4.1. Reformulation as a Controller vs. Stopper Game
Let
be the wealth process in a crash-free market controlled by the pre-crash strategy
: then,
follows the stochastic differential equation (SDE):
where
solves Equation (
1). At the crash time
τ the investor’s wealth equals
, and the interest rate is denoted by
. Considering the post-crash value function, we can replace
by these values, and therefore, we can reformulate the worst-case optimization problem in (
2) as the pre-crash problem:
Since
, given in Equation (
8), is strictly monotone increasing with respect to
x, this problem can be rewritten as a controller
vs. stopper game of the form:
and
.
Remark 2. Compared to the previous literature, where a non-negative strategy was required, we have now included the positive part of pre-crash strategies k in the controller vs. stopper game. First, as already mentioned, the optimal post-crash strategy can become negative. It would therefore be conceptually bad to exclude negative pre-crash strategies. This is in particular due to the fact that there is nothing preventing us from following the optimal post-crash strategy before the crash, given that it is negative. In such a setting, the investor will benefit two-fold. On the one hand, he behaves optimally with regard to the terminal wealth utility criterion. Even more, having a negative position, he would benefit from a positive crash height at such a time instant. It is thus clear that in this situation, the worst case for the investor is a jump of size zero. Further, for all pre-crash strategies, the worst case is a crash of size zero when they attain negative values. As it makes no sense from the point of optimal final utility to hold a position smaller than , we can thus also restrict the class of admissible strategies for our worst-case problem to those that are bounded from below by and, thus, are bounded in total. Therefore, if , then the worst case crash size is . Otherwise, if , the investor holds risky assets at the crash time, and the worst-case is the maximal crash size .
Now, the aim is to solve the controller
vs. stopper game (
10). As already mentioned above, [
6] and [
5] used the notion of indifference to determine the optimal pre-crash strategy for a model with a constant interest rate. Therein, a pre-crash strategy
is called an indifference strategy if the investor, who applies this strategy, reaches the same performance for two different stopping times, which means (see, for example, [
6], Chapter 4.2):
for all stopping times
. In the next section, we will also use this definition to identify the optimal pre-crash strategy.
4.2. Identification of Optimal Pre-Crash Strategy by the Martingale Method
The main result of this paper is the following theorem, which gives the optimal pre-crash strategy for the worst-case optimization problem in (
2).
Theorem 2. Let be the optimal post-crash strategy given by Equation (9), and let be the uniquely determined solution of the following ordinary differential equation (ODE):where:and is given by Equation (
7).
Then, is the optimal pre-crash strategy for the worst-case optimization problem in (
2).
Remark 3. Note that for general parameters and (i.e., the model indeed contains a stochastic interest rate), ODE Equation (
11)
is a non-autonomous equation, because is not constant over time. In order to prove this result, we give a sequence of auxiliary results. The first Lemma ensures that is an admissible pre-crash strategy in the sense of Definition 1.
Lemma 3. Let and be given by Equation (
9)
and (
12),
respectively. Then, the ordinary differential equation:has a uniquely determined solution with for all . Remark 4. Since is a deterministic, continuous and bounded function on , it is easy to check that it is admissible in the sense of Definition 1. Especially, the lemma above provides the inequality for all . Thus, following this strategy before the market crash, the investor’s wealth stays positive at the crash time.
In the next lemma, we will show that an investor who applies the pre-crash strategy
is indifferent with respect to the market crash, which means
is an indifference strategy for the controller
vs. stopper game (
10).
Lemma 4. Let be the uniquely determined solution of the ODE Equation (
11)
, and let be given by Equation (
10)
for and . Then, is a martingale on and is an indifference strategy for the controller vs. stopper game. Proof of Lemma 4. As in [
5], we use a martingale argument to prove the assertion. The proof will be divided into two steps. First, we show that
is a martingale on
, and then, we obtain the assertion by applying Doob’s optional sampling theorem.
By applying Ito’s formula on
and using that
for all
, we obtain that:
Here, we used that
solves Equation (
6) for all
. Because of the fact that
fulfills Equation (
11), it remains to show that:
is a martingale. The solution of this linear SDE is given by:
By Novikov’s condition (see, for example, [
12], Corollary 5.13), the second factor is a martingale, and therefore,
is a martingale on
. It remains to show, that
By definition of
and with
, we have:
Finally,
is a martingale on
. By Doob’s optional sampling theorem, we obtain:
for all stopping times
. By definition,
is thus an indifference strategy for the controller
vs. stopper game (
10). ☐
Due to the martingale property of the process
, we also obtain an indifference frontier, which prevents the investor from too optimistic of an investment (see, e.g., [
6], p. 343): let
be an arbitrary admissible pre-crash strategy, and let
be the solution of ODE (
11); then,
is a martingale on
. Define
and:
Then, as in ([
6], Lemma 4.3), we obtain by the martingale property that:
Consequently, it is sufficient to consider pre-crash strategies
with
for all
. The optimal strategy cannot cross the indifference frontier
, because one can then improve its performance by cutting it off at
, and therefore, it would not be optimal. Thus, the optimal pre-crash strategy is an element of the set:
The next lemma will show that is optimal in the no-crash scenario in the class . This result is an important part of the proof of Theorem 2.
