Coherent Diversification Measures in Portfolio Theory: An Axiomatic Foundation
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Axioms
- (i)
- The optimal degree of diversification of and must be equal;
- (ii)
- The optimal weight of in must be equal to the optimal weight of in ;
- (iii)
- The optimal weight of in must be equal to the sum of the optimal weights of and in .
- (a)
- Comonotonicity (Dhaene et al. 2002a): A random vector is comonotonic if and only , for all .
- (b)
- Upper comonotonicity (Cheung 2009): A random vector is upper comonotonic if and only there is a point , called the comonotonic threshold of , such that the following are true:
- (i)
- (ii)
- if , then .
- (iii)
- if , then
- (c)
- Lower comonotonicity (Cheung 2010): A random vector is lower comonotonic if and only if is upper comonotonic.
3. Compatibility with Economic Theories
3.1. Identification
3.2. Test
- (1)
- (2)
3.2.1. Nonlinear and Location-Scale Family of Distributions
- (i)
- , and are twice continuously differentiable. Then, can be written as an expected utilitywith ;
- (ii)
- is strictly increasing;
- (iii)
- is the negative exponential utility function: with the coefficient of risk aversion;
- (iv)
- with a parameter capturing the degree of concavity of ;
- (v)
- is a continuous normal random variable.
3.2.2. Linear and Nonlinear: Yaari’s (1987) Dual Utility Theory
4. Existing Diversification Measures
- (i)
- Portfolio variance
- (ii)
- Diversification ratio (DR)
- (i)
- Portfolio variance satisfies Axioms 1–8 if and only if all assets have the same volatility.
- (ii)
- The diversification ratio satisfies Axioms 1’–8.
5. Example of a Functional Representation
- (P1)
- is concave in for each fixed ;
- (P2)
- for all permutation matrices ;
- (P3)
- is Borel-measurable in for each fixed .
6. Concluding Remarks and Future Research
- (i)
- To re-examine the compatibility of our axioms considering other risk measures in rank-dependent expected utility theory, such as the optimal expected utility risk measures in the study by Geissel et al. (2018) and the extreme risk aggregation approach in the study by Chen and Hu (2019);
- (ii)
- To extend the compatibility of our axioms to cumulative prospect theory;
- (iii)
- To investigate what axioms could be added or strengthened in order to provide a unique family of representations, given that our axiomatic system does not do this;
- (iv)
- To develop more empirical research on portfolio correlation diversification.
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Proofs
Appendix A.1. Proposition 1
- Axiom 1:
- Since is convex on , is concave on .
- Axiom 2:
- It is straightforward to verify that .
- Axiom 3:
- Since with and ,Let and . It follows thatThen
- Axiom 4:
- Since and , . The result follows.
- Axiom 5:
- Consider a portfolio with , where the length of is equal to the cardinal of minus that of . Since and , .
- Axiom 6:
- Because covariance is translation invariant.
- Axiom 7:
- Because covariance is homogeneous of degree two.
- Axiom 8:
- Since for each and for each when is exchangeable, . It is straightforward to verify that is symmetric.
Appendix A.2. Proposition 2
- Axiom 1:
- Since is concave, is convex on (Dhaene et al. 2006; Sereda et al. 2010; Tsanakas and Desli 2003) and consequently, is concave.
- Axiom 2:
- Let be a single-asset i portfolio. It is straightforward to show that .
- Axiom 3:
- Follows the proof of Proposition 1.
- Axiom 4:
- Since is coherent risk measure, comonotonic and non-independent additive (Dhaene et al. 2006; Sereda et al. 2010; Tsanakas and Desli 2003), satisfies Axiom 4.
- Axiom 5:
- Follows the proof of Proposition 1.
- Axiom 6:
- Since is concave, is translation invariant (Dhaene et al. 2006; Sereda et al. 2010; Tsanakas and Desli 2003). Therefore is translation invariant.
- Axiom 7:
- Since is concave, is positive homogeneous of degree one (Dhaene et al. 2006; Sereda et al. 2010; Tsanakas and Desli 2003). Therefore is homogeneous of degree one.
- Axiom 8:
- Suppose that is exchangeable. From Marshall et al. (2011, B.2. Proposition, p. 394), it is straightforward to verify that is symmetric.
Appendix A.3. Proposition 3
Appendix A.3.1. Portfolio Variance
Sufficiency
Necessity
Appendix A.3.2. Diversification Ratio
- Axiom 1’:
- Since is convex and is linear on , from Avriel et al. (2010), is quasi-concave.
