the total risk of the portfolio among the different departments such that the individual risk of each one of them is properly measured.
The following formal definition of capital allocation was proposed by [
37] and [
38] and it is the one we set out to study in this paper. In fact, the following gives a mathematical definition of capital allocation for a coherent risk measure.
Definition 6. Consider a coherent risk measure ρ on and a vector of risks such that for . A fair capital allocation for X is a vector such that- 1.
- 2.
The first condition is called the
full allocation property and it simply states the fact that the total risk of the whole portfolio should be the aggregated risks of each department. The second condition is called the
linear diversification property of capital allocation. In fact, this condition has a one to one correspondence with the positive homogeneity and subadditivity of a coherent risk measure
ρ (see [
25]). Since we work in this paper with a coherent risk measure it is somehow natural to adopt this definition of capital allocation.
The following is an interesting result characterizing the set of possible such capital allocations and it is adapted from [
36].
Theorem 3. Let be the determining set of a given coherent risk measure ρ on and let be a vector such that for . Consider the following set The set of capital allocations for , satisfying Definition 6, is convex and bounded and it has the formwhere is the inner product in , and argmax is the set of points of G for which attains its maximum value. If moreover, and is weakly compact, then U can be identified to be Proof. In [
36], the author provides a proof of the theorem for coherent utility functions. The result follows by noticing that, for a given coherent risk measure
ρ, if we set
we obtain a coherent utility function and the result in [
36] holds. So, from
the results for the statement of our theorem holds. ☐
The set
in Theorem 3 is called the
generator for
X and
ρ (see [
36]). The following corollary gives a condition on
G for the uniqueness of the capital allocation.
Corollary 2. Under the conditions of Theorem 3. If moreover, is strictly convex (i.e., its interior is non-empty and its border contains no interval), then there is a unique capital allocation satisfying Definition 6.
Proof. See [
36] for a proof in terms of coherent utility functions. ☐
4.1. CEVaR and the Capital Allocation Problem
Our main goal in this paper is to apply cumulative entropic risk measure in a capital allocation problem. So far, we have discussed key notions of the capital allocation problem for a risk measure on
. In this subsection, we apply these results in order to give an answer to the problem of capital allocation for
CEVaR which is a risk measure on
. Notice that this is a somewhat more complicated problem since there is a dynamic component to this problem. Here, this is overcome by the cumulative property of CEVa
. We start by extending Definition 6 to the more general notion of capital allocation with respect to a coherent risk measure on the space
. The following definition is taken from [
39].
Definition 7. Let be d random processes in representing d financial positions or departments. Moreover, consider a coherent risk measure defined on the space . A fair capital allocation for with respect to ρ is a vector such that- 1.
- 2.
where
denotes the process
.
In this section, we show how a capital allocation satisfying Definition 7 can be obtained when using CEVaR as risk measure. In fact we show that the border of the set
in the robust representation (
13) for EVa
is not a convex set so leads to the fact that the border of the set
G in (15) is not a convex set as well. This yields to the uniqueness of the capital allocation for
EVaR (Corollary 2) as well as for
CEVaR.
Theorem 4. Let D be the determining set in the robust representation (9) for EVa. Then the convex combination of elements of is never an element of where .
Proof. It is sufficient to show that for any
and any two functions
f and
g in
, the function
is not in
. Define the function
H on the space of positive real line taking real values as follows.
for all
It is clear that the function
H is strictly convex on the positive real line. Since,
and
for all
Now again we define a new function
K on
with its values in
by using the composition function
as follows.
for the fixed functions
f and
g in
. Notice that we use a slight abuse of notation, here
is to be understood point-wise. That is, for
, the function
.
If we take the first and second derivatives for the function
K, we see that this function is strictly convex too.
and
. Now, considering
and
along with the strictly convexity of the function
K, we come up with the inequality
This proves our assertion. ☐
Now, we are going to characterize the capital allocation satisfying Definition 7 with respect to CEVa
given by (
11). Notice that this seems to be a more complicated problem since CEVa
is a risk measure defined on the space of stochastic processes
. However, this is possible thanks to the cumulative property of CEVa
. In fact, this enables us to study the problem of capital allocation for CEVa
through studying the same problem for EVa
. A characterization theorem for the problem of capital allocation for coherent risk measures on space of random variables has been proved by [
16] in the context of game theory. But in the following theorem, for the sake of completeness, we provide a different proof for the capital allocation for EVa
using different approach.
