1. Introduction
Risk measurement is becoming increasingly more important in economics, finance and insurance. Although the standard deviation has many interesting properties as a risk measure in a Gaussian world, asymmetries and heavy tails imply inconsistencies between the standard deviation and second order stochastic dominance (or classical utility functions). This also makes it difficult to interpret the standard deviation in terms of potential capital losses. Several recent approaches have attempted to overcome these drawbacks. In particular, a first line of research deals with the axioms that an index of riskiness must satisfy from a Theory of Economics perspective (Aumann and Serrano [
1]), whereas a second line deals with the properties allowing us to interpret a risk measure as potential losses and capital requirements (Artzner
et al. [
2]).
This paper focuses on the Artzner
et al.’s [
2] approach with a significant novelty: we allow for risks generating unbounded expected losses. As will be seen, the inclusion of risks with unbounded expectation (for instance, risks with a Cauchy or a Pareto distribution) presents many mathematical problems when extending the notion of coherence (Artzner
et al. [
2]) or expectation boundedness (Rockafellar
et al. [
3]), and previous literature has addressed this caveat by losing some desirable mathematical properties. For instance, if we use value at risk (VaR) as a risk measure, then we lose continuity and sub-additivity. Though there are risk measures for heavy tailed risks that can recover sub-additivity (or convexity at least, Kupper and Svindland [
4]), continuity is still lost.
This paper overcomes the mathematical problems above by extending a given coherent or expectation bounded risk measure to a limited new setting. For instance, despite the fact that the conditional value at risk (CVaR) cannot be continuously extended to the whole space of random risks, we will see that, in fact, it can be continuously extended to some “smaller” spaces containing some risks with infinite expected value. In practical situations, most of the involved risks will have a finite expected value, so we should not find infinitely many candidates with infinite expectation. More likely, there will be just a few, or even only one. Then, instead of extending a coherent risk measure to a “too large set of risks”, we look for extensions that apply only if the set of heavy tailed risks is finitely generated.
The outline of the paper is as follows.
Section 2 introduces the notation, the framework and the main problem to be addressed: the extension of risk measures, so as to conserve continuity and sub-additivity (or convexity, at least) and simultaneously include risks whose fat tails lead to unbounded expected losses. We summarize the mathematical problems affecting this objective.
Theorem 1 is the main result of
Section 3. It states the existence of the required extension if the set of fat tailed risks has a finite generator. Furthermore, Remarks 2 and 3 show how to construct the extended risk measure in a recursive manner.
Section 4 provides illustrative examples and applications. In particular, we extend the CVaR and the weighted CVaR (WCVaR) by “integrating in a coherent manner” these risk measures with the VaR of the heavy tailed risks. We have selected CVaR and WCVaR due to their additional properties, since they are consistent with second order stochastic dominance (Ogryczak and Ruszczynski [
5]) and may be optimized by linear programming methods (Mansini
et al. [
6], see also Konno
et al. [
7]). We also summarize some actuarial applications, such as some extensions of the expected value premium principle. Empirical applications based on real-world data are not addressed and could be an interesting subject for future research.
The last section of the paper summarizes the most important conclusions.
2. Preliminaries and Notations
Consider the probability space
composed of the set of “states of the world” Ω, the
σ-algebra
and the probability measure
. Denote by
the mathematical expectation of every
-valued random variable
y defined on Ω. Let
and denote by
the Banach space of random variables
y on Ω such that
,
1 is endowed with the norm:
According to the Riesz representation theorem,
is the dual space of
, where
is characterized by
, and
is the space of essentially bounded random variables endowed with the supremum norm.
Let
be a time interval. From an intuitive point of view, one can interpret that
represents the portfolio pay-off at
T for some arbitrary investor (finance) or claims at
T for some arbitrary insurer (actuarial science). Throughout this paper,
y will represent the random wealth at
T, although other interpretations would not modify our main conclusions. If:
is a risk measure, then
may be understood as the “risk” associated with the wealth
y. Let us assume that
ρ satisfies a representation theorem in the line of Artzner
et al. [
1] or Rockafellar
et al. [
3]. More precisely, consider the sub-gradient of
ρ:
composed of those linear expressions lower than
ρ. We assume that
is convex and
-compact
2 and that
ρ is its envelope, in the sense that:
holds for every
. Furthermore, we assume the existence of
, such that:
These assumptions are equivalent to the well-known properties of sub-additivity, homogeneity and translation invariance. To sum up, we have:
Assumption 1. The risk measure ρ satisfies the equivalent Conditions a and b below:
(a) The set given by (1) is convex and -compact, (2) holds for every , and (3) holds.