- Axiom 2:
- .
- Axiom 3:
- Follows the proof of Proposition 1.
- Axiom 4:
- See Example 4.
- Axiom 5:
- Follows the proof of Proposition 1.
- Axiom 6:
- Because volatility is translation invariant.
- Axiom 7:
- Because volatility is homogeneous of degree one.
- Axiom 8:
- Follows the proof of Proposition 1.
1 | Correlation aversion was introduced as a term by Epstein and Tanny (1980) and as a concept by Richard (1975) but under the name multivariate risk aversion, and was popularized by Eeckhoudt et al. (2007). In two-attribute utility theory, Eeckhoudt et al. (2007) define correlation aversion as follows: a decision maker is correlation averse if he/she prefers the lottery to the lottery for all such that and with and . Richard (1975)’s definition is based on the second-order mixed partial derivatives of the two-attribute utility function: a decision maker is correlation averse if the second-order mixed partial derivative of his/her two-attribute utility function is negative. The equivalence between the two definitions can be found in Eeckhoudt et al. (2007); see also Dorfleitner and Krapp (2007). |
2 | |
3 | |
4 | For example, in Artzner et al.’s (1999) monetary risk measurement theory, correlation diversification is taken into account through the properties of sub-additivity and homogeneity. In Föllmer and Weber’s (2015) monetary risk measurement theory, correlation diversification is taken into account through the property of convexity. In concave distortion risk measures, correlation diversification is taken into account through the properties of comonotonic additivity and sub-additivity (Dhaene et al. 2006). |
5 | For example, in Artzner et al.’s (1999) and Föllmer and Weber’s (2015) monetary risk measurement theories, the possibility of reducing risks by concentration is taken into account through the property of monotonicity, and is as important as diversification. |
6 | To illustrate, without loss of generality, consider the variance risk measure and an universe of four assets , , and . Assume that with the variance of , that the correlation between assets and is equal to one (), and that the correlation between assets and is equal to zero (). It is easy to verify that the variance of the portfolio is lower than the variance of the portfolio . However, portfolio is more diversified in terms of correlation diversification than portfolio . Thus, the less risky portfolio is not the more correlation diversified portfolio. As a result, variance risk measure is not an adequate correlation diversification measure. Now, assume that the four assets have the same variance . In this case, it is straightforward to verify that the variance of portfolio is greater than the variance of portfolio . Thus, the less risky portfolio is the more correlation diversified portfolio. As a result, variance risk measure is an adequate correlation diversification measure, in this example. |
7 | Strong risk aversion is equivalent to risk aversion in the sense of a mean-preserving spread as defined by De Giorgi and Mahmoud (2016, Definition 9, p. 152). |
8 | More precisely, is the space of bounded real-valued random variables on a probability space , where is the set of states of nature, is the sigma-algebra of events, and P is a sigma-additive probability measure on . |
9 | A risk measure is additive for independent risks if for independent , (Sereda et al. 2010). An example of a risk measure additive for independence is the mixed Esscher premium or the mixed exponential premium analyzed by Goovaerts et al. (2004). |
10 | A dependence measure is invariant if for strictly increasing and continuous transformations (Schmid et al. 2010, p. 213). |
11 | A dependence measure is symmetric if (Schmid et al. 2010, p. 213, Equation (10.5)). |
12 | The random variables are said to be exchangeable if and only if their joint distribution is symmetric. A well-known example of an exchangeable sequence of random variables is an independent and identically distributed sequence of random variables. For more details on exchangeable random variables, we refer readers to Aldous (1985). |
13 | The measure of correlation diversification at the core of the mean-variance model was identified by Carmichael et al. (2022); see also Koumou (2020b). |
References
- Abdellaoui, Mohammed. 2002. A genuine rank-dependent generalization of the Von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility theorem. Econometrica 70: 717–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aldous, David J. 1985. Exchangeability and related topics. In École d’Été de Probabilités. De Saint-Flour XIII-1983. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 1–198. [Google Scholar]
- Andersen, Steffen, Glenn W. Harrison, Morten I. Lau, and E. Elisabet Rutström. 2018. Multiattribute utility theory, intertemporal utility, and correlation aversion. International Economic Review 59: 537–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Artzner, Philippe, Freddy Delbaen, Jean-Marc Eber, and David Heath. 1999. Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance 9: 203–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Avriel, Mordecai, Walter E. Diewert, Siegfried Schaible, and Israel Zang. 2010. Generalized Concavity. In The Classics in Applied Mathematics. Philadelphia: SIAM. [Google Scholar]