Lemma 5. Let be given by Equation (
9)
, and let be the uniquely determined indifference strategy as a solution of Equation (
11)
. Then, the solution of the constrained stochastic optimal control problem:is given by . Proof of Lemma 5. Let
denote the value function of the constrained stochastic optimal control problem Equation (
15). To obtain it, we consider the corresponding HJB equation given by:
By the standard separation method
with
for all
, we can reduce the HJB equation to an equation for
. By the first order condition, we obtain a candidate for the optimal control:
Inserting
in the equation and applying
with
and
, we obtain (with Equation (
7)) that:
and:
Therefore, we conclude that:
solves the HJB Equation (
16). Using the same arguments for the verification result as in ([
8], Corollary 3.2), we obtain that:
is the optimal control for the constrained optimization problem, because
for all
. ☐
Remark 5. Lemma 5 shows that is the optimal strategy in the no-crash scenario in the class . Note that the value function only differs from the post-crash value function by the factor instead of .
Now, using Lemma 3–5, we prove Theorem 2.
Proof of Theorem 2. We have to show that
is the optimal strategy for the controller
vs. stopper game (
10). Then, by the arguments of
Section 4.1, we obtain that
is the optimal pre-crash strategy for the worst-case optimization problem Equation (
2).
Let . Since and , the infimum is attained at , which is the point of intersection of and (if it exists).
Now, let us consider the stochastic process on the interval . For , we have . In Theorem 4, we already proved that is a martingale on , and therefore, is a martingale on . Note that if , that means for all , then is a martingale on . In particular, this is the case if (see Lemma 6 below).
Now, let , and assume that , which means there exists a (uniquely determined) intersection point of and , denoted by . Moreover, let us define . If , then denotes the uniquely determined root of , because it is strictly monotone increasing for .
Let us consider the stochastic process with on the interval .
For
, we have:
With:
we have:
Now, by Novikov’s condition, the second factor is a martingale on
. As further,
is
-measurable for
, we have for
:
The inequality above holds because of two arguments: First, we observe that
for
, and therefore, the integrand of the deterministic integral is positive. Secondly, we only have to consider the cases
and
(because of
) for the estimate of the deterministic integral. For both of these cases, we easily obtain that:
for
because
for
and
for
. By the arguments above, we obtain that
for
. Therefore,
is a supermartingale on
. If
, we obtain, together with the martingale property on
, that
is a supermartingale on
.
Otherwise, if
, then we have to consider
on the interval
. By assumption, we have that
, and therefore,
for
. For
, we obtain:
Again, by Novikov’s condition, we obtain that is a martingale on .
Finally,
is a supermartingale on
(for
,
is even a martingale on
). By Doob’s optional sampling theorem (see, for example, ([
13], Theorem 16)), we have:
The inequality implies that is a worst-case scenario for the strategy .
Analogously, to the indifference optimality principle in [
6] and [
5], we have:
The second inequality holds, because
is optimal in the no-crash scenario (see Lemma 5). By inequality (
18),
is the optimal strategy for the controller
vs. stopper game in the class
. Due to the indifference frontier, that means, due to the fact that the optimal strategy is in the class
, we obtain that
is the optimal pre-crash strategy for the worst-case optimization problem in (
2). Obviously,
is admissible in the sense of Definition 1, because it is a deterministic, continuous and bounded function on
. Due to the fact that
for all
(see Lemma 3), we easily obtain that
for all
. ☐
Lemma 6. Let . Then, for all , where is a solution of Equation (
13)
and is the optimal post-crash strategy given by Equation (
9).
Remark 6. For the case , we obtain that for all , and therefore, . By Lemma 4, we obtain that is a martingale on . In this case, we have an equality instead of the first inequality in Equation (
18)
, because of Doob’s optional sampling theorem for a martingale. Therefore, if , then it is optimal to follow the indifference strategy before the market crash. For the special case of , which occurs when either the price and the interest rate are uncorrelated or (log-utility case), we obtain the optimal post-crash strategy given by: Moreover, the optimal pre-crash strategy has to fulfill ODE (
11)
, which reduces to the same ODE given in ([6], Equation 4.3) for this special case. In the next section, we can illustrate the strategies that are optimal before and after the market crash, respectively.