(b) ρ is continuous, sub-additive (), homogeneous ( if ) and -translation invariant ( if is zero-variance).
We will not prove the equivalence between Conditions
a and
b above, as similar results may be found in several papers (see, for instance, Balbás
et al. [
9]).
Assumption 1 is not at all restrictive, since it is satisfied by every expectation bounded risk measure (Rockafellar
et al. [
3]) with
and by every deviation measure (Rockafellar
et al. [
3]) with
. Examples of expectation bounded risk measures are, amongst many others, the CVaR and the WCVaR. Recall that the VaR of a random variable
y with cumulative distribution function equaling
F is given by:
and for
, the CVaR and the WCVaR are given by:
and:
denoting the level of confidence of VaR and CVaR and
ν being a probability measure on the interval
. Examples of deviation measures are, amongst others, the classical
p-deviation:
or the upside and downside
p-semi-deviations:
and:
If
, then it is easy to see that
ρ is also coherent in the sense of Artzner
et al. [
1] if and only if:
Assumption 1 may be relaxed, and the main conclusions of this paper remain true. For instance, sub-additivity and homogeneity may be replaced by convexity (in the line of Balbás
et al. [
10] or Föllmer and Schied [
11]). Besides,
-translation invariance may be removed in (1b), in which case, the elements in the sub-gradient of
ρ do not necessarily have constant expectation equaling
(see (3)). Nevertheless, we prefer to impose Assumption 1 because it significantly simplifies the exposition.
We will also deal with the (metric, but not Banach) space
. Every random variable belongs to
, whose usual metric is given by:
It is known that Metric
d above leads to “convergence in probability”, which is strictly weaker than the
-convergence. As said above,
d cannot be given by a norm, and
is not a Banach space. Therefore, the dual space of
may be “too small”, and this dual actually reduces to zero if
is atomless (Rudin [
8]). In particular, if a function
satisfies Condition (1a), then (2) implies that
. In other words:
Remark 1. Assumption 1 cannot be imposed for functionals , because it would imply if were atomless.
The latter remark implies that there are no non-null, continuous, sub-additive and homogeneous functionals on
(or even on much smaller proper subspaces of
, Delbaen [
12]). Yet, in finance, operational risk and insurance, one can find risks whose distribution does not belong to
,
, it does not have a finite expectation. For instance, the advanced measurement approach (AMA) to Pillar I modeling of operational risk, as defined in Basel II, deals with random risks given by:
where every
is related to a specific business line and/or risk type as defined in the Basel II Accord (Nešlehová
et al. [
13]). Several
usually follow the Pareto distribution with parameters
and
and with density function:
The expectation of
is infinite if
.
Several authors have proposed to use VaR if tails are so heavy that it is impossible to find sub-additive risk measures (Chavez-Demoulin
et al. [
14], Embrechts
et al. [
15],
etc.). Others have studied non-continuous sub-additive risk measures (Kupper and Svindland [
4]). On the other hand, using continuous sub-additive risk measures has many important analytical advantages, since the optimization of such functions is much simpler and many classical financial and actuarial problems (pricing and hedging, portfolio choice, equilibrium, optimal reinsurance,
etc.) become easier to tackle (Balbás
et al. [
10], among others). For these reasons, it may be worthwhile to look for partial solutions overcoming Remark 1 above, while still preserving some kind of continuity and sub-additivity. This is the main purpose of this paper.
Consider a finite collection of linearly independent final wealth:
and suppose that their tails are very heavy and
,
(
,
,
). Consider the linear manifold
L generated by
and suppose that it does not contain non-null elements of
. Since
L has finite dimension, it only has a unique separated vector topology (Rudin [
8]), and this is the one induced by the topology of
. In other words, the sequence
converges in probability to
if and only if
converges to
,
. Thus, manifold
L recovers the structure of a Banach space, and we can define non-trivial risk measures on
L, that we will denote
.