- Bouchey, Paul, Vassilii Nemtchinov, Alex Paulsen, and David M. Stein. 2012. Volatility harvesting: Why does diversifying and rebalancing create portfolio growth? Journal of Wealth Management 15: 26–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Brumelle, Shelby L. 1974. When does diversification between two investments pay? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 15: 473–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carmichael, Benoît, Gilles Boevi Koumou, and Kevin Moran. 2022. Unifying Portfolio Diversification Measures Using Rao’s Quadratic Entropy. CRREP Working Paper 2015-02. Rochester: SSRN. [Google Scholar]
- Chakravarty, Satya R. 1999. Measuring Inequality: The Axiomatic Approach. In Handbook of Income Inequality Measurement. Edited by Silber J. Recent Economic Thought Series; Dordrecht: Springer, vol. 71. [Google Scholar]
- Chambers, Donald R., and John S. Zdanowicz. 2014. The limitations of diversification return. Journal of Portfolio Management 40: 65–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chateauneuf, Alain, and Ghizlane Lakhnati. 2007. From sure to strong diversification. Economic Theory 32: 511–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chateauneuf, Alain, and Jean-Marc Tallon. 2002. Diversification, convex preferences and non-empty core in the Choquet expected utility model. Economic Theory 19: 509–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chen, Ouxiang, and Taizhong Hu. 2019. Extreme-aggregation measures in the RDEU model. Statistics & Probability Letters 148: 155–63. [Google Scholar]
- Cheung, Ka Chun. 2009. Upper comonotonicity. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 45: 35–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cheung, Ka Chun. 2010. Characterizing a comonotonic random vector by the distribution of the sum of its components. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 47: 130–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chew, Soo Hong, and Larry G. Epstein. 1989. A unifying approach to axiomatic non-expected utility theories. Journal of Economic Theory 49: 207–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Choueifaty, Yves, and Yves Coignard. 2008. Toward maximum diversification. Journal of Portfolio Management 35: 40–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Choueifaty, Yves, Tristan Froidure, and Julien Reynier. 2013. Properties of the most diversified portfolio. Journal of Investment Strategies 2: 49–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Giorgi, Enrico G., and Ola Mahmoud. 2016. Diversification preferences in the theory of choice. Decisions in Economics and Finance 39: 143–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dekel, Eddie. 1989. Asset demand without the independence axiom. Econometrica 57: 163–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Denuit, Michel, Jan Dhaene, Marc Goovaerts, Rob Kaas, and Roger Laeven. 2006. Risk measurement with equivalent utility principles. Statistics & Decisions 24: 1–25. [Google Scholar]
- Dhaene, Jan, Michel Denuit, Marc J. Goovaerts, Rob Kaas, and David Vyncke. 2002a. The concept of comonotonicity in actuarial science and finance: Theory. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 31: 3–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dhaene, Jan, Mark J. Goovaerts, and Rob Kaas. 2003. Economic capital allocation derived from risk measures. North American Actuarial Journal 7: 44–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dhaene, Jan, Steven Vanduffel, Marc J. Goovaerts, Rob Kaas, Qihe Tang, and David Vyncke. 2006. Risk measures and comonotonicity: A review. Stochastic Models 22: 573–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dong, Jing, Ka Chun Cheung, and Hailiang Yang. 2010. Upper comonotonicity and convex upper bounds for sums of random variables. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 47: 159–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dorfleitner, Gregor, and Michael Krapp. 2007. On multiattributive risk aversion: Some clarifying results. Review of Managerial Science 1: 47–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eeckhoudt, Louis, Béatrice Rey, and Harris Schlesinger. 2007. A good sign for multivariate risk taking. Management Science 53: 117–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Embrechts, Paul, Hansjörg Furrer, and Roger Kaufmann. 2009. Different Kinds of Risk. In Handbook of Financial Time Series. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 729–51. [Google Scholar]
- Epstein, Larry G., and Stephen M. Tanny. 1980. Increasing generalized correlation: A definition and some economic consequences. Canadian Journal of Economics 13: 16–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Evans, John L., and Stephen H. Archer. 1968. Diversification and the reduction of dispersion: An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance 23: 761–67. [Google Scholar]
- Fernholz, Robert. 2010. Diversification. In Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance. Berlin/Heidelberg: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. [Google Scholar]
- Föllmer, Hans, and Alexander Schied. 2002. Convex measures of risk and trading constraints. Finance and Stochastics 6: 429–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Föllmer, H. Hans, and Stefan Weber. 2015. The axiomatic approach to risk measures for capital determination. Annual Review of Financial Economics 7: 301–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Frahm, Gabriel, and Christof Wiechers. 2013. A diversification measure for portfolios of risky assets. In Advances in Financial Risk Management. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 312–30. [Google Scholar]
- Frittelli, Marco, and Emanuela Rosazza Gianin. 2002. Putting order in risk measures. Journal of Banking & Finance 26: 1473–86. [Google Scholar]
- Frittelli, Marco, and Emanuela Rosazza Gianin. 2005. Law Invariant Convex Risk Measures. In Advances in Mathematical Economics. Tokyo: Springer, pp. 33–46. [Google Scholar]
- Geissel, Sebastian, Jörn Sass, and Frank Thomas Seifried. 2018. Optimal expected utility risk measures. Statistics & Risk Modeling 35: 73–87. [Google Scholar]
- Gilboa, Itzhak, Andrew Postlewaite, Larry Samuelson, and David Schmeidler. 2019. What are axiomatizations good for? Theory and Decision 86: 339–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goovaerts, Marc J., Rob Kaas, Roger J.A. Laeven, and Qihe Tang. 2004. A comonotonic image of independence for additive risk measures. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 35: 581–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hadar, Josef, and Tae Kun Seo. 1995. Asset diversification in Yaari’s dual theory. European Economic Review 39: 1171–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Han, Xia, Liyuan Lin, and Ruodu Wang. 2022. Diversification Quotients: Quantifying Diversification via Risk Measures. arXiv arXiv:2206.13679. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hua, Lei, and Harry Joe. 2012. Tail comonotonicity: Properties, constructions, and asymptotic additivity of risk measures. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 51: 492–503. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ilmanen, Antti, and Jared Kizer. 2012. The death of diversification has been greatly exaggerated. Journal of Portfolio Management 38: 15–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Konrad, Kai A. 1993. Two-moment decision models and rank-dependent utility. Journal of Economics 57: 95–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Koumou, Gilles Boevi. 2020a. Diversification and portfolio theory: A review. Financial Markets and Portfolio Management 34: 267–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Koumou, Gilles Boevi. 2020b. Mean-variance model and investors’ diversification attitude: A theoretical revisit. Finance Research Letters 37: 101360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lintner, John. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- MacMinn, Richard D. 1984. A general diversification theorem: A note. The Journal of Finance 39: 541–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Markowitz, Harry. 1952. Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance 7: 77–91. [Google Scholar]
- Markowitz, Harry. M. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments, 2nd ed. Malden: Blackwell Publishers, Inc. [Google Scholar]
- Marshall, Albert W., Ingram Olkin, and Barry C. Arnold. 2011. Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and its Applications, 2nd ed. Springer Series in Stastictics; Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer. [Google Scholar]
- Meyer, Jack. 1987. Two-moment decision models and expected utility maximization. American Economic Review 77: 421–30. [Google Scholar]
- Miccolis, Jerry A., and Marina Goodman. 2012. Next generation investment risk management: Putting the ’modern’ back in modern portfolio theory. Journal of Financial Planning 25: 44–51. [Google Scholar]
- Nakamura, Yutaka. 1995. Rank dependent utility for arbitrary consequence spaces. Mathematical Social Sciences 29: 103–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nam, Hee Seok, Qihe Tang, and Fan Yang. 2011. Characterization of upper comonotonicity via tail convex order. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 48: 368–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ortobelli Lozza, Sergio, Wing-Keung Wong, Frank J. Fabozzi, and Martin Egozcue. 2018. Diversification versus optimality: Is there really a diversification puzzle? Applied Economics 50: 4671–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Polkovnichenko, Valery. 2005. Household portfolio diversification: A case for rank-dependent preferences. The Review of Financial Studies 18: 1467–502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qian, Edward. 2012. Diversification return and leveraged portfolios. Journal of Portfolio Management 38: 14–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Quiggin, John. 1982. A theory of anticipated utility. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 3: 323–43. [Google Scholar]
- Quiggin, John. 1993. Generalized Expected Utility Theory: The Rank-Dependent Model, 1st ed. Dordrecht: Springer Science+Business Media. [Google Scholar]
- Quiggin, John, and Peter Wakker. 1994. The axiomatic basis of anticipated utility: A clarification. Journal of Economic Theory 64: 486–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rényi, Alfréd. 1959. On measures of dependence. Acta Mathematica Academiae Scientiarum Hungarica 10: 441–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Richard, Scott F. 1975. Multivariate risk aversion, utility independence and separable utility functions. Management Science 22: 12–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rockafellar, R. Tyrrell, Stan Uryasev, and Michael Zabarankin. 2006. Generalized deviations in risk analysis. Finance and Stochastics 10: 51–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rothschild, Michael, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1970. Increasing risk: I. A definition. Journal of Economic Theory 2: 225–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roy, Andrew Donald. 1952. Safety First and the Holding of Assets. Econometrica 20: 431–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rudin, Alexander M., and Jonathan S. Morgan. 2006. A portfolio diversification index. Journal of Portfolio Management 32: 81–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Flores, Yuri Salazar, Robert J. Bianchi, Michael E. Drew, and Stefan Trück. 2017. The diversification delta: A different perspective. Journal of Portfolio Management 43: 112–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Samuelson, Paul A. 1967. General proof that diversification pays. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 2: 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Segal, Uzi. 1993. Order indifference and rank-dependent probabilities. Journal of Mathematical Economics 22: 373–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sereda, Ekaterina N., Efim M. Bronshtein, Svetozar T. Rachev, Frank J. Fabozzi, Wei Sun, and Stoyan V. Stoyanov. 2010. Distortion risk measures in portfolio optimization. In Handbook of Portfolio Construction. Edited by Guerard J. and John B. New York: Springer, pp. 649–73. [Google Scholar]
- Scheffman, David T. 1973. The Diversification Problem in Portfolio Models. In Department of Economics Research Reports, 7318. London: Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario. [Google Scholar]
- Scheffman, D. T. 1975. A definition of generalized correlation and its application for portfolio analysis. Economic Inquiry 13: 277–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schmid, Friedrich, Rafael Schmidt, Thomas Blumentritt, Sandra Gaißer, and Martin Ruppert. 2010. Copula-based measures of multivariate association. In Copula Theory and Its Applications. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 209–36. [Google Scholar]
- Sharpe, William F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19: 425–42. [Google Scholar]
- Starmer, Chris. 2000. Developments in non-expected utility theory: The hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. Journal of Economic Literature 38: 332–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Statman, Meir. 2013. INVITED EDITORIAL COMMENT: Is Markowitz Wrong? Investment Lessons from the Financial Crisis. Journal of Portfolio Management 40: 8–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tasche, Dirk. 2006. Measuring sectoral diversification in an asymptotic multifactor framework. Journal of Credit Risk 2: 33–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tsanakas, Andreas, and Evangelia Desli. 2003. Risk measures and theories of choice. British Actuarial Journal 9: 959–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Vermorken, Maximilian A., Francesca R. Medda, and Thomas Schröder. 2012. The diversification delta: A higher-moment measure for portfolio diversification. Journal of Portfolio Management 39: 67–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Willenbrock, Scott. 2011. Diversification return, portfolio rebalancing, and the commodity return puzzle. Financial Analysts Journal 67: 42–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wright, Randall. 1987. Expectation dependence of random variables, with an application in portfolio theory. Theory and Decision 22: 111–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yaari, Menahem E. 1987. The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 55: 95–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zheng, Buhong. 1997. Aggregate poverty measures. Journal of Economic Surveys 11: 123–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Koumou, G.B.; Dionne, G. Coherent Diversification Measures in Portfolio Theory: An Axiomatic Foundation. Risks 2022, 10, 205. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110205
Koumou GB, Dionne G. Coherent Diversification Measures in Portfolio Theory: An Axiomatic Foundation. Risks. 2022; 10(11):205. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110205
Chicago/Turabian StyleKoumou, Gilles Boevi, and Georges Dionne. 2022. "Coherent Diversification Measures in Portfolio Theory: An Axiomatic Foundation" Risks 10, no. 11: 205. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110205
APA StyleKoumou, G. B., & Dionne, G. (2022). Coherent Diversification Measures in Portfolio Theory: An Axiomatic Foundation. Risks, 10(11), 205. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110205