Theorem 5. Let be a vector such that each (for ) represents the cash-flow or risk exposure from one risk position or department at time . We denote by the portfolio-wide cash-flow produced at time . Furthermore, define the function where ρ is EVa as defined in Definition 2. Then, the capital allocation satisfying Definition 7 over the period , with respect to CEVa as defined in (
11)
, is determined uniquely for bywhere is Proof. From the definition of
it is clear that
Because of the linear property of integral, studying the problem of capital allocation, both existence and uniqueness of capital allocation, for
can be reduced to study this problem for
. Now, we show that
provided in the theorem is the capital allocation for
and the vector
for a fixed
. For this first of all we show that the possible capital allocations for the vector
are those belonging to the following set.
where
G is given by (
15),
and
is the inner product in
. To show this, we assume that
is a capital allocation for the vector
. Thus, we have
. Then, for every
we have
. Therefore,
. Now, assume that
, then
for all
. By replacing
and
into the last inequality we get
. Therefore, the set of capital allocation associated to the vector
is
. Since, the risk measure EVaR
is positive homogeneous, i.e., for all
we have EVaR
λ EVaR
, we deduce that the function
above is a homogeneous function. So, by Euler’s theorem on homogeneous functions we have
which implies
for
. Because
has smooth explicit representation so partial derivative
exists for all
Now, referring to [
36] we can see that
belongs in
G as well as in
. This shows that gradient of
evaluated at
is one choice for capital allocation of the vector
. To show the uniqueness we refer to any classical convex analysis textbook to see when the gradient exists then the set
is a singleton [
40]. i.e., the gradient of
evaluated at
is the only possible allocation for the vector
. Now to get the capital allocation for
we just need to multiply
by
and take integral w.r.t
t. This finishes the proof. ☐
Corollary 3. Under the assumptions of Theorem 5, the capital allocated to the department for the cumulative risk measure given by (
12)
iswhere is given by Equation (
19).
Proof. By replacing
into Equation (
18) we get the required capital for the department
. ☐
Theorem 5, gives us a solution to the problem of capital allocation for stochastic processes over a finite time period
. Interesting enough, unlike other solutions to this problem, this capital allocation can be readily computed for a large family of processes. But before we turn our attention to an application of our results, we elaborate further on the connection of our results and existing alternatives for capital allocation in similar contexts, namely the approach in [
7].
4.2. Connection to other Optimum Capital Allocation Principles
Within our framework, Theorem 5 and Corollary 3 give a solution the capital allocation problem described in Definition 7. This can be seen as a way to circumvent technical difficulties associated with the allocation problem within the space of stochastic processes which are non-trivial. Now, we would like to briefly compare our approach to existing alternatives in the literature. Indeed, the problem of static capital allocation for random variables in a general optimization framework has been developed in [
7]. The authors in [
7] derive the optimal capital allocation for different business lines or sub portfolios via solving the following minimization problem.
where the
are n individual losses, the
are non-negative real numbers such that
, the
are non-negative random variables such that
, D is a non-negative function, and
K is the given total risk capital. Specializing
, the authors reduce Equation (
22) to the quadratic version of it and provide a closed form solution for
as follows,
It is worth pointing out that this proposed capital allocation solution in Equation (
23) holds for the static framework, i.e., it provides the solutions for the problem of capital allocation for risk measures defined on the space of random variables. In the following we elaborate further on the connection between Equation (
23) and the presented method for solving the capital allocation problem in this paper.
Setting EVaR and referring to Definition 6 and Corollary 2, it can be seen that for all where f is the Radon-Nikodym derivative associated to the robust representation of EVaR.
Now, if we compare Equation (
23) with Equation (
17) and we use Corollary 2, we can see that the capital allocation associated to each
is uniquely determined by
. One just has to remember that in Equation (
17) we considered
as profit and loss (P&L) random variables which explains the “−” signs in Equation (
17). Therefore, interestingly enough, Equation (
23) is reduced to
.
Now, in practice it is not an easy task to derive the function
f and, consequently, to obtain a closed form for
in this setting. Other alternatives need to be adapted to find
like Euler allocation method. Under this light, in
Section 4.1 we have somewhat developed and extended the quadratic optimal capital allocation problem proposed in [
7] for a class of risk measures defined on a subspace of stochastic processes,
. Due to the closed form representation of the underlying class of risk measures, we derived solutions for the problem of quadratic capital allocation without restoring the complicated mathematical tools.
5. Capital Allocation for Insurance Lévy Risk Processes
We now illustrate how Corollary 3 can be used to give an answer to the capital allocation problem for an insurance risk process. We consider here an insurance company consisting of
n departments. For each department, we let
be a risk reserve process of the form (
1). In other words,
where
denotes the net-loss process related to the
i-th department. We recall that
is the initial reserve,
is the loaded premium and
is a model for the aggregate claims while the index
i refers to one of the
n departments. In order to allow for a more rich description of an insurance company, we can think of a similar setting to that used in the
CreditRisk+ Model (see [
41]) where the aggregate claims process
is being described by
m independent systemic risk factors
which are themselves spectrally positive Lévy processes. Alternatively, one can think of the aggregate amount paid out by the department
i as being composed of fractions of
m independent classes of claims. That is, let
be
m independent spectrally positive Lévy process modeling aggregate claims of
m different types. In this perspective, one can think for instance of claims associated with car accidents, home damage, medical insurance, etc. From either perspective, the aggregate claims
paid out by the
i-th department would be a linear combination of some of these
systemic claims processes. For example, consider aggregate claims produced by a car insurance contract. We suppose that one department will pay out property damage coverage (a fraction of the aggregate claims from the contract) while another department will pay out third-party liability costs (another fraction of the aggregate claims from the contract).
Mathematically, we let
be
m independent spectrally positive Lévy processes having moment generating function(m.g.f) for
. Now, we let each
to be a linear combination of some, or all, of the
, i.e.,
where
’s are non-negative real numbers for
and
.
We point out that we chose this structure because it admits a neat solution for the capital allocation problem through Theorem 5. One can always fall back on the more simple case where each department pays out one, and only one, type of claims as oppose to paying fractions of different types of claims. This would correspond to having
and a diagonal matrix in (
24) with all elements in the diagonal equal to one yielding
for all
i. We also point out that this construction endows the processes
’s with a dependence structure through the aggregate claims
’s. Now, the main objective would be to identify the capital allocation for each net-loss process
as measured by CEVa
. The next result is one of the main contribution of our paper.
Theorem 6. Consider n risk processes such that , for . Now, let such where the aggregate risk processes be those defined in (24)
. Then the capital allocation that satisfies Definition 7 over the time period , for each net-loss process and with respect to the risk measure CEVa in (
12)
iswhereand for , , and . Proof. First we want to find the capital allocation with respect to the risk measure EVa
before applying Theorem 5. For any coherent risk measure
ρ defined on
, we have, by the cash-invariant property, that, for each
That is, in order to find the capital allocation (at ) in this setting with respect to a coherent risk measure (in particular for EVa), we just need to find the capital allocation for each claim process .
For a given coherent risk measure
ρ on
, let us define the function
for
. Taking into account the structure of the processes
, we can write, for
If we let
we can write a more compact form
By using the independence of principal factors
, we have, for
where the last equality comes from
.
If we specialize the above equations to the case of EVaR, then Equation (
28) becomes, for
Now, consider the right-hand side of Equation (
29). By taking derivatives with respect to
s we have, for
,
By setting Equation (
30) equal to zero, we can find the value
that minimizes the right-hand side in (
29). As indicated by the notation, this minimum value
is a function of
t and
for
but in the following we use the more simple notation
for this value. Notice that the value
is in fact the infimum too. Based on convexity property of Laplace transform for one-sided Lévy processes and the condition
, the infimum in (29) should be reached at some point we denote
(see [
42]).
According to Theorem 5, the
Euler allocation is the only possible allocation method for EVa
. So, in order to find the capital allocation, it is sufficient to find the derivative of the right-hand side of Equation (
29) with respect to the variable
and evaluate it at the point
. Straight-forward differentiation yields, for
and
where we use the notation
.
Since
is the solution of setting Equation (
30) equal to zero, we can simplify (31) as follows, for
.
Evaluating Equation (
32) at the point
yields the allocated capital associated to the
department at time
. Namely, for
Using Corollary 3 and integrating
in (33) yields the allocated capital satisfying Definition 7 with respect to the risk measure CEVa
. Thus, the allocated capital to
department over the period
with respect to CEVa
is
This completes the proof. ☐