Assumption 2. A risk measure satisfies the equivalent Conditions a and b below:
(a) The set
is convex and compact, and:
holds for every
.
(b) is continuous, sub-additive and homogeneous.
3. Extending the Risk Measure
As said above, L does not present the drawbacks of , and the risk measure does satisfy the required properties. According to Remark 1, cannot be extended to the whole space unless we lose its good properties. Thus, let us propose a partial extension that allows us “to integrate” those risks included in L and those included in . In practical applications, we do not expect to find infinitely many risks involving infinite expectations. More likely, we will just find a few (or even only one). Then, the proposed solution may be sufficient, since we will be able to have a “global risk measure” containing both ρ and .
In order to jointly manage the risk given by
ρ and
, we need to deal with the space:
which contains those risks included in
, those ones included in
L and their linear combinations.
Theorem 1. There exists an extension , such that:
(a) is continuous, sub-additive, homogeneous and -translation invariant (, if , and ).
(b) if and if .
(c) is minimal among the functionals satisfying a and b.
(d) The set (sub-gradient of ):is convex and -compact. (e)holds for every and every .
3 From an intuitive viewpoint, Theorem 1 has a simple interpretation. One can extend both ρ and in such a manner that they become “integrated” in a global measure , which preserves the required properties, despite the fact that has infinitely many dimensions and the convergence in this global space still involves convergence in probability. Therefore, one can simultaneously deal with those standard risks y with finite expectations and those much heavier tailed risks w whose expectations are not finite.
Theorem 1 is an existence result, but it does not indicate how to construct in practice. Let us address this point.
Remark 2. Building in practice for a single heavy tailed risk: Suppose firstly that , , L is a linear manifold generated by only one heavy tailed risk w with no finite expected value.
Step 1: Construct the sub-gradient of in such a way that the natural projections and satisfy and . This may be easily done as follows.
Step 2: Fix ,
and:(see (2)). Choose ϕ in such a manner that .
4 Notice that (6) and (7) obviously imply that:holds for every .
Step 3: Transform the interval:into the intervalby means of the (one to one, unless ) increasing affine function 5:
Step 4: will be chosen according to the affine function above. More precisely,According to (8), the construction of is correct and its -compactness follows from the -compactness of and the continuity of F and . It may be also proven that and hold, though this proof is trivial and therefore omitted. Step 5: Once is known, is given by (5), which becomes now:for every and every . Manipulating,and (2) and (11) imply that: Notice that (12) leads to if , and if and . Furthermore, if and . In other words, really extends ρ and .
The selection of ϕ (Step 2) is only constrained by the inequality , which generates many degrees of freedom. In other words, we really have a choice when computing in practice the extension of Theorem 1, since it is not unique. The next section gives some rules to select ϕ, mainly related to the specific risk that one would like to associate with some reachable strategies of .
The selection of F in (9) is not unique, since the decreasing affine surjective function:may play the role of F. Thus, if G replaces F, one will find a second extension of ρ and still satisfying Theorem 1. Nevertheless, bearing in mind Condition c in Theorem 1, F and G are the unique valid choices. Other functions will make Condition c fail. We will not prove this result, because the proof is complex and beyond the scope of this paper. Notice that (12) leads to:where the parameters and must satisfy and other additional constraints. If ϕ may be selected in such a way that and , then (12) implies hat and . Thus, (13) becomes:for every . An “intuitive interpretation” of (14) could be like this: pick an integrable random variable that corresponds to the same risks as and , and then combinations may be “identified” with combinations in terms of risk. Remark 3. Building in practice (the general case): Let us apply the induction method on the number m of heavy tailed risks. Suppose that we have an extension of ρ and on ,
denoting the linear manifold generated by . In such a case, we have to extend to one more dimension, and it is obvious that the methodology described in Step 1–Step 5 above applies again. Thus, bearing in mind (12), we can select with , and the global risk measure will be